peter whiteford, social policy research centre, university of new south wales

46
Welfare state design: Architecture and outcomes - the New Zealand benefit system in comparative perspective Welfare Working Group Forum, Victoria University of Wellington, 9-10 June 2010 Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales [email protected] 1

Upload: simone

Post on 21-Jan-2016

18 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Welfare state design: Architecture and outcomes - the New Zealand benefit system in comparative perspective Welfare Working Group Forum, Victoria University of Wellington, 9-10 June 2010. Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales [email protected]. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Welfare state design: Architecture and outcomes - the New Zealand benefit system in comparative perspectiveWelfare Working Group Forum, Victoria University of Wellington, 9-10 June 2010

Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

[email protected]

1

Page 2: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

2

Outline Nature and limitations of the approach The design of benefit systems Targeting, progressivity and redistribution How New Zealand compares – particularly to

Australia Summary and some conclusions

Sources and additional material

Page 3: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

3

Caveats and limitations Approach is descriptive and based on statistical calculations. Most analysis is static. The counterfactual effectively assumes that the welfare state has had no

incentive effects, or at least is the same in all countries. Some welfare state features treated as if they are produced by market

mechanisms (e.g. minimum wages). Does not include non-cash benefits (health care, education, social housing,

child care); indirect taxes – VAT, employer social security contributions also not included.

Employer social security contributions are paid by businesses direct to government and do not pass through the household sector. Particularly problematic as they are one of main sources of funding for the welfare state.

Employer provided fringe benefits not included. The distribution of wealth, including owner-occupied housing makes a

difference.

Page 4: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

A framework for assessing social protection Many analyses focus only on government provided social protection, but

this needs to be seen within a broad framework In addition to government cash benefits, assistance can be provided

through allowances or concessions in the tax system or through direct service provision. (e.g. child care).

The tax system can also offset or reinforce the objectives of social protection.

Occupational social welfare can be provided on a voluntary or mandatory basis.

In New Zealand and Australia, labour force regulation has a long history – since the 19th century.

Private social welfare can be provided by churches, NGOs, family and friends or purchased in the market (insurance).

4

Page 5: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Social security design The New Zealand and the Australian social security systems differ from

those in most other countries In Europe, the United States and Japan, most government benefits are

financed by contributions from employers and insured employees, and benefits are often related to past earnings, so that higher income workers receive higher absolute levels of benefits if they become unemployed or incapacitated or when they retire.

In contrast, in New Zealand and Australia, most government benefits are flat-rate entitlements financed from general government revenue, and there are no explicit social security taxes.

In addition, in both countries – but more so in Australia – most benefits are income-tested or asset-tested, so that entitlements reduce as resources increase.

Because these systems are not contributory, eligibility is based on residence and coverage of the population is broad.

Duration of payment receipt is not time limited, with income support payments being paid indefinitely subject to the continued meeting of eligibility criteria.

5

Page 6: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Social security design Because the New Zealand and Australian systems are income-tested and

not contributory, there is a tendency for overseas commentators to see them as residual, rather like vast forms of social assistance. This view is mistaken.

Benefits are legal entitlements and there is very limited discretion in the system, and recipients have the right to appeal to administrative and judicial tribunals in case of disagreements about administrative decisions.

The social security system is also a national system, with entitlements and conditions being uniform across the country. While income support payments are means-tested, these assets tests are much more generous than those typically applying in social assistance schemes in other countries.

In a sense, the New Zealand and Australian systems are hybrids falling between a social insurance system and a social assistance system, being less “generous” than some social insurance systems, but more “generous” than most social assistance systems.

6

Page 7: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Who benefits under different welfare states?

A “pure” social insurance system is status maintaining – contributors get out what they have put in, and you have to be a contributor to benefit.

On average, social insurance systems are more expensive and therefore appear more “generous”, but this can be generosity to the middle classes and the well-off.

Universal and income-tested schemes are therefore likely to be relatively more generous to the lifetime poor and to those who have not contributed or been able to contribute to social insurance schemes, particularly young people, women and migrants.

However, one of the central issues in the literature is that more encompassing welfare states provide higher levels of benefits because the middle class have a stake in the system.

Does targeting undercut political support for generosity to the poor?

Page 8: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Incentives – general considerations Different forms of assistance and financing have different implications

for incentives: Contributory systems may enhance incentives to participate in the labour

market Paid maternity/parental leave with right to return to work promotes labour force attachment, but

if parental leave is too long (> 6 months) may be associated with loss of earnings potential.

Child care support encourages employment, particularly if targeted to employed families or those looking for work;

Family allowances likely to have a small income effect, discouraging employment;

More generous, joint income-tested payments for the low paid likely to have stronger work disincentives;

Family-based taxation likely to discourage employment of second earners; Practically all OECD countries have income-tested payments for low income

families, which dominate the effects of the tax unit. Generous income support for the non-employed may act as work

disincentive, unless associated with active job search requirements; Generosity needs to take account of ease of access and potential duration of

benefits, not just benefit levels. Specific eligibility conditions are important, e.g. Early retirement

provisions Expectations are likely to be important.

Page 9: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

9

Types of redistribution in social security systems The design features of social protection differ in important respects - two of the

most important features relate to the funding – i.e. the different ways in which programmes are financed – and structure of benefits – i.e. the relationship between benefits received and the past or current income of beneficiaries.

Redistribution can be between rich and poor (Robin Hood) or across the lifecycle (the piggy bank) – risk insurance (against unemployment, disability, sickness etc.), savings (for retirement).

All welfare states are a mix of the two, but the mix varies. Other types of redistribution – notably between men and women and also across

regions. Behavioural effects may undercut redistribution; private provision also redistributes

across the lifecycle. Point in time, static analysis implicitly treats all measured redistribution as if it were

between rich and poor. Taking account of redistribution across the life course, the level of redistribution

between rich and poor is less than it appears, but is still strongly associated with progressivity of benefit structure.

Page 10: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Targeting, progressivity and redistribution Targeting is a means of determining either eligibility for benefits or the level

of entitlements for those eligible. In a sense, all benefit systems – apart from a universal “basic income” or “guaranteed minimum income” scheme – are targeted to specific categories of people, such as the unemployed, people with disabilities or those over retirement age. Income and asset-testing is a further form of targeting that can be applied once people satisfy categorical eligibility criteria.

Progressivity refers to the profile of benefits when compared to market or disposable incomes – how large a share of benefits is received by different income groups – e.g. do the poor receive more than the rich from the transfer system?

Redistribution refers to the outcomes of different tax and benefit systems – how much does the benefit system actually change the distribution of household income?

Effectiveness measured by how much redistribution is achieved; efficiency by the resources used to achieve this redistribution.

10

Page 11: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

New Zealand’s distinctive tax/benefit system Total NZ spending on social protection (cash benefits, health care, social services) at

18.5% of GDP in 2005 was about 90% of the OECD average – but this is mainly due to lower than average spending on age pensions; health and disability spending are a little higher than average and cash benefits for people of working age about 20% higher; spending on non-health services about 2/3rds of average. (Australia spent 17.1% of GDP.)

Direct taxation paid by benefit recipients is higher than average, but indirect taxation of benefits is a little lower – in Australia direct and indirect taxes on benefits are amongst the lowest in the OECD .

NZ tax expenditures are very low. Australian pension tax expenditures are the highest in the OECD, but other tax expenditures below average.

Mandatory private social benefits are very low in New Zealand, but in Australia (sick pay and superannuation) they are amongst highest.

Thus, net expenditure – after direct and indirect taxes paid on benefits – is even closer to average – and tax expenditures and mandatory private social expenditure increase Australia’s ranking but reduce New Zealand’s ranking.

Net total social expenditure is 16.4% of GDP in New Zealand, but 19.3% of GDP in Australia – the rankings are reversed (in addition, Denmark falls from 26.9% of GDP to 21.6%, while USA rises from 15.9 to 25.3% of GDP).

To assess distributional impacts it is necessary to look at all components of the system together – ideally.

11

Page 12: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Australia and New Zealand rely on income-testing more than any other OECD countries% of GDP spent on income-tested benefits, 2005

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

12

Page 13: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

13

Australia and New Zealand have the most progressive benefit systems in the OECDRatio of benefits received by poorest quintile to benefits received by richest quintile, total population, 2005

Page 14: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

14

Progressivity of transfers, 2005Concentration coefficient of transfers

-0.5

-0.4

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

Page 15: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Australia and New Zealand have low levels of churningChurning as % of equivalent household disposable income

15

Page 16: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

The progressivity of direct taxes is highest in the English speaking countries and lowest in the Nordic countriesConcentration coefficient for direct taxes around 2005

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

16

Page 17: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

17

Direct taxes on public transfers% of public social benefits paid in direct taxes

Page 18: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

18

Indirect taxes on public transfers Implicit average indirect tax rate (%)

Page 19: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

OUTCOMES

19

Page 20: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

20

Levels of inequality, OECD countries, 2005Gini coefficient for disposable income

Page 21: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Income poverty rates and poverty gaps

In most international comparisons, income poverty is measured by reference to median household income “after” taxes and benefits, adjusted by household size (either 40, 50 or 60%).

The poverty rate or headcount is the % of the population with incomes below the benchmark; the poverty gap is the difference between the average income of the poor and the benchmark – a measure of distance (and possibly exclusion?).

Household surveys do not include many of the most disadvantaged – people who are homeless, in nursing homes, boarding houses or in prison (about 2% of the Australian population).

Measured at 50% of median income, New Zealand is almost exactly at the OECD average, with the equal lowest poverty rate among the population aged 65 years and over in the OECD (2%). Poverty among the working age population is a little higher than average (11% compared to 9%), and child poverty is higher (15% compared to 12%)

Australia has more people between 40% and 50% of median income than any other OECD country. Using a 50% of median income poverty line, the poverty gap is the 6 th lowest in the OECD and a little lower than in Denmark. So Australia has a relatively high share of the population in poverty, but close to the poverty line.

New Zealand has more households between 50% and 60% of median income than any other OECD country. At 60% of median income, New Zealand has the fifth highest poverty rate in the OECD. The poverty gap is the 8th highest in the OECD.

21

Page 22: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

22

Poverty gap and composite measure of income poverty, mid-2000s

Page 23: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

23

Benefit recipiency in New Zealand is below average% of working age population in receipt of income replacement benefits, full-time equivalents, 2004

Page 24: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

24

Reliance on benefits has increased, most rapidly in New Zealand (from a low base)% of working age population in receipt of income replacement benefits, full-time equivalents, 1980 and 2004

Page 25: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Relative to their high overall employment, the UK and Australia do worst for joblessness among families with children – with New Zealand not far behind

Percentage point difference between actual and predicted joblessness among families with children

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

Italy

Gre

ece

Bel

gium

Spa

inLu

xem

bour

gP

olan

dJa

pan

Por

tuga

lF

ranc

eA

ustri

aF

inla

ndO

EC

DIr

elan

dC

anad

a

US

AS

wed

enC

zech

Den

mar

kG

erm

any

Net

herla

nds

New

Zea

land

Nor

way

Aus

tralia

Uni

ted

Kin

gdom

Page 26: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Reduction in inequality due to public cash transfers and household taxes Point reduction in the concentration coefficient

Page 27: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Australia is the most efficient country in the OECD in reducing povertyPoint change in mean poverty gap per unit of transfer spending

0

0.005

0.01

0.015

0.02

0.025

0.03

0.035

0.04

27

Page 28: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

28

Net redistribution to the poorNet transfers received by poorest quintile as % of household disposable income

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Page 29: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Summary

New Zealand relies on income testing more than any other OECD country except Australia, and has one of the most progressive structure of benefits of all OECD countries.

New Zealand has lower churning than most other OECD countries, and the third highest level of transfer efficiency in reducing poverty.

Australia (and Ireland) prove to be nearly as effective in reducing inequality as the Nordic countries, while New Zealand is above average in reducing inequality.

But these are measures of programme efficiency, not economic efficiency. Efficiency is a means to an end – the goal is more effectiveness.

29

Page 30: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Conclusions The broad architecture of the New Zealand system has

considerable strengths. Broadly speaking, in looking at reform options you can consider

refurbishment and modernisation, or demolition and rebuilding. Despite impressive design features of tax and transfer systems,

disposable income inequality in New Zealand is above the OECD average; this means that income inequality before taxes and transfers is higher than in most countries with better inequality outcomes.

If New Zealand wants to be more effective it could either increase its high level of progressivity, or tax and spend more while at least maintaining effective progressivity, or identify the factors associated with its relatively high level of market income inequality and address these problems more directly.

30

Page 31: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

ADDITIONAL MATERIAL

31

Page 32: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Australia has the most progressive direct taxes on retirement age households – New Zealand the least progressiveConcentration coefficient for direct taxes on retirement age households

32

Page 33: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

33

Effective contributions to public pensions, redistributive and actuarial components, mid-1990s% of wages

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

Effective tax Contribution

Page 34: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

34

Net incomes of social assistance recipients, 2005% of median equivalent household income, with and without housing benefits

Lone parent, two children

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

ITA TUR GRC USA CHE ESP SWE HUN PRT FIN FRA DEU CAN IRL LUX NLD AUT GBR BEL POL CZE NZL JPN DNK NOR AUS

Page 35: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Effective tax rates for parents seeking part-time work are lower in Australia than most other countriesAETR from zero to 33% APW, 2004

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

Italy

Gre

ece

Uni

ted

Sta

tes

Aus

tralia

Fra

nce

Irel

and

Uni

ted

Kin

gdom

Nor

way

Por

tuga

lC

anad

aN

ew Z

eala

ndK

orea

Pol

and

Hun

gary

OE

CD

Fin

land

Luxe

mbo

urg

Slo

vak

Rep

ublic

Japa

nS

wed

enG

erm

any

Bel

gium

Den

mar

kC

zech

Rep

ublic

Spa

inA

ustri

aN

ethe

rland

sS

witz

erla

nd

Page 36: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Effective tax rates can be high for parents seeking full-time work, but are lower in Australia than most other countriesAETR from zero to 67% APW, 2004

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

Gre

ece

Uni

ted

Sta

tes

Hun

gary

Can

ada

Aus

tralia

Slo

vak

Rep

ublic

Irel

and

Kor

eaO

EC

DN

orw

ayS

wed

enP

olan

dP

ortu

gal

Cze

ch r

epub

licF

inla

ndJa

pan

Uni

ted

Kin

gdom

Luxe

mbo

urg

Aus

tria

Bel

gium

Icel

and

Net

herla

nds

New

Zea

land

Ger

man

yD

enm

ark

Sw

itzer

land

Fra

nce

Page 37: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Child care costs can increase effective tax ratesAETR from zero to 67% APW, plus child care costs, 2004

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

Gre

ece

Hun

gary

Uni

ted

Sta

tes

Nor

wa

yA

ustr

alia

Por

tug

alS

we

den

Pol

and

Slo

vak

Rep

ubl

icK

orea

Fin

land

Bel

giu

mLu

xem

bou

rgO

EC

DA

ustr

iaN

ethe

rland

sJa

pan

Cze

ch re

pub

licIc

elan

dG

erm

any

New

Zea

land

Den

mar

kF

ranc

eC

anad

aU

nite

d K

ingd

omS

witz

erla

nd

Irel

and

Page 38: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Effective marginal tax rates can be high in Australia but over specific income ranges

38

Page 39: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

In contrast, the Nordic approach has much higher EMTRs at lower income levels

39

Page 40: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Social insurance does not necessarily reduce EMTRs (for lone parents and single people)

40

Page 41: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Why are we interested in the design of benefit systems?

“The tax-transfer system is the principal means of expressing societal choices about equity. The tax-transfer system is a reflection of the kind of society we aspire to be.” Ken Henry, ACOSS National Conference, (2009).

41

Page 42: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Working-age recipients of selected social security payments, Australia, 2005

42

Page 43: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Trends in receipt of government benefits, 1978-79 to 2007-08% of households whose principal income source is government benefits

43

Page 44: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Household reliance on income support, 1994-95 to 2007-08

44

Page 45: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

Inequality of earnings among households of working age, 2005Gini coefficients for different earnings measures

45

Page 46: Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales

46

Sources OECD Family database -

www.oecd.org/els/social/family/database OECD Social Expenditure database -

http://www.oecd.org/document/2/0,2340,en_2649_33933_31612994_1_1_1_1,00.html

Net Social Expenditure – Adema and Ladaique (2005) - http://www.oecd.org/findDocument/0,2350,en_2649_33933_1_119684_1_1_1,00.html

OECD, Benefits and Wages -http://www.oecd.org/department/0,2688,en_2649_34633_1_1_1_1_1,00.html

OECD study of income distribution (2005) - http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/48/9/34483698.pdf

Benefit recipiency - Employment Outlook (2003) OECD Social Indicators -

http://www.oecd.org/department/0,2688,en_2649_34637_1_1_1_1_1,00.html