party identification and the vote six european countries ... · attachment to a political party....

30
Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries Compared by Frode Berglund, ISR Oslo Sören Holmberg, University of Gothenburg Hermann Schmitt, MZES, University of Mannheim Jacques Thomassen, University of Twente Paper prepared for presentation at the Second General Conference of the ECPR, University of Marburg, Germany, September 18-21, 2003. Authors are listed in alphabetical order. 1

Upload: others

Post on 24-Jul-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Party Identification and the Vote

Six European Countries Compared

by

Frode Berglund, ISR Oslo Sören Holmberg, University of Gothenburg

Hermann Schmitt, MZES, University of Mannheim Jacques Thomassen, University of Twente

Paper prepared for presentation at the Second General Conference of the ECPR, University of Marburg, Germany, September 18-21, 2003. Authors are listed in alphabetical order.

1

Page 2: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

1. Introduction

Previously, we found a secular decline of the impact of the traditional cleavage structure on

people’s party choice.1 As the strong and lasting relationship between the social structure on

the one hand and people’s political loyalties on the other hand used to be one of the most

essential elements of in most European democracies, this development might be a threat to

political stability.

However, social roots are not the only possible basis for enduring party preferences. An

alternative is the direct psychological attachment to a particular party. In the Michigan

tradition of electoral research party identification has the function of ensuring people’s lasting

attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological

identification with one’s preferred political party.

At first, the concept of party identification was met quite critically in European electoral

research. As in European elections party identification and party vote tended to coincide and

to change in tandem, one of the most innovative elements of the use of party identification in

electoral research, i.e. studying the impact of short term forces on the vote against the baseline

of the normal vote, was hardly applicable in the European context.

Paradoxically, one of the major reasons why party identification, at least the directional

component of the concept, used to be less useful in the European compared to the American

context, was the overriding importance of political parties. In European parliamentary systems

political parties and not individual politicians are the principal actors in the interaction

between voters and governmental institutions, leaving little lee-way for individual candidates

to run their own campaign for office and offering little incentives for voters to deviate from

their party preference in favour of an individual candidate from another party. This is quite

different from Americans politics, in particular in presidential elections, where the policy

stands and characteristics of the candidates have an important weight in addition to their party

background. In a parliamentary democracy with its indirect election of the head of

government a split of party identification and the actual vote is less likely.

The functional model of party identification (Shively 1982) offers another possible

explanation why party identification might be less important for European than American

voters. According to this view party identification is a cost saving device, providing people

2

Page 3: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

with a short cut to all kinds of decisions, including the decision for which party or candidate

to vote. However, European voters might not have needed party identification as a cost saving

device, because that function was already fulfilled by people’s ties to a social class or religion,

which in turn was strongly associated with a particular political party. Under these conditions

expressed partisanship will be synonymous with the vote and parties as such will not serve as

guides to organise behaviour.

The logical extension of this argument might be that once the importance of the traditional

cleavage structure will decline and voters are deprived of their traditional shortcutting device,

they will develop party identification in the same way as their American counterparts. In other

words party identification would not necessarily decline in the slipstream of the decline of the

relationship between the social structure and party system.

However, it is the very same functional theory that contradicts this prediction. The need of an

information costs saving device is supposed to be a function of the political skills of the

voters. Modernisation and in particular the cognitive mobilisation of citizens have increased

these skills. According to Dalton, the dramatic spread of education in advanced industrial

democracies has produced a qualitative change in the political sophistication of citizens. At

the same time, these societies have experienced an information explosion through the mass

media. Both developments have led to a substantial decrease of information costs. Because of

this cognitive mobilisation, more voters now are able to deal with the complexities of politics

and make their own political decisions. Thus, the functional need for partisan cues to guide

voting behaviour is declining for a growing number of citizens (Dalton 1984). As a

consequence, we should expect a decline of the level of party identification.

In principle, testing this hypothesis requires not more than an assessment of the development

of the level of party identification over time. The hypothesis predicts a secular decline of

party identification in advanced industrial democracies. An advantage of the selection of

countries in our study is that all six are advanced industrial democracies at about the same

level of development. Modernisation theory therefore would predict a more or less similar

secular decline of party identification in these six countries. This hypothesis will be tested in

section two.

However, even if the development of the level of party identification is consistent with what

the functional theory as part of the broader theory of modernisation predicts, this does not

1 This is a draft chapter of a book that is forthcoming at Oxford University Press under the title “The European

3

Page 4: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

necessarily prove that this development is caused by the mechanisms supposed in functional

theory. This theory is based on specific assumptions at the micro-level, which are anything

but uncontested (Barton & Döring 1986). In section three we will elaborate these

assumptions and test to what extent the assumed relations at the micro-level can be found in

our data.

The theory of modernisation tries to explain developments in politics by developments in

society. As such one might call it a sociological approach, devoid of a political component in

the explanans. As a reaction to this a-political approach an alternative explanation of the

development of party identification has been proposed emphasising developments in the

political context, in particular in the demand side of politics, rather than the developments in

society. Schmitt and Holmberg (1995) for instance introduce and test the hypothesis that

developments and fluctuations in the level of party identifications can be explained by

simultaneous fluctuations in the level of polarisation and the degree of issue conflict between

political parties. This approach does not necessarily lead to different predictions than the

theory of modernisation. In the early ‘end of ideology’ debate a gradual decline of the

ideological political differences was predicted as a logical consequence of the decline of the

importance of the cleavage structure. As far as the decline of the level of party identification

is a consequence of such a gradual depolarisation, it should be a secular decline, just like

predicted by the theory of modernisation. However, polarisation can fluctuate from one

election to the other and differ across countries at the same level of modernisation. Therefore,

other than the theory of modernisation, it can possibly explain non-linear fluctuations in the

level of party identification. In section four we will further discuss this theoretical perspective

and test it. Section five finally will be devoted to party identification as an independent

variable: has modernisation and/or a possible decrease in ideological polarisation made it less

closely tied to the vote?

2. The Evolution of Party Identification

The question whether or not a secular decline in the level of party identification has occurred

in advanced industrial democracies and whether modernisation is an underlying cause of

decline, has been the subject of several previous comparative studies. Holmberg and Schmitt,

having studied the developments in fourteen West-European countries and the United States

Voter”. The editor is Jacques Thomassen.

4

Page 5: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

until 1992 came to the conclusion that ‘If there is an overall tendency, it is of loosening party

bonds. But specific developments, by country and party, are so varied that any general

‘overall’ view disguises more than it discloses.’ (Schmitt & Holmberg 1995: 121). On the basis

of a larger number of countries and a longer time span, regressing the year of the survey on

trends in partisanship, Dalton (2000) comes to a less ambiguous conclusion. He finds negative

trends in 17 of the 19 advanced industrial democracies represented in his study.

In this chapter we will see to what extent the trends in partisanship in the six countries

included in our study confirm these trends. Limiting ourselves to these six countries might

have the disadvantage of a smaller database, but on the other hand it clearly has two major

advantages. First, Dalton (2000) objects to the study by Holmberg and Schmitt that they

include countries which have not yet become advanced industrial countries, and that many

time-series are too short to reveal effects of cognitive mobilisation. An analysis based on

national election surveys from Great Britain, Denmark, Germany, the Netherlands, Norway

and Sweden, avoids these problems. All are old democracies, they were traditional industrial

societies in the sixties and have transformed into advanced industrial societies in the nineties.

Secondly, the limitation to six countries enables us to study the development in these

countries in more detail.

Figure 1 about here

The development of the level of party identification for each of the six countries is presented

in figure 1. In two countries at least the development is pretty much in line with what the

modernisation thesis would predict. These countries are Great Britain and Sweden. Although

the development in neither country is strictly linear, there can hardly be a dispute about the

direction of change: ‘down we go’ (Holmberg 1998). In Britain the decline started in the early

1970s, and continued for more than a decade. The decline came to a halt in the 1980s, i.e. in

the Thatcher years, but went further in the 1990s. The pattern in Sweden is very similar,

although the development over time is a little bit different. After an initial decline in the

1960s, the trend stabilised in the 1970s, to be followed by a continuous decline ever since.

In the other three countries the development is more complex. In Norway a secular decline

can be observed since 1980, but this decline was preceded by an increase of the level of party

identification in the 1970s after an initial decline in the 1960s. Neither in Denmark nor in the

Netherlands a clear trend can be observed. After a sudden decline in the early seventies, in

1973 to be precise when all of a sudden the party system was shaken up, the level of party

5

Page 6: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

identification slowly clambered, but slowly declined again in the 1990s. In the Netherlands a

sudden increase in the 1980s interrupts a trend that otherwise is a negative one. The German

trend starts out at about thirty percent in 1961, reaches its highest level well above 50 percent

in 1972, but then continuously declines afterwards, falling back to the 30 percent mark again

– with the major exception of the re-unification election in 1990.

If we conduct a linear regression analysis on the numbers in figure 1, the technique used by

Dalton in his analysis of changes in partisanship, we find compelling evidence that

partisanship is declining with time, which is consistent with the modernisation thesis. In all

countries partisanship is lower in the late nineties than in the sixties and the early seventies.

However, it is disputable whether a linear technique is a proper technique in analysing these

trends. It seems more likely that the fluctuations and deviations from a linear trend are due to

periodical effects and country specific events. Therefore, we applied a non-linear approach to

the time variable (year) in each country in order to test for periodical effects. Table 1 shows

the results from logistic regressions with partisanship as dependent variable and time as

explanatory variable. Partisanship is dichotomised – partisan or independent, while time is

treated as a nominal variable. The first election constitutes the reference category, positive

signs indicate an increase of independents relatively to the first election, negative signs a

decrease.

Table 1 about here

Table 1 confirms the impression from figure 1. As the signs of most of the coefficients in the

table are positive, it is obvious that there is general trend towards a lower level of

partisanship. In all countries but Denmark the percentage of partisans at the end of the trend

line is lower than at the beginning. However, it is also clear that partisanship has developed in

a more complex way than the modernisation thesis would predict. At least part of he

development seems to be due to nation-specific characteristics, like Reiter (1989) suggested.

It is hard to link the various patterns in the development of partisanship between countries to

one general explanation associated with modernisation, at least if time is taken as an indicator

for the process of modernisation. Not in a single case does time explain more than six percent

of the variance (pseudo-r2), as can be seen at the bottom line of the table.

Given the limited explanatory power of the modernisation thesis we will continue our analysis

by two consecutive steps. First, in the next section we will test the micro-theory underlying

modernisation theory. Secondly, in section four and five we will – in the spirit of Przeworski

6

Page 7: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

and Teune – see to what extent we can replace what seem to be nation specific causes by

more general variables.

3. Dealignment and Cognitive Mobilisation

In order to test the validity of the underlying assumptions of modernisation theory at the

micro-level we first need to specify which aspects of modernisation are relevant. These can be

derived from functional theory. The functional model argues that partisanship is becoming

less relevant for electorates and predicts a lasting loss of loyalties to political parties in

general. Theories of mass politics proposed that party identification had a functional value for

citizens in industrial societies, as parties provided political cues that guided them through the

complex world of politics (Campbell et al. 1960). Not just regarding the vote, but also in

shaping public opinion and in evaluating political events. Party identification was of special

importance for a certain segment of the electorate, as ‘partisanship provides a clear and low-

cost voting cue for the unsophisticated voter’ (Converse 1975:111). As political sophistication

was not considered to be widespread in the industrial society (Converse 1964), the functional

value of party identification was considered to be high in that kind of society.

One consequence of the transition to advanced industrial societies is that the functional value

of partisanship will vanish. The transition brings about a radical improvement of citizens’

political resources, because of a sharp rise in the level of education. At the same time, the

media-explosion leads to an increase of the amount of (political) information available. Thus,

the media-explosion is associated with citizens becoming more capable in processing the

information they receive. As sophisticated citizens do not need political guidance from

parties, this development should lead to a decline of partisanship. This process is usually

referred to as the process of cognitive mobilisation. It implies that ever more ‘citizens possess

the skills and resources necessary to become politically engaged with little dependence on

external cues. In addition, cognitive mobilization implies a psychological involvement in

politics’ (Dalton 1984:267). If we accept this definition, cognitive mobilisation can only be a

cause of a possible decline of party identification when the following is true.

1. Education and political involvement have been increasing over time.

2. There is a stable negative relationship between education and political

involvement on the one hand and partisanship on the other hand, i.e. the higher the

education and political involvement, the lower the level of partisanship

7

Page 8: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Nationally established measures of education are used, recoded into the trichotomy primary,

secondary, and university education. Political involvement is measured here by questions

measuring a general interest in politics.

Table 2 about here

In table 2 the effect of time on the two indicators of cognitive mobilisation is presented. The

results are totally different for the two indicators. In all countries the level of education has

been increasing over time. This, of course, is not really surprising. However, the effect of time

on political involvement is negative in four of the six countries, meaning that political

involvement has been decreasing rather than increasing. The effects are small but are pointing

in the ‘wrong’ direction. Therefore, of the two conditions for cognitive mobilisation being a

cause of declining partisanship, the first one is met for education but not for political

involvement.

The second condition refers to the relationship between the indicators of cognitive

mobilisation and partisanship. As the two indicators refer to different dimensions of the

concept, skills and involvement respectively, it would make little sense to combine them in a

single index. However, the least we should expect of two aspects of the same concept is that

they point into the same direction, i.e if higher education leads to a lower level of

partisanship, higher political interest should do so as well. Otherwise, the indicators will

counterbalance each other.

Table 3 about here

As can be observed in table 3, education and political interest do not point into the same

direction. The relationship between political interest and partisanship is relatively stable

across time and countries. However, the sign of the relationship contradicts the cognitive

mobilisation hypothesis. All relationships are positive, which means that political

involvement leads to a higher rather than a lower level of partisanship.

The effect of education in general is lower than that of political involvement, but at least

points in the expected direction. However, the effect is not significant in Germany and the

Netherlands. In Britain, Norway and Sweden it is clearly declining over time. Only Denmark

shows a more or less stable and significant effect.

As the two components of cognitive mobilisation show a different pattern with regard to the

two conditions it is impossible to draw an unambiguous conclusion from these data. However,

it might be argued that of the two components of cognitive mobilisation education is the more

8

Page 9: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

important one. Cognitive mobilisation literally emphasises cognitive aspects more than

psychological involvement, the second element of Dalton’s definition of cognitive

mobilisation. Also, the main argument of the functionalist model is that modernisation leads

to a politically more sophisticated electorate that no longer needs the costs saving device of

partisanship to find their way in the world of politics. In this argument political involvement

might be considered as a possible consequence rather than an factor of cognitive mobilisation.

Skills are more relevant than involvement. Moreover, it is most likely that political involve-

ment will co-vary with the political context in the same way as predicted for partisanship in

the alternative explanation of changes in the level of partisanship that will be tested in the

second part of this chapter. In the case of education this alternative explanation is impossible.

Therefore, avoiding a mix up of the two alternative explanations might be a second reason to

focus on education as the major indicator of cognitive mobilisation. Tables 4a/f enable us to

look at the relationship between education and partisanship in more detail. These tables

confirm that at least in Britain, Denmark, Norway and Sweden the findings are consistent

with the cognitive mobilisation hypothesis in the sense that there are relatively more

independents among people with higher education than among less educated people.

However, in the Netherlands and particularly in Germany the pattern contradicts the

hypothesis. Also, in Britain, Norway and Sweden the differences between the different levels

of education have become smaller. This is mainly due to a decline of partisanship among

people with a low education. This again is the opposite of what the cognitive mobilisation

hypothesis would predict.

Table 4 about here

It might be obvious that the level of education is a function of age. The level of education

among the population at large has been increasing due to generation replacement. Younger

cohorts are much better educated than older cohorts are. At the same time age is considered as

the most important factor in the development of party identification, not because age in itself

is important, but because it is a proxy for the length of time people have experience with a

particular party or the length of time people have been able to confirm their identification with

a particular party (Converse 1969, 1976). On the other hand, in the context of the party

decline thesis, it has been claimed that the life-cycle thesis is no longer valid for the post-war

generation. Being better educated they are less likely to develop partisanship and something

that does not come into being cannot be confirmed either. Regardless which interpretation is

correct, it is obvious that in order to assess the net effect of education on partisanship one

9

Page 10: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

should control for age. The results of this analysis are presented on the bottom line of tables

4a/f , where the correlation between education and partisanship for the youngest generation is

shown. As far as we were able to discern the predicted relationship in at least some countries,

this is no longer the case among the youngest generation. At first, the correlations are lower

than among the population at large and then over time turn into the ‘wrong’ direction. This

means that among the younger generations people with a lower instead of a higher level of

education tend to turn their back to political parties.

Taking all evidence together there is little support for the cognitive mobilisation hypothesis

and thus for the modernisation thesis. Therefore, in the next section we will turn to the

possible alternative explanation of changes in partisanship, focussing on the political context

rather than changes in society.

4. Party Polarisation Schmitt and Holmberg (1995) tested four political factors as possible causal agents behind

decreasing levels of partisanship – the degree of party polarisation, the extent of ideological

conflicts, the intensity of issue differences, and the evolution of new parties – and found

positive, yet weak relationships. The decline in the strength of party identification tended to

be related to weakening party polarisation, declining ideological conflicts, diminished issue

differences and increases in the number of political parties.

We will not replicate their study in this context. We will, however, test three related

hypotheses. In doing that, we will use a different set of data when measuring the relevant

political variables than Schmitt and Holmberg did. The hypotheses we propose to test are the

following. Hypothesis number one is tested on the aggregated macro level using elections as

the unit of analysis. It specifies that:

- partisanship will be higher in electoral systems with more polarised parties than

in systems with less polarised parties.

Hypothesis number two is also tested on the aggregate level. Here we will take advantage of

the time-series aspect of our election study data. The hypothesis states that

- within countries and across time, partisanship will change with the level of

party polarisation.

If polarisation goes up we expect partisanship to increase and if party conflict decreases we

expect partisanship to decrease as well. This means that we do not view party identification as

10

Page 11: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

something truly steadfast and almost unmoveable like in the original Michigan conceptuali-

sation (Campbell et al. 1960). Our hypothesis presupposes that people’s degrees of party

attachment can vary somewhat between elections depending on the nature of party

competition. The third and final hypothesis of this section is on the micro level and states that

people’s degree of party identification is related to the extent that they perceive ideological

differences between relevant political parties. It states that:

- people who experience larger differences between parties tend to develop

stronger party attachments.

If parties flock to the ideological centre and appear as look-a-likes, it is difficult for people to

identify with particular parties. Why pick one if they are all the same?

In order to determine how polarised a party system is, we consider two data sources. One is

the familiar left-right differential derived from the content analyses of party manifestos

(Budge, Klingemann, et al. 2001). The other relies on survey evidence and takes the distance

between the mean left-right self-placement of party voters as a measure of polarisation.

Moreover, we consider the left-right distance between the two major parties and that of the

two polar parties (among those that reached parliamentary representation) as separate and

distinct indicators of polarisation. With regard to partisanship, finally, we look at proportions

of all identifiers and proportions of strong identifiers as two separate and distinct criteria.

After this, we can turn to the business of hypothesis testing. Is it indeed the case that the

proportion of party identifiers in national electorates covaries with left-right polarisation?

Over 6 countries and about half a hundred elections, we find that the more polarised a systems

is, the more numerous party identifiers are (see first row of table 5). There is clear evidence

that party polarisation “produces” partisanship no matter what criterion we apply – with one

exception: overall partisanship seems to drop when the ideological distance between the

voters of polar parties rises. All other coefficients are positive, two of them statistically

significant despite the limited number of cases: large distances between the two polar system

go along with high proportions of strong party identifiers both according to MRG data (r=.42)

and survey evidence (r=.32).

Table 5 about here

The empirical evidence is less clear with regard to the second hypothesis: the within-country

diachronic perspective produces a variety of different patterns. If we start at the bottom of

table 5, Sweden is characterised by positive co-variations between polarisation and

11

Page 12: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

partisanship: all but one coefficients seem to indicate that polarisation indeed produces

partisanship. However, things are exactly the other way around just across the border in

Norway: there, rising ideological polarisation decreases partisanship no matter what criterion

we look at. Findings for the Netherlands are similar to the Swedish: the higher polarisation,

the more identification. In the German findings, the particular importance of the two major

parties is standing out: the farther apart SPD and CDU/CSU voters are ideologically, the more

partisanship there is. In Denmark, manifesto-based measures of partisanship are hardly

correlated with partisanship, while survey-based indicators are: the higher the ideological

distance between party electorates is, the more partisanship we find. For Britain, finally, the

funny finding is that manifesto- polarisation goes along with declining partisanship, while

survey-polarisation coincides with rising partisanship. It should have become evident at this

point that things are considerable less uniform in individual countries, than one would expect

on the basis of the findings of the pooled analysis. Obviously, there are factors intervening in

the association between polarisation and identification which cannot be controlled for in the

bivariate design of the current analysis (see Schmitt 2002 for a more complex study design).

In order to test the third and final hypothesis, in each of our six countries and across all

elections, we created an individual level variable measuring how people perceived the

ideological distance on the left-right scale between the Social Democratic party and the

largest of the conservative parties (see table 6). This perceived polarisation variable turned out

to be positively correlated, if only modestly, with people’s strength of party attachment in

each election studied in each of our six countries. Perceptions of large differences go along

with stronger degrees of party identification.

Table 6 about here

Of course, correlations do not prove causality. In theory, our relationship could as well have

been shaped by self-rationalisations, e.g. that people who are strong party identifiers tend to

see, and perhaps want to see, large differences between parties. Lacking good panel data we

can not disprove this counter-argument, but we have tried to strengthen our test by controlling

in multiple regressions for a couple of other variables that we know are, or might be, related

to the strength of party identification, for example people’s age, but also level of education.

These regression controls did not alter the conclusion. There is a significant relationship

between people’s perceptions of party conflicts and degrees of partisanship even after relevant

controls have been applied. Voters who perceive large party differences tend to have, and

maybe also tend to develop, stronger party identifications.

12

Page 13: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

The conclusion of our endeavours in this section is fairly obvious. Ideological polarisation of

the party system goes along with partisanship, not in each country and according to each

indicator, and not very strongly, but on average and in the pooled analysis we find a moderate

and positive correlation between the two constructs. What is more: we were able to

demonstrate on the level of the individual voter that perceptions of ideological polarisation are

conducive to partisanship (or caused by it as it may be the case as well).

5. Party Identification and the Vote

In this last section of the paper, we finally change our analytical perspective and look at party

identification as an independent rather than as the dependent variable. Is it still the over-

deterministic predictor of vote choices that it was described to be in the early European

analyses? Or is its impact on the vote declining over time? These are the research questions

that we are pursuing in the following.

As always, there is more than one way of doing it.2 In the present paper, we will settle for a

rather basic and yet straightforward and informative approach. We will determine, for each

national election that has been covered by the NES programme in the six West-European

countries under study, the proportion of “loyalists”, that is, identifiers who actually vote for

their party. Those who don’t are called defectors. Simple as this strategy may sound, it is still

a matter of dispute what the appropriate percentage base should be. There are two basic

option: all identifiers or only those who actually went to vote. The all identifier-option treats

non-voting as a “silent” exit option; in the all voting-identifiers-option, these silent defectors

are disregarded. We will pursue both paths and start with the former.

In the six countries under study, during the 1990s, the proportion of party identifiers that

actually support their party in an election varies between 70 and 80 percent (see figure 2 and

table 7). A significant decline becomes apparent for three countries: Sweden, Norway and

Germany. In these countries, proportions of identifiers supporting their party were up at close

to 90 percent in the late sixties and seventies. In the remaining three countries – Denmark, the

Netherlands and the UK – developments are less spectacular, mainly because our trend line

there starts out from lower levels.

2 Among the alternatives, one option would be a series of block-recursive regressions – as many as there are complete data matrices for specific elections; partisanship would always enter in the regression equation after social-structural factors and before more short-term factors like issue preferences and candidate evaluations.

13

Page 14: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Figure 2 and Table 7 about here

In the 1990s, on average three in four West European citizens vote for the party they identify

with. This is hardly a sign for a deterministic relationship: party identification and the vote are

no longer one and the same thing (if this was ever the case). However, things look somewhat

differently if we restrict our analysis to only those identifiers who actually turned out and

went to vote. Compared to the ‘easy way out’ into abstention, voting for another party is

clearly a harder criterion for identifying defection rates. And as one would expect, loyalists in

this perspective are more numerous, defectors less numerous. But still, in the 1990s, one in

seven party identifiers who turn out and vote do vote for another party than their own (see

table 8).

Table 8 about here

This proportion as well has risen over the past decades (in five of the six countries that we

cover here – Denmark being a clear exception). In the 1960s and early 1970s, on average only

one in ten identifiers who did turn out failed to support his or her party. So in this perspective

as well, partisanship and the vote have become more independent than they were a few

decades ago.

6. In Lieu of Conclusion

This chapter started out in a theoretical manner. We reviewed very briefly the history of the

concept of part identification in European electoral systems, and identified reasons why it was

at first rather critically received. Then, we discussed two alternative perspectives on the

evolution of partisanship, one sociological, the other political. In the first perspective, which

coincides in some way with the functional model of partisanship, a secular decline of the

proportion of partisans is expected as the process of social modernisation proceeds. The

simple reason is that modern citizens – educated, politically skilful and involved as they are –

do not need anymore the crunch of party identification to meaningfully participate in an

election. The other perspective is somewhat less linear and deterministic, and concentrates on

political rather than social roots of party identification. It proceeds from the assumption that

parties themselves have it in their hands whether they can rely on a stable basis of party

identifiers. Adversary politics, to use Samuel Finer’s term, is taken to produce partisanship

Another option could be a structural equations model in which one could model the interactive effect of time even more elegantly.

14

Page 15: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

while the opposite of it – a broad political consensus across the major parties – is expected to

prevent partisanship from developing.

According to the first explanatory perspective, proportions of party identifiers should decline,

while the second is less explicit about diachronic developments – here it all depends on the

heat of party conflict and the degree of polarisation, i.e. on the political climate of a polity.

What we actually find in our descriptive section on the evolution of partisanship in six

Western European countries over the last three or four decades seems to conform quite nicely

with the social modernisation perspective. Party identifiers are becoming less numerous over

time. However, developments are all but linear in most countries. And when we test for the

micro-foundations of modernisation theory, we find that cognitive mobilisation is not what

actually drives the development. Something else is going on.

This is why we went on and tested an alternative explanation of the evolution of partisanship,

which centres around the notion of political polarisation. And indeed, there is some effect of

left-right polarisation on partisanship. Both the analysis of aggregate and individual-level data

confirms that politics matter. The more polarised a party system is, the more partisans do we

find: this is what the pooled analysis (cross-country and over-time) revealed. Moreover, the

more polarised a system is perceived to be by individual citizens, the more likely it is that

they are partisans themselves. But again, these political correlates of the development of party

identification are modest at best, and can not fully explain what is going on in the six West

European countries under study.

We have changed the perspective of looking at party identification in the final step of our

analysis. Treating it as an independent variable, we considered the predictive power of it for

vote choices. What we find is that an average of three in four partisans actually support the

party they identify with, while one in four abstains from the election or votes for another

party. If we restrict this analysis to voting identifiers only, the respective proportion rises to

six in seven: one in seven voting identifiers votes for another party than the one he or she

identifies with. In both perspectives, party identification has lost some of it’s predictive power

for vote choices in Western European settings over the past decades.

Where does all of this lead us to? We believe there are a few insights that we have added to

the body of knowledge in this domain. One is that there is indeed no linear decline in

partisanship. While party identification is on the downturn in all the countries investigated,

the patterns we identify in this evolution are very country-specific. Secondly: sociological

explanations inspired by modernisation theory do not lead very far. Thirdly: political

15

Page 16: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

polarisation is one factor in the evolution of partisanship, but certainly no the only one and

perhaps not even a very powerful one. And fourth and finally: partisanship and the vote have

become more independent over the past decades in Western Europe, which makes party

identification a more powerful analytical instrument than it was found to be in the early

analysis.

References

Barton, Terry & Herbert Döring (1986), «Weaking partisanship and the higher educated in

Britain». European Journal of Political Research, 14:521-542.

Campbell, Angus, Philip Converse, Warren Miller & Donald Stokes (1960), The American

Voter. New York: John Wiley.

Converse, Philip (1964), «The Nature of Belief System in Mass Publics». I: David Apter, red.,

Ideology and Discontent. New York: The Free Press.

Converse, Philip (1969), «Of time and Partisan Stability». Comparative Political Studies,

2:139-171.

Converse, Philip (1975), «Public Opinion and Voting Behavior». I: F. Greenstein & N.

Polsby, red., Handbook of Political Science. Reading, Mass: Addison-Wesley.

Converse, Philip (1976), The Dynamics of Party Support. Cohort-Analyzing Party

Identification. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.

Dalton, Russel (1984), «Cognitive Mobilization and Partisan Dealignment in Advanced

Industrial Democracies». The Journal of Politics, 46:264-284.

Dalton, Russel (2000), «The Decline of Party Identifications». I: Russell Dalton & Martin

Wattenberg, red., Parties without partisans: Political Change in Advanced Industrial

Societies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

16

Page 17: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Reiter, Howard (1989), «Party decline in the West. A sceptic's view». Journal of Theoretical

Politics, 1:325-348.

Schmitt, Hermann (2002), “Partisanship in Western Europe and the US: Causes and

Consequences.” Paper prepared for presentation at the Annual Conference of the APSA in

Boston, MA, August 27 to September 1.

Schmitt, Hermann & Sören Holmberg (1995), «Political Parties in Decline?». I: Hans-Dieter

Klingemann & Dieter Fuchs, red., Citizens and the State. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

17

Page 18: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Table 1. A secular development of non-partisanship? Pooled country files. Log-odds.

Britain Denmark Germany Holland Norway Sweden

Reference election 1964 1973 1972 1971 1965 1968

1 0,1* 0,1* 0,3 0* 0,5 0*

2 0,3 -0,2* 0,6 0,1* 0,4 0,2

3 0,5 -0,4 0,8 -0,2 0,1* 0,2

4 0,8 0,6 0,7 0,2 0,1* 0,3

5 1 -0,1* 0,2 0,1* 0,2* 0,2

6 1,1 0* 1,1 0,4 0,5 0,5

7 1 0,8 0,7 0,6

8 1,2 0,8 0,7

9 1,1 1,3 0,8

10 0,9

pseudo-r2 ,045 ,059 ,039 ,009 ,049 ,026

Asterisk marks entries that are not significant at the 1 % level.

Coding for partisanship: Partisan 0, independent 1.

Table 2. Time and cognitive mobilisation (skills and involvement component) Pearson’s r.

education political interest

Great Britain ,04# -,08

Denmark ,22 -,05

Germany ,26 ,07

The Netherlands ,20 -,03

Norway ,19 ,04

Sweden ,20 -,03 # check coding!

18

Page 19: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Cognitive mobilisation indicators and strength of party identification Table 3. Cognitive mobilisation indicators and strength of party identification.

Raw regression coefficients.

Great Britain 1974 1979 1997 2001 Political interest ,25 ,26 ,23 ,23 Education -,21 -,15 -,06 -,09 Age ,09 ,12 ,12 ,13 Denmark 1979 1984 1990 1994 1998 Political interest ,38 ,19 ,17 ,21 ,33 Education -,15 -,10 -,08 -,09 -,16 Age ,21 ,07 ,22 ,18 ,07 Germany 1972 1976 1983 1987 1990 1994 1998 Political interest ,35 ,36 ,28 ,16 ,15 ,15 ,31 Education -,01 -,02 -,01 -,03 -,07 ,00 ,03 Age ,14 ,00 ,06 ,03 ,00 ,06 -,03 The Netherlands 1971 1977 1981 1986 1994 1998 Political interest ,33 ,11 ,32 ,36 ,32 ,42 Education -,04 -,04 -,05 -,06 ,03 -,06 Age ,19 ,09 ,12 ,17 ,23 ,18 Norway 1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997 2001 Political interest ,35 ,30 ,38 ,33 ,34 ,32 ,38 ,28 ,36 ,33 Education -,13 -,20 -,16 -,16 -,12 -,16 -,15 -,03 -,01 -,08 Age ,15 ,16 ,18 ,13 ,18 ,15 ,17 ,18 ,09 ,10 Sweden 1968 1970 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1998 Political interest ,22 ,21 ,22 ,25 ,23 ,26 ,25 ,23 ,22 ,22 ,24 Education -,27 -,22 -,23 -,23 -,17 -,14 -,18 -,15 ,07 -,15 -,13 Age ,14 ,15 ,22 ,11 ,14 ,15 ,16 ,17 ,18 ,17 ,17 Bold types: Significant at the 1 % - level. Coding: Party identification 1. Independent 2. weak identification 3 strong identification. In 1997, 1. Independent 2. Party Identification. Highest Education, 1 primary, 2 high school, 3 university Political interest, 1. no interest at all, little interest 2. fairly interested, 3. very interested Age 1. 30 and below, 2. 31- 50, 3. 51 and above +.

19

Page 20: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Partisanship and education Table 4a. Percent independents at different levels of education in Great Britain.

1964 1970 1974 1979 1983 1987 1992 1997 2001

primary 16 19 25 29 37 38 37 43 34

Britain secondary 19 25 28 34 41 40 39 40 42

high school 32 31 39 44 36 33 41 37 40

All Pearson r 0,06 0,08 0,06 0,08 0 -0,01 0,02 -0,04 0,06

Below 30 Pearson r 0,02 0,01 -0,01 0,04 -0,07 -0,06 -0,06 -0,04 0,07

Table 4b. Percent independents at different levels of education in Denmark.

1973 1975 1977 1979 1984 1990 1994

primary 44 38 70 43 45

Denmark secondary n.a. n.a. 49 48 78 53 54

high school 54 48 75 53 60

All Pearson r 0,07 0,09 0,04 0,08 0,12

Below 30 Pearson r n.a. -0,09 -0,06 -0,05 -0,05

Table 4c. Percent independents at different levels of education in Germany.

1972 1976 1980 1983 1987 1990 1994 1998

primary 39 52 58 60 56 48 69 65

Germany secondary 36 39 45 57 54 42 66 60

high school 34 34 43 43 52 39 61 46

All Pearson r -0,04 -0,14 -0,12 -0,09 -0,03 -0,07 -0,06 -0,15

Below 30 Pearson r -0,01 -0,12 -0,17 -0,1 -0,04 -0,02 -0,12 -0,16

Table 4d. Percent independents at different levels of education in the Netherlands.

1971 1972 1977 1981 1986 1989 1994 1998

primary 67 66 67 58 67 69 71

Netherlands secondary 60 n.a 71 66 61 74 68 75

high school 59 57 64 60 67 61 71

All Pearson r -0,06 -0,02 0,02 0,02 -0,06 0,01

Below 30 Pearson r -0,13 -0,05 -0,06 n.a. -0,18 -0,08

20

Page 21: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Table 4e. Percent independents at different levels of education in Norway.

1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997

Primary 22 32 33 23 24 24 29 37 45

Norway High school 32 42 37 34 31 33 40 46 50

University 33 53 49 36 34 37 46 44 42

All Pearson r 0,10 0,14 0,1 0,11 0,08 0,1 0,12 0,04 -0,02

Below 30 Pearson r 0,04 0,08 0,08 0,1 -0,01 0,01 -0,03 -0,12 -0,12

Table 4f. Percent independents at different levels of education in Sweden. .

1968 1970 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1998

primary 49 45 56 48 36 52 56 63 71 69 76

Sweden secondary 45 49 56 53 55 51 59 60 65 67 74

high school 56 52 61 52 54 54 66 65 67 66 68

All Pearson r 0,12 0,15 0,14 0,14 0,12 0,10 0,16 0,14 0,05 0,12 0,10

Below 30 Pearson r 0,02 0,05 0,03 0,03 0,02 0,01 0,08 0,03 -0,02 -0,02 -0,07

21

Page 22: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Table 5. Left-Right Polarisation and Party Identification. Pearson’s r (and n in parenthesis).

MRG-based left-right distance

two big parties

MRG-based left-right distance two polar parties

survey based left-right distance

two big parties

survey based left-right distance two polar parties

all identifier strong identifier

+.13 (61) +.21 (59)

+.18 (61) +.42 (59)**

+.24 (46) +.29 (44)

-.27 (46) +.32 (44)*

Great Britain all identifier strong identifier

-.45 (10) -.49 (10)

-.59 (10) -.60 (10)

+.38 (7) +.41 (7)

+.38 (7) +.41 (7)

Denmark all identifier strong identifier

+.07 (10) -.12 ( 9)

+.03 (10) -.09 ( 9)

+.49 (7)

+.88 (6)*

+.60 (7) +.67 (6)

Germany all identifier strong identifier

-.05 (11) -.42 ( 8)

+.05 (11) -.44 ( 8)

+.76 (8)* +.73 (8)*

-.04 (8) -.24 (8)

The Netherlands all identifier strong identifier

-.18 (9) +.30 (9)

+.30 (9) +.50 (9)

+.53 (7) +.43 (7)

+.74 (7) +.67 (7)

Norway all identifier strong identifier

-.51 (10) -.63 ( 9)

-.07 (10) -.21 ( 9)

-.44 (7) -.33 (6)

-.20 (7) -.06 (6)

Sweden all identifier strong identifier

+.11 (11)

+.69 (14)**

-.52 (11) +.24 (14)

+.20 (10) +.31 (10)

+.33 (10) +.41 (10)

Source: European Voters Data File; the MRG database (Budge, Klingemann et al. 2001); and the data collected and reported in the appendix tables of Schmitt 2002. Note: *p=.05 **p=.01

22

Page 23: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Table 6. Perception of Left-Right Polarisation Between the Two Major Parties and Party Identification.

two major

parties

election

perceived left-right distance

by strength PID(Pearson’s r)

n of cases

Great Britain Labour-Conservatives

2001

+.18

2221

Denmark S-Venstre 1994 +.10 1801

Germany SPD-CDU/CSU 1980 1983 1987 1990 1998

+.13 +.15 +.20 +.06 +.12

1055 920

1215 765

1546

The Netherlands PvdA-CDA 1981 1982 1986 1989 1994 1998

+.12 +.05 +.06 +.13 +.06 +.09

1468 674

1239 1429 516

1596

Norway Labour-Conservatives

1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993

+.08 +.08 +.13 +.06 +.15 +.09

892 1344 1350 1923 1982 1870

Sweden S-M 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1998

+.25 +.25 +.18 +.23 +.23 +.19 +.20

2416 2592 2535 2395 2326 2154 1959

Source: European Voters Data File.

23

Page 24: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Table 7 Proportion of Loyalists in All Identifiers

(i.e. including those who did not vote or can not tell which party; figures are %)

Denmark Germany Netherlands Norway Sweden Great Britain 1960

1 2 3 4 81

1965 84 6 77 7 8 87 9 85

1970 86 74 1 68 2 88 3 78 85 85 4 75

1975 75 6 78 90 87 7 78 72 87 8 9 81 89 75

1980 88 1 ? 85 2 ? 86 3 87 74 4

1985 86 85 6 ? 7 86 76 8 82 9 72 83

1990 81 72 1 79 2 77 3 76 4 82 80 75 82

1995 6 7 81 70 8 81 77 ? 77 9

2000 1 68

Source: National Election Studies of these countries as available in the European Voters Data File. Note: Empty spaces indicate that the respective information is not available. A “?” indicates that the recoding of the data does not allow to produce the figure in question.

24

Page 25: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Table 8 Proportion of Loyalists in Voting Identifiers

(i.e. excluding those who did not vote or can not tell which party; figures are %)

Denmark Germany Netherlands Norway Sweden Great Britain 1960

1 2 3 4 91

1965 89 6 90 7 8 93 9 91

1970 95 90 1 91 2 92 3 81 92 93 4 86

1975 87 6 85 96 91 7 87 93 96 8 9 88 93 88

1980 94 1 82 94 2 93 92 3 93 87 4

1985 96 90 6 86 7 92 86 8 90 9 86 92

1990 90 86 1 86 2 87 3 89 4 88 88 82 89

1995 6 7 89 87 8 85 84 83 85 9

2000 1 87

Source: National Election Studies of these countries as available in the European Voters Data Base.

25

Page 26: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Figure 1 The Evolution of the Level of Partisanship

in Six European Democracies

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

Germany Sweden UK Norway Netherlands Denmark

26

Page 27: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Figure 2 Proportion of Loyalists in All Identifiers

Source: National Election Studies. Note that all identifiers include those who do not report their vote and abstainers.

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 50

60

70

80

90

100

UK all N all S all D all NL all DK all

27

Page 28: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Appendix Education Table 3a. Education in Great Britain. Percent.

1964 1970 1974 1979 1983 1987 1992 1997 2001

primary 67 69 67 55 75 62 77 75 53# Britain secondary 31 28 29 40 15 31 16 14 33 high school 2 3 5 6 10 7 7 11 14 1740 1772 2454 1846 3935 3813 3527 4178 2303 # check coding!

Table 3b. Education in Denmark. Percent.

1973 1975 1977 1979 1984 1990 1994

primary 68 63 55 45 45

Denmark secondary n.a. n.a. 23 26 31 35 34

high school 9 12 13 20 21

Table 3c. Education in Germany. Percent.

1972 1976 1980 1983 1987 1990 1994 1998

primary 82 63 69 67 69 58 46 29 Germany secondary 9 23 20 22 19 26 34 39 high school 9 14 11 12 12 16 20 32

2039 2053 979 1622 1934 2046 2007 1993

Table 3d. Education in the Netherlands. Percent.

1971 1972 1977 1981 1986 1989 1994 1998

primary 78 79 81 63 59 47 45 51

Netherlands secondary 14 12 7 19 23 33 35 27

high school 8 10 13 17 19 19 23 22

Table 3e. Education in Norway. Percent.

1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997

Primary 43 37 32 36 30 19 24 23 18

Norway High school 47 49 53 51 54 54 57 52 58

University 11 14 15 14 16 17 19 25 24

28

Page 29: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

Table 3f. Education in Sweden. Percent.

1968 1970 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1998

primary 49 45 56 48 36 52 56 63 71 69 76

Sweden secondary 45 49 56 53 55 51 59 60 65 67 74

high school 56 52 61 52 54 54 66 65 67 66 68

Political interest Table 4a. Political interest in Britain. Percent.

1964 1970 1974 1979 1983 1987 1992 1997 2001*

great deal 17 13 31 28

Britain some 45 48 36 33

not much 29 32 26 28

not at all 8 8 7 10

means 2,3 2,3 2,1 2,2 * In 2001, the alternative ‘great deal’ was replaced with ‘quite’ and ‘quite a lot’. These two are collapsed into

‘great deal’ in table 4a.

Table 4b. Political interest in Denmark. Percent.

1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1984 1987 1990 1994 1998

Very 12 19 21 21 20 20 18 15 19 20 24

Denmark Fairly 38 54 42 57 42 43 43 42 43 44 49

Little 50 24 32 18 32 31 31 35 32 32 24

Not at all 2 5 5 7 7 8 8 6 5 3

means 2,4 2,1 2,2 2,1 2,3 2,3 2,3 2,4 2,3 2,2 2,1

Table 4c. Political interest in Germany. Percent.

1972 1976 1980 1983 1987 1990 1994 1998

very 56 56 10 7 16 7 10

Germany strong 33 32 31 28 43 18 38

fairly 11 12 19 22 10 50 46

not 0 0 40 42 31 25 6

means 1,5 1,6 2,9 3,0 2,6 2,9 2,5

Different question in 1972 and 1976.

29

Page 30: Party Identification and the Vote Six European Countries ... · attachment to a political party. Party identification is a long-term, affective, psychological identification with

30

Table 4d. Political interest in the Netherlands. Percent.

1971 1972 1977 1981 1986 1989 1994 1998

very 47 44 39 32 27 23 22 26

Netherlands fairly 43 45 50 55 57 63 66 65

not at all 10 11 11 14 16 14 13 9

means 1,6 1,7 1,7 1,8 1,9 1,9 1,9 1,8

Table 4e. Political interest in Norway. Percent.

1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997

very 8 8 14 9 11 8 8 7 9

Norway fairly 50 52 58 53 57 32 53 52 52

little 42 40 28 37 32 53 36 37 36

not at all 7 2 4 3

means 2,3 2,3 2,2 2,3 2,2 2,6 2,3 2,4 2,3

Table 4f. Political interest in Sweden. Percent.

1968 1970 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1998

very 10 10 11 12 13 10 9 9 10 11 10

Sweden fairly 40 39 41 44 41 42 43 42 45 47 45

little 40 40 38 35 39 39 41 43 39 35 37

not at all 10 11 10 8 7 8 7 7 7 7 7

means 2,5 2,5 2,5 2,4 2,5 2,5 2,5 2,5 2,4 2,4 2,4