patriarchy, power, and pay: the transformation of american

59
†Correspondence should be directed to: Steve Ruggles University of Minnesota, 50 Willey Hall, 225 19th Ave S., Minneapolis, MN 55455 e-mail: [email protected], phone: 612-624-5818, fax:612-626-8375 Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American Families, 1800–2015 Steven Ruggles † Regents Professor, History Director, Minnesota Population Center University of Minnesota September 2015 Working Paper No. 2015-3

Upload: hangoc

Post on 02-Jan-2017

230 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

†Correspondence should be directed to: Steve Ruggles University of Minnesota, 50 Willey Hall, 225 19th Ave S., Minneapolis, MN 55455 e-mail: [email protected], phone: 612-624-5818, fax:612-626-8375

Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American Families, 1800–2015

Steven Ruggles † Regents Professor, History

Director, Minnesota Population Center University of Minnesota

September 2015

Working Paper No. 2015-3

Page 2: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

Abstract

This article proposes explanations for the transformation of American families over the

past two centuries. I describe the impact on families of the rise of male wage labor

beginning in the nineteenth century and the rise of female wage labor in the twentieth

century. I then examine the effects of decline in wage labor opportunities for young men

and women during the past four decades. I present new estimates of a precipitous decline

in the relative income of young men and assess its implications for the decline for

marriage. Finally, I discuss explanations for the deterioration of economic opportunity and

speculate on the impact of technological change on the future of work and families.

Page 3: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

1

Introduction

Before the nineteenth century, most families were organized according to patriarchal

tradition. Household heads owned and controlled the means of production, and their wives

and children were obliged to provide the unpaid labor needed to sustain family enterprises.

Masters of the household had a legal right to command the obedience of their wives and

children—as well as any servants or slaves—and to use corporal punishment to correct

disobedience (Coontz 2005; Cott 2009; Hartog 2000; Mintz and Kellogg 1988; Shammas

2002; Siegel 1996; Stanley 2002). Over the past two centuries, this patriarchal family

system collapsed, as household heads lost control over their sons, wives, and servants.

<Figure 1 about here>

The waning of patriarchy was accompanied by a shift toward simpler and more

unstable family structures. Intergenerational coresidence, once a standard phase of the life

course, is now rare (Ruggles 1994, 2007). As shown in Fig. 1, in the mid-nineteenth

century, 74 % of persons aged 65 or older resided in multigenerational families.

Coresidence declined continuously from 1850 to 1990, reaching a low point of 18 % before

recovering slightly during the past few decades.1 After the Civil War, divorce rates began

to climb. Except for a temporary spike at the end of World War II, divorce has increased

almost continuously for 150 years. New estimates controlling for age composition

1 Except where otherwise specified, statistics in this article derive from the Integrated

Public Use Microdata Series (Flood et al. 2015; Ruggles et al. 2015). In many cases, the

analyses also appear in Ruggles (forthcoming), which includes additional documentation of

sources and methods.

Page 4: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

2

presented in Fig. 2 show that the standardized divorce rate leveled off only briefly in the

early 1980s and has climbed rapidly since (Kennedy and Ruggles 2014).

<Figure 2 about here>

In the past half-century, the long-run trend toward atomization of families has

accelerated. A broad retreat from marriage began after 1960. It is likely that about one-

third of persons now in their early 20s will never marry, and this trend shows no sign of

slowing (Martin et al. 2014; Ruggles forthcoming).2 This is unprecedented; as shown in

Fig. 3, among all prior cohorts, at least 90 % of women married. Cohabitation is growing

rapidly, and cohabiting unions are more unstable than marriages (Kennedy and Bumpass

2008; Kennedy and Ruggles 2015). Increasingly, however, young adults are forgoing

partners altogether. In 2014, 54 % of persons aged 25 to 29 had no coresiding partner of

any kind, up from 48 % in 2007 and about 23 % in 1970.3

<Figure 3 about here>

This article presents an interpretation of the transformations in American families

over the past two centuries. I argue that more than anything else, the changes in families

reflect changes in work. An upheaval in the economic organization of families had

2 Martin et al. (2014) projected that assuming current marriage rates remain unchanged,

31 % of women and 35 % of men born in 1990 will not have married by age 40.

3 The 2014 and 2007 estimates come from the Current Population Survey (CPS), adjusted

to account for group quarters (Flood et al. 2015). The 1970 estimate derives from the

census microdata, adjusted to account for cohabitation (Fitch et al. 2005).

Page 5: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

3

profound implications for gender and generational relations. The economic revolution was

responsible for revolutions in family composition, divorce, and marriage.4

I begin with a broad overview of changes in family economies over the past 200

years. I then describe the rise of male wage labor beginning in the nineteenth century and

the rise of female wage labor in the twentieth century, and examine the implications of

those changes for family relations. The second half of this article explores a decline in

wage labor opportunities for young men and women during the past four decades. I

present new estimates of the precipitous decline in the relative income of young men and

assess its implications for the decline of marriage. Finally, I discuss explanations for the

deterioration of economic opportunity and speculate on the impact of technological change

on the future of work and families.

Family Economies

For most of the nineteenth century, production was carried out by families. In 1800, three-

quarters of the workforce was engaged in agricultural work, and a majority of the

population lived on farms until 1850 (Ruggles et al. 2015; Weiss 1992). Farms could not

operate without family labor; all family members who were old enough contributed to farm

production. Among the one-quarter of the population who did not work on farms at the

beginning of the nineteenth century, most still made their living through the family

economy. Most nonfarm production was carried out by family businesses, with occupations

4 This analysis is confined to the United States because it is presently the only country with

a suitable long-run data series. Similar processes, however, occurred in Northern Europe

and now seem to be occurring in some East Asian and Latin American countries (Ruggles

2009; Stanfors and Goldscheider 2015).

Page 6: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

4

such as shopkeeper, shoemaker, tailor, physician, or tavern keeper. In most such

enterprises, the family resided on the same premises as the shop, and the whole family

worked for the business. Like farms, these family businesses were usually handed down

from generation to generation.

<Figure 4 about here>

Figure 4 describes the major transformations in the economic organization of

married-couple households over the past two centuries.5 In the nineteenth century,

corporate families predominated. I define corporate families to include all married couple

households with self-employed heads, except for those in which the wife had an

occupation outside the family business. Most corporate families were farm families. In

addition to kin, corporate families often included farmhands, servants, slaves, and

sometimes apprentices. Corporate families were in the majority throughout the nineteenth

century and remained important through the first half of the twentieth century.

Corporate families were replaced by male breadwinner families in the early

twentieth century. Male breadwinner families are defined as those in which the husband

works for wages or salary and the wife has no occupation listed in the census. By 1920,

the number of male-breadwinner families exceeded the number of corporate families, and

this percentage continued to grow until World War II. This change was driven by

expanding wage labor opportunities for men. The male breadwinner category represented

5 This graph was inspired by a similar illustration that appears in Stanfors and

Goldscheider (2015). The term “Corporate Family Economy” was coined by Ryan (1981),

and my characterization of change was informed by Mintz (1998).

Page 7: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

5

a majority of marriages for just four decades—from 1920 to 1960—reaching a peak of 57

% in 1940.

Male breadwinner families were replaced by dual-earner families in the mid-

twentieth century. In the early decades of the twentieth century, the number of married

women working for wages began to increase, and the pace of change accelerated in the

middle decades of the century. Dual-earner families have now predominated for almost a

half-century. Over the past several decades, female-breadwinner families—shown in the

top right of Fig. 4—have emerged as a significant new form, and they now account for one-

tenth of marriages.

The Rise of Male Wage Labor

How to keep boys on the farm and induce them cheerfully to choose

farming as their occupation for life is a question of deep interest to many

parents. The stampede of young men from the country to cities and large

towns is not an evil which finds its limit in the domestic circles which they

leave, but is one which extends through society and makes its depressing

influence felt everywhere. How to check this evil is a question of great

importance and is well worthy of consideration. (Read 1884:848) Corporate families predominated in the nineteenth century because before the

Industrial Revolution, people did not have many other options. The earliest data showing

the full male occupational distribution come from the 1850 census, when the

transformation of the economy as already well underway. As shown in Fig. 5, wage labor

jobs that paid enough to support a family were still scarce in 1850. At that time, about two-

thirds of men were self-employed farmers or proprietors, unpaid sons on farms or in family

businesses, or slaves. Another 15 % were unskilled workers, who were mostly farmhands:

wage laborers who were paid mainly in the form of room and board. Such laborers usually

did not get paid enough to get married. In 1850, the biggest groups of skilled workers and

Page 8: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

6

operatives were miners and sailors. They were paid better than farmhands, but they

worked in places where there were few women available to marry. If a young man wanted

to marry, his best prospect was still to inherit the family farm or business. Accordingly, in

most families, one child remained in the parental household under the control of the

patriarch, with the expectation of eventual succession.

<Figure 5 about here>

As the century progressed, new high-paying opportunities arose in factories. The

number of factory jobs grew 600 % between 1850 and 1900, and there were rapidly

expanding opportunities in clerical, sales, and professional occupations (Lebergott 1984).

The growth of well-paying wage labor jobs for men undermined the economic

underpinnings of patriarchal authority. As young men took jobs off the farm, they moved

away from home and out of the control of the patriarch. Figure 6 compares the percentage

of men in agriculture with the percentage of elderly residing in multigenerational families. A

generation after agricultural employment began to decline, multigenerational coresidence

followed suit.

<Figure 6 about here>

The decline of multigenerational families occurred mainly because of increasing

wage labor opportunities for the young (Ruggles 2003, 2007). When young men could

obtain well-paying employment for wages, they no longer had as much incentive to remain

at home under the control of their fathers. As wage earners grew old, the incentives for

intergenerational coresidence declined further. Under the wage labor system, patriarchs no

longer needed the labor that their sons and daughters once provided. Moreover, retired

wage earners could no longer offer the younger generation employment and eventual

inheritance of the family farm or business.

Page 9: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

7

A second major consequence of the rise of well-paying male jobs was a long-run

decline in marriage age, especially among men. Under the corporate family system, young

men had to wait until they either inherited a farm or built up sufficient resources to

establish an independent household. Under the wage labor system, men could achieve

high earnings early in life. As jobs paying good wages began to open up in the late

nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, men could increasingly afford to marry at an

earlier age. Accordingly, between 1890 and 1960, age at first marriage declined 3.6 years

among men and 2.2 years among women (Ruggles forthcoming).

The rise of male-breadwinner families empowered young men, but it did not do

much for women. Even though first-wave feminists obtained the vote in 1920, in most

respects, patriarchal gender norms remained firmly entrenched. In the mid-twentieth

century, women still could not get a bank account or a loan without their husband’s

signature, husbands had the right to determine where the family lived, and patriarchal

authority was still enforced through violence (Coontz 1992, 2005; May 1990).

In 1958, the New York Mirror—then the second-largest circulation newspaper in the

nation—featured man-in-the street interviews asking the question, “If a woman needs it,

should she be spanked?” All four of the men interviewed affirmed that the spanking of

wives was necessary to enforce discipline. Teddy Gallei, a parking lot attendant,

explained, “It teaches them who’s boss. A lot of women tend to forget this is a man’s

world.” William Davis, a toy factory owner, concurred: “Most of them have it coming to

them anyway. If they don’t it will remind them how well off they are . . . An ounce of

prevention is worth a pound of cure” (Aidala 1958a).

Page 10: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

8

The Rise of Female Wage Labor

Patriarchal control over women began to erode with the rise of female wage labor. Wage

labor opportunities for men were highly limited in the mid-nineteenth century, but the

opportunities for women were virtually nonexistent (Kessler-Harris 1982). Figure 7 shows

the occupational distribution for women since 1850.6 In the mid-nineteenth century, the

great majority of working women were unpaid workers in family enterprises, mostly farm

wives and daughters and slaves. The next largest category—unskilled workers—was

almost entirely domestic servants in 1850. The best jobs available for women were in

factories, which employed 1.3 % of women. The tiny professional and managerial

category—accounting for less than 1 % of adult women in the mid-nineteenth century—

consisted almost entirely of teachers. The growth of better-paying jobs for women began

around 1900 and expanded rapidly after WWII.

<Figure 7 about here>

The long-run pattern of women’s employment shown in Fig. 7 is U-shaped, and the

low point of the U was at the peak period for male-breadwinner families (Goldin 1995).

Although the great majority of women engaged in economically productive work in the

nineteenth century, that economic role did not afford them independence or power. In all

but a tiny fraction of cases, nineteenth-century women worked in corporate families under

the direction and control of their husbands, fathers, or masters.

6 The white space at the top—labeled “Not in the labor force”—identifies women without

identifiable economic activities, whose effort was probably devoted mainly to housework

and childcare. Housework and childcare clearly have economic value (Folbre and Nelson

2000), but do not enable economic independence.

Page 11: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

9

The twentieth-century rise of wage labor for women undermined the authority of

husbands and fathers. New economic opportunities enabled some women to delay or

forgo marriage, and the availability of paid work also provided a means of escape from bad

marriages. From 1880 to 1990, there was a strong spatiotemporal association between the

availability of jobs for women and the prevalence of divorce and separation (Ruggles

1997). In times and places where women had no means of subsistence outside corporate

families, they usually remained married even if they were unhappy.

<Figure 8 about here>

Figure 8 shows the wage labor participation rate for women aged 25–29, a group

old enough that few were still in school, but they were still of marrying age. By 1920, most

young single women had wage-paying jobs. The percentage of young married women with

such jobs grew gradually from 1900 until 1962 and then took off.

Before the 1950s, women generally left wage labor employment when they married,

partly because most employers barred married women from working for wages (Goldin

1991a). Despite the symbolic resonance of Rosie the Riveter, emergency work experience

during World War II had little impact on employment after the war (Goldin 1991b). Most

economic historians agree that the main reason for the sharp rise of married women’s

employment in the 1950s was the extraordinary demand for labor, which created pressure

to overcome institutional barriers to change. The economy heated up just as the marriage

boom reduced the supply of single women, so the rules against hiring married women

disappeared (Costa 2000; Cotter, Hermson, and Vanneman 2001; Goldin 1990;

Oppenheimer 1970).

As more and more married women began to work for wages, the balance of power

within marriages shifted. Many men and some women were alarmed by the rise of the

Page 12: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

10

dual-earner family. A second 1958 New York Mirror man-in-the-street interview asked, “Is

Father Losing his Place as Head of Family?” Charles Cogswell, a bank guard, responded:

Yes. Too many wives are getting independent. They go to work and begin

feeling they have more to say than the father. The old-fashioned way—when

father was THE boss—kept families happier. Not so many divorces,

separations, and juvenile delinquents, then.

Simon Golos, an attorney, agreed that there was a “confusion of authority” and “a gradual

usurpation of power by the lady of the house.” Two women were also queried by the

Mirror. Harriett Weisman, a housewife, agreed with Cogswell and Golos, but felt that the

decline in the power of the father was a good thing because the wife “copes with all the

family problems.” Only Mrs. Lillian Ciarvino—a housewife and secretary—disagreed,

saying that “a majority [of fathers] are still heads of their homes.” Even Ciarvino, however,

recognized that a fundamental change in gender relations was underway, but she saw it as

an issue of character: “The father who gives up his place as head is either weak or doesn’t

care to assume the responsibility.” (Aidala 1958b:27).

Attitudes

Attitudes toward married women’s work shifted rapidly during the 1970s. The evidence on

the timing of change suggests that the transformation of attitudes represented an

accommodation to the new reality of married women’s wage labor (Rindfuss et al. 1996).

Figure 9 compares the percentage of married women who were in the labor force with the

percentage of married women who disagreed with the idea that women should stay home.

In 1970, when the series of attitudinal surveys began, 44 % of wives were already in the

workforce, but less than 20 % of wives thought that women should work outside the home.

Among working wives in 1970, 70 % thought that it would be “much better for everyone

involved if the man is the achiever and the woman takes care of the home and family”

Page 13: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

11

(Westoff and Ryder n.d.). The great majority of working wives felt that wives ought to stay

at home. The cognitive dissonance between behavior and attitudes was soon resolved,

however. As married women flooded into the paid workforce, the stigma that had

surrounded married women’s participation in wage labor quickly disappeared. By 1980,

most married women approved of married women’s work (Smith et al. 2013).

<Figure 9 about here>

When behavior changes, attitudes adjust. As divorce became more common, for

example, it lost much of its stigma. This mechanism operates at the individual level; in a

study of divorce in the Detroit area between 1962 and 1977, Thornton (1985) found that

when people get divorced, they become much more accepting of divorce. Likewise, Axinn

and Thornton (1993) found that young people’s cohabitation experience in the Detroit Area

Study had dramatic effects on their approval of cohabitation, and also positively affected

their mothers’ approval of cohabitation.

Changing attitudes are a crucial part of the process of family change. There is a

feedback loop: as family attitudes shift, they allow still more family change (Axinn and

Thornton 2000). Changing attitudes can have especially powerful effects on family

behavior through their impact on institutional change (Bumpass 1990). Over the past 150

years, for example, shifting attitudes permitted progressive loosening of once-formidable

legal barriers to divorce (Cherlin 2009; Hartog 2000; May 1980; Mintz 1998). Similarly,

shifting attitudes helped eliminate legal barriers to contraception and abortion in the 1960s

and early 1970s (May 2010). Women’s control of their own fertility led to a marked decline

in unplanned pregnancies, which in turn contributed to delayed marriage and childbearing,

increased educational attainment among women, and rising female labor force

participation (Akerlof et al. 1996; Bailey 2006; Goldin and Katz 2002; Myers 2012). Thus,

Page 14: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

12

attitudinal change enables institutional change, which in turn affects family behavior. The

massive long-run changes in family behavior of the past 200 years could never have

occurred without fundamental changes in attitudes about family behavior.

We should not, however, view attitudinal change as the initial stimulus of family

change. For family change to occur, traditional values must be overcome. Attitudes are

ordinarily a barrier to change, not a cause of change: there must be a source of exogenous

pressure for people to reject the values with which they were raised. Between 1800 and

2000, that pressure was exerted by an economic revolution. The rise of wage labor, first

among men and then among women, catalyzed family change by disrupting traditional

patterns of authority. When families began to change, attitudes followed. The decline in

multigenerational families occurred a generation after the rise of wage labor for men. The

shift in attitudes about married women’s work outside the family occurred significantly after

the rapid ascent of married women’s wage labor. In both cases, rise of wage labor

undercut the economic control of the patriarch, shifting power from old to young and from

men to women.7

Change in the U.S. Census reflected the transformation of family relations. In 1970,

patriarchy was embedded in the census: the form asked each respondent to identify the

household head, just as it had for the 18 previous censuses. The household head was

always the man, and the spouse of the head was always the wife. Thanks to the

7 Some theorists argue the opposite, maintaining that that both family change and married

women’s employment resulted mainly from the rise of individualistic values (e.g.,

Lesthaeghe 1983, 2010; Van de Kaa 1987). I discuss this interpretation in Ruggles

(forthcoming).

Page 15: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

13

coordinated efforts of feminist social scientists, by 1980 the household head was

decapitated and replaced by the gender-neutral “householder” concept (Presser 1998).

Either husband or wife could be listed as the householder, and either could be listed as the

spouse of the householder (Ruggles and Brower 2003). Initially, all but a few respondents

maintained the traditional order of enumeration even though the rules had changed; in

1980, just 4 % of married householders were female. That percentage has grown steadily,

and by 2013, women represented 39 % of married householders (Ruggles et al. 2015).

The Decline of Marriage

The classification of family economies based on the economic activities of husbands and

wives—corporate, male breadwinner, and dual-earner—makes sense for the nineteenth

century and the first half of the twentieth century, when the great majority of households

were headed by a married couple. In recent decades, however, the dominance of the

married-couple household has receded, and it makes less and less sense to classify family

economies based on the economic activities of married couples. Figure 10 shows the

percentage of households without a married couple from 1850 to 2013. For the first 100

years, the percentage of households with no married couple grew slowly, from 16 % in

1850 to 21 % in 1950. After 1960, young people began delaying or forgoing marriage,

sometimes cohabiting but more often residing alone or with children but without a partner.

Simultaneously, remarriage rates dropped, and the growing divorced and widowed

populations increasingly opted for solitary residence. By 2012, the majority of households

no longer included a married couple.8

8 Rising cohabitation can account for less than one-fifth of this overall change; in 2013, 44

% of households included no couple at all, either married or cohabiting (Flood et al. 2015).

Page 16: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

14

<Figure 10 about here>

Structural factors are responsible for the boom and bust of marriage. As shown in

Fig. 11, age at first marriage declined steadily from 1890 to 1930 as well-paid male wage

earners acquired the means to marry earlier in life. The Great Depression led to a slight

uptick in marriage age between 1930 and 1940. After World War II, median age at

marriage fell sharply to about 20 for women and 22 for men in 1960. During the past half-

century, age at first marriage has increased rapidly, and today Americans are marrying at

later ages than ever before. The marriage boom of the postwar period was fueled by the

rapid expansion of men’s wages, and the decline of young men’s wages since 1975 is the

main reason for the retreat from marriage in that period (Carbone and Cahn 2014; Cherlin

2014; Oppenheimer 1988, 1994).

<Figure 11 about here>

The three decades after WWII were a golden age of wage labor for young men. The

availability of labor was sharply constrained: immigration had been restricted since 1924,

and fertility levels during the Great Depression were the lowest that had ever been

recorded, meaning the new cohorts entering the labor force were small. The “Lucky Few”

entering the labor force after the war saw a spectacular rise in wages (Carlson 2008).

Figure 12 shows the median wages for 25- to 29-year-old men and women in 2013 dollars.

The top panel shows the medians for full-time wage and salary workers; the lower panel is

the same, but includes the entire population aged 25–29, not just full-time wage earners.

Median income for full-time employed young men more than doubled in the postwar era, to

a peak of $48,500 in 1973. After that peak, young men’s wages declined 26 % to $36,000

Page 17: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

15

in 2013. Wages for full-time working women went up too, but not as rapidly. Women’s

wages peaked in 2004, but by 2013, they were lower than they were in 1973.9

<Figure 12 about here>

Focusing on median wages for full-time wage and salary workers understates the

decline in the earning power of young men. More and more young men are working part-

time, and a growing percentage are not working at all. As a result, if we look at all men

aged 25–29 shown in the lower panel of Fig. 12—not just the full-time wage earners—

median wages declined 44 %, from a peak of $41,000 in 1973 to just $23,000 in 2013.

Women do not register in the lower panel until 1968 because that was the first year that

more than one-half of 25- to 29-year-old women were in the wage labor force. The median

wages for all women age 25–29 peaked in 2001 and then fell 24 % over the next 12 years.

9 Figures 12–14 are inflated to 2013 dollars using the Consumer Price Index Research

Series (CPI-U-RS), which was designed to address concerns that the standard Consumer

Price Index for all urban consumers (CPI-U) exaggerates inflation, especially in the late

1970s (Stewart and Reed 1999). If I had instead used CPI-U, the decline in young men’s

wages would have been even greater (32 % for full-time workers and 48 % for all men

aged 25–29). Both CPI series, however, may actually understate inflation as experienced

by young adults in the 1970s and 1980s: young adults spent a high proportion of their

income on rent; and before 1987, the CPI seriously understated rent inflation (Crone et al.

2006; Gordon and Van Goethem 2007). CPI-U-RS is available only for the period from

1978 to the present; to inflate the earlier years, I calculated the ratio of CPI-U-RS to CPI-U

in 1978, and used it to adjust the CPI-U from 1940 to 1977.

Page 18: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

16

Young men’s wages have been dropping rapidly for four decades. By comparison,

during the Great Depression, wages declined for just a few years before they started

heading back up. No such sustained decline in wages has previously occurred in the

United States. The sharp decline of young men’s wages provided strong incentives for

married women to enter the workforce even after opportunities for women stagnated in the

mid-1970s: for many couples, two incomes were essential for economic survival (Bianchi

1995; Oppenheimer 1994).

Easterlin (1966, 1987) argued that the salient threshold in marriage decisions is not

the absolute level of income but relative income, defined as the income of young men

relative to expectations they formed in their parental home. Figure 13 provides a simple

measure of relative income: income of young men relative to the income of men of about

the same age a generation before. This number is calculated as the ratio of median total

income of all men aged 25–29 to the median total income for the same age group 30 years

earlier, when their fathers were approximately aged 25–29.10 The horizontal line at 100 in

Fig. 13 shows the point at which the older and younger generations made the same

amount. In 1961, young men were making four times what their fathers had made at about

the same age. For the past three decades, the younger generation has consistently done

10 Median generation length for men ranged from 27.8 in 1970 to 32.2 in 2013 (Ruggles et

al. 2015). To estimate incomes before 1939, I assumed that annual changes in income for

young men were proportional to annual changes in the mean income of the bottom 90 % of

the population excluding capital gains, as estimated by Alvaredo et al. (2015). Accordingly,

the early decades shown in Fig. 13 should be viewed as approximate.

Page 19: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

17

worse than their fathers. Overall, generational relative income dropped a stunning 80 %

since its peak in 1958.

<Figure 13 about here>

We can also assess income of the young relative to the income of the affluent.

Figure 14 compares the median income of young men with the average income of the top

1 % of the population. This measure peaked in 1970, when 25- to 29-year-old men were

making about 12 % as much as the average income of the nation’s elite; by 2013, this

statistic was down to just 2.6 %.

<Figure 14 about here>

Both of these measures of relative income fit the timing of the marriage boom well.

In the 1950s and 1960s, when young men were doing exceptionally well in terms of

relative income, marriage age was exceptionally young. For the past four decades, relative

income has declined sharply, and marriage age has been rising at a record pace.

How much family change since 1960 can be explained by the drop in the relative

income of young men? To address that question, I carried out a demographic

decomposition, following the Das Gupta (1978) framework.11 The dependent variable is

the percentage of 25- to 29-year-old men who were currently married, with spouse

present, between 1960 and 2013. This measure went from about 75 % of young men living

with a spouse in 1960 down to 24 % in 2013—a drop of 50 percentage points. This

dramatic change mainly reflects decisions to delay or forgo marriage, but it also is affected

by the rise of divorce and separation and the decline of remarriage.

11 The analysis used the open-source DECOMP software (Ruggles 1989).

Page 20: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

18

In the decomposition exercise, I analyzed four components of change, described in

Table 1. The left two columns show the percentage of men aged 25–29 who were married

in each category of each component. Foreign-born young men are excluded because the

relative income measure is not valid for them.

<Table 1 about here>

The first component is relative income, defined as the income of men aged 25–29

divided by the median income of men the same age 30 years earlier. I pooled the 1960

and 2013 data sets, calculated relative income as a percentile, and classified each case

into deciles of the combined data set. As shown in the left two columns of Table 1, there

was a close linear association between decile of relative income and marriage in both

periods, with more than four times as much marriage in the highest decile as in the lowest.

The right two columns describe the sea change in the distribution of relative income during

the past half-century.

The second component is occupation.12 In both periods, the men with craft

occupations were most often married. These jobs—carpenters, machinists, mechanics,

painters, and plumbers—have declined dramatically since 1960. The occupational groups

least often married in both periods were the service workers and laborers, and their

frequency has almost doubled.

The third component is employment characteristics, combining information on class

of worker and employment status. Self-employed young men were disproportionately likely

12 The occupational classification is based on the first digit of the OCC1950 variable in

IPUMS; the decomposition categories correspond to OCC1950 codes 0–99; 100–399;

400–499; 500–599; 600–699; and 700–970 (Ruggles et al. 2015).

Page 21: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

19

to be married in both years, possibly because self-employment is still often a family

enterprise. These jobs were already uncommon for young men in 1960, and by 2013, they

were rare. Wage labor also declined substantially, and the percentage of young men not in

the labor force—who usually were not married even in 1960—increased dramatically.

The final component is educational attainment. The relationship of education to

marriage has shifted substantially (Torr 2011). In 1960, high school graduates were more

often married than any other group, and those with education beyond college were the

least married. By 2013, the relationship between educational attainment and marriage was

strong and positive.

The decomposition shows the amount of change in marriage between 1960 and

2013 that can be attributed to compositional changes in each component. It is based on a

cross-classification of the percentage married for each combination of the four components

in each census year, a matrix of 2,240 cells. For each component, the analysis yields a

composition effect representing how much of the change is attributable to changes in the

distribution of that component, net of other components. The rate effect is the change in

marriage that is unaccounted for by changes in all four components (Das Gupta 1978).

The results appear in Table 2. The total change in the crude percentage of 25- to

29-year-old men married was 50.3, reflecting the drop from 74.5 % married to 24.2 %

married. The compositional effects for each component indicate how much of the change

would disappear if the socioeconomic composition of the young adult population had not

changed. The right column expresses the effects of each component as a percentage of

total change.

<Table 2 about here>

Page 22: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

20

The first component—relative income—is the important one. If that distribution is

held constant over time, 40.6 % of the change disappears. Each of the other components

explains about 5 % of the change. Summing them, this simple analysis of four economic

components can account for 54 % of the overall decline in marriage.

This analysis omits many aspects of relative economic circumstances. For example,

we know that job insecurity has been increasing (Kalleberg 2011), but the decomposition

cannot capture that. We have information about current income and occupation, but

nothing about the perceived future prospects of workers, which must be less bright for

young men than they were 50 years ago. The census cannot tell whether young people

are optimistic about their prospects or whether their jobs are insecure. Moreover, the

decomposition analysis also does not account for the stagnating prospects of women

during this period. Thus, the real impact of declining economic opportunity is probably

even bigger than this decomposition suggests. The evidence therefore suggests that

Easterlin was broadly right about relative income: the decline of marriage since 1960 can

be largely explained by the deteriorating circumstances of young men compared with the

previous generation.13

13 I conducted a series of decompositions using a similar approach to assess the

difference in the percentage married between black and white men. The results suggest

that at least one-half of race differences in marriage in the 1960–2013 period can be

ascribed to race differences in the economic characteristics of young men, lending further

support to a structural interpretation (e.g., Wilson and Neckerman 1987).

Page 23: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

21

The Decline of Wage Labor

Easterlin (1978, 1987) argued that the decline in relative wages for young men resulted

from generational competition. Figure 15 recreates the key graph from his 1978

Presidential Address to the Population Association of America, showing the number of

men aged 15–29 as a percentage of the number of men aged 30–64. Easterlin argued that

young men’s job prospects depended above all on how many of them were competing for

those jobs. Thus, he argued, the huge boom in relative income after WWII occurred

because young men were in short supply. As the Baby Boomers came of age, the number

of young men entering the labor force exploded. With the abundance of workers, the

golden age of postwar labor came to a screeching halt.

<Figure 15 about here>

Easterlin’s 1978 address came just after the peak of his graph. He could see that

generational competition was going to drop just as quickly as it had risen. Accordingly, he

predicted that a second golden age for young men’s employment was just around the

corner. By 1984, he argued, wages would be up, relative income would recover, marriage

age would decline sharply, and there would be a new baby boom.

As it turned out, the second golden age did not materialize. Despite the smaller

cohorts entering the job market after 1978, men’s wages continued to decline. One factor

was doubtless the mass entry of married women into the labor force, which partly

compensated for the smaller size of the new cohorts. Political change also affected youth

opportunities. Ronald Reagan was elected President in 1980, and America shifted to the

right. The fading of labor unions, decline in the minimum wage, globalization, outsourcing,

and stagnation of educational attainment all contributed to the dramatic decline of wages

Page 24: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

22

for young men entering the labor force and the long stagnation of wages for young women

(Massey 1996; Piketty 2014; Stiglitz 2012; Weil 2014; Goldin and Katz 2010).

The largest source of decline of economic opportunity for young people, especially

over the past two decades and in future decades, may be the automation of both

manufacturing and services made possible by new technologies. The world’s computing

capacity is doubling every 18 months (Hilbert and Lopez 2011). Because of innovations in

artificial intelligence and sensing technology, robots are becoming increasingly flexible and

easier to train, and their cost is dropping rapidly (Brynjolfsson and McAfee 2014). New

technologies have eliminated millions of jobs over the past several decades, and they are

on the verge of eliminating many more (Frey and Osborne 2013).

From the late eighteenth century to the late twentieth century, technological

innovation created more jobs than it destroyed. Indeed, the rise of wage labor—the driving

force of family change—was a direct consequence of technological innovation. When

Henry Ford introduced the moving automobile assembly line in 1914, it doubled

productivity (Ford and Crowther 1922). The assembly line threw a few carriage makers out

of work as people shifted to cars, but overall employment surged. With prices declining

steadily, car sales exploded. Employment at Ford’s Detroit area plants went from 14,000 in

1914 to 100,000 by 1926 (Ford and Crowther 1922; Segal 2005). There were also

hundreds of thousands of new jobs in automobile sales and service stations. This is a

perfect example of creative destruction, and similar processes occurred again and again

over the course of more than a century.

Today, mechanization seldom adds more jobs than it eliminates. Manufacturing

employment in the United States peaked in 1979 and declined 37 % over the next four

decades (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics 2015); during the same period, manufacturing

Page 25: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

23

output more than doubled (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 2015).

These trends are not confined to the United States. Owing to productivity improvements,

employment in manufacturing is falling in most manufacturing countries, and worldwide

manufacturing employment is probably declining (Levinson 2015).

The rise of intelligent machines is also eliminating service jobs. Travel agents,

insurance agents, parking lot attendants, warehouse workers, and checkout clerks are

being replaced by machines. Within the next few decades, driving will be automated (IEEE

2014). This will eliminate some 7 million working-class jobs—from taxi drivers to truck

drivers—employing about 5 % of the nation’s workforce. Frey and Osborne (2013)

estimated that about one-half of the U.S. workforce is employed in jobs that are at high risk

of automation within the next decade or two, and another one-fifth have a moderate risk of

automation. They judged that only about one-third of jobs are reasonably safe. Eventually,

perhaps, just a few percent of the population may be sufficient to produce all the goods

and services society needs.

Figure 16 shows the percentage of men and women aged 18–64 who were

employed for wages since 1800, with extrapolations into the future. Male wage work went

up for 170 years, from 13 % in 1800 to a peak of 75 % in 1970. For the past four decades,

the percentage has declined, to 64 % by 2013.14 This decline is unprecedented. Suppose

14 Among the 36 % of working-age men who did not work for wages in 2013, 10 % were

enrolled in school or college; 11 % were in institutions; 15 % were unemployed; 24 % were

self-employed (down from 42 % in 1970); and 40 % were not in school, not employed, not

institutionalized, and not looking for a job (Ruggles et al. 2015).

Page 26: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

24

that current trends were to continue. The dashed line for men in Fig.16 is simply a linear

extrapolation of the current trend, which has been roughly the same for four decades. If the

decline of male wage employment were to continue at the same pace over the next four

decades, only 44 % working-age men would have wage jobs by 2050.

<Figure 16 about here>

Among women, wage labor peaked in 2000. So far, the decline in wage labor has

been slower for women than for men. Because male wage work is declining so rapidly,

female wage employment will almost certainly exceed that of men within a few years. This

is partly because young women entering the labor force are increasingly better educated

than are young men (Goldin et al. 2006). In the long run, however, the disappearance of

jobs will affect women as well as men, and women’s employment will likely follow the same

trajectory. If current trends continue, however, only 56 % of working-age women will work

for wages by 2050.

For centuries, observers have been making dystopian predictions that technological

innovation would create massive unemployment and inequality, predictions that proved to

be false or at least premature (Mokyr et al. 2015). Is this time different? The past four

decades of decline in the relative income of the young might be only a temporary setback.

Easterlin could yet prove prescient: dramatic fertility decline across much of the globe is

creating very small cohorts, which might finally improve the prospects of young workers.

Perhaps some new technological innovation, as yet unimagined, will increase rather than

reduce the need for labor. It is equally possible, however, that the opportunities are not

coming back, and that we are witnessing the beginning of the end of the era of wage labor.

Page 27: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

25

Wage Labor and Families

For thousands of years, corporate families provided the means of subsistence for most

people. Then, for about 130 years, wage labor opportunities grew rapidly, first among men

and then among women. The tectonic shifts in the structure of the economy since the early

nineteenth century transformed family relations. The transition from corporate families to

male breadwinner families was a consequence of the rise of male wage labor in the

Industrial Revolution. The transition from male breadwinner families to dual-earner families

reflects the massive increase in wage labor among married women following the Second

World War. The decline of corporate families led to a profound upheaval of generational

relations as family patriarchs lost control over their wage-earning sons. The decline of

male-breadwinner families led to an equally profound upheaval of gender relations as men

lost control over their wage-earning wives and daughters. The two great transformations of

family economies—from corporate to male breadwinner and from male breadwinner to

dual earner—undermined the economic logic of patriarchal authority.

The dramatic retreat from marriage over the past half-century could never have

occurred without the loss of patriarchal control and the shift in attitudes that accompanied

it. But the proximate cause of the retreat from marriage since 1975 is a different structural

change: the massive decline of relative earnings and falloff of wage labor participation

among young men, combined with the long stagnation in earnings among young women.

With growing inequality, families are facing diverging destinies (McLanahan 2004).

A minority of young people are faring well in the new economy, and young people with

resources are continuing to form marital and cohabiting unions. Among the college-

educated with good jobs, the impact of family change is muted. Marriage is still feasible;

marital instability is declining; and cohabitation and single parenthood can be managed

Page 28: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

26

without hardship. For much of the population, however, the outlook is grim. Almost one-

fifth of young adults live in poverty, more than double the percentage in 1973 (Ruggles et

al. 2015). More than 10 % of young earners have their wages garnished because of debt,

often for child support (Arnold and Keil 2014). Many who have jobs are underemployed,

taking unskilled and part-time jobs even if they have good qualifications. Among young

people who lack resources, families are difficult to form or sustain: fewer and fewer young

adults are marrying, and those who do are at increasing risk of divorce. For people without

secure jobs that provide a living wage, cohabitating unions are highly unstable. Whether

cohabiting or not, most unmarried mothers of infants are in poverty (Amato et al. 2014;

Carbone and Cahn 2014; Cherlin 2014; Flood et al. 2015).

Despite these challenges, few would choose to return to the families of the past.

Patriarchy has receded; today’s families are far more humane and egalitarian than

anything that came before. Corporal punishment of wives is universally condemned, and

wife-beating is illegal in every state. Child-beating is still legal in the United States, but

even in Texas, it is no longer acceptable to punish a child with a switch (Zinser 2014).

Women are no longer legally subordinate to their husbands. Wives can work for wages,

they can keep their earnings, and they no longer need their husband’s permission to open

a checking account or sign a contract. There is growing tolerance of new family forms, to

the point where same-sex marriage is now legal throughout the United States. Time-use

data show that families are becoming more and more egalitarian with respect to

housework and childcare (Goldscheider et al. 2015).

If the era of ever-expanding wage labor is truly drawing to a close, that will create

new challenges for families, but it will also create new opportunities. For the last 10,000

years, most of humanity has been forced to work long hours in repetitive and backbreaking

Page 29: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

27

toil just to earn basic subsistence. We are on the verge of being able to make everything

we need, including all kinds of things unimagined by previous generations, without that

kind of tedious and grueling drudgery—indeed, with hardly any work at all. Our silicon

servants will have the potential to provide everyone with food, shelter, and all other

necessities, freeing us to pursue our dreams and passions.

In 1930, John Maynard Keynes wrote an essay on “The Economic Possibilities for

our Grandchildren.” He predicted that the combination of technological innovation and

capital accumulation will eventually solve the problem of material needs. Keynes argued

that “the economic problem may be solved, or be at least within sight of solution, within a

hundred years” (Keynes 1930:96). Eighty-five years after this prediction, I believe we are

already within sight of solving the economic problem. We now must address what Keynes

saw as the real problem: how “to live wisely and agreeably and well” (Keynes 1930:97).

To make families stronger, reduce family instability, enable young people to form

marital or cohabiting unions, and eliminate child poverty, we must figure out how to share

the bounty of the machines. Our biggest challenge is not how to produce wealth but how to

distribute it: how to get money into the hands of people—especially young people—so that

they can buy all those goods and services that the robots can produce with so little human

effort.

Page 30: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

28

Acknowledgments This article is a revised version of my Presidential Address to the

Population Association of America, delivered in San Diego on May 1, 2015. Funding for

data preparation was provided by the Eunice Kennedy Shriver National Institute of Child

Health and Human Development (R01HD43392, R01HD047283, and R24HD41023). I also

had a lot of help from my friends. I presented versions of this article at 10 population center

seminars and conferences, and at every venue received feedback that reshaped my

thinking. Several people were extraordinarily generous, providing detailed critiques of

multiple drafts: Philip Cohen, Stephanie Coontz, Cathy Fitch, Katie Genadek, Claudia

Goldin, Fran Goldscheider, Miriam King, Steven Mintz, Phyllis Moen, Lisa Norling, Gina

Rumore, Carole Shammas, and Matt Sobek. My greatest debt is to the data creators,

curators, integrators, and disseminators of the Minnesota Population Center, without whom

it would be impossible to describe long-run family change.

Page 31: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

29

References

Aidala, A. (1958a, Nov. 21). If a woman needs it, should she be spanked? New York Daily

Mirror, p. 29.

Aidala, A. (1958b, Feb. 27). Is father losing place as head of family? New York Daily

Mirror, p. 27.

Akerlof, G. A., Yellen, J. L. & Katz, M. L. (1996). An analysis of out-of-wedlock childbearing

in the United States. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111, 277–317.

Alvaredo, F., Atkinson, A. B., Saez, E., & Piketty, T. (2015). World top incomes database.

Retrieved from http://topincomes.parisschoolofeconomics.eu/

Amato, P. R., Booth, A., McHale, S. M., & Van Hook J. (Eds.). (2014). Families in an era of

increasing inequality: Diverging destinies. Cham, Switzerland: Springer International

Publishing.

Arnold, C., & Kiel, P. (2014, Sept. 14). Millions of Americans’ wages seized over credit

card and medical debt. In Morning Edition. Washington, DC: National Public Radio.

Retrieved from http://www.npr.org/2014/09/15/347957729/when-consumer-debts-

go-unpaid-paychecks-can-take-a-big-hit

Axinn, W. G., & Thornton, A. (1993). Mothers, children, and cohabitation: The

intergenerational effects of attitudes and behavior. American Sociological Review,

58, 233–246.

Axinn, W. G., & Thornton, A. (2000). The transformation in the meaning of marriage. In L.

Waite, C. Bachrach, M. Hindin, E. Thomson, & A. Thornton, (Eds.), Ties that bind:

Perspectives on marriage and cohabitation (pp. 147–165). New Brunswick, NJ:

Transaction.

Bailey, M. J. (2006). More power to the pill: The impact of contraceptive freedom on

Page 32: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

30

women’s life cycle labor supply. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121, 289–320.

Bianchi, S. M. (1995). Changing economic roles of women and men, in Reynolds Farley

(ed.), State of the union: America in the 1990s (Vol. 1, pp. 107–154). New York, NY:

Russell Sage Foundation.

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. (2015). Industrial Production:

Manufacturing (NAICS) [IPMAN]. Retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of

St. Louis, https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/IPMAN/

Brynjolfsson, E., & McAfee, A. (2014). The second machine age: Work, progress, and

prosperity in a time of brilliant technologies. New York, NY: Norton.

Bumpass, L. L. (1990). What’s happening to the family? Interactions between demographic

and institutional change. Demography, 27, 483–498.

Carbone, J., & Cahn, N. (2014). Marriage markets: How inequality is remaking the

American family. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

Carlson, W. (2008). The lucky few: Between the greatest generation and the baby boom.

New York, NY: Springer.

Cherlin, A. J. (2009). The marriage-go-round: The state of marriage and the family in

America today. New York, NY: Vintage.

Cherlin, A. J. (2014). Labor’s love lost: The rise and fall of the working-class family in

America. New York, NY: Russell Sage.

Coontz, S. (1992). The way we never were: American families and the nostalgia trap. New

York, NY: Basic.

Coontz, S. (2005). Marriage, a history: How love conquered marriage. New York, NY:

Penguin.

Costa, D. L. (2000). From mill town to board room: The rise of women’s paid labor. Journal

Page 33: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

31

of Economic Perspectives, 14, 101–122.

Cott, N. (2009). Public vows: A history of marriage and the nation. Cambridge, MA:

Harvard University Press.

Cotter, D. A., Hermsen, J. M., & Vanneman, R. Women's work and working women: The

demand for female labor. Gender & society 15, 429-452.

Crone, T. M., Nakamura L. I., Voith, R. (2006). The CPI for rents: A case of understated

inflation (Working Paper No. 06-7). Philadelphia, PA: Federal Reserve Bank of

Philadelphia.

Das Gupta. P. (1978). A general method of decomposing a difference between two rates

into several components. Demography, 15, 99–111.

Easterlin, R. A. (1966). On the relation of economic factors to recent and projected fertility

changes. Demography, 3, 131–153.

Easterlin, R. A. (1978). What will 1984 be like? Socioeconomic implications of recent twists

in age structure. Demography, 15, 397–432.

Easterlin R. A. (1987). Birth and fortune (2nd ed.). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago

Press.

Fitch, C., Goeken, R., & Ruggles S. (2005). The rise of cohabitation in the United States:

New historical estimates (MPC Working Paper No. 2005−03). Minneapolis:

Minnesota Population Center. Retrieved

from http://www.pop.umn.edu/sites/www.pop.umn.edu/files/cohabit_2005-03.pdf

Flood, S., King, M. L, Ruggles, S., & Warren, J. R. (2015). Integrated Public Use Microdata

Series, Current Population Survey: Version 4.0 [Machine-readable database].

Minneapolis: University of Minnesota.

Folbre, N. & Nelson, J.A. (2000). For love or money—or both? Journal of Economic

Page 34: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

32

Perspectives 14, 123-140.

Ford, H., & Crowther, S. (1922). My life and work. Garden City, NY: Garden City

Publishing.

Frey, C. B., & Osborne, M. A. (2013). The future of employment: How susceptible are jobs

to computerization? Oxford, UK: Oxford Martin School Study. Retrieved from

http://www.oxfordmartin.ox.ac.uk/downloads/academic/The_Future_of_Employment

.pdf

Goldin, C. (1990). Understanding the gender gap: An economic history of American

women. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

Goldin, C. (1991a). Marriage bars: Discrimination against married women workers from the

1920s to the 1950s. In P. Higonnet, D. S. Landes, & H. Rosovsky (Eds.), Favorites

of fortune: Technology, growth, and economic development since the Industrial

Revolution (pp. 511–536). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Goldin, C. (1991b). The role of World War II in the rise of women’s employment. American

Economic Review 81, 741–756.

Goldin, C. (1995). The U-shaped female labor force function in economic development and

economic history. In T. P. Schultz (Ed.), Investment in women’s human capital and

economic development (pp. 61–90). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Goldin, C. & Katz, L. F. (2002). The power of the pill: Oral contraceptives and women’s

career and marriage decisions. Journal of Political Economy 110, 730-70.

Goldin, C. & Katz, L. F. (2010). The race between education and technology. Cambridge,

MA: Harvard.

Goldin, C., Katz, L. F., and Kuziemko, I. (2006). The homecoming of american college

women: The reversal of the college gender gap. Journal of Economic Peerspectives

Page 35: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

33

20, 133-156.

Goldscheider, F., Bernhardt, E., & Lappegård, T. (2015). A theoretical framework for

understanding new family-demographic behavior: The two halves of the gender

revolution. Population and Development Review, 41, 207–239.

Gordon, R. J., & van Goethem, T. (2007). A century of downward bias in the biggest CPI

component: The case of rental shelter, 1914–2003. In E. Berndt and C. Hulten

(Eds.), Hard-to-measure goods and services: Essays in honor of Zvi Griliches (pp.

153–195)Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Hartog, H. (2000). Man and wife in America: A history. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University

Press.

Hilbert, M. & López, P. (2011). The World’s Technological Capacity to Store,

Communicate, and Compute Information. Science 332: 6025, 60-65.

Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers (IEEE). (2014). IEEE survey reveals cars

will not have steering wheels, pedals, horns, or rearview mirrors by 2035. Retrieved

from http://electricvehicle.ieee.org/telematics/ieee-survey-reveals-mass-produced-

cars-will-steering-wheels-gasbrake-pedals-horns-rearview-mirrors-2035/

Kalleberg, A. L. (2011). Good Jobs, Bad Jobs: The Rise of Polarized and Precarious

Employment Systems in the United States, 1970s-2000s. New York: Russell Sage.

Kennedy, S., & Bumpass, L. (2008). Cohabitation and children’s living arrangements: New

estimates from the United States. Demographic Research, 19(article 47), 1663–

1692. doi: 10.4054.DemRes.2008.19.47

Kennedy, S., & Ruggles, S. (2014). Breaking up is hard to count: The rise of divorce in the

United States, 1980–2010. Demography, 51, 587–598.

Kennedy, S., & Ruggles, S. (2015). Trends in union instability in the United States, 1980s-

Page 36: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

34

2010s (MPC Working Paper No. 2015-1). Minneapolis: Minnesota Population

Center.

Kessler-Harris, A. (1982). Out to work: A history of wage-earning women in the United

States. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

Keynes, J. M. (1930). Economic possibilities for our grandchildren. The Nation and

Athenaeum, 48, 2:36–37, 3:96–98.

Lebergott, S. (1984). The Americans: An economic record. New York, NY: W. W. Norton &

Company.

Lesthaeghe, R. (1983). A century of demographic and cultural change in western Europe:

An exploration of underlying dimensions. Population and Development Review, 9,

411–435.

Lesthaeghe, R. (2010). The unfolding story of the second demographic transition.

Population and Development Review, 36, 211–251.

Levinson, M. (2015). U.S. manufacturing in international perspective (CRS Report

R42135). Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service.

Martin, S. P., Astone, N. M., & Peters, H. E. (2014). Fewer marriages, more divergence:

Marriage projections for Millennials to age 40. Washington, DC: Urban Institute.

Massey, D. S. (1996). The age of extremes: Concentrated affluence and poverty in the

twenty-first century. Demography, 33, 395–412.

May, E. T. (1980). Great expectations: Marriage and divorce in post-Victorian America.

Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press.

May, E. T. (1990). Homeward bound: American families in the Cold War era. New York,

NY: Basic.

May, E. T. (2010). America and the pill: A history of promise, peril, and liberation. New

Page 37: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

35

York, NY: Basic.

McLanahan, S. (2004). Diverging destinies: How children are faring under the second

demographic transition. Demography, 41, 607–627.

Mintz, S. (1998). From patriarchy to androgyny and other myths: Placing men’s family

roles in historical perspective. In A. Booth & A. C. Crouter (Eds.), Men in families:

When do they get involved? What difference does it make? (pp. 3–30). Florence,

KY: Taylor and Francis.

Mintz, S., & Kellogg, S. (1988). Domestic revolutions: A social history of American family

life. New York, NY: Free Press.

Mokyr, J., Vickers, C., and Ziebarth, N.I.. (2015). The history of technological anxiety and

the future of economic growth: Is this time different? Journal of Economic

Perspectives, 29, 31-50.

Myers, C.K. (2012). Power of the pill or power of abortion? Re-examining the effects of

young women’s access to reproductive control. (Discussion Paper No. 6661)

Institute for the Study of Labor, Bonn, Germany.

Oppenheimer, V. K. (1970). The female labor force in the United States: Demographic and

economic factors governing its growth and changing composition (Population

Monograph Series No. 5). Berkeley: University of California.

Oppenheimer, V. K. (1988). A theory of marriage timing. American Journal of Sociology,

94, 563–91.

Oppenheimer, V. K. (1994). Women’s rising employment and the future of the family in

industrialized societies. Population and Development Review, 20, 293–342.

Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University

Press.

Page 38: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

36

Presser, H. B. (1998). Decapitating the U.S. Census Bureau’s head of household: Feminist

mobilization in the 1970s. Feminist Economics, 4, 147–160.

Read, J. E. (1884). Farming for profit: An encyclopedia of useful information and a

practical assistant in the management of farm affairs. Devoted to agriculture and

mechanics, fruit growing and gardening, live-stock, business principles, home life,

and showing how to make money and secure health and happiness on the farm.

Philadelphia, PA: J.C. McCurdy.

Rinfduss, R. R., Brewster, K. L, & Kavee, A. L. (1996). Women, work, and children:

Behavioral and attitudinal change in the United States. Population and Development

Review, 22, 457–482.

Ruggles, S. (1989). DECOMP: A program for multiple standardization and decomposition.

Retrieved from http://www.umn.edu/~ruggles/DECOMP.html

Ruggles, S. (1994). The transformation of American family structure. American Historical

Review, 99, 103–128.

Ruggles, S. (1997). The rise of divorce and separation in the United States, 1880–1990.

Demography, 34, 455–466.

Ruggles, S. (2003). Multigenerational families in nineteenth-century America. Continuity

and Change, 18, 139–165.

Ruggles, S. (2007). The decline of intergenerational coresidence in the United States,

1850–2000. American Sociological Review, 72, 962–989.

Ruggles, S. (2009). Reconsidering the northwest European family system: Living

arrangements of the aged in comparative historical perspective. Population and

Development Review, 35, 249–273.

Ruggles, S. (Forthcoming). Marriage, family systems, and economic opportunity in the

Page 39: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

37

United States since 1850. In S (pp. 3–41). Cham, Switzerland: Springer

International Publishing.

Ruggles, S., & Brower, S. (2003). The measurement of family and household composition

in the United States, 1850–1999. Population and Development Review, 29, 73–101.

Ruggles, S., Genadek, K., Goeken, R., Grover J., & Sobek, M. (2015). Integrated Public

Use Microdata Series: Version 6.0 [Machine-readable database]. Minneapolis:

University of Minnesota.

Ryan, M. P. (1981). Cradle of the middle class. The family in Oneida County, New York,

1790–1865. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

Segal, H. P. (2005). Recasting the machine age: Henry Ford’s Village Industries. Amherst:

University of Massachusetts Press.

Shammas, C. (2002). A history of household government in America. Charlottesville:

University of Virginia Press.

Siegel, R. B. (1996). “The rule of love”: Wife beating as prerogative and privacy. Yale Law

Journal, 105, 2117–2207.

Smith, T. W., Hout, M., & Marsden, P. V. (2013). General Social Survey, 1972–2012

Cumulative File (ICPSR 34802-v1). Storrs, CT: Roper Center for Public Opinion

Research, University of Connecticut /Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for

Political and Social Research. Retrieved

from http://doi.org/10.3886/ICPSR34802.v1

Stanfors, M. & Goldscheider, F. (2015). The forest and the trees: Industrialization,

demographic change, and the ongoing gender revolution in Sweden and the United

States, 1870–2010. Stockholm Research Reports in Demography 2015: 18.

Stanley, A.D. (2002). Marriage, property, and class. In A Companion to American

Page 40: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

38

Women's History, ed. Nancy A. Hewitt (Blackwell Publishing), 193-205.

Stewart, K. J. and Reed, S. B. (1999). CPI research series using current methods, 1978–

98. Monthly Labor Review, June 1999, 29–38.

Stiglitz, J. E. (2012). The price of inequality. New York, NY: Norton.

Thornton, A. (1985). Changing attitudes toward separation and divorce: Causes and

consequences. American Journal of Sociology 90: 856–872.

Torr, B. (2011). The changing relationship between education and marriage in the United

States: 1940–2000. Journal of Family History, 36, 483–503.

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2015). All Employees: Manufacturing [MANEMP],

retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/MANEMP/

Van de Kaa, D. J. (1987). Europe’s second demographic transition. Population Bulletin, 42,

1–59.

Weil, D. (2014). The fissured workplace: Why work became so bad for so many and what

can be done to improve it. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Weiss, T. (1992). U.S. labor force estimates and economic growth, 1800–1860. In R. E.

Gallman & J. J. Wallis (Eds.), American economic growth and standards of living

before the Civil War (pp. 19–75). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Westoff, C. F., & Norman B. Ryder, N. B. (n.d.). National Fertility Survey, 1970

(ICPSR20003-v1). Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and

Social Research [distributor], 2008-08-08. Retrieved from

http://doi.org/10.3886/ICPSR20003.v1

Wilson, W. J., & Neckerman, K. (1987). Poverty and family structure: The widening gap

between evidence and public policy issues. In W. J. Wilson (Ed.), The truly

Page 41: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

39

disadvantaged: The inner city, the underclass, and public policy (pp. 63–92).

Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press.

Zinser, L. (2014, Nov. 5). Adrian Peterson agrees to plea deal in child-abuse case. New

York Times, p. B13.

Page 42: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

Fig. 1 Percentage of persons aged 65 or older residing in multigenerational families: United States, 1850–2013. Multigenerational families defined according to the IPUMS MULTGEN variable. Source: Ruggles et al. (2015)

0.00

10.00

20.00

30.00

40.00

50.00

60.00

70.00

80.00

1850 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010

Perc

ent m

ultig

ener

atio

nal

Page 43: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

1

Fig. 2 Annual divorces per 1,000 married women, standardized by age: United States, 1867–2013. Source: Ruggles (forthcoming)

0

5

10

15

20

1865 1885 1905 1925 1945 1965 1985 2005

Page 44: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

2

Fig. 3 Percentage of women never married by aged 40–44 by birth cohort: U.S. women born 1825–1994. Source: Ruggles (forthcoming)

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

Perc

ent n

ever

-mar

ried

by 4

0-44

Year of Birth

Observed

Predicted

Page 45: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

3

Fig. 4 Family economies of U.S. couples aged 18–64: United States, 1800–2010. Source: Ruggles (forthcoming)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Corporate Family

Male Breadwinner Dual Earner

Female Breadwinner

Page 46: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

4

Fig. 5 Occupations of men aged 18–64: United States, 1850–2010. Source: Ruggles (forthcoming)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

1850 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010

Farmer & other self-employed

Unpaid family work

Skilled & operatives

Unskilled wage work

Professional & managerial

Clerical & sales

Slave

Not in labor force

Page 47: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

5

Fig. 6 Agricultural employment and multigenerational families: United States, 1800–2010. Source: Ruggles et al. (2015), Weiss (1992)

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

Multigenerational families(persons age 65+)

Agriculturalemployment

(male labor force)

Page 48: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

6

Fig. 7 Occupations of women aged 18–64: United States, 1850–1910. Source: Ruggles (forthcoming)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

1850 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010Farmer & self-employed

Unpaid work in family enterprise

Skilled & operatives

Unskilled wage work

Professional & managerial

Clerical & sales

Unskilled

Unskilled

Slave

Not in labor force

Page 49: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

7

Fig. 8 Percentage of women aged 25–29 engaged in wage labor, by marital status: United States, 1860–2013. Source: Ruggles (forthcoming)

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Unmarried women

Married women

All Women

Page 50: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

8

Fig. 9 Labor force participation and attitudes toward labor force participation: Married women under age 45: United States, 1930–2013. Sources: Ruggles et al. (2015), Flood et al. (2015), Westoff and Ryder (n.d.), and Smith et al. (2013)

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Percent of wives disagreeing:"It is much better for everyone

involved if the man is the achiever outside the home and

the woman takes care of the home and family."

Percent of wives in labor force

Page 51: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

9

Fig. 10 Percentage of households without a married couple: United States, 1850–2013. Source: Ruggles et al. (2015)

0

10

20

30

40

50

1850 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 2010

Page 52: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

10

Fig. 11 Median age at first marriage, 1850–2013. Source: Ruggles (forthcoming)

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26

27

28

29

30

1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Men

Women

Year of Marriage

Page 53: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

11

Fig. 12 Median wages for persons aged 25–29, 1940–2013. Sources: Ruggles et al. (2015) and Flood et al. (2015)

$0

$10,000

$20,000

$30,000

$40,000

$50,000

1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Men

Women

$0

$10,000

$20,000

$30,000

$40,000

1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Women

Men

A. Full-time wage and salary

B. All persons aged 25–29

Page 54: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

12

Fig. 13 Median wage income as a percentage of median wage income in the previous generation (30 years previously): U.S. men aged 25–29, 1945–2013. Sources: Ruggles et al. (2015), Flood et al. (2015), and Alvaredo et al. (2015)

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

1945 1955 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015

Page 55: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

13

Fig. 14 Median wage income as a percentage of the income of the top 1 %: U.S. men aged 25–29, 1940–2013. Sources: Ruggles et al. (2015), Flood et al. (2015), and Alvaredo et al. (2015)

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Page 56: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

14

Fig. 15 Number of men age 15 to 29 as a percentage of the number of men age 30–64. Sources: Ruggles et al. (2015) and Flood et al. (2015)

40

45

50

55

60

65

70

75

1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Page 57: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

15

Fig. 16 The rise and fall of wage labor: percentage of persons aged 18–64 engaged in wage and salary work, by sex: 1800–2050. Source: Ruggles et al. (2015)

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

1800 1830 1860 1890 1920 1950 1980 2010 2040

Men

Women

Page 58: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

16

Table 1 Percentage currently married with spouse present and distribution of characteristics by selected factors: U.S.-born men aged 25–29, 1960 and 2013

% Married Population Distribution

1960 2013 1960 2013 Relative Income (percentiles of combined

data sets) 0–9 18.9 7.0 3.9 13.0 10–19 35.1 11.0 2.1 14.2 20–29 45.5 16.8 2.7 11.8 30–39 47.9 21.4 2.2 12.6 40–49 51.6 29.1 2.1 14.6 50–59 59.4 35.6 4.1 13.1 60–69 68.4 38.5 9.8 11.9 70–79 76.4 39.8 21.2 5.8 80–89 82.8 43.0 24.4 2.0 90–99 87.6 42.5 27.5 1.1

Occupation Professional, technical 74.2 29.7 14.2 18.4 Managers, clerical 76.4 24.0 16.7 21.2 Sales 77.2 22.7 6.0 6.0 Crafts 79.8 35.2 23.9 14.0 Operatives 79.4 27.2 22.7 11.3 Service and laborers 66.2 18.5 13.8 21.5 No occupation for 5+ years 10.6 4.9 2.6 7.7

Employment Characteristics Self-employed 83.3 32.7 6.6 3.0 Employed for wages 78.2 28.6 83.8 74.4 Unemployed 53.5 10.7 3.6 8.2 Not in the labor force 24.6 7.9 5.9 14.4

Education Less than high school 73.0 15.5 38.1 7.6 High school graduate 76.4 23.7 47.1 65.7 College graduate 73.9 26.7 8.9 21.1 Postgraduate 69.7 33.3 5.9 5.5

Total 74.5 24.2 100.0 100.0 Number of Men Aged 25–29 in Samples 46,708 74,095

Page 59: Patriarchy, Power, and Pay: The Transformation of American

17

Table 2 Components of change in the percentage married: U.S.-born men aged 25–29, 1960–2013

Components of Change

Index of Change

Total Change in Marriage 50.3 100.0 Effects of Compositional Factors

Relative Income 20.4 40.6 Occupation 2.2 4.4 Employment characteristics 2.9 5.7 Education 1.6 3.2

Combined Effect of Factors 27.1 53.9 Rate Effect 23.2 46.1