open access models access in developing countries · access in developing countries open access...

54
Information for Development Program www.infoDev.org OPEN ACCESS MODELS Options for Improving Backbone Access in Developing Countries OPEN ACCESS MODELS + ACCESS FOR ALL

Upload: trinhkhanh

Post on 11-Apr-2018

221 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

TRANSCRIPT

www.infoDev.org

Information for Development Program

www.infoDev.org

OPEN ACCESS MODELS Options for Improving Backbone Access in Developing Countries

OPEN

AC

CESS M

OD

ELS

+ ACCESS FOR ALL

OPEN ACCESS MODELS

www.infoDev.org

Information for Development Program

Options for Improving Backbone Access in Developing Countries

Open Access front 2-27-07.indd iOpen Access front 2-27-07.indd i 2/27/07 1:03:12 PM2/27/07 1:03:12 PM

OPEN ACCESS MODELS

www.infoDev.org

Information for Development Program

Options for Improving Backbone Access in Developing Countries

Open Access front 2-27-07.indd iOpen Access front 2-27-07.indd i 2/27/07 1:03:12 PM2/27/07 1:03:12 PM

To cite this publication:Spintrack AB. 2005. Open Access Models: Options for Improving Backbone Access in Developing Countries. Washington, DC: infoDev / World Bank. Available at: http://www.infodev.org/en/Publication.10.html

©2005The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank1818 H Street, N.W.Washington, D.C. 20433U.S.A.

All rights reservedManufactured in the United States of America

The fi ndings, interpretations and conclusions expressed herein are entirely those of the author(s) and do not necessarily refl ect the view of infoDev, the Donors of infoDev, the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank and its affi liated organizations, the Board of Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank cannot guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply on the part of the World Bank any judgement of the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.

The material in this publication is copyrighted. Copying or transmitting portions of this work may be a violation of applicable law. The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and normally will promptly grant permission for use. For permission to copy or reprint any part of this work, please contact [email protected].

Open Access front 2-27-07.indd iiOpen Access front 2-27-07.indd ii 2/27/07 1:03:14 PM2/27/07 1:03:14 PM

To cite this publication:Spintrack AB. 2005. Open Access Models: Options for Improving Backbone Access in Developing Countries. Washington, DC: infoDev / World Bank. Available at: http://www.infodev.org/en/Publication.10.html

©2005The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank1818 H Street, N.W.Washington, D.C. 20433U.S.A.

All rights reservedManufactured in the United States of America

The fi ndings, interpretations and conclusions expressed herein are entirely those of the author(s) and do not necessarily refl ect the view of infoDev, the Donors of infoDev, the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank and its affi liated organizations, the Board of Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank cannot guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply on the part of the World Bank any judgement of the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.

The material in this publication is copyrighted. Copying or transmitting portions of this work may be a violation of applicable law. The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and normally will promptly grant permission for use. For permission to copy or reprint any part of this work, please contact [email protected].

Open Access front 2-27-07.indd iiOpen Access front 2-27-07.indd ii 2/27/07 1:03:14 PM2/27/07 1:03:14 PM

Table of Contents . iii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

INTRODUCTION 1

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 5

1. OVERCOMING CURRENT OBSTACLES 9

2. UNLOCKING WIDER ACCESS TO ICT 15

2.1 IP Networks: a Paradigm Shift that Opens up Potential 15

2.2 Significant Market Developments – “Going with the Grain” 17

2.3 The Open Access Approach 19

2.4 Rural “Plug and Play” 21

2.5 Infrastructure Providers and Municipal Networks 22

2.6 Keeping Traffic Local and Regional to Save Money – National and Regional Internet Exchange Points (IXPs)and Inter-Country Links 24

2.7 Bringing Down the Price of International Connectivity 24

2.8 Implications for Policymakers and Regulators 26

3. TAKING ADVANTAGE OF THE OPPORTUNITY 29

3.1 Government Policymakers and Regulators 29

3.2 International Donors 29

3.3 The Private Sector 30

4. APPENDICES 33

Appendix A1: Background Reading 33

Appendix A2: Open Access Models for Information and Communication Infrastructure – Some Basic Principles 34

A2.1 Anyone can play 34

A2.2 Technological Neutrality 34

Open Access front 2-27-07.indd iiiOpen Access front 2-27-07.indd iii 2/27/07 1:03:14 PM2/27/07 1:03:14 PM

Table of Contents . iii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

INTRODUCTION 1

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 5

1. OVERCOMING CURRENT OBSTACLES 9

2. UNLOCKING WIDER ACCESS TO ICT 15

2.1 IP Networks: a Paradigm Shift that Opens up Potential 15

2.2 Significant Market Developments – “Going with the Grain” 17

2.3 The Open Access Approach 19

2.4 Rural “Plug and Play” 21

2.5 Infrastructure Providers and Municipal Networks 22

2.6 Keeping Traffic Local and Regional to Save Money – National and Regional Internet Exchange Points (IXPs)and Inter-Country Links 24

2.7 Bringing Down the Price of International Connectivity 24

2.8 Implications for Policymakers and Regulators 26

3. TAKING ADVANTAGE OF THE OPPORTUNITY 29

3.1 Government Policymakers and Regulators 29

3.2 International Donors 29

3.3 The Private Sector 30

4. APPENDICES 33

Appendix A1: Background Reading 33

Appendix A2: Open Access Models for Information and Communication Infrastructure – Some Basic Principles 34

A2.1 Anyone can play 34

A2.2 Technological Neutrality 34

Open Access front 2-27-07.indd iiiOpen Access front 2-27-07.indd iii 2/27/07 1:03:14 PM2/27/07 1:03:14 PM

iv . Open Access Models

A2.3 Fair and non-discriminatory competition at all layers 34

A2.4 Transparency to ensure fair trading within and between layers 34

A2.5 Everyone can connect to everyone else at the layer interface 34

A2.6 Devolved rather than centralized solutions 35

Appendix A3: Origins of the Term Open Access 35

Appendix A4: Business Model and Technology Approaches for Small-Scale Rural Operators 36

A.4.1 n-Logue, India (CorDECT wireless local loop) 38

A.4.2 A “GSM-lite” network utilizing IP technology 39

Appendix A5: Municipal Networks – Background Information 40

A5.1 How municipal networks arose and their characteristics 40

A5.2 An early municipal network development (Stokab) 41

A5.3 Rural municipal providers (UTOPIA, iProvo, and Zipp) 42

A5.4 A recent municipal network initiative (Amsterdam) 43

A5.5 The case of state finance (ATLAS) 44

A5.6 Arguments for and against municipal networks 45

Appendix A6: Glossary of Terms 46

Open Access front 2-27-07.indd ivOpen Access front 2-27-07.indd iv 2/27/07 1:03:14 PM2/27/07 1:03:14 PM

iv . Open Access Models

A2.3 Fair and non-discriminatory competition at all layers 34

A2.4 Transparency to ensure fair trading within and between layers 34

A2.5 Everyone can connect to everyone else at the layer interface 34

A2.6 Devolved rather than centralized solutions 35

Appendix A3: Origins of the Term Open Access 35

Appendix A4: Business Model and Technology Approaches for Small-Scale Rural Operators 36

A.4.1 n-Logue, India (CorDECT wireless local loop) 38

A.4.2 A “GSM-lite” network utilizing IP technology 39

Appendix A5: Municipal Networks – Background Information 40

A5.1 How municipal networks arose and their characteristics 40

A5.2 An early municipal network development (Stokab) 41

A5.3 Rural municipal providers (UTOPIA, iProvo, and Zipp) 42

A5.4 A recent municipal network initiative (Amsterdam) 43

A5.5 The case of state finance (ATLAS) 44

A5.6 Arguments for and against municipal networks 45

Appendix A6: Glossary of Terms 46

Open Access front 2-27-07.indd ivOpen Access front 2-27-07.indd iv 2/27/07 1:03:14 PM2/27/07 1:03:14 PM

1 The Project Director is Bjorn Soderberg and other team members are: Petter Lundkvist, Olof Hesselmark, Erik Eliasson, Johan Montelius and Johan Bilien.

Introduction . 1

INTRODUCTION

In late 2004, infoDev commissioned a team fromSpintrack AB of Stockholm, Sweden, to conduct astudy titled “Leveraging New Technologies and OpenAccess Models: Options for Improving BackboneAccess in Developing Countries (with a Focus onSub-Saharan Africa).” The Spintrack core team work-ing on the project included Anders Comstedt, EricOsiakwan and Russell Southwood1. The study wascompleted in the summer of 2005.

During the course of the study, team membersvisited: Ghana, Kenya, Tanzania, Mozambique, andSouth Africa. They also spoke to Africans in manyother countries who were at events the membersattended during the study period. These eventsincluded: a United Nations (UN) information andcommunication technology (ICT) Task ForceMeeting, the International TelecommunicationsUnion (ITU) African Public-Private PartnershipMeeting, GSM Africa, Internet Corporation forAssigned Names and Numbers (ICANN), theTRASA/CATIA Wireless Regulation and PolicySeminar, and the first African Voice-Over InternetProtocol (VoIP) Forum.

To keep a clear focus in the report, the study exam-ines the leveraging of new technologies in relationto Open Access ideas rather than as a topic in itsown right. It focuses on how, under the right cir-cumstances, new and cheaper technologies canoffer opportunities for low-cost market entry indeveloping countries. Therefore, the study does notinclude detailed descriptions of technologyapproaches except in Appendix A4.

This report has three main sections that are sup-ported by supplementary material in the appen-dices and endnotes:

Section 1 looks at the kinds of obstacles that pre-vent the wider use of ICTs as development tools.

Section 2 examines how the obstacles might beovercome. It describes what an Open Accessapproach is and how it might be applied at differentlevels: local, national, regional, and international.

The report concludes by highlighting the implicationsof the approach for policymakers and regulators.

Section 3 examines how the different stakeholders -policymakers, regulators, international donors, andthe private sector – might make use of an OpenAccess approach.

The appendices provide supporting material, including:a list of Background Reading (A1); a set of OpenAccess Principles (A2); Origins of the term OpenAccess (A3); technology approaches for small-scale ruraloperators (A4); municipal networks – backgroundinformation (A5); and a Glossary of Terms (A6).

This study tackles some of the major difficultiesexperienced by developing countries by stepping backfrom day-to-day battles over policy and regulation.It attempts to see a way ahead through a flexible butholistic approach that will maximize the economicand social returns communications technologies canbring. It does not seek to provide a universal panaceabut a set of ideas that can be applied in different waysin particular local circumstances.

This study is not intended to be the last word onOpen Access but as a way of provoking a debateabout how certain objectives can be achievedthrough policy and regulation. It will be an evolvingdebate that needs to draw in all those involved. Thispaper is intended as a contribution to that debate.

The primary focus of the study is Sub-SaharanAfrica because we believe that Open Access ideasprovide a useful way of overcoming some of thehistoric obstacles to providing greater access to com-munication in that region. However, the ideas maywell be more broadly applicable and the degree towhich they are will emerge from subsequent debate.

Although the study has recommendations, thesehave been kept at a fairly general level to avoidspecific prescriptions becoming precise formulas foraction. There are different ways of achieving thesame ends in different circumstances, and it is impor-tant not to have yet another mono-dimensional set ofapproaches to complex issues. If on this basis thepaper lacks precision in its recommendations, it isbecause those using Open Access ideas need to beable to reach conclusions that are appropriate to

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 1

1 The Project Director is Bjorn Soderberg and other team members are: Petter Lundkvist, Olof Hesselmark, Erik Eliasson, Johan Montelius and Johan Bilien.

Introduction . 1

INTRODUCTION

In late 2004, infoDev commissioned a team fromSpintrack AB of Stockholm, Sweden, to conduct astudy titled “Leveraging New Technologies and OpenAccess Models: Options for Improving BackboneAccess in Developing Countries (with a Focus onSub-Saharan Africa).” The Spintrack core team work-ing on the project included Anders Comstedt, EricOsiakwan and Russell Southwood1. The study wascompleted in the summer of 2005.

During the course of the study, team membersvisited: Ghana, Kenya, Tanzania, Mozambique, andSouth Africa. They also spoke to Africans in manyother countries who were at events the membersattended during the study period. These eventsincluded: a United Nations (UN) information andcommunication technology (ICT) Task ForceMeeting, the International TelecommunicationsUnion (ITU) African Public-Private PartnershipMeeting, GSM Africa, Internet Corporation forAssigned Names and Numbers (ICANN), theTRASA/CATIA Wireless Regulation and PolicySeminar, and the first African Voice-Over InternetProtocol (VoIP) Forum.

To keep a clear focus in the report, the study exam-ines the leveraging of new technologies in relationto Open Access ideas rather than as a topic in itsown right. It focuses on how, under the right cir-cumstances, new and cheaper technologies canoffer opportunities for low-cost market entry indeveloping countries. Therefore, the study does notinclude detailed descriptions of technologyapproaches except in Appendix A4.

This report has three main sections that are sup-ported by supplementary material in the appen-dices and endnotes:

Section 1 looks at the kinds of obstacles that pre-vent the wider use of ICTs as development tools.

Section 2 examines how the obstacles might beovercome. It describes what an Open Accessapproach is and how it might be applied at differentlevels: local, national, regional, and international.

The report concludes by highlighting the implicationsof the approach for policymakers and regulators.

Section 3 examines how the different stakeholders -policymakers, regulators, international donors, andthe private sector – might make use of an OpenAccess approach.

The appendices provide supporting material, including:a list of Background Reading (A1); a set of OpenAccess Principles (A2); Origins of the term OpenAccess (A3); technology approaches for small-scale ruraloperators (A4); municipal networks – backgroundinformation (A5); and a Glossary of Terms (A6).

This study tackles some of the major difficultiesexperienced by developing countries by stepping backfrom day-to-day battles over policy and regulation.It attempts to see a way ahead through a flexible butholistic approach that will maximize the economicand social returns communications technologies canbring. It does not seek to provide a universal panaceabut a set of ideas that can be applied in different waysin particular local circumstances.

This study is not intended to be the last word onOpen Access but as a way of provoking a debateabout how certain objectives can be achievedthrough policy and regulation. It will be an evolvingdebate that needs to draw in all those involved. Thispaper is intended as a contribution to that debate.

The primary focus of the study is Sub-SaharanAfrica because we believe that Open Access ideasprovide a useful way of overcoming some of thehistoric obstacles to providing greater access to com-munication in that region. However, the ideas maywell be more broadly applicable and the degree towhich they are will emerge from subsequent debate.

Although the study has recommendations, thesehave been kept at a fairly general level to avoidspecific prescriptions becoming precise formulas foraction. There are different ways of achieving thesame ends in different circumstances, and it is impor-tant not to have yet another mono-dimensional set ofapproaches to complex issues. If on this basis thepaper lacks precision in its recommendations, it isbecause those using Open Access ideas need to beable to reach conclusions that are appropriate to

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 1

2 Because much of what is happening in Sub-Saharan Africa has taken place over the last year, many of these endnotes are not referenced to academic orconsultancy studies. As there is a time-lag between what appear to be emerging realities and the capturing of what is happening, they are based on ourconversations with players on the continent. In some instances, these include plans that can be described but cannot be more clearly identified for reasonsof commercial confidentiality.

their own circumstances: there is no policy kit witha single set of instructions.

This study is primarily designed to be read bynational policymakers and their counterparts indonor agencies. It is written assuming some famil-iarity with the field but is neither an expert nor anacademic paper. For this reason, much of the sup-porting evidence for assertions made in the study isin footnotes.2

The study’s authors wish thank those interviewed who gave generously their time and ideas (particularly

those in Sub-Saharan Africa). They also wish to thankWebopedia for the definition of terms found in theglossary in Appendix A5.

Finally they convey their thanks to all of those whocommented on the draft version of this study:Mavis Ampah, Peter Lane Baldwin, JeromeBezzina, Doreen Bogdan, William Kerr-Smith,Kerry McNamara, William Melody, SamiaMelhem, Bjorn Pehrson, Susan Schorr, Peter LSmith, Mostafa Terrab and Charles Watt.

2 . Open Access Models

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 2

2 Because much of what is happening in Sub-Saharan Africa has taken place over the last year, many of these endnotes are not referenced to academic orconsultancy studies. As there is a time-lag between what appear to be emerging realities and the capturing of what is happening, they are based on ourconversations with players on the continent. In some instances, these include plans that can be described but cannot be more clearly identified for reasonsof commercial confidentiality.

their own circumstances: there is no policy kit witha single set of instructions.

This study is primarily designed to be read bynational policymakers and their counterparts indonor agencies. It is written assuming some famil-iarity with the field but is neither an expert nor anacademic paper. For this reason, much of the sup-porting evidence for assertions made in the study isin footnotes.2

The study’s authors wish thank those interviewed who gave generously their time and ideas (particularly

those in Sub-Saharan Africa). They also wish to thankWebopedia for the definition of terms found in theglossary in Appendix A5.

Finally they convey their thanks to all of those whocommented on the draft version of this study:Mavis Ampah, Peter Lane Baldwin, JeromeBezzina, Doreen Bogdan, William Kerr-Smith,Kerry McNamara, William Melody, SamiaMelhem, Bjorn Pehrson, Susan Schorr, Peter LSmith, Mostafa Terrab and Charles Watt.

2 . Open Access Models

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 2

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 3 Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 3

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 4 Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 4

3 Open Access as a term is used in several different ways and a brief summary of the origins of the term is provided in Appendix A3.4 There are several more detailed ways of describing the layers and these capture what are essentially technical functions of the network. Applications include

things like Web and mail browsers. Services include all forms of content whether voice, data or images.

the realities of the current moment: What mighthave happened before now no longer works.

A number of obstacles have prevented practical,effective action on the desired policy outcomesidentified. These include: the dominance of thehistoric operator in policy discussions; the politi-cal difficulties of the privatization process; thereasons for resistance to the introduction of new,cost-saving technologies; the difficulties with pro-viding universal access; the high cost of interna-tional bandwidth; and the difficulties of financingnew, international infrastructure to lower costs.

Rather than continuing a fruitless debate over thedetails of what might have been, it is perhaps timeto see whether there is another way of looking athow these obstacles might be overcome. If ICTs areto serve as tools for development we need to lookat how it might be possible to provide easier,cheaper and wider access to them.

The gradual transition from circuit-switched networks to Internet protocol (IP) networks is cre-ating a paradigm shift that is allowing the growthof decentralized services. It argues that IP networkarchitecture – where the “intelligence” is located atthe edge of the network – creates an opportunity tochange the underlying structure, and thus the busi-ness model, of information and communicationsinfrastructure and services.

The basis for these changes can be understood bylooking at how those involved describe the operationof IP networks. Diagram 1 shows a Network Layersmodel. Essentially there are three key layers: physicalinfrastructure, transmission and services (includingapplications and content). In practical terms eachlayer has a set of functional rules that allow it tointerface with the other layer and for informationto flow over the network.4 In terms of day-to-dayreality, these network functions are combined withReach (the geographic scope of providers) and Typeof Customer (wholesale or retail).

The interface between layers is technically standard-ized by protocols and commercially agreed in ServiceLevel Agreements and other businesses and contractcommitments. The latter also tend to be standardized

EXECUTIVESUMMARY“Open Access is about creating competition in all layers

of the IP network (see diagram on opposite page) allow-ing a wide variety of physical networks and applicationsto interact in an open architecture. Put plainly, anyonecan connect to anyone in a technology-neutral frame-work that encourages innovative, low-cost delivery tousers. It encourages market entry from smaller, localcompanies and seeks to ensure that no one entity cantake a position of dominant market power. It requirestransparency to ensure fair trading within and betweenthe layers based on clear, comparative information onmarket prices and services. It seeks to build on the char-acteristics of the IP network to allow devolved localsolutions rather than centralized ones.3”

Developing country heads of state have committedthemselves to creating information societies as part ofthe World Summit on the Information Society(WSIS) process. Considerable energy is beingexpended both as part of WSIS and elsewhere tobring this about. For those involved in development –whether governments, donors or non–governmentalorganizations (NGOs) – ICTs are essential tools fordelivering work in a number of important areas,including health, education, and e-government.

These ICT tools have the capacity to make infor-mation and services more widely available, thusimproving the opportunities of the poorest in soci-ety. In order for these tools to be successfully used,all those involved in development require commu-nications that are cheap and widely available, par-ticularly in the poorer and harder-to-reach, ruralareas.

ICT as a development issue is now high on theagenda but developing country policymakers findthemselves frustrated by a policy and regulatoryenvironment that is not yet producing the “step-change” required to address these issues in a pro-ductive way. Past circumstances have resulted in amismatch between the desired policy objectives and

Executive summary . 5

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 5

3 Open Access as a term is used in several different ways and a brief summary of the origins of the term is provided in Appendix A3.4 There are several more detailed ways of describing the layers and these capture what are essentially technical functions of the network. Applications include

things like Web and mail browsers. Services include all forms of content whether voice, data or images.

the realities of the current moment: What mighthave happened before now no longer works.

A number of obstacles have prevented practical,effective action on the desired policy outcomesidentified. These include: the dominance of thehistoric operator in policy discussions; the politi-cal difficulties of the privatization process; thereasons for resistance to the introduction of new,cost-saving technologies; the difficulties with pro-viding universal access; the high cost of interna-tional bandwidth; and the difficulties of financingnew, international infrastructure to lower costs.

Rather than continuing a fruitless debate over thedetails of what might have been, it is perhaps timeto see whether there is another way of looking athow these obstacles might be overcome. If ICTs areto serve as tools for development we need to lookat how it might be possible to provide easier,cheaper and wider access to them.

The gradual transition from circuit-switched networks to Internet protocol (IP) networks is cre-ating a paradigm shift that is allowing the growthof decentralized services. It argues that IP networkarchitecture – where the “intelligence” is located atthe edge of the network – creates an opportunity tochange the underlying structure, and thus the busi-ness model, of information and communicationsinfrastructure and services.

The basis for these changes can be understood bylooking at how those involved describe the operationof IP networks. Diagram 1 shows a Network Layersmodel. Essentially there are three key layers: physicalinfrastructure, transmission and services (includingapplications and content). In practical terms eachlayer has a set of functional rules that allow it tointerface with the other layer and for informationto flow over the network.4 In terms of day-to-dayreality, these network functions are combined withReach (the geographic scope of providers) and Typeof Customer (wholesale or retail).

The interface between layers is technically standard-ized by protocols and commercially agreed in ServiceLevel Agreements and other businesses and contractcommitments. The latter also tend to be standardized

EXECUTIVESUMMARY“Open Access is about creating competition in all layers

of the IP network (see diagram on opposite page) allow-ing a wide variety of physical networks and applicationsto interact in an open architecture. Put plainly, anyonecan connect to anyone in a technology-neutral frame-work that encourages innovative, low-cost delivery tousers. It encourages market entry from smaller, localcompanies and seeks to ensure that no one entity cantake a position of dominant market power. It requirestransparency to ensure fair trading within and betweenthe layers based on clear, comparative information onmarket prices and services. It seeks to build on the char-acteristics of the IP network to allow devolved localsolutions rather than centralized ones.3”

Developing country heads of state have committedthemselves to creating information societies as part ofthe World Summit on the Information Society(WSIS) process. Considerable energy is beingexpended both as part of WSIS and elsewhere tobring this about. For those involved in development –whether governments, donors or non–governmentalorganizations (NGOs) – ICTs are essential tools fordelivering work in a number of important areas,including health, education, and e-government.

These ICT tools have the capacity to make infor-mation and services more widely available, thusimproving the opportunities of the poorest in soci-ety. In order for these tools to be successfully used,all those involved in development require commu-nications that are cheap and widely available, par-ticularly in the poorer and harder-to-reach, ruralareas.

ICT as a development issue is now high on theagenda but developing country policymakers findthemselves frustrated by a policy and regulatoryenvironment that is not yet producing the “step-change” required to address these issues in a pro-ductive way. Past circumstances have resulted in amismatch between the desired policy objectives and

Executive summary . 5

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 5

and in a form appropriate to them. A diversity ofservices and physical infrastructure means that nosingle business model has to fit all users: smaller,lower cost operators can go where larger organiza-tions might fear to tread.

Open Access focuses on lowering the cost of busi-ness entry but is “technology-neutral.” The OpenAccess approach seeks to emphasize innovation thatencourages providers to identify which technologieswork at the right (lower) price: the technologies thatare suitable will vary enormously depending on his-toric legacy equipment and physical circumstances.

Through Open Access, the market (with a gentlehand from the public sector) can begin to turn com-munication into a public good available to widergroups of people. Although Open Access places theeffective operation of markets at its core, it acknowl-edges that the market will not deliver in all circum-stances. It sees the challenge as extending communi-cations to those at the bottom of the income pyra-mid by lowering the cost of services. In these situa-tions the function of the public sector is to create thecircumstances for successful Open Access (throughpartly funding infrastructure) and provide incentivesfor the roll-out of services as widely as possible.

At the rural level, Open Access emphasizes the impor-tance of small-scale providers who can provide cheaperservices than traditional operators because their entryand operating costs are lower. In an Open Access

as the number of actors grows. For example, oneplayer on the transport layer can rent fiber from sev-eral dark fiber providers to span its network and willneed similar performance standards from each tosimplify its offer to the service layer.

There are a number of market developments thatwill shape policy and regulation in the future. Twomain trends are the separation of infrastructure andservices and availability of “disruptive” technologiesthat offer the possibility of cheaper access to voiceand data. These trends not only make possible, butcreate a strong rationale for, Open Access models.

Open Access is designed to create competition in alllayers of the IP network allowing a wide variety ofphysical networks and applications to interact in anopen architecture. Put plainly, anyone can connect toanyone in a technology-neutral framework thatencourages innovative, low-cost delivery to users. Itencourages market entry from smaller, local compa-nies and seeks to ensure that no one entity can take aposition of dominant market power. It requires trans-parency to ensure fair trading within and between thelayers based on clear, comparative information onmarket prices and services. It seeks to build on thecharacteristics of the IP network to allow devolvedlocal solutions rather than centralized ones.

The “openness” creates a market dynamic at everylevel in the system, emphasizing the need to inno-vate in cost terms to expand the user base at a price

6 . Open Access Models

DIAGRAM 1: Layered networks model

Local National International

Layer

Physical infrastructure

Transmission

Services

WholesaleR

etail

Type ofcustomer

Reach

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 6

and in a form appropriate to them. A diversity ofservices and physical infrastructure means that nosingle business model has to fit all users: smaller,lower cost operators can go where larger organiza-tions might fear to tread.

Open Access focuses on lowering the cost of busi-ness entry but is “technology-neutral.” The OpenAccess approach seeks to emphasize innovation thatencourages providers to identify which technologieswork at the right (lower) price: the technologies thatare suitable will vary enormously depending on his-toric legacy equipment and physical circumstances.

Through Open Access, the market (with a gentlehand from the public sector) can begin to turn com-munication into a public good available to widergroups of people. Although Open Access places theeffective operation of markets at its core, it acknowl-edges that the market will not deliver in all circum-stances. It sees the challenge as extending communi-cations to those at the bottom of the income pyra-mid by lowering the cost of services. In these situa-tions the function of the public sector is to create thecircumstances for successful Open Access (throughpartly funding infrastructure) and provide incentivesfor the roll-out of services as widely as possible.

At the rural level, Open Access emphasizes the impor-tance of small-scale providers who can provide cheaperservices than traditional operators because their entryand operating costs are lower. In an Open Access

as the number of actors grows. For example, oneplayer on the transport layer can rent fiber from sev-eral dark fiber providers to span its network and willneed similar performance standards from each tosimplify its offer to the service layer.

There are a number of market developments thatwill shape policy and regulation in the future. Twomain trends are the separation of infrastructure andservices and availability of “disruptive” technologiesthat offer the possibility of cheaper access to voiceand data. These trends not only make possible, butcreate a strong rationale for, Open Access models.

Open Access is designed to create competition in alllayers of the IP network allowing a wide variety ofphysical networks and applications to interact in anopen architecture. Put plainly, anyone can connect toanyone in a technology-neutral framework thatencourages innovative, low-cost delivery to users. Itencourages market entry from smaller, local compa-nies and seeks to ensure that no one entity can take aposition of dominant market power. It requires trans-parency to ensure fair trading within and between thelayers based on clear, comparative information onmarket prices and services. It seeks to build on thecharacteristics of the IP network to allow devolvedlocal solutions rather than centralized ones.

The “openness” creates a market dynamic at everylevel in the system, emphasizing the need to inno-vate in cost terms to expand the user base at a price

6 . Open Access Models

DIAGRAM 1: Layered networks model

Local National International

Layer

Physical infrastructure

Transmission

Services

WholesaleR

etail

Type ofcustomer

Reach

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 6

At the international level, the Open Access approachemphasizes the importance of bringing the cost ofinternational bandwidth down to cut the cost ofcommunication for developing countries (particularlySub-Saharan Africa), help spread national infrastruc-ture, and encourage the growth of new global busi-nesses such as call centers and outsourcing.

With an Open Access approach, government – at anational or local level – represents the public inter-est, particularly for the growth of the economy, anda social responsibility for the less well-off. It needsto act as a fair referee on competition issues andcreate a level playing field for providers. It alsoensures that the interests of the users of the infra-structure (both consumers and service companies)are well represented in any governance mechanism.

In this new light touch role, government and theautonomous regulators that implement its policieshave several key roles: to lower the barriers toremove as many unnecessary regulatory barriers aspossible; to create a favorable business environmentthat offers investors enough certainty to developtheir businesses and have a fair chance at a reason-able rate of return; and where necessary, to provideshort-term “seed-funding” to encourage the risk-taking needed to expand the market.

There are also several important roles for the inter-national donor community in helping to foster theexpansion of affordable access through OpenAccess models, including policy dialogue andawareness raising; support for the transition fromthe historic incumbent operator; investment or riskunderwriting for international and regional back-bone infrastructure; and assistance with prototyp-ing and piloting sustainable approaches in the mostdifficult environments, particularly poor and ruralareas.

environment, these “plug-and-play” operators have thepotential to spread voice and Internet use to placescurrently not covered, while at the same time encour-aging significant economic activity in rural areas.

At the national and city levels, Open Access empha-sizes the importance of building networks that canhelp provide cheaper, lower-cost access to all users,particularly to government facilities such as schoolsand hospitals, and user-access points in poor, peri-urban areas. However the networks are built, andwhoever operates them, the aim would be to connectan ever-widening base of users to the national infra-structure at prices that can become sustainable for all.

The key change would be for the historic operatorto undergo a process of transformation that wouldallow it to emerge as the infrastructure provider.Depending on the history of the historic provider,this would be more or less difficult. The processwill be relatively straightforward for historicproviders that remain government-owned and setup operationally separate “business units” that areprofit centers. But it will be more difficult forhistoric operators that still merge operations andcross-subsidize parts. If the historic operator hasalready been sold off in part or in whole, this maymean that the issue will have to be tackled in policyand regulatory terms.

Within this overall change, there would be a num-ber of different options: a single, trusted nationwideinfrastructure provider at all levels; trusted infra-structure providers at two different levels (nationaland district/municipal); or two competing infra-structure providers in every area, the alternativeinfrastructure provider using the assets of the utili-ties and railway organizations. The choice betweenthese options is largely a function of scale but alsomight include considerations of governance.

Executive summary . 7

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 7

At the international level, the Open Access approachemphasizes the importance of bringing the cost ofinternational bandwidth down to cut the cost ofcommunication for developing countries (particularlySub-Saharan Africa), help spread national infrastruc-ture, and encourage the growth of new global busi-nesses such as call centers and outsourcing.

With an Open Access approach, government – at anational or local level – represents the public inter-est, particularly for the growth of the economy, anda social responsibility for the less well-off. It needsto act as a fair referee on competition issues andcreate a level playing field for providers. It alsoensures that the interests of the users of the infra-structure (both consumers and service companies)are well represented in any governance mechanism.

In this new light touch role, government and theautonomous regulators that implement its policieshave several key roles: to lower the barriers toremove as many unnecessary regulatory barriers aspossible; to create a favorable business environmentthat offers investors enough certainty to developtheir businesses and have a fair chance at a reason-able rate of return; and where necessary, to provideshort-term “seed-funding” to encourage the risk-taking needed to expand the market.

There are also several important roles for the inter-national donor community in helping to foster theexpansion of affordable access through OpenAccess models, including policy dialogue andawareness raising; support for the transition fromthe historic incumbent operator; investment or riskunderwriting for international and regional back-bone infrastructure; and assistance with prototyp-ing and piloting sustainable approaches in the mostdifficult environments, particularly poor and ruralareas.

environment, these “plug-and-play” operators have thepotential to spread voice and Internet use to placescurrently not covered, while at the same time encour-aging significant economic activity in rural areas.

At the national and city levels, Open Access empha-sizes the importance of building networks that canhelp provide cheaper, lower-cost access to all users,particularly to government facilities such as schoolsand hospitals, and user-access points in poor, peri-urban areas. However the networks are built, andwhoever operates them, the aim would be to connectan ever-widening base of users to the national infra-structure at prices that can become sustainable for all.

The key change would be for the historic operatorto undergo a process of transformation that wouldallow it to emerge as the infrastructure provider.Depending on the history of the historic provider,this would be more or less difficult. The processwill be relatively straightforward for historicproviders that remain government-owned and setup operationally separate “business units” that areprofit centers. But it will be more difficult forhistoric operators that still merge operations andcross-subsidize parts. If the historic operator hasalready been sold off in part or in whole, this maymean that the issue will have to be tackled in policyand regulatory terms.

Within this overall change, there would be a num-ber of different options: a single, trusted nationwideinfrastructure provider at all levels; trusted infra-structure providers at two different levels (nationaland district/municipal); or two competing infra-structure providers in every area, the alternativeinfrastructure provider using the assets of the utili-ties and railway organizations. The choice betweenthese options is largely a function of scale but alsomight include considerations of governance.

Executive summary . 7

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 7

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 8 Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 8

Overcoming Current Obstacles . 9

to work with developing country governments toinvest in projects that will open up developmentpotential rather than reinforce a status quo defend-ed by a variety of vested interests.

Because of the link between government owner-ship and the historic operator, policymakers arecaught in a trap: on the one hand, they areinclined to protect their asset through decisionsthat do not disadvantage the historic operator.6

On the other hand, they need to find ways ofopening up the market to provide better publicservices. This tension has made independent regu-lation difficult to achieve. Governments and regu-lators often have a natural inclination to defendthe status quo in the form of the historic operatoras a “national asset.”

1.OVERCOMINGCURRENTOBSTACLES

Developing country heads of state have committedthemselves to creating information societies as partof the WSIS process, and considerable energy isbeing expended both as part of WSIS and else-where to bring this about. For those involved indevelopment – whether governments, donors orNGOs – ICT is an essential tool for deliveringwork in a number of important areas includinghealth, education, and e-government.

ICT tools can make information and services morewidely available, thus improving the opportunities ofthe poorest in society. For these tools to be success-fully used, all those involved in development requirecommunications that are cheap and widely available,particularly in the poorer and harder-to-reach, ruralareas.

ICT as a development issue is now high on theagenda. But developing country policymakers findthemselves frustrated by a policy and regulatoryenvironment that is not yet producing the “step-change” required to address the issue in a produc-tive way. Past circumstances have led to a mismatchbetween the desired policy objectives and the reali-ties of the current moment: what might haveworked before no longer works.

The situation varies a great deal among developingcountries. Some have approached a dead-end5,while others face a situation that is full of promisebut not yet accessible. Almost no developingcountries have policy and regulatory environmentsthat positively encourage the development of infor-mation societies at all levels. For donors, it is time

5 This dead-end and the frustration it brings was described by the then Director-General of the Kenyan regulator (who is now MD of the historic operator,Telkom Kenya):”We have come from a regulatory environment that was dictated by – consciously or unconsciously – the protection of the incumbent’srevenue. That obsession – even though its revenues fell anyway – was like trying to hold on to an illogical scenario.”

6 The historic operator is the term used to refer to what might also be called the incumbent. In other words, it is the former public or private monopoly operator.7 What the Ministry of Communications may want to achieve (wider access, greater competition) will not usually be compatible with the position of the Ministry of

Finance (defending the asset value of the historic operator). This conflict could be seen at key points in the development of South Africa’s ICT policy among others.

The state of privatization in Sub-Saharan Africa

According to the ITU, only three historic operators were fullyprivatized in Africa, and 34 were partially privatized or in theprocess of privatization. The remaining 13 were state-owned.There have also been a significant number of “distressed” pri-vatizations (most notably Ghana, Guinea-Bissau and Tanzania)where the new ownership has created a significant number ofunresolved legal issues. In 24 out 48 Sub-Saharan Africancountries, the historic operator maintains a monopoly on inter-national voice. Without privatization, governments lack theresources to invest in network development.

Although many governments have been able toarticulate clear ICT policies, they have rarely beenable to innovate or make decisive changes to imple-ment their aspirations. In Sub-Saharan Africa, mostgovernments no longer have the resources to investdirectly in the historic operator to deliver on policy.They find themselves (along with their regulators)as referees of powerful institutional interests thatoften pit different government departments againsteach other.7 The requirements for a successful ICTpolicy are not the same as the financial needs ofhard-pressed governments.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 9

Overcoming Current Obstacles . 9

to work with developing country governments toinvest in projects that will open up developmentpotential rather than reinforce a status quo defend-ed by a variety of vested interests.

Because of the link between government owner-ship and the historic operator, policymakers arecaught in a trap: on the one hand, they areinclined to protect their asset through decisionsthat do not disadvantage the historic operator.6

On the other hand, they need to find ways ofopening up the market to provide better publicservices. This tension has made independent regu-lation difficult to achieve. Governments and regu-lators often have a natural inclination to defendthe status quo in the form of the historic operatoras a “national asset.”

1.OVERCOMINGCURRENTOBSTACLES

Developing country heads of state have committedthemselves to creating information societies as partof the WSIS process, and considerable energy isbeing expended both as part of WSIS and else-where to bring this about. For those involved indevelopment – whether governments, donors orNGOs – ICT is an essential tool for deliveringwork in a number of important areas includinghealth, education, and e-government.

ICT tools can make information and services morewidely available, thus improving the opportunities ofthe poorest in society. For these tools to be success-fully used, all those involved in development requirecommunications that are cheap and widely available,particularly in the poorer and harder-to-reach, ruralareas.

ICT as a development issue is now high on theagenda. But developing country policymakers findthemselves frustrated by a policy and regulatoryenvironment that is not yet producing the “step-change” required to address the issue in a produc-tive way. Past circumstances have led to a mismatchbetween the desired policy objectives and the reali-ties of the current moment: what might haveworked before no longer works.

The situation varies a great deal among developingcountries. Some have approached a dead-end5,while others face a situation that is full of promisebut not yet accessible. Almost no developingcountries have policy and regulatory environmentsthat positively encourage the development of infor-mation societies at all levels. For donors, it is time

5 This dead-end and the frustration it brings was described by the then Director-General of the Kenyan regulator (who is now MD of the historic operator,Telkom Kenya):”We have come from a regulatory environment that was dictated by – consciously or unconsciously – the protection of the incumbent’srevenue. That obsession – even though its revenues fell anyway – was like trying to hold on to an illogical scenario.”

6 The historic operator is the term used to refer to what might also be called the incumbent. In other words, it is the former public or private monopoly operator.7 What the Ministry of Communications may want to achieve (wider access, greater competition) will not usually be compatible with the position of the Ministry of

Finance (defending the asset value of the historic operator). This conflict could be seen at key points in the development of South Africa’s ICT policy among others.

The state of privatization in Sub-Saharan Africa

According to the ITU, only three historic operators were fullyprivatized in Africa, and 34 were partially privatized or in theprocess of privatization. The remaining 13 were state-owned.There have also been a significant number of “distressed” pri-vatizations (most notably Ghana, Guinea-Bissau and Tanzania)where the new ownership has created a significant number ofunresolved legal issues. In 24 out 48 Sub-Saharan Africancountries, the historic operator maintains a monopoly on inter-national voice. Without privatization, governments lack theresources to invest in network development.

Although many governments have been able toarticulate clear ICT policies, they have rarely beenable to innovate or make decisive changes to imple-ment their aspirations. In Sub-Saharan Africa, mostgovernments no longer have the resources to investdirectly in the historic operator to deliver on policy.They find themselves (along with their regulators)as referees of powerful institutional interests thatoften pit different government departments againsteach other.7 The requirements for a successful ICTpolicy are not the same as the financial needs ofhard-pressed governments.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 9

10 . Open Access Models

The historic operators are major employers, and large-scale redundancies8 are nearly always the outcome ofthe transition from a state-owned entity to a profit-making company into which investors can put newcapital.9 There is an understandable political reluc-tance to address this issue. The historic operator repre-sents a considerable opportunity for political patron-age.10 Yet many historic operators are effectively in aholding pattern.

A significant number of governments are delayingprivatization, but do not have the money to improveto their operator’s networks and other operationsthat would help maintain their assets. As a conse-quence, the physical condition of their networks ispoor in many (but not all) cases. In the past, historicoperators made financial contributions to govern-ment coffers, but now there is a significant numberthat are loss-making or only marginally profitable.11

Government ownership of the historic operatordominates practical actions on policy and in manycases does not create the conditions for the growthof the market or for investment, either at a local orinternational level.

It can take months or years to get a fixed line forindividual or corporate customers in Sub-Saharancountries where telecommunications have not beenprivatized. This situation provides ample opportu-nities for corruption, ranging from small-scale indi-vidual bribes to secure service, to instances of largescale call-diversion scandals.12 In the private sector,where shortages are governed by how quickly themarket can provide, no one pays bribes for services,and instances of large-scale corruption are few and

far between. For example, no one pays a bribe toobtain a mobile phone anywhere in Africa. Thelevel of corruption in some state-owned entitiesmeans both a significant lowering of their overalleffectiveness as well as significant financial losses.

The first major step towards liberalization has gen-erally been through the offering of mobile licenses.But despite the investment, efficient business prac-tices, and energy they have brought, their impacthas been limited as they have only been able (orwanted) to provide mobile telephony. They havemet the demand for voice communications but havenot always had much impact on infrastructuredevelopment, access to the Internet or data carriage,in particular for VoIP services.

While there has been competition among mobileoperators in some markets, there are still many coun-tries with only one or two operators.13 After initialmarket entry, there is usually only a very narrowband of price competition between operator tariffs.14

Prices for local mobile calls are between five to tentimes higher than their fixed network equivalents.However, the costs of operating a GSM network arelow in comparison with fixed networks, and the capitalcost per user drops as the user base increases. Whengreater competition strips away the protected privi-leges of the historic operators, the mobile operatorswill in many countries emerge as the “new incum-bents,” becoming the largest entities (by value) intheir markets.15

In a limited number of instances in Sub-SaharanAfrica, the market has been opened to a Second

8 Often Governments give explicit instructions to management to avoid redundancies: Ghana Telecom and Nitel in Nigeria (where external management agentswere employed) are two good examples. This makes the management task of creating a commercially healthy company extremely difficult and puts furtherpressure on historic operators to behave in an entirely defensive manner to all forms of competition. This in turn acts as a brake on the speed of futuremarket development.

9 The Senegalese operator Sonatel, with roughly the same number of fixed line customers as Telkom Kenya, had only 2,000 employees compared to just over17,000. PKF Consulting has recommended to Telkom Kenya that 12,281 of these employees should be laid off. On this basis, Telkom Kenya would still havedouble the employees it needs. The cost of making 12,281 employees redundant is according to the consultants somewhere between US$74-232.5 million andwith pension costs included the figure rises to between US$146.8-304 million.

10 The scale of this patronage can most clearly be seen in the historic operator Telkom Kenya which has 3,052 watchmen, messengers and porters.11 Although few historic operators operate with transparent accounting procedures, the following countries have historic operators that are either loss-making or

marginally profitable: Botswana, Cameroon, Congo-Brazzaville, Ethiopia, Ghana, Guinea Bissau, Kenya, Liberia, Malawi, Mozambique, Nigeria, Sierra Leone,Tanzania, Zambia and Zimbabwe. This list includes a number of countries where the historic operator is not generating sufficient resources to invest in itsnetwork. This pattern mirrors that found in the developed world where the stock value of the 10 largest historic operators worldwide has steadily declined.

12 In 2003, then NITEL CEO said that 30-40% of internal revenues were lost through fraud. Before he was dismissed, the former Director of Licensing,Compliance and Standards of Kenyan regulator CCK described a fraudulent call-diversion operation uncovered in 2003 as a “mini-Telkom Kenya.” Thereare a significant number of other instances of major fraud in historic operators but they have not been publicly identified.

13 In mainland Sub-Saharan Africa, there are 20 countries out of 32 that have two operators or less and seven that have only three operators. There are noMobile Virtual Network Operators (MVNOs) although Botswana has expressed interest in attracting a third operator on this basis and Virgin Mobile willwork with Cell-C in South Africa and may get involved with V-Mobile in Nigeria.

14 There are a bewildering array of time-limited sales promotions that lower prices temporarily but there is usually less than a 5% spread in published tariffprices, even where there are 3 operators (for example, South Africa). At the other end of the range, in early 2005 in Botswana, there was almost nodifference between the published tariffs of the two operators.

15 One implication of this shift is that it may change who takes the lead in terms of the roll-out of national infrastructure. Some mobile companies (Celtel, MTN)have been involved in developing infrastructure whilst others have been significantly less involved. The key question is will a network built to respond tomobile customer needs be adequate for other requirements? The spread of GPRS and 3G implementations (Ghana, Kenya, Nigeria, South Africa, Tanzania,Uganda thus far announced) may go some way towards answering the question but the long-term success of these implementations has yet to be proven.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 10

10 . Open Access Models

The historic operators are major employers, and large-scale redundancies8 are nearly always the outcome ofthe transition from a state-owned entity to a profit-making company into which investors can put newcapital.9 There is an understandable political reluc-tance to address this issue. The historic operator repre-sents a considerable opportunity for political patron-age.10 Yet many historic operators are effectively in aholding pattern.

A significant number of governments are delayingprivatization, but do not have the money to improveto their operator’s networks and other operationsthat would help maintain their assets. As a conse-quence, the physical condition of their networks ispoor in many (but not all) cases. In the past, historicoperators made financial contributions to govern-ment coffers, but now there is a significant numberthat are loss-making or only marginally profitable.11

Government ownership of the historic operatordominates practical actions on policy and in manycases does not create the conditions for the growthof the market or for investment, either at a local orinternational level.

It can take months or years to get a fixed line forindividual or corporate customers in Sub-Saharancountries where telecommunications have not beenprivatized. This situation provides ample opportu-nities for corruption, ranging from small-scale indi-vidual bribes to secure service, to instances of largescale call-diversion scandals.12 In the private sector,where shortages are governed by how quickly themarket can provide, no one pays bribes for services,and instances of large-scale corruption are few and

far between. For example, no one pays a bribe toobtain a mobile phone anywhere in Africa. Thelevel of corruption in some state-owned entitiesmeans both a significant lowering of their overalleffectiveness as well as significant financial losses.

The first major step towards liberalization has gen-erally been through the offering of mobile licenses.But despite the investment, efficient business prac-tices, and energy they have brought, their impacthas been limited as they have only been able (orwanted) to provide mobile telephony. They havemet the demand for voice communications but havenot always had much impact on infrastructuredevelopment, access to the Internet or data carriage,in particular for VoIP services.

While there has been competition among mobileoperators in some markets, there are still many coun-tries with only one or two operators.13 After initialmarket entry, there is usually only a very narrowband of price competition between operator tariffs.14

Prices for local mobile calls are between five to tentimes higher than their fixed network equivalents.However, the costs of operating a GSM network arelow in comparison with fixed networks, and the capitalcost per user drops as the user base increases. Whengreater competition strips away the protected privi-leges of the historic operators, the mobile operatorswill in many countries emerge as the “new incum-bents,” becoming the largest entities (by value) intheir markets.15

In a limited number of instances in Sub-SaharanAfrica, the market has been opened to a Second

8 Often Governments give explicit instructions to management to avoid redundancies: Ghana Telecom and Nitel in Nigeria (where external management agentswere employed) are two good examples. This makes the management task of creating a commercially healthy company extremely difficult and puts furtherpressure on historic operators to behave in an entirely defensive manner to all forms of competition. This in turn acts as a brake on the speed of futuremarket development.

9 The Senegalese operator Sonatel, with roughly the same number of fixed line customers as Telkom Kenya, had only 2,000 employees compared to just over17,000. PKF Consulting has recommended to Telkom Kenya that 12,281 of these employees should be laid off. On this basis, Telkom Kenya would still havedouble the employees it needs. The cost of making 12,281 employees redundant is according to the consultants somewhere between US$74-232.5 million andwith pension costs included the figure rises to between US$146.8-304 million.

10 The scale of this patronage can most clearly be seen in the historic operator Telkom Kenya which has 3,052 watchmen, messengers and porters.11 Although few historic operators operate with transparent accounting procedures, the following countries have historic operators that are either loss-making or

marginally profitable: Botswana, Cameroon, Congo-Brazzaville, Ethiopia, Ghana, Guinea Bissau, Kenya, Liberia, Malawi, Mozambique, Nigeria, Sierra Leone,Tanzania, Zambia and Zimbabwe. This list includes a number of countries where the historic operator is not generating sufficient resources to invest in itsnetwork. This pattern mirrors that found in the developed world where the stock value of the 10 largest historic operators worldwide has steadily declined.

12 In 2003, then NITEL CEO said that 30-40% of internal revenues were lost through fraud. Before he was dismissed, the former Director of Licensing,Compliance and Standards of Kenyan regulator CCK described a fraudulent call-diversion operation uncovered in 2003 as a “mini-Telkom Kenya.” Thereare a significant number of other instances of major fraud in historic operators but they have not been publicly identified.

13 In mainland Sub-Saharan Africa, there are 20 countries out of 32 that have two operators or less and seven that have only three operators. There are noMobile Virtual Network Operators (MVNOs) although Botswana has expressed interest in attracting a third operator on this basis and Virgin Mobile willwork with Cell-C in South Africa and may get involved with V-Mobile in Nigeria.

14 There are a bewildering array of time-limited sales promotions that lower prices temporarily but there is usually less than a 5% spread in published tariffprices, even where there are 3 operators (for example, South Africa). At the other end of the range, in early 2005 in Botswana, there was almost nodifference between the published tariffs of the two operators.

15 One implication of this shift is that it may change who takes the lead in terms of the roll-out of national infrastructure. Some mobile companies (Celtel, MTN)have been involved in developing infrastructure whilst others have been significantly less involved. The key question is will a network built to respond tomobile customer needs be adequate for other requirements? The spread of GPRS and 3G implementations (Ghana, Kenya, Nigeria, South Africa, Tanzania,Uganda thus far announced) may go some way towards answering the question but the long-term success of these implementations has yet to be proven.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 10

Overcoming Current Obstacles . 11

National Operator (SNO).16 Where they exist,SNOs have nearly always mirrored the verticallyintegrated structure of the historic operators,while seeking to focus on the more lucrative mar-kets available in their country of operation. Theimpact of SNOs on prices for end-users has notbeen dramatic. This is because the market as awhole has not been liberalized and with a duop-oly, operators tend to shadow each other’s pricingstructures.

Until recently, Sub-Saharan African regulators andgovernments have sought to contain the disruptiveimpact of new technologies on their historic opera-tors rather than encourage technological innova-tion. VoIP calling has only recently been definedas a legal activity in a small number of countries.17

Wireless technologies have often remained out-lawed or been rendered difficult to use throughregulatory inexperience or unwillingness to extendaccess to low-cost spectrum.18

Despite these barriers, in certain African countriesthese new technologies have gone around regulatoryrules like water running downhill. The grey marketin international voice traffic using VoIP has variedbetween 10–30 percent in most African countries,often acting as hidden competition for the historicoperator on international voice calling. Before theannounced regulatory changes in South Africa in2004, it was estimated that there were between70–80 unlicensed wireless-based Internet ServiceProviders. However the somewhat clandestinenature of these operators restricts their ability togrow their business as an unpredictable environ-ment does not encourage larger-scale investment.This use of new technologies – both legal and clan-destine – has helped lower prices for users (particu-larly VoIP’s impact on international prices) andexpanded the market, particularly in countries

where Wi-Fi is unambiguously legal and operatorscan use low-cost or free spectrum. However there isstill considerable potential for lowering costs andwidening usage by actively encouraging low-costdeployment.19

Because of fears that change would damage the his-toric operator, the early steps towards liberalizationwere highly controlled and still left markets in thehands of a relatively small number of influential,big players. The absence of competition law inmost Sub-Saharan African countries means thatregulation has legalized a number of de-factomonopolies.20

The next steps on the road to liberalization are farless clear than what has gone before. It is almostas if everyone has embarked on a journey withoutknowing its final destination. Competition hasbeen assumed to be a good thing but policymak-ers have not always defined what they want fromwider competition. In 2004, the first countries inAfrica – Kenya, Tanzania and South Africa –announced wider competition frameworks. Anumber of other countries will announce compe-tition frameworks this year including, Botswana,Nigeria, Uganda, and Zambia. More countries aresure to follow.

With greater liberalization, the responsibility forwidening access has shifted. Governments have gonefrom being directly responsible for universal access toacting as the policymakers and facilitators for it. Inpractical terms, this has meant working with regula-tors to set roll-out targets and charging private oper-ators money to raise funds for widening access.What was once a fairly centralized process (involv-ing government and the historic operator) is nowbecoming one in which many commercial playerstake different parts of the remit to widen access.

16 Existing SNOs include: Côte d’Ivoire, Ghana (although its effectiveness is hobbled by a dispute with Government over roll-out which is taking several years toresolve), Mali, Nigeria and Uganda. Planned SNOs include: Kenya (now doubtful), Senegal, South Africa and Zimbabwe (also doubtful).

17 Strategies for containing “illegal” VoIP calling have ranged from periodic police raids (Ethiopia) to trying to filter out VoIP calls, often with disastrous conse-quences for business traffic (Kenya). There are a number of Africa countries where VoIP has been made legal recently (DRC, Kenya, Tanzania, Togo, SouthAfrica) subject only to licensing requirements. In a smaller number of countries (for example, Egypt) it has been made legal for PC to PC phone calls and forVirtual Private Networks (VPNs) because in both instances it would be almost impossible to police effectively. A recent study for ECOWAS and the WorldBank (see A1) found that VoIP had been legalized in six out of fifteen ECOWAS countries but this overstates what is actually happening as there are disputesor extremely limiting conditions in four of these countries.

18 See study by Isabel Neto listed in A1. She surveyed 47 out of 54 African countries and territories, covering 95% of its population and found that:” Lack ofclarity in regulation and enforcement creates confusion and may discourage smaller players from entering the market. For bigger players interested in tak-ing advantage of economies of scale and implementing common strategies across borders, the heterogeneous regulatory environment will also act as a deter-rent and a barrier to entry”.

19 The discussion of new, cheaper technology need not be restricted to VoIP and wireless based equipment. It could also include new low-cost network elementequipment, including transceivers for optical fiber links, switches, routers and terminals. Much of the complex equipment necessary to build communicationnetworks that formerly could only be purchased from specialist telecoms suppliers can now be bought cheaply from consumer outlets.

20 In Senegal, the historic operator Sonatel controls upwards of 80% of the ISP market and has a similar position in a number of other key markets. The posi-tion is very similar in Mauritius.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 11

Overcoming Current Obstacles . 11

National Operator (SNO).16 Where they exist,SNOs have nearly always mirrored the verticallyintegrated structure of the historic operators,while seeking to focus on the more lucrative mar-kets available in their country of operation. Theimpact of SNOs on prices for end-users has notbeen dramatic. This is because the market as awhole has not been liberalized and with a duop-oly, operators tend to shadow each other’s pricingstructures.

Until recently, Sub-Saharan African regulators andgovernments have sought to contain the disruptiveimpact of new technologies on their historic opera-tors rather than encourage technological innova-tion. VoIP calling has only recently been definedas a legal activity in a small number of countries.17

Wireless technologies have often remained out-lawed or been rendered difficult to use throughregulatory inexperience or unwillingness to extendaccess to low-cost spectrum.18

Despite these barriers, in certain African countriesthese new technologies have gone around regulatoryrules like water running downhill. The grey marketin international voice traffic using VoIP has variedbetween 10–30 percent in most African countries,often acting as hidden competition for the historicoperator on international voice calling. Before theannounced regulatory changes in South Africa in2004, it was estimated that there were between70–80 unlicensed wireless-based Internet ServiceProviders. However the somewhat clandestinenature of these operators restricts their ability togrow their business as an unpredictable environ-ment does not encourage larger-scale investment.This use of new technologies – both legal and clan-destine – has helped lower prices for users (particu-larly VoIP’s impact on international prices) andexpanded the market, particularly in countries

where Wi-Fi is unambiguously legal and operatorscan use low-cost or free spectrum. However there isstill considerable potential for lowering costs andwidening usage by actively encouraging low-costdeployment.19

Because of fears that change would damage the his-toric operator, the early steps towards liberalizationwere highly controlled and still left markets in thehands of a relatively small number of influential,big players. The absence of competition law inmost Sub-Saharan African countries means thatregulation has legalized a number of de-factomonopolies.20

The next steps on the road to liberalization are farless clear than what has gone before. It is almostas if everyone has embarked on a journey withoutknowing its final destination. Competition hasbeen assumed to be a good thing but policymak-ers have not always defined what they want fromwider competition. In 2004, the first countries inAfrica – Kenya, Tanzania and South Africa –announced wider competition frameworks. Anumber of other countries will announce compe-tition frameworks this year including, Botswana,Nigeria, Uganda, and Zambia. More countries aresure to follow.

With greater liberalization, the responsibility forwidening access has shifted. Governments have gonefrom being directly responsible for universal access toacting as the policymakers and facilitators for it. Inpractical terms, this has meant working with regula-tors to set roll-out targets and charging private oper-ators money to raise funds for widening access.What was once a fairly centralized process (involv-ing government and the historic operator) is nowbecoming one in which many commercial playerstake different parts of the remit to widen access.

16 Existing SNOs include: Côte d’Ivoire, Ghana (although its effectiveness is hobbled by a dispute with Government over roll-out which is taking several years toresolve), Mali, Nigeria and Uganda. Planned SNOs include: Kenya (now doubtful), Senegal, South Africa and Zimbabwe (also doubtful).

17 Strategies for containing “illegal” VoIP calling have ranged from periodic police raids (Ethiopia) to trying to filter out VoIP calls, often with disastrous conse-quences for business traffic (Kenya). There are a number of Africa countries where VoIP has been made legal recently (DRC, Kenya, Tanzania, Togo, SouthAfrica) subject only to licensing requirements. In a smaller number of countries (for example, Egypt) it has been made legal for PC to PC phone calls and forVirtual Private Networks (VPNs) because in both instances it would be almost impossible to police effectively. A recent study for ECOWAS and the WorldBank (see A1) found that VoIP had been legalized in six out of fifteen ECOWAS countries but this overstates what is actually happening as there are disputesor extremely limiting conditions in four of these countries.

18 See study by Isabel Neto listed in A1. She surveyed 47 out of 54 African countries and territories, covering 95% of its population and found that:” Lack ofclarity in regulation and enforcement creates confusion and may discourage smaller players from entering the market. For bigger players interested in tak-ing advantage of economies of scale and implementing common strategies across borders, the heterogeneous regulatory environment will also act as a deter-rent and a barrier to entry”.

19 The discussion of new, cheaper technology need not be restricted to VoIP and wireless based equipment. It could also include new low-cost network elementequipment, including transceivers for optical fiber links, switches, routers and terminals. Much of the complex equipment necessary to build communicationnetworks that formerly could only be purchased from specialist telecoms suppliers can now be bought cheaply from consumer outlets.

20 In Senegal, the historic operator Sonatel controls upwards of 80% of the ISP market and has a similar position in a number of other key markets. The posi-tion is very similar in Mauritius.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 11

12 . Open Access Models

The new liberalized environment calls for increasedcommercial risk and decreased political risk.

Several challenges have emerged from this transi-tion. Getting independent regulators in place hastaken time and absorbed much attention andenergy on the part of governments and operators.Establishment of effective universal access mecha-nisms has nearly always lagged behind liberaliza-tion of the market. Universal Access Funds orUniversal Service Agencies are in place in somecountries, and additional funding has come fromorganizations such as the World Bank. However,in Sub-Saharan Africa, the money raised is inade-quate for the scale of the task involved. In addition,there are long-term issues of revenue support:there is no developed business model that allowsfor the steady spread of communications topoorer, rural areas in a financially sustainableway.21

Governments and donors have attempted to over-come the economic difficulties faced by poor potentialusers by offering funded telecenters with a mixture ofvoice and Internet services, thus lowering the price forusers by spreading over many users. And undoubtedlythere have been some successful telecenters but overallthe results have been mixed. Users seem to be moreinterested in having a mobile on which they can bereached (either their own or a shared phone.)Connectivity has also often been relatively expensiveand not always reliable. In most cases, income fromusers has not covered operating costs.

The underlying issue is that there is currently nobusiness model for delivering voice and data at anappropriate price to those at the bottom of theincome pyramid. Nevertheless, there are examplesin the United States, Asia and, Latin America thatpoint the way, using newer, cheaper technologiesin combination with existing infrastructure. Thelower the entry and operating cost, the better thebusiness case and the higher the likely level ofusage.

The situation is particularly acute for Sub-Saharan Africa. It finds itself trapped in a set of

“chicken-and-egg” problems that are also mir-rored in some other developing countries. Theabsence of cheap international bandwidth meansthat even its most competitive economies find ithard to compete at a global level. For example,the cost of offering call center services in SouthAfrica was found to be a third higher than inIndia, largely because of telecommunicationscosts.22 This lack of competitive advantage makesit hard to attract local and international investment.A cost-effective communications infrastructure isalmost a precondition for attracting externalinvestment that goes beyond traditional extractiveindustries. Without investment, markets staysmall and uncompetitive.

Much of the national and international infrastruc-ture that created the low bandwidth prices inEurope was built during a market upswing. A greatdeal of that private investment (particularly on theNorth Atlantic routes) has simply been written offat 5–10 percent of its original value. The creationof plentiful, relatively cheap bandwidth throughthis “market accident” has opened up considerablenew economic opportunities for the developedworld. It has driven local roll-out, whether or notthis was profitable in the short-term.

Such an approach is simply not an option forSub-Saharan Africa and many of the other devel-oping regions of the world. Where major infra-structure has been built, it has tended to bethrough structures that createdis internationalmonopolies that have kept the price of band-width high. The African historic operators thatbelong to the SAT-3/SAFE club consortium havemonopoly access to that capacity, the only signifi-cant fiber optic cable connecting Sub-SaharanAfrica to the rest of the world.23 Each companyinvolved invested a certain amount of money andgot monopoly access to the bandwidth from thatcountry. Since its construction largely predatedliberalization, it is inevitably a club of existinghistorical operators whose approach to pricingvaries considerably. Neither the equity in theSAT3 Consortium nor its bandwidth is easilytradable.

21 This can be contrasted with Latin America where several countries have held reverse auction processes and in Peru, the regulator has approved the settingup of a low-cost, rural operator.

22 See Deloitte study cited in A1.23 The SAT3/SAFE cable that links 11 Sub-Saharan African countries with Europe and Asia was built using the industry’s traditional approach to financing, the

Club Consortium model. For background see: http://www.balancingact-africa.com/news/back/balancing-act_247.html

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 12

12 . Open Access Models

The new liberalized environment calls for increasedcommercial risk and decreased political risk.

Several challenges have emerged from this transi-tion. Getting independent regulators in place hastaken time and absorbed much attention andenergy on the part of governments and operators.Establishment of effective universal access mecha-nisms has nearly always lagged behind liberaliza-tion of the market. Universal Access Funds orUniversal Service Agencies are in place in somecountries, and additional funding has come fromorganizations such as the World Bank. However,in Sub-Saharan Africa, the money raised is inade-quate for the scale of the task involved. In addition,there are long-term issues of revenue support:there is no developed business model that allowsfor the steady spread of communications topoorer, rural areas in a financially sustainableway.21

Governments and donors have attempted to over-come the economic difficulties faced by poor potentialusers by offering funded telecenters with a mixture ofvoice and Internet services, thus lowering the price forusers by spreading over many users. And undoubtedlythere have been some successful telecenters but overallthe results have been mixed. Users seem to be moreinterested in having a mobile on which they can bereached (either their own or a shared phone.)Connectivity has also often been relatively expensiveand not always reliable. In most cases, income fromusers has not covered operating costs.

The underlying issue is that there is currently nobusiness model for delivering voice and data at anappropriate price to those at the bottom of theincome pyramid. Nevertheless, there are examplesin the United States, Asia and, Latin America thatpoint the way, using newer, cheaper technologiesin combination with existing infrastructure. Thelower the entry and operating cost, the better thebusiness case and the higher the likely level ofusage.

The situation is particularly acute for Sub-Saharan Africa. It finds itself trapped in a set of

“chicken-and-egg” problems that are also mir-rored in some other developing countries. Theabsence of cheap international bandwidth meansthat even its most competitive economies find ithard to compete at a global level. For example,the cost of offering call center services in SouthAfrica was found to be a third higher than inIndia, largely because of telecommunicationscosts.22 This lack of competitive advantage makesit hard to attract local and international investment.A cost-effective communications infrastructure isalmost a precondition for attracting externalinvestment that goes beyond traditional extractiveindustries. Without investment, markets staysmall and uncompetitive.

Much of the national and international infrastruc-ture that created the low bandwidth prices inEurope was built during a market upswing. A greatdeal of that private investment (particularly on theNorth Atlantic routes) has simply been written offat 5–10 percent of its original value. The creationof plentiful, relatively cheap bandwidth throughthis “market accident” has opened up considerablenew economic opportunities for the developedworld. It has driven local roll-out, whether or notthis was profitable in the short-term.

Such an approach is simply not an option forSub-Saharan Africa and many of the other devel-oping regions of the world. Where major infra-structure has been built, it has tended to bethrough structures that createdis internationalmonopolies that have kept the price of band-width high. The African historic operators thatbelong to the SAT-3/SAFE club consortium havemonopoly access to that capacity, the only signifi-cant fiber optic cable connecting Sub-SaharanAfrica to the rest of the world.23 Each companyinvolved invested a certain amount of money andgot monopoly access to the bandwidth from thatcountry. Since its construction largely predatedliberalization, it is inevitably a club of existinghistorical operators whose approach to pricingvaries considerably. Neither the equity in theSAT3 Consortium nor its bandwidth is easilytradable.

21 This can be contrasted with Latin America where several countries have held reverse auction processes and in Peru, the regulator has approved the settingup of a low-cost, rural operator.

22 See Deloitte study cited in A1.23 The SAT3/SAFE cable that links 11 Sub-Saharan African countries with Europe and Asia was built using the industry’s traditional approach to financing, the

Club Consortium model. For background see: http://www.balancingact-africa.com/news/back/balancing-act_247.html

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 12

Overcoming Current Obstacles . 13

Unless checked, this kind of dominance by existinglarge-scale organizations is likely to increase ascompetition intensifies and is unlikely to bringabout lower prices. A number of countries connect-ed to SAT3 have begun to address this issue.24

The intractability of policy and regulatory issuesin Sub-Saharan Africa indicates that many ofthose involved are focused on securing tactical vic-tories and for understandable reasons find it diffi-cult to step back and see the way things might bemoving. Full competition has almost crept up onthe continent and there has been little preparatory

discussion about what it might mean. Completeliberalization assumes competition is a “goodthing” but much less thought is given to specificpolicy objectives that might be achieved withgreater competition.

However, rather than arguing over the details ofwhat might have been, it is perhaps time to takebreath and see whether there’s another way of look-ing at how these obstacles might be overcome. IfICT is a set of tools for development, then whatfollows examines how it might be possible to gaineasier and cheaper access to the technology.

The high cost of underdeveloped infrastructure in Africa

Africa lacks significant regional and international communications backbone infrastructure25. As a result, a considerable amount of itsvoice and data traffic – both within countries and among countries – goes via Europe or North America. For a voice call to go fromNairobi to Kigali it goes via London or for an e-mail to go from Ouagadougou to Bamako it goes via Paris. This situation has its parallelin airline routes where it is both easier and cheaper for a senior executive from a telco in Senegal to fly to a meeting in Kampala viaParis rather than directly. The cost of this international routing of voice and data traffic costs Africa a considerable amount in hard curren-cy payments every year.

Many African countries use relatively expensive international satellite capacity to route calls within their borders and to other African coun-tries because there is no national or regional backbone infrastructure. In the case of one of the poorest countries in Africa, its historic opera-tor spends US$3.2 million on satellite transmission, of which US$2.4 million is spent on routing calls within the country and the balance isspent on international calls.

Africa suffers from a whole range of problems that make the creation of regional and international infrastructure harder. Some are foundelsewhere, while others are mainly a continental problem. There are several key countries that are either in or coming out of civil war.There is a high level of vandalism on existing copper cables and other facilities. And there are particular gate-keeping or transit problemsassociated with small land-locked countries.

Despite these substantial barriers to growth, Africa remains economically the second fastest-growing continent in the world. Although alarge part of that growth comes from South Africa, that in itself tells its own story. South African companies are investing in communica-tions across the continent and are an illustration of how the country can provide the impetus for growth across the region.

24 The absence of either national or regional competition law makes addressing these issues difficult: there is no equivalent to European Commission competitionlaw. The individual SAT3 country monopolies last until 2007. Nevertheless, in the meantime, Ghana is investigating the possibility of hiving off its SAT3 band-width from the historic operator, Ghana Telecom. Nigeria was also going down the same route but policy-makers appear to be less interested since the NigerianSNO Globacom announced that it would build its own Lagos-London fiber connection. In South Africa, there is discussion about taking the SAT3 capacity awayfrom the historic operator, Telkom. In Mauritius (which is connected to the eastern extension of the SAT3 cable, SAFE) the Government has employed consult-ants to look at the cost of buying out the monopoly from the historic operator, Mauritius Telecom, which the Government stills owns 60% of the shares.

25 The World Bank has funded two extensive studies that describe the current state of infrastructure in Sub-Saharan Africa: For West Africa, there is the Cross-Border Connectivity Initiative in the ECOWAS region. For the Southern and East Africa, there is the Study of Telecoms Infrastructure and Development Initiativesin Southern and East Africa. For full references, see A1.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 13

Overcoming Current Obstacles . 13

Unless checked, this kind of dominance by existinglarge-scale organizations is likely to increase ascompetition intensifies and is unlikely to bringabout lower prices. A number of countries connect-ed to SAT3 have begun to address this issue.24

The intractability of policy and regulatory issuesin Sub-Saharan Africa indicates that many ofthose involved are focused on securing tactical vic-tories and for understandable reasons find it diffi-cult to step back and see the way things might bemoving. Full competition has almost crept up onthe continent and there has been little preparatory

discussion about what it might mean. Completeliberalization assumes competition is a “goodthing” but much less thought is given to specificpolicy objectives that might be achieved withgreater competition.

However, rather than arguing over the details ofwhat might have been, it is perhaps time to takebreath and see whether there’s another way of look-ing at how these obstacles might be overcome. IfICT is a set of tools for development, then whatfollows examines how it might be possible to gaineasier and cheaper access to the technology.

The high cost of underdeveloped infrastructure in Africa

Africa lacks significant regional and international communications backbone infrastructure25. As a result, a considerable amount of itsvoice and data traffic – both within countries and among countries – goes via Europe or North America. For a voice call to go fromNairobi to Kigali it goes via London or for an e-mail to go from Ouagadougou to Bamako it goes via Paris. This situation has its parallelin airline routes where it is both easier and cheaper for a senior executive from a telco in Senegal to fly to a meeting in Kampala viaParis rather than directly. The cost of this international routing of voice and data traffic costs Africa a considerable amount in hard curren-cy payments every year.

Many African countries use relatively expensive international satellite capacity to route calls within their borders and to other African coun-tries because there is no national or regional backbone infrastructure. In the case of one of the poorest countries in Africa, its historic opera-tor spends US$3.2 million on satellite transmission, of which US$2.4 million is spent on routing calls within the country and the balance isspent on international calls.

Africa suffers from a whole range of problems that make the creation of regional and international infrastructure harder. Some are foundelsewhere, while others are mainly a continental problem. There are several key countries that are either in or coming out of civil war.There is a high level of vandalism on existing copper cables and other facilities. And there are particular gate-keeping or transit problemsassociated with small land-locked countries.

Despite these substantial barriers to growth, Africa remains economically the second fastest-growing continent in the world. Although alarge part of that growth comes from South Africa, that in itself tells its own story. South African companies are investing in communica-tions across the continent and are an illustration of how the country can provide the impetus for growth across the region.

24 The absence of either national or regional competition law makes addressing these issues difficult: there is no equivalent to European Commission competitionlaw. The individual SAT3 country monopolies last until 2007. Nevertheless, in the meantime, Ghana is investigating the possibility of hiving off its SAT3 band-width from the historic operator, Ghana Telecom. Nigeria was also going down the same route but policy-makers appear to be less interested since the NigerianSNO Globacom announced that it would build its own Lagos-London fiber connection. In South Africa, there is discussion about taking the SAT3 capacity awayfrom the historic operator, Telkom. In Mauritius (which is connected to the eastern extension of the SAT3 cable, SAFE) the Government has employed consult-ants to look at the cost of buying out the monopoly from the historic operator, Mauritius Telecom, which the Government stills owns 60% of the shares.

25 The World Bank has funded two extensive studies that describe the current state of infrastructure in Sub-Saharan Africa: For West Africa, there is the Cross-Border Connectivity Initiative in the ECOWAS region. For the Southern and East Africa, there is the Study of Telecoms Infrastructure and Development Initiativesin Southern and East Africa. For full references, see A1.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 13

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 14 Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 14

2. UNLOCKINGWIDER ACCESSTO ICTThe introduction of IP networks as the basis forcommunications and services is a significant devel-opment. IP networks operate in markedly differentways than traditional telephony, and this paradigmshift offers considerable potential for unlockingwider access to ICT. It has already allowed the sepa-ration of services and infrastructure and is beingbuilt with new, disruptive technologies that lowerboth business entry and operating costs.

Almost all major telecoms carriers are committed tointroducing VoIP26 services across their networks, andcarriers in Sub-Saharan Africa have already begunintroducing such services at an international level. A handful of African carriers have announced theirintention to make the transition to IP-based networksin the next 2–3 years.27 But the impact of IP networkshas made its presence felt everywhere as operators areincreasingly running a hybrid of traditional telephonyand IP networks. In the next five years, these willprobably cease to be parallel operations.

The introduction of IP-networks has been the mid-wife of a number of developments across all forms ofnetworks. One of the most significant of these devel-opments – the separation of physical infrastructureand services – is creating new ways of doing business.Since a liberalized environment needs sustainablebusiness models, policymakers and regulators needto “go with the grain” of market developments andunderstand the implications of these developments.

2.1 IP NETWORKS: A PARADIGM SHIFT THATOPENS UP POTENTIALIP networks are the transmission system for almostanything that can be sent in digital form. Where

they are already well established, they have creatednew markets for services and applications. In thedeveloping world, they allow the growth of decentral-ized, “intelligent” services at the edge of the network.

Traditional telephony is a highly centralizing tech-nology. The “intelligence” in the network is locatedcentrally (in the functionalities of the switch) andusually controlled by one organization. In its his-toric form, largely “dumb” devices (telephones) wereattached to the network and these had only a limit-ed set of functions. More recently, the functionalattributes of devices attached to the network hasincreased but this functionality is still centrally run.

The telephone network’s root and branch structuremeans that traffic flows to and from exchanges inways that reinforce this pattern. For example, trafficfor international destinations tends to go via a sin-gle international gateway. Telecom carriers maintainbilateral relationships with other carriers throughthe Accounting Rate System (although to a muchmore limited extent than before).

By contrast, the IP network (the basis for theInternet) is one where no single entity controlsanything but the most basic transport and relation-ships with other networks. The service-providing“intelligence” is deliberately designed out of the net-work architecture. Indeed, the network is “dumb”and intelligence is at the edge of the network. Forexample, a computer accessing the network has a farmore complex range of service functionality in itsapplication programs and this is not solely relatedto its size.

Traffic on the network is routed wherever it canfind the easiest route and therefore not always viacentral points. For example, international trafficcan as easily flow from an Internet service provider(ISP), a cyber-café or a telephone company: eachhas only to open a network connection and havethe required capacity available. The network designoriginated from U.S. military demands that it with-stand nuclear attack where an important featurewas a decentralized network without a central focusor control point. Also from its university origins, it

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 15

26 VoIP as a service can and does go over the internet (which is carried on an IP network) but to achieve higher quality calling carriers have installed their ownIP networks.

27 Major carriers committed to VoIP include: MCI (100% of all traffic by the end of 2005); AT&T (100% by the end 2010); Telecom Italia (80% of all traffic wentby VoIP by the end of 2003). Between a fifth to a quarter of all historic operators in Africa were using VoIP for a part of their international traffic. As theseagreements are politically sensitive, establishing exact numbers is difficult. Telkom Kenya is about to offer publicly a VoIP-based international service. FourAfrican carriers – BTC (Botswana), Mundo Startel (Angola), Telecom Namibia and UTL – have announced that they will introduce IP-based networks.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 15

2. UNLOCKINGWIDER ACCESSTO ICTThe introduction of IP networks as the basis forcommunications and services is a significant devel-opment. IP networks operate in markedly differentways than traditional telephony, and this paradigmshift offers considerable potential for unlockingwider access to ICT. It has already allowed the sepa-ration of services and infrastructure and is beingbuilt with new, disruptive technologies that lowerboth business entry and operating costs.

Almost all major telecoms carriers are committed tointroducing VoIP26 services across their networks, andcarriers in Sub-Saharan Africa have already begunintroducing such services at an international level. A handful of African carriers have announced theirintention to make the transition to IP-based networksin the next 2–3 years.27 But the impact of IP networkshas made its presence felt everywhere as operators areincreasingly running a hybrid of traditional telephonyand IP networks. In the next five years, these willprobably cease to be parallel operations.

The introduction of IP-networks has been the mid-wife of a number of developments across all forms ofnetworks. One of the most significant of these devel-opments – the separation of physical infrastructureand services – is creating new ways of doing business.Since a liberalized environment needs sustainablebusiness models, policymakers and regulators needto “go with the grain” of market developments andunderstand the implications of these developments.

2.1 IP NETWORKS: A PARADIGM SHIFT THATOPENS UP POTENTIALIP networks are the transmission system for almostanything that can be sent in digital form. Where

they are already well established, they have creatednew markets for services and applications. In thedeveloping world, they allow the growth of decentral-ized, “intelligent” services at the edge of the network.

Traditional telephony is a highly centralizing tech-nology. The “intelligence” in the network is locatedcentrally (in the functionalities of the switch) andusually controlled by one organization. In its his-toric form, largely “dumb” devices (telephones) wereattached to the network and these had only a limit-ed set of functions. More recently, the functionalattributes of devices attached to the network hasincreased but this functionality is still centrally run.

The telephone network’s root and branch structuremeans that traffic flows to and from exchanges inways that reinforce this pattern. For example, trafficfor international destinations tends to go via a sin-gle international gateway. Telecom carriers maintainbilateral relationships with other carriers throughthe Accounting Rate System (although to a muchmore limited extent than before).

By contrast, the IP network (the basis for theInternet) is one where no single entity controlsanything but the most basic transport and relation-ships with other networks. The service-providing“intelligence” is deliberately designed out of the net-work architecture. Indeed, the network is “dumb”and intelligence is at the edge of the network. Forexample, a computer accessing the network has a farmore complex range of service functionality in itsapplication programs and this is not solely relatedto its size.

Traffic on the network is routed wherever it canfind the easiest route and therefore not always viacentral points. For example, international trafficcan as easily flow from an Internet service provider(ISP), a cyber-café or a telephone company: eachhas only to open a network connection and havethe required capacity available. The network designoriginated from U.S. military demands that it with-stand nuclear attack where an important featurewas a decentralized network without a central focusor control point. Also from its university origins, it

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 15

26 VoIP as a service can and does go over the internet (which is carried on an IP network) but to achieve higher quality calling carriers have installed their ownIP networks.

27 Major carriers committed to VoIP include: MCI (100% of all traffic by the end of 2005); AT&T (100% by the end 2010); Telecom Italia (80% of all traffic wentby VoIP by the end of 2003). Between a fifth to a quarter of all historic operators in Africa were using VoIP for a part of their international traffic. As theseagreements are politically sensitive, establishing exact numbers is difficult. Telkom Kenya is about to offer publicly a VoIP-based international service. FourAfrican carriers – BTC (Botswana), Mundo Startel (Angola), Telecom Namibia and UTL – have announced that they will introduce IP-based networks.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 15

16 . Open Access Models

was designed to be open to users through publiclyavailable standards, making it easy to access.

The significance of IP networks and the core argu-ment of Open Access is that they have provided theopportunity to change the structure paradigm.Instead of needing a small number of large, verti-cally-integrated organizations (as in the telephonymodel), it is possible (using IP-networks) to haveextremely diverse “ecosystems” with a mixture ofsmall, medium, and large organizations.

The decentralized “intelligence” in IP networks hasallowed the strong growth of innovative services,content, and applications in the developed world.It is arguable that all of the creative commercialenergy that this shift has produced could not havebeen harnessed through the traditional telephonybusiness model. All of this flows from companiesand organizations being able to access infrastruc-ture on fair terms. Therefore, the challenge forthose wanting to use competition to foster cheapercommunications, technology innovation, andinvestment in a developing world is to ensure thatany “gate-keeping” function (which gives dominantmarket power to a single entity) is minimized.

For developing countries, this paradigm shift from aclosed to open network architecture offers plentifulopportunities to carve out a competitive environmentthat does not need to follow a single path or necessar-ily copy all aspects of developed world examples. Anda competitive environment shaped by developingcountries will open up newer, cheaper ways of gettingaccess to communications that will increasinglyenfranchise larger numbers of their citizens.

The basis for these changes can be understood bylooking at how those involved describe the operationof IP networks. Diagram 1 on page 4 shows aNetwork Layers model. Essentially, there are threekey layers: physical infrastructure, transmission, andservices (including applications and content). In prac-tical terms, each layer has a set of functional rulesthat allows it to interface with the other layer and forinformation to flow over the network.28 In terms ofday-to-day reality, these network functions are com-bined with Reach (the geographic scope of providers)and Type of Customer (wholesale or retail).

A vertically-integrated organization, such as a his-toric operator or SNO, will sell at every layer: itwill carry traffic and offer services. In this way, thehistoric operator in Africa finds itself selling inter-national transmission to external ISP customersand to its own ISP, leading inevitably to accusationsof conflict of interest. An ISP may offer its owninfrastructure at a local or city-wide level (usingWi-Fi) to reach its customers but will buy bothnational and international transmission fromanother carrier. A relatively recent market entrantin Kenya – KDN – is providing national and inter-national transmission to corporate customers, ISPs,and other carriers but not selling to individualretail customers.

One ISP or cyber-cafe that has an “under-the-counter” agreement with the historic operator inMali (Sotelma) buys international minutes fromthe carrier at a wholesale price and sells to its cus-tomers at a retail price. Senegal’s mobile carrierSentel (which until recently had a relatively lowproportion of its own infrastructure) buys a signifi-cant proportion of its national and internationaltransmission from the historic operator Sonatel toprovide mobile voice services. A mobile virtual net-work operator (MVNO) offers a service that goesout over someone else’s network for which theoperator pays a percentage of its revenues. A shortmessage service (SMS) data service provider willuse its own platform to provide text messaged serv-ices via the mobile operator’s network to the latter’scustomers. The Layered Networks model describesa world in which there are multiple relationshipsbetween providers operating in different layers inthe model.

As IP networks begin to take over from telephonenetworks, this layered approach will become a toolfor understanding how markets function. In termsof an Open Access approach, it is being argued thatthe transmission layer needs to be separated fromthe other layers in operational terms to create maxi-mum growth through competition in all the otherlayers. If a vertically integrated entity operates acrossseveral layers and dominates any one (particularlytransmission or physical infrastructure) it can exert astranglehold on market growth, particularly if it is ahistoric operator defending its inherited markets.

28 There are several more detailed ways of describing the layers and these capture what are essentially technical functions of the network. Applications includethings like Web and mail browsers. Services include all forms of content whether voice, data or images.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 16

16 . Open Access Models

was designed to be open to users through publiclyavailable standards, making it easy to access.

The significance of IP networks and the core argu-ment of Open Access is that they have provided theopportunity to change the structure paradigm.Instead of needing a small number of large, verti-cally-integrated organizations (as in the telephonymodel), it is possible (using IP-networks) to haveextremely diverse “ecosystems” with a mixture ofsmall, medium, and large organizations.

The decentralized “intelligence” in IP networks hasallowed the strong growth of innovative services,content, and applications in the developed world.It is arguable that all of the creative commercialenergy that this shift has produced could not havebeen harnessed through the traditional telephonybusiness model. All of this flows from companiesand organizations being able to access infrastruc-ture on fair terms. Therefore, the challenge forthose wanting to use competition to foster cheapercommunications, technology innovation, andinvestment in a developing world is to ensure thatany “gate-keeping” function (which gives dominantmarket power to a single entity) is minimized.

For developing countries, this paradigm shift from aclosed to open network architecture offers plentifulopportunities to carve out a competitive environmentthat does not need to follow a single path or necessar-ily copy all aspects of developed world examples. Anda competitive environment shaped by developingcountries will open up newer, cheaper ways of gettingaccess to communications that will increasinglyenfranchise larger numbers of their citizens.

The basis for these changes can be understood bylooking at how those involved describe the operationof IP networks. Diagram 1 on page 4 shows aNetwork Layers model. Essentially, there are threekey layers: physical infrastructure, transmission, andservices (including applications and content). In prac-tical terms, each layer has a set of functional rulesthat allows it to interface with the other layer and forinformation to flow over the network.28 In terms ofday-to-day reality, these network functions are com-bined with Reach (the geographic scope of providers)and Type of Customer (wholesale or retail).

A vertically-integrated organization, such as a his-toric operator or SNO, will sell at every layer: itwill carry traffic and offer services. In this way, thehistoric operator in Africa finds itself selling inter-national transmission to external ISP customersand to its own ISP, leading inevitably to accusationsof conflict of interest. An ISP may offer its owninfrastructure at a local or city-wide level (usingWi-Fi) to reach its customers but will buy bothnational and international transmission fromanother carrier. A relatively recent market entrantin Kenya – KDN – is providing national and inter-national transmission to corporate customers, ISPs,and other carriers but not selling to individualretail customers.

One ISP or cyber-cafe that has an “under-the-counter” agreement with the historic operator inMali (Sotelma) buys international minutes fromthe carrier at a wholesale price and sells to its cus-tomers at a retail price. Senegal’s mobile carrierSentel (which until recently had a relatively lowproportion of its own infrastructure) buys a signifi-cant proportion of its national and internationaltransmission from the historic operator Sonatel toprovide mobile voice services. A mobile virtual net-work operator (MVNO) offers a service that goesout over someone else’s network for which theoperator pays a percentage of its revenues. A shortmessage service (SMS) data service provider willuse its own platform to provide text messaged serv-ices via the mobile operator’s network to the latter’scustomers. The Layered Networks model describesa world in which there are multiple relationshipsbetween providers operating in different layers inthe model.

As IP networks begin to take over from telephonenetworks, this layered approach will become a toolfor understanding how markets function. In termsof an Open Access approach, it is being argued thatthe transmission layer needs to be separated fromthe other layers in operational terms to create maxi-mum growth through competition in all the otherlayers. If a vertically integrated entity operates acrossseveral layers and dominates any one (particularlytransmission or physical infrastructure) it can exert astranglehold on market growth, particularly if it is ahistoric operator defending its inherited markets.

28 There are several more detailed ways of describing the layers and these capture what are essentially technical functions of the network. Applications includethings like Web and mail browsers. Services include all forms of content whether voice, data or images.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 16

IP networks allow growth at the edges of the net-work. It becomes possible at the local level to havea small-scale, “plug-and-play” operator intercon-necting with much larger operators. Local andmunicipal networks can co-exist as infrastructureproviders alongside more traditional operators.Alternative infrastructure providers such as utilitycompanies and railways can add their fiber capacityto an existing network and sell to those wantingnational transmission.29 More transparent andcompetitive arrangements can be reached for build-ing inter-country and international infrastructure.The use of IP networks means that newer, cheapertechnologies can be used to build and operate serv-ices and infrastructure. All of this requires newbusiness models that can reflect the implications ofthe changes that are already taking place.

2.2 SIGNIFICANT MARKETDEVELOPMENTS – “GOINGWITH THE GRAIN”One of the most significant market developments isthe separation of infrastructure and services. Theimpact of this is already widely known and highlyvisible in the developed world: the growth oforganizations as diverse as e-Bay, Skype, andAmazon.com are a product of a lively market ofproviders in the service layer. These successful serv-ice companies have not by and large been part ofthe vertically integrated, historic operators.

In Africa, the same process is occurring, but it isnot as large or as visible because the service marketstake different forms and often services have not yetbeen legalized because of the perceived need todefend the historic operator. Roughly 10-30 per-cent of the international voice market in eachcountry in Sub-Saharan Africa is in the grey mar-ket. ISPs and cyber-cafes are buying services frominternational providers to offer calling services.Wholesalers and retailers of mobile prepaid callingcards sell to customers from street corners. InSouth Africa, larger ISPs operate virtual ISPs (act-ing as wholesalers) for smaller organizations with

local or specialist customer bases. MVNOs willsoon start to operate on the continent.

A transition is occurring – both in the developedand developing world – from large vertically inte-grated organizations (such as the historic opera-tors and SNOs to a small number of infrastruc-ture providers feeding a mass of service-basedcompanies. These changes are messy and notclear-cut but they will lead to more horizontalplayers with trading between the different net-work layers in the market. Whether from marketimperatives or regulatory pressures, significantnumbers of historic operators are separating outtheir different operations into more or less free-standing subsidiaries.30

Currently core infrastructure is usually provided bythe historic operator but there have been a signifi-cant number of instances where SNOs and alterna-tive infrastructure providers (such as utilities andrailways) have set up competing infrastructurelinks. Even with the falling costs of technology,infrastructure is a large-scale, big-investment busi-ness and therefore there are unlikely to be morethan one or two large-scale entities providing it in amature market. Greater infrastructure competitiondepends on the value of the market and populationdensity found in a particular country.

Reasonably wealthy and densely populated coun-tries such as Nigeria and South Africa have twoinfrastructure providers. Thinly populated andpoorer countries such as Mali or Niger, may onlyhave one. Mid-scale countries such as Kenya have asecond infrastructure operator that provides com-petition in the larger urban markets and betweenthose centers.31 In either of these cases, licensingalternative infrastructure providers can open upcompetition on major transmission routes.Covering a thinly dispersed rural population is theultimate challenge: it may only sustain one infra-structure provider and then only with soft loanfinancing for capital investment. But even in thesecircumstances, it would make sense to have someelement of competition to allow price and servicecompetition to occur.

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 17

29 Three power companies in Africa are actively selling their fiber capacity and have the relevant license in their respective countries: Voltacom (Ghana), Zesco(Zambia) and Powertel (Zimbabwe). The Ghanaian government has announced its intention to privatize Voltacom.

30 Ghana Telecom has been asked by the Ghanaian regulator to separate out its broadband operation after various accusations from competitor ISPs. The newMD of Telkom Kenya has announced that its new ISP will not be subsidized from revenues derived from other parts of the company.

31 Owned by the Sameer Group, KDN is investing US$330 million in creating an East African transmission network. It is building a national network in Kenyabetween main cities (including the Nairobi-Mombasa route to connect to EASSy, the proposed international fiber cable. It will connect to other networks inneighboring countries and is close to completing a fiber route to the Ugandan border.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 17

IP networks allow growth at the edges of the net-work. It becomes possible at the local level to havea small-scale, “plug-and-play” operator intercon-necting with much larger operators. Local andmunicipal networks can co-exist as infrastructureproviders alongside more traditional operators.Alternative infrastructure providers such as utilitycompanies and railways can add their fiber capacityto an existing network and sell to those wantingnational transmission.29 More transparent andcompetitive arrangements can be reached for build-ing inter-country and international infrastructure.The use of IP networks means that newer, cheapertechnologies can be used to build and operate serv-ices and infrastructure. All of this requires newbusiness models that can reflect the implications ofthe changes that are already taking place.

2.2 SIGNIFICANT MARKETDEVELOPMENTS – “GOINGWITH THE GRAIN”One of the most significant market developments isthe separation of infrastructure and services. Theimpact of this is already widely known and highlyvisible in the developed world: the growth oforganizations as diverse as e-Bay, Skype, andAmazon.com are a product of a lively market ofproviders in the service layer. These successful serv-ice companies have not by and large been part ofthe vertically integrated, historic operators.

In Africa, the same process is occurring, but it isnot as large or as visible because the service marketstake different forms and often services have not yetbeen legalized because of the perceived need todefend the historic operator. Roughly 10-30 per-cent of the international voice market in eachcountry in Sub-Saharan Africa is in the grey mar-ket. ISPs and cyber-cafes are buying services frominternational providers to offer calling services.Wholesalers and retailers of mobile prepaid callingcards sell to customers from street corners. InSouth Africa, larger ISPs operate virtual ISPs (act-ing as wholesalers) for smaller organizations with

local or specialist customer bases. MVNOs willsoon start to operate on the continent.

A transition is occurring – both in the developedand developing world – from large vertically inte-grated organizations (such as the historic opera-tors and SNOs to a small number of infrastruc-ture providers feeding a mass of service-basedcompanies. These changes are messy and notclear-cut but they will lead to more horizontalplayers with trading between the different net-work layers in the market. Whether from marketimperatives or regulatory pressures, significantnumbers of historic operators are separating outtheir different operations into more or less free-standing subsidiaries.30

Currently core infrastructure is usually provided bythe historic operator but there have been a signifi-cant number of instances where SNOs and alterna-tive infrastructure providers (such as utilities andrailways) have set up competing infrastructurelinks. Even with the falling costs of technology,infrastructure is a large-scale, big-investment busi-ness and therefore there are unlikely to be morethan one or two large-scale entities providing it in amature market. Greater infrastructure competitiondepends on the value of the market and populationdensity found in a particular country.

Reasonably wealthy and densely populated coun-tries such as Nigeria and South Africa have twoinfrastructure providers. Thinly populated andpoorer countries such as Mali or Niger, may onlyhave one. Mid-scale countries such as Kenya have asecond infrastructure operator that provides com-petition in the larger urban markets and betweenthose centers.31 In either of these cases, licensingalternative infrastructure providers can open upcompetition on major transmission routes.Covering a thinly dispersed rural population is theultimate challenge: it may only sustain one infra-structure provider and then only with soft loanfinancing for capital investment. But even in thesecircumstances, it would make sense to have someelement of competition to allow price and servicecompetition to occur.

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 17

29 Three power companies in Africa are actively selling their fiber capacity and have the relevant license in their respective countries: Voltacom (Ghana), Zesco(Zambia) and Powertel (Zimbabwe). The Ghanaian government has announced its intention to privatize Voltacom.

30 Ghana Telecom has been asked by the Ghanaian regulator to separate out its broadband operation after various accusations from competitor ISPs. The newMD of Telkom Kenya has announced that its new ISP will not be subsidized from revenues derived from other parts of the company.

31 Owned by the Sameer Group, KDN is investing US$330 million in creating an East African transmission network. It is building a national network in Kenyabetween main cities (including the Nairobi-Mombasa route to connect to EASSy, the proposed international fiber cable. It will connect to other networks inneighboring countries and is close to completing a fiber route to the Ugandan border.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 17

18 . Open Access Models

Because of cost, the idea of a single, rational infra-structure network seems like a good idea whereresources are short. But this beguiling notion isunlikely to work except in highly controlled cir-cumstances where good governance ensures thatvested interests are held at bay. This obviouslywould work better in some countries than in oth-ers. Therefore, it is almost certainly better to “over-provide” rather than leave control of the infrastruc-ture resources in the hands of a single entity,whether publicly or privately controlled. That said,within a competitive framework there are a numberof mechanisms that allow operators to shareresources (and thus gain some cost-savings): somehave been self-organized, while others have beenimposed by regulatory pressure.32

The strategic business shift for historic operators isto move from getting a majority share in everyservice market to seeing their future as taking ashare of revenues on all service markets as theyemerge: in other words, to become a carriers’ carri-er at the transmission level. A few historic opera-tors in Africa have already been making plans inthis direction.33 Following this strategy may startwith simply separating out different parts of thebusiness and ending internal cross-subsidies.34 Thebusiness case for acting as a carriers’ carrierinvolves creating infrastructure companies withlower levels of staffing and costs and seeking topersuade a significant part of the market to use thecompany’s services. Volume and increased efficien-cy through technology innovation has to compen-sate for low margins.

If an infrastructure provider offers services, itends up competing with its own customers. Thisdifficulty can already be seen in the most liberal-ized markets, in relation to the historic operator’srelationship with mobile operators and ISPs. Itsets up a constantly defensive dynamic in thediscussion between the historic operators andother players. It enables neither side in the dis-cussion to focus clearly on innovation and devel-opment of the market.

The second significant market development is theavailability of a number of “disruptive technolo-gies” that are offering the possibility of cheaperaccess to voice and data than traditional wireline.Some examples include VoIP, Wi-Fi, Wi-MAX,code-division multiple access (CDMA), enhanceddata GSM environment (EDGE), and very smallaperture terminal (VSAT). VoIP network deploy-ment costs often come in increments ofUS$50,000–$100,000, rather than the US$1 millionplus increments of telecoms switching facilities anddedicated circuits. As a result, it is possible to addcapacity in smaller steps that will begin to makereturn more quickly rather than the multi-milliontraditional telecom equipment investments thatrequire many years before they fill up and make areturn over much longer periods. Smaller invest-ments can often be financed out of cash flow ratherthan requiring major external borrowing.

Disruptive technologies changingthe shape of the market

Disruptive technology is a term coined by Harvard Business SchoolProfessor Clayton M. Christensen to describe a new technology thatunexpectedly displaces an established technology35. These tech-nologies operate at the edge of the possible and may have per-formance problems because they are new. Although it is difficult toremember, the phone was once one of these technologies.

Larger companies work with existing technologies that are provenand seek to refine and develop their use. Disruptive technologiesoften undercut the business model of larger companies bydemanding structural changes and thus are particularly hard forthem to react to: why offer a service more cheaply when youmake good money from a more expensive service? In the tele-coms field, equipment investment cycles (the economic life of theequipment) for core equipment have been as long as 10–15years and previously even longer. The newer disruptive communi-cations technologies have buying cycles that are much more likethose for PCs, typically requiring updating over 2–3 year cycles.

32 Self-organized initiatives include things like MVNOs using existing networks and national ISP associations agreeing to create IXPs. Imposed infrastructurecost savings would cover things like shared use of masts (often on environmental grounds) and of network (for areas of marginal business).

33 TTCL has announced its intention to become a “carriers’ carrier” with the idea that it will be given the fiber assets of the Tanzanian power and railwayprostates. In another instance, TDM in Mozambique, whilst it will not become a carriers’ carrier, is clearly thinking about how it will build its business modelwith infrastructure as a key element.

34 See endnote 29 above.35 See his book The Innovator’s Dilemma.

Depending on the structure of national and inter-national trunk traffic tariffs, sending calls by a datanetwork may also result in significant savings. Withthese savings, a developing country telephone com-pany can consider connecting a range of places thatwith traditional public switched telephone network

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 18

18 . Open Access Models

Because of cost, the idea of a single, rational infra-structure network seems like a good idea whereresources are short. But this beguiling notion isunlikely to work except in highly controlled cir-cumstances where good governance ensures thatvested interests are held at bay. This obviouslywould work better in some countries than in oth-ers. Therefore, it is almost certainly better to “over-provide” rather than leave control of the infrastruc-ture resources in the hands of a single entity,whether publicly or privately controlled. That said,within a competitive framework there are a numberof mechanisms that allow operators to shareresources (and thus gain some cost-savings): somehave been self-organized, while others have beenimposed by regulatory pressure.32

The strategic business shift for historic operators isto move from getting a majority share in everyservice market to seeing their future as taking ashare of revenues on all service markets as theyemerge: in other words, to become a carriers’ carri-er at the transmission level. A few historic opera-tors in Africa have already been making plans inthis direction.33 Following this strategy may startwith simply separating out different parts of thebusiness and ending internal cross-subsidies.34 Thebusiness case for acting as a carriers’ carrierinvolves creating infrastructure companies withlower levels of staffing and costs and seeking topersuade a significant part of the market to use thecompany’s services. Volume and increased efficien-cy through technology innovation has to compen-sate for low margins.

If an infrastructure provider offers services, itends up competing with its own customers. Thisdifficulty can already be seen in the most liberal-ized markets, in relation to the historic operator’srelationship with mobile operators and ISPs. Itsets up a constantly defensive dynamic in thediscussion between the historic operators andother players. It enables neither side in the dis-cussion to focus clearly on innovation and devel-opment of the market.

The second significant market development is theavailability of a number of “disruptive technolo-gies” that are offering the possibility of cheaperaccess to voice and data than traditional wireline.Some examples include VoIP, Wi-Fi, Wi-MAX,code-division multiple access (CDMA), enhanceddata GSM environment (EDGE), and very smallaperture terminal (VSAT). VoIP network deploy-ment costs often come in increments ofUS$50,000–$100,000, rather than the US$1 millionplus increments of telecoms switching facilities anddedicated circuits. As a result, it is possible to addcapacity in smaller steps that will begin to makereturn more quickly rather than the multi-milliontraditional telecom equipment investments thatrequire many years before they fill up and make areturn over much longer periods. Smaller invest-ments can often be financed out of cash flow ratherthan requiring major external borrowing.

Disruptive technologies changingthe shape of the market

Disruptive technology is a term coined by Harvard Business SchoolProfessor Clayton M. Christensen to describe a new technology thatunexpectedly displaces an established technology35. These tech-nologies operate at the edge of the possible and may have per-formance problems because they are new. Although it is difficult toremember, the phone was once one of these technologies.

Larger companies work with existing technologies that are provenand seek to refine and develop their use. Disruptive technologiesoften undercut the business model of larger companies bydemanding structural changes and thus are particularly hard forthem to react to: why offer a service more cheaply when youmake good money from a more expensive service? In the tele-coms field, equipment investment cycles (the economic life of theequipment) for core equipment have been as long as 10–15years and previously even longer. The newer disruptive communi-cations technologies have buying cycles that are much more likethose for PCs, typically requiring updating over 2–3 year cycles.

32 Self-organized initiatives include things like MVNOs using existing networks and national ISP associations agreeing to create IXPs. Imposed infrastructurecost savings would cover things like shared use of masts (often on environmental grounds) and of network (for areas of marginal business).

33 TTCL has announced its intention to become a “carriers’ carrier” with the idea that it will be given the fiber assets of the Tanzanian power and railwayprostates. In another instance, TDM in Mozambique, whilst it will not become a carriers’ carrier, is clearly thinking about how it will build its business modelwith infrastructure as a key element.

34 See endnote 29 above.35 See his book The Innovator’s Dilemma.

Depending on the structure of national and inter-national trunk traffic tariffs, sending calls by a datanetwork may also result in significant savings. Withthese savings, a developing country telephone com-pany can consider connecting a range of places thatwith traditional public switched telephone network

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:10 PM Page 18

(PSTN) investment might simply not have beenviable. A similar set of arguments apply to usingwireless for national traffic links. Historic operatorsin Africa that have used wireless links betweentowns indicate that they have cost between 10–15percent of the sum needed for laying equivalentfixed-line connections.36

These technological changes might be implement-ed as they stand without significant policy or regu-latory change. But just as IP networks allowed the“Siamese twins” of infrastructure and services to beseparated, these disruptive technologies hold awider potential to allow the creation of small andmedium enterprises (SMEs) to address low-incomemarkets. This is already happening, but against alargely unsympathetic policy and regulatoryenvironment: the changing of this environment(particularly allowing access to free or low-costwireless spectrum) will allow the market potentialof disruptive technologies to deliver a wider rangeof new benefits.

2.3 THE OPEN ACCESSAPPROACHOpen Access is a broad approach to policy and reg-ulatory issues that starts from the question: what dowe want to bring about outside of purely industrysector concerns? It places an emphasis on: empower-ing citizens; encouraging local innovation, economicgrowth, and investment; and getting the best frompublic and private sector contributions. It is notsimply about making micro-adjustments to thetechnical rules of the policy and regulatory frame-work but seeking to produce fundamental changesin the outcomes that can be delivered through it.

Micro-managing competition with detailed rules istoo slow and cumbersome: developing countries arenot alone in finding difficulty in reaching decisionsin this way. In future, regulators and policymakerswill need to work with an approach that involves alighter set of rules and base these on a stable set ofcore values that encourage technological innovationand growth.

The Open Access approach is about creating a setof core values that can be summarized as follows:■ a technology-neutral framework (that encour-

ages innovative, low-cost delivery to users),■ competition at all layers in the IP network

(allowing a wide variety of physical networks andapplications to interact in an open architecture),

■ transparency to ensure fair trading within andbetween layers (that allows clear, comparativeinformation on market prices and services),

■ the circumstances where everyone can connect toeveryone else at the layer interface (so that any sizeorganization can enter the market and no onetakes a position of dominant market power), and

■ devolved local solutions rather than centralized ones(encouraging services that are closer to the user).

The “openness” creates a market dynamic at every levelin the system, emphasizing the need to innovate incost terms to expand the user base at a price and in aform appropriate to them. A diversity of services andphysical infrastructure means that no single businessmodel has to fit all users: smaller, lower cost operatorscan go where larger organizations might fear to tread.

Through Open Access, the market (with a gentlehand from the public sector) can begin to turn com-munication into a public good available to widergroups of people. Naturally, the private sector needsto obtain short-term returns for its shareholders.Therefore, the public sector has to create a widerrange of circumstances in which this can occur: itneeds to provide incentives for the private sector togrow the market. The public sector for its part willcontinue to represent the public good, and in thisrole take medium and long-term risks that the pri-vate sector might be unwilling to shoulder. Forexample, it might act as the equivalent of an “anchorcustomer” for the roll-out of a network or invest inthe network itself under some circumstances.

Although Open Access places the effective opera-tion of markets at its core, it acknowledges that themarket will not deliver in all circumstances. It seesthe challenge as being able to extend communica-tions to those at the bottom of the income pyramidby lowering the cost of services. In these situations

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 19

36 Although precise details are commercially confidential, we are aware of two relatively large-scale projects to deploy Wi-Fi relay links: one to connect two coun-tries whose capitals are relatively close to each other and the other to build a national backbone for a smaller country. The capital costs of these projects aresignificantly cheaper than their wireline equivalent. The estimate of the cost-saving through using a Wi-Fi relay link was provided confidentially by a seniormanager at a Southern African historic operator in early 2005. At the local loop level, both Wi-Fi and Wi-Max can provide extremely competitive capital devel-opment costs. There are developed, city-wide canopy solutions in Accra, Dar es Salaam and Nairobi. There are three Wi-Max solutions – in DRC, Kenya andMalawi – all again being used to deliver at the local level in cities.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 19

(PSTN) investment might simply not have beenviable. A similar set of arguments apply to usingwireless for national traffic links. Historic operatorsin Africa that have used wireless links betweentowns indicate that they have cost between 10–15percent of the sum needed for laying equivalentfixed-line connections.36

These technological changes might be implement-ed as they stand without significant policy or regu-latory change. But just as IP networks allowed the“Siamese twins” of infrastructure and services to beseparated, these disruptive technologies hold awider potential to allow the creation of small andmedium enterprises (SMEs) to address low-incomemarkets. This is already happening, but against alargely unsympathetic policy and regulatoryenvironment: the changing of this environment(particularly allowing access to free or low-costwireless spectrum) will allow the market potentialof disruptive technologies to deliver a wider rangeof new benefits.

2.3 THE OPEN ACCESSAPPROACHOpen Access is a broad approach to policy and reg-ulatory issues that starts from the question: what dowe want to bring about outside of purely industrysector concerns? It places an emphasis on: empower-ing citizens; encouraging local innovation, economicgrowth, and investment; and getting the best frompublic and private sector contributions. It is notsimply about making micro-adjustments to thetechnical rules of the policy and regulatory frame-work but seeking to produce fundamental changesin the outcomes that can be delivered through it.

Micro-managing competition with detailed rules istoo slow and cumbersome: developing countries arenot alone in finding difficulty in reaching decisionsin this way. In future, regulators and policymakerswill need to work with an approach that involves alighter set of rules and base these on a stable set ofcore values that encourage technological innovationand growth.

The Open Access approach is about creating a setof core values that can be summarized as follows:■ a technology-neutral framework (that encour-

ages innovative, low-cost delivery to users),■ competition at all layers in the IP network

(allowing a wide variety of physical networks andapplications to interact in an open architecture),

■ transparency to ensure fair trading within andbetween layers (that allows clear, comparativeinformation on market prices and services),

■ the circumstances where everyone can connect toeveryone else at the layer interface (so that any sizeorganization can enter the market and no onetakes a position of dominant market power), and

■ devolved local solutions rather than centralized ones(encouraging services that are closer to the user).

The “openness” creates a market dynamic at every levelin the system, emphasizing the need to innovate incost terms to expand the user base at a price and in aform appropriate to them. A diversity of services andphysical infrastructure means that no single businessmodel has to fit all users: smaller, lower cost operatorscan go where larger organizations might fear to tread.

Through Open Access, the market (with a gentlehand from the public sector) can begin to turn com-munication into a public good available to widergroups of people. Naturally, the private sector needsto obtain short-term returns for its shareholders.Therefore, the public sector has to create a widerrange of circumstances in which this can occur: itneeds to provide incentives for the private sector togrow the market. The public sector for its part willcontinue to represent the public good, and in thisrole take medium and long-term risks that the pri-vate sector might be unwilling to shoulder. Forexample, it might act as the equivalent of an “anchorcustomer” for the roll-out of a network or invest inthe network itself under some circumstances.

Although Open Access places the effective opera-tion of markets at its core, it acknowledges that themarket will not deliver in all circumstances. It seesthe challenge as being able to extend communica-tions to those at the bottom of the income pyramidby lowering the cost of services. In these situations

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 19

36 Although precise details are commercially confidential, we are aware of two relatively large-scale projects to deploy Wi-Fi relay links: one to connect two coun-tries whose capitals are relatively close to each other and the other to build a national backbone for a smaller country. The capital costs of these projects aresignificantly cheaper than their wireline equivalent. The estimate of the cost-saving through using a Wi-Fi relay link was provided confidentially by a seniormanager at a Southern African historic operator in early 2005. At the local loop level, both Wi-Fi and Wi-Max can provide extremely competitive capital devel-opment costs. There are developed, city-wide canopy solutions in Accra, Dar es Salaam and Nairobi. There are three Wi-Max solutions – in DRC, Kenya andMalawi – all again being used to deliver at the local level in cities.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 19

20 . Open Access Models

the function of the public sector is to create the cir-cumstances for successful Open Access (throughpartly funding infrastructure and thus assuring itsavailability to all) and to create incentives for theroll-out of services as widely as possible.

Open Access seeks to ensure that market gap (or“market-stretch”) funding will deliver final marketdemand. In particular, the public sector’s role inOpen Access is to address key structural problemssuch as national and international infrastructure. Itneeds to play a role in unlocking the “chicken andegg” problem that if there is no market, there is noinvestment but that without investment, the mar-ket will not have the opportunity to grow. But evenif this is successful, there will continue to be areasof social need that the market will not meet andthese remain the responsibility of government.

In this way, the Open Access approach seeks to cre-ate a “virtuous circle” that addresses almost all mainimpediments to growth. The “bottom-up” operatorsof infrastructure at the local level will increase theuser base. This will feed into the volume of traffic atthe regional, national, and international levels.

Service operators at every level will have some levelof infrastructure they operate themselves. As theyexpand, the reach of the infrastructure network andits capacity will grow along with them.

At each level, roles vary. A national infrastructureprovider wholesales (or connects) to those at a locallevel. But the same national infrastructure providerconnects to retailers of international bandwidththat is supplied wholesale to it (or its customers) atthe international level. The separation of infrastruc-ture and services (or wholesale and retail) allows theemergence of clearer roles for each of the players.Organizations no longer need to compete withtheir own customers and the costs of infrastructurebecome more transparent.

Open Access focuses on lowering the cost ofbusiness entry but is “technology-neutral.” TheOpen Access approach seeks to emphasize inno-vation that makes providers look for whatevertechnology works at the right (lower) price: thetechnologies that are suitable will vary enor-mously depending on historic legacy equipmentand physical circumstances.

37 This trust has grown in a wide variety of business sectors in the developed world where outsourcing of functions (both nationally and internationally) hasbeen an accepted approach to lowering costs. In Sub-Saharan Africa, the pressures on enterprise costs have until recently been less intense: the relative lackof competition in the airline or banking sectors in many countries is a good example. However this relative lack of familiarity with outsourced relationshipsand the trust required to operate them will change for two reasons. Increasingly a small but significant number of African countries are acting as outsourc-ing markets for developing countries and there is steadily increasing competition across the continent in market sectors outside of communications. For exam-ple, Zantel is using Vodacom’s mobile infrastructure to roll-out its mobile service on the Tanzanian mainland (source: Tanzania’s Guardian 1/7/2005)

Creating trust between service and infrastructure providers

One of the major issues in an Open Access business model is that it requires trust in parties outside of one’s own organization.37 A serviceprovider potentially puts the whole business at risk through trusting somebody to supply the required infrastructure. The service providerneeds to be assured that the infrastructure provider is going to tackle its needs with the same degree of attention as if the organization wasdoing it itself. The fundamental factors for assessing this are no different from any other area of business. They include: financial stability;operational capability; gradual development of the offer; and a reasonable price. The two keystone business practices for establishing trusttherefore are non-discriminatory pricing and no competition from the infrastructure supplier itself.

Trust is also easier to establish if there is a feeling of mutual inter-dependency. This is why alternative infrastructure providers can succeed:they are focused, know who they depend on, and are eager to be cost effective as they need to acquire new customers. And the serviceproviders also know this. Mutual self-interest means that each side needs the other to succeed.

The historic operators as vertical players have very reluctantly (pressed by legislation) made some network resources available to others.This is of course not a good foundation for creating the necessary trust. There are all too many stories of the tricks and delaying tacticsemployed. The infrastructure provider sees the other party as a competitor and not a valued customer.

When the combined market share of all non-facilities-based service providers approaches the historic operator in size, the network department (whichprovides the infrastructure) of that operation will begin to behave differently. It will begin to see its volumes are shrinking, and it may be faced withstaff lay-offs. At this point, there is usually a shift in “mind-set” and it begins to behave properly to both its internal and external customers.

Where there is only one infrastructure provider, two things are essential to creating trust. First, there is a need to separate out the serviceprovider elements of the historic operator. Regulators in several developing countries have already requested this for both mobile operationsand ISPs so that they operate at “arms-length” to network provision. In the medium-term, a complete separation would almost certainly befeasible. Secondly, it would be important to create governance structures with oversight powers of the kind described in the sections below.

In contractual terms, there is a variety of Service Level Agreements (SLAs) that have been developed out of fiber lease, and capacity salesdeals between service providers and infrastructure companies. These address all the detailed conditions and actions between the two par-ties should anything happen. Once trust is established, these are rarely called upon.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 20

20 . Open Access Models

the function of the public sector is to create the cir-cumstances for successful Open Access (throughpartly funding infrastructure and thus assuring itsavailability to all) and to create incentives for theroll-out of services as widely as possible.

Open Access seeks to ensure that market gap (or“market-stretch”) funding will deliver final marketdemand. In particular, the public sector’s role inOpen Access is to address key structural problemssuch as national and international infrastructure. Itneeds to play a role in unlocking the “chicken andegg” problem that if there is no market, there is noinvestment but that without investment, the mar-ket will not have the opportunity to grow. But evenif this is successful, there will continue to be areasof social need that the market will not meet andthese remain the responsibility of government.

In this way, the Open Access approach seeks to cre-ate a “virtuous circle” that addresses almost all mainimpediments to growth. The “bottom-up” operatorsof infrastructure at the local level will increase theuser base. This will feed into the volume of traffic atthe regional, national, and international levels.

Service operators at every level will have some levelof infrastructure they operate themselves. As theyexpand, the reach of the infrastructure network andits capacity will grow along with them.

At each level, roles vary. A national infrastructureprovider wholesales (or connects) to those at a locallevel. But the same national infrastructure providerconnects to retailers of international bandwidththat is supplied wholesale to it (or its customers) atthe international level. The separation of infrastruc-ture and services (or wholesale and retail) allows theemergence of clearer roles for each of the players.Organizations no longer need to compete withtheir own customers and the costs of infrastructurebecome more transparent.

Open Access focuses on lowering the cost ofbusiness entry but is “technology-neutral.” TheOpen Access approach seeks to emphasize inno-vation that makes providers look for whatevertechnology works at the right (lower) price: thetechnologies that are suitable will vary enor-mously depending on historic legacy equipmentand physical circumstances.

37 This trust has grown in a wide variety of business sectors in the developed world where outsourcing of functions (both nationally and internationally) hasbeen an accepted approach to lowering costs. In Sub-Saharan Africa, the pressures on enterprise costs have until recently been less intense: the relative lackof competition in the airline or banking sectors in many countries is a good example. However this relative lack of familiarity with outsourced relationshipsand the trust required to operate them will change for two reasons. Increasingly a small but significant number of African countries are acting as outsourc-ing markets for developing countries and there is steadily increasing competition across the continent in market sectors outside of communications. For exam-ple, Zantel is using Vodacom’s mobile infrastructure to roll-out its mobile service on the Tanzanian mainland (source: Tanzania’s Guardian 1/7/2005)

Creating trust between service and infrastructure providers

One of the major issues in an Open Access business model is that it requires trust in parties outside of one’s own organization.37 A serviceprovider potentially puts the whole business at risk through trusting somebody to supply the required infrastructure. The service providerneeds to be assured that the infrastructure provider is going to tackle its needs with the same degree of attention as if the organization wasdoing it itself. The fundamental factors for assessing this are no different from any other area of business. They include: financial stability;operational capability; gradual development of the offer; and a reasonable price. The two keystone business practices for establishing trusttherefore are non-discriminatory pricing and no competition from the infrastructure supplier itself.

Trust is also easier to establish if there is a feeling of mutual inter-dependency. This is why alternative infrastructure providers can succeed:they are focused, know who they depend on, and are eager to be cost effective as they need to acquire new customers. And the serviceproviders also know this. Mutual self-interest means that each side needs the other to succeed.

The historic operators as vertical players have very reluctantly (pressed by legislation) made some network resources available to others.This is of course not a good foundation for creating the necessary trust. There are all too many stories of the tricks and delaying tacticsemployed. The infrastructure provider sees the other party as a competitor and not a valued customer.

When the combined market share of all non-facilities-based service providers approaches the historic operator in size, the network department (whichprovides the infrastructure) of that operation will begin to behave differently. It will begin to see its volumes are shrinking, and it may be faced withstaff lay-offs. At this point, there is usually a shift in “mind-set” and it begins to behave properly to both its internal and external customers.

Where there is only one infrastructure provider, two things are essential to creating trust. First, there is a need to separate out the serviceprovider elements of the historic operator. Regulators in several developing countries have already requested this for both mobile operationsand ISPs so that they operate at “arms-length” to network provision. In the medium-term, a complete separation would almost certainly befeasible. Secondly, it would be important to create governance structures with oversight powers of the kind described in the sections below.

In contractual terms, there is a variety of Service Level Agreements (SLAs) that have been developed out of fiber lease, and capacity salesdeals between service providers and infrastructure companies. These address all the detailed conditions and actions between the two par-ties should anything happen. Once trust is established, these are rarely called upon.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 20

2.4 RURAL “PLUG AND PLAY” At the rural level, Open Access emphasizes theimportance of small-scale providers who can pro-vide cheaper services than traditional operatorsbecause their entry and operating costs are lower.In an Open Access environment, these “plug-and-play” operators have the potential to spread voiceand Internet use to places currently not covered,while at the same time encouraging significant eco-nomic activity in rural areas.

At present, a single base station connected to thenetwork might cost between US$125,000–$250,000to deliver. Recent approaches by one manufacturermay potentially reduce this cost to US$100,000.38

Work carried out for this study suggests that itmay be possible to lower this further to aroundUS$30–50,000.39 Operating costs would be keptto a minimum by offering almost exclusively pre-pay options to users and the operation would besimplified to allow non-technical users to run it.While this desire to lower business costs mightequally happen without an Open Access approach,there is not (in developing countries) a policyframework that provides incentives for this to hap-pen and allows its practical operation.

The local “plug-and-play” operator would have aninterconnection agreement with the traditionaloperators (mobile or PSTN) for calls that wererouted out into the wider network and equally, backinto the smaller, local network.40 Each would deriveincome and advantage from this arrangement. Thelarge-scale mobile operator would not have to re-engineer its business model to chase marginal mar-kets but would gain access to additional traffic. Thesmall-scale operator would gain income and derivestrength from being part of a wider network.

Providing electricity to power the network becomes amajor design factor. It would be essential to link theencouragement of communications and power supply.If the power utility is rolling out new power lines, theaddition of a few extra strands of fiber is a marginaladditional cost.41 A local power operator would beable to sell power to a local store, school, clinic andInternet café as well as provide telecommunications.

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 21

Reaching users at the bottom of the pyramid

C.K.Prahalad and Stuart Hart defined the different populations ofthe world in terms of income.42 They identified that 4 billionpeople or more live on annual incomes of less than US$1500. Inother words, somewhere between US$2–$4 per day. MichaelBest has calculated that communications micro-businesses in Indiacan sustain themselves on US$3-$5 per day.43 These may ormay not turn out to be the correct break-even point but the point iseloquently illustrated. For even double or triple that sum would fun-damentally change the parameters of the current business model.

To reach this group of people, Prahalad identifies a number offactors for success based upon existing companies (from smalllocal companies to multinationals) that already operate well inthese markets. All are interesting but a few are absolutely key forcommunications activities. Because the skills needed are not wide-ly available, it is important to simplify the activity. It should notrequire sophisticated technicians to implement or maintain.Interfaces need to be simple and easy to learn. Business practicesmay often make use of hybrid approaches: in this case, it mayinvolve blending existing mobile network operations with small-scale Internet functionality. Simplicity of operation should meanlower manufacturing costs because the functionality needed inother markets may not be relevant here. Indeed different function-alities may become more relevant.

38 Whilst every operator and equipment manufacturer is looking for ways to lower costs, they do so from very different positions. Mobile operators are relativelylarge organizations and therefore their breakeven position will be higher than their smaller counterparts. Likewise traditional, developed world equipmentmanufacturers are large-scale entities and look for ways of gently migrating their customers downwards in terms of lower equipment costs: their businessmodel would have difficulty sustaining price cost drops of over 50%. Developing world equipment manufacturers (like Huawei of China and Omniacom ofTunisia) have no such inhibitions and offer cheaper options to the larger telephony organizations. However below this level there are also the small-scalecompanies than are building local and national solutions with IP network equipment that can be bought out of an online catalogue at much lower costs: theydo not need to buy “total solutions” as functionality can be increased as markets grow.

39 A discussion with an operator that is installing a CDMA-based network during the redrafting of this paper suggests that it is already possible to achieve theUS$50,000 figure already.

40 This is the basis of the operation of the small-scale, rural telecommunications operators in the USA, many of whom are members of the NationalTelecommunications Co-operative Association.

41 There are a number of different kinds of synergies that can be found when combining deployment of electrical power distribution networks and optical fibernetworks, whether underground or overhead (opgw or skywrap). The operation of the power network requires communication for control and measurementsand the fiber infrastructure will facilitate new ICT applications and broadband services attracting more customers and requiring equipment consuming powerthat will add to the sustainability of the power network.

42 C.K.Prahalad and Stuart Hart, The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid, Strategy + Business, Issue 26, 200243 The Wireless Revolution and Universal Access, Trends in Telecommunication Reform 2003, Michael L Best for the International Telecommunication Union, 200344 Whilst it would be tempting to introduce asymmetric charging to address the imbalance between rural and urban calling, it would introduce a somewhat

cumbersome level of price control that would be at odds with the wider thrust of reducing micro-management of the sector.45 See Isabel Neto study cited in A1.

This approach needs to be accompanied by a policythat provides as fewer barriers to entry as possible.44

Government needs to foster local SMEs in the sector,including financing. From the regulatory point ofview, licensing should be as cheap as possible (either atno-cost or a nominal charge) and might even makeextensive use of license-exempt radio bands.45

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 21

2.4 RURAL “PLUG AND PLAY” At the rural level, Open Access emphasizes theimportance of small-scale providers who can pro-vide cheaper services than traditional operatorsbecause their entry and operating costs are lower.In an Open Access environment, these “plug-and-play” operators have the potential to spread voiceand Internet use to places currently not covered,while at the same time encouraging significant eco-nomic activity in rural areas.

At present, a single base station connected to thenetwork might cost between US$125,000–$250,000to deliver. Recent approaches by one manufacturermay potentially reduce this cost to US$100,000.38

Work carried out for this study suggests that itmay be possible to lower this further to aroundUS$30–50,000.39 Operating costs would be keptto a minimum by offering almost exclusively pre-pay options to users and the operation would besimplified to allow non-technical users to run it.While this desire to lower business costs mightequally happen without an Open Access approach,there is not (in developing countries) a policyframework that provides incentives for this to hap-pen and allows its practical operation.

The local “plug-and-play” operator would have aninterconnection agreement with the traditionaloperators (mobile or PSTN) for calls that wererouted out into the wider network and equally, backinto the smaller, local network.40 Each would deriveincome and advantage from this arrangement. Thelarge-scale mobile operator would not have to re-engineer its business model to chase marginal mar-kets but would gain access to additional traffic. Thesmall-scale operator would gain income and derivestrength from being part of a wider network.

Providing electricity to power the network becomes amajor design factor. It would be essential to link theencouragement of communications and power supply.If the power utility is rolling out new power lines, theaddition of a few extra strands of fiber is a marginaladditional cost.41 A local power operator would beable to sell power to a local store, school, clinic andInternet café as well as provide telecommunications.

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 21

Reaching users at the bottom of the pyramid

C.K.Prahalad and Stuart Hart defined the different populations ofthe world in terms of income.42 They identified that 4 billionpeople or more live on annual incomes of less than US$1500. Inother words, somewhere between US$2–$4 per day. MichaelBest has calculated that communications micro-businesses in Indiacan sustain themselves on US$3-$5 per day.43 These may ormay not turn out to be the correct break-even point but the point iseloquently illustrated. For even double or triple that sum would fun-damentally change the parameters of the current business model.

To reach this group of people, Prahalad identifies a number offactors for success based upon existing companies (from smalllocal companies to multinationals) that already operate well inthese markets. All are interesting but a few are absolutely key forcommunications activities. Because the skills needed are not wide-ly available, it is important to simplify the activity. It should notrequire sophisticated technicians to implement or maintain.Interfaces need to be simple and easy to learn. Business practicesmay often make use of hybrid approaches: in this case, it mayinvolve blending existing mobile network operations with small-scale Internet functionality. Simplicity of operation should meanlower manufacturing costs because the functionality needed inother markets may not be relevant here. Indeed different function-alities may become more relevant.

38 Whilst every operator and equipment manufacturer is looking for ways to lower costs, they do so from very different positions. Mobile operators are relativelylarge organizations and therefore their breakeven position will be higher than their smaller counterparts. Likewise traditional, developed world equipmentmanufacturers are large-scale entities and look for ways of gently migrating their customers downwards in terms of lower equipment costs: their businessmodel would have difficulty sustaining price cost drops of over 50%. Developing world equipment manufacturers (like Huawei of China and Omniacom ofTunisia) have no such inhibitions and offer cheaper options to the larger telephony organizations. However below this level there are also the small-scalecompanies than are building local and national solutions with IP network equipment that can be bought out of an online catalogue at much lower costs: theydo not need to buy “total solutions” as functionality can be increased as markets grow.

39 A discussion with an operator that is installing a CDMA-based network during the redrafting of this paper suggests that it is already possible to achieve theUS$50,000 figure already.

40 This is the basis of the operation of the small-scale, rural telecommunications operators in the USA, many of whom are members of the NationalTelecommunications Co-operative Association.

41 There are a number of different kinds of synergies that can be found when combining deployment of electrical power distribution networks and optical fibernetworks, whether underground or overhead (opgw or skywrap). The operation of the power network requires communication for control and measurementsand the fiber infrastructure will facilitate new ICT applications and broadband services attracting more customers and requiring equipment consuming powerthat will add to the sustainability of the power network.

42 C.K.Prahalad and Stuart Hart, The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid, Strategy + Business, Issue 26, 200243 The Wireless Revolution and Universal Access, Trends in Telecommunication Reform 2003, Michael L Best for the International Telecommunication Union, 200344 Whilst it would be tempting to introduce asymmetric charging to address the imbalance between rural and urban calling, it would introduce a somewhat

cumbersome level of price control that would be at odds with the wider thrust of reducing micro-management of the sector.45 See Isabel Neto study cited in A1.

This approach needs to be accompanied by a policythat provides as fewer barriers to entry as possible.44

Government needs to foster local SMEs in the sector,including financing. From the regulatory point ofview, licensing should be as cheap as possible (either atno-cost or a nominal charge) and might even makeextensive use of license-exempt radio bands.45

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 21

22 . Open Access Models

These rural operators might emphasize voice provi-sion first but at the same time each might provideone or more access points for the Internet. Thevoice offers made by these operators would beaimed at satisfying three different kinds of marketneed: conversations with family and friends, locallyand nationally; making local commerce and socialdelivery more effective; and allowing those in theseareas to be contacted by friends and relatives in theDiaspora.

The operators of these organizations would reflectthe culture of the region in which they were locat-ed. In some parts of the world, there is a strongentrepreneurial tradition to draw upon. In others,there will be established forms of social enterpriselike cooperatives that can take on the task. Oftenit will be the women of the community who willbe empowered through doing this activity, provid-ing new income for their families and communi-ties. Although less visible than telecenters, there isa considerable amount of experience of this kindof provision already at a local level.

In broad terms, there are three different approachesto creating voice and data services at this level: afranchise model (similar to Grameen);46 a hybridapproach that combines existing mobile technologywith IP voice and data; or a completely distributedmodel that depends on raw IP connectivity.

The franchise model starts with the pragmaticassumption that access to voice is the service of mostimmediate interest to potential users but it can becombined with a central point for access to theInternet. A number of places in India have this kindof provision.

The franchise model relies on encouraging existingmobile operators to roll out a coverage “footprint”to cover an ever-wider range of users. They alsoneed to provide a simple franchise model thatworks well with relatively unskilled, rural people.In effect, the local operators – the franchisees – areselling handsets and call–time.

The next model is a hybrid mobile-IP connectivityoption. The local operator can offer Internet con-

nectivity to a small number of government andprivate sector clients. Users’ calls can go locally asVoIP traffic, while long distance calls can be con-verted to enter other networks. This option mightbe particularly suitable for small towns wherethere is sufficient population to create a user basein the high hundreds or low thousands.

Longer-term, it makes sense to build a model that iscompletely based upon traffic going over IP net-works.47 The system would support local VoIP callsover systems such as Wi-Fi and connect over an IPaccess base station to deliver them. It might be ableto extend 20–50 kilometers from networks run byexisting operators. Despite some drawbacks, this optionhas significant cost advantages worth considering.

2.5 INFRASTRUCTUREPROVIDERS AND MUNICIPALNETWORKSAt the national and city levels, Open Access empha-sizes the importance of building networks that canhelp provide cheaper, lower-cost access to all users,particularly to government facilities such as schoolsand hospitals, and user-access points in poor, peri-urban areas. However, the networks are built andwhoever operates them, the aim would be to con-nect an ever-widening base of users to the nationalinfrastructure at prices that can become sustainablefor all.

The key change would be for the historic operator toundergo a process of transformation that would allowit to emerge as the infrastructure provider.Depending on the history of the historic provider,this would be more or less difficult. The process willbe relatively straightforward for historic providers thatremain government-owned and set up operationallyseparate “business units” that are profit centers. But itwill be more difficult for historic operators that stillmerge operations and cross-subsidize parts. If the his-toric operator has already been sold off in part or inwhole, this may mean that the issue will have to betackled in policy and regulatory terms.

46 The term franchise is used in its commercial sense: the seller operates as branded agent who receives financing and support from the parent operator.47 Such a model is already being tested in one African country where the operator will offer IP payphones because it does not have a mobile license. The details

are commercially confidential.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 22

22 . Open Access Models

These rural operators might emphasize voice provi-sion first but at the same time each might provideone or more access points for the Internet. Thevoice offers made by these operators would beaimed at satisfying three different kinds of marketneed: conversations with family and friends, locallyand nationally; making local commerce and socialdelivery more effective; and allowing those in theseareas to be contacted by friends and relatives in theDiaspora.

The operators of these organizations would reflectthe culture of the region in which they were locat-ed. In some parts of the world, there is a strongentrepreneurial tradition to draw upon. In others,there will be established forms of social enterpriselike cooperatives that can take on the task. Oftenit will be the women of the community who willbe empowered through doing this activity, provid-ing new income for their families and communi-ties. Although less visible than telecenters, there isa considerable amount of experience of this kindof provision already at a local level.

In broad terms, there are three different approachesto creating voice and data services at this level: afranchise model (similar to Grameen);46 a hybridapproach that combines existing mobile technologywith IP voice and data; or a completely distributedmodel that depends on raw IP connectivity.

The franchise model starts with the pragmaticassumption that access to voice is the service of mostimmediate interest to potential users but it can becombined with a central point for access to theInternet. A number of places in India have this kindof provision.

The franchise model relies on encouraging existingmobile operators to roll out a coverage “footprint”to cover an ever-wider range of users. They alsoneed to provide a simple franchise model thatworks well with relatively unskilled, rural people.In effect, the local operators – the franchisees – areselling handsets and call–time.

The next model is a hybrid mobile-IP connectivityoption. The local operator can offer Internet con-

nectivity to a small number of government andprivate sector clients. Users’ calls can go locally asVoIP traffic, while long distance calls can be con-verted to enter other networks. This option mightbe particularly suitable for small towns wherethere is sufficient population to create a user basein the high hundreds or low thousands.

Longer-term, it makes sense to build a model that iscompletely based upon traffic going over IP net-works.47 The system would support local VoIP callsover systems such as Wi-Fi and connect over an IPaccess base station to deliver them. It might be ableto extend 20–50 kilometers from networks run byexisting operators. Despite some drawbacks, this optionhas significant cost advantages worth considering.

2.5 INFRASTRUCTUREPROVIDERS AND MUNICIPALNETWORKSAt the national and city levels, Open Access empha-sizes the importance of building networks that canhelp provide cheaper, lower-cost access to all users,particularly to government facilities such as schoolsand hospitals, and user-access points in poor, peri-urban areas. However, the networks are built andwhoever operates them, the aim would be to con-nect an ever-widening base of users to the nationalinfrastructure at prices that can become sustainablefor all.

The key change would be for the historic operator toundergo a process of transformation that would allowit to emerge as the infrastructure provider.Depending on the history of the historic provider,this would be more or less difficult. The process willbe relatively straightforward for historic providers thatremain government-owned and set up operationallyseparate “business units” that are profit centers. But itwill be more difficult for historic operators that stillmerge operations and cross-subsidize parts. If the his-toric operator has already been sold off in part or inwhole, this may mean that the issue will have to betackled in policy and regulatory terms.

46 The term franchise is used in its commercial sense: the seller operates as branded agent who receives financing and support from the parent operator.47 Such a model is already being tested in one African country where the operator will offer IP payphones because it does not have a mobile license. The details

are commercially confidential.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 22

Within this overall change, there would be a numberof different options: a single, trusted nationwideinfrastructure provider at all levels; trusted infrastruc-ture providers at two different levels (national anddistrict/municipal); and the encouragement of twocompeting infrastructure providers in every area, thealternative infrastructure provider using the assets ofthe utilities and railway organizations. The choicebetween these options is largely a function of scalebut also might include considerations of governance.

Existing mobile operators might choose to developtheir own trunk networks or simply use those providedby the new infrastructure provider.48 Also, if there aremore than two mobile operators, there would be goodcase for network sharing with new entrants underagreed terms as the market matures. This might lead tonew entrants focusing more on under-serviced areas orthe addition of MVNO competitors competing fornew customers in a price band not currently offered.In this way it would be possible to share costs withoutlosing overall business potential and in either case,there would be a higher level of competition on price,added services, and packages.

Infrastructure and services would over time be large-ly separated. In this circumstance, a country mighthave anything from 30 to several hundred serviceproviders. These would provide the following kindsof services: voice (mobile and fixed), data, Internetand content and consumer services. In each servicearea, competition would best be maximized by theexistence of 4–5 companies.49 The strong growth ofnational providers wholesaling services would in turnfeed into the further growth of privately run cyber-cafes and phone shops. The offerings made by theseservice providers would be aimed at every level ofthe millions of people currently using mobile voice.

The structural creation of an infrastructureprovider will not by itself lead to an effective mar-ket dynamic. There are historic trust issues thatneed to be dealt with. Service providers need toknow that they will get equal, non-discriminatoryaccess to the infrastructure, and the infrastructureoperator must have this cardinal principle put intoits founding constitution.

In addition, the governance structure for thesetypes of entities needs to include the key stake-holders at the board level: business users, con-sumers, and government. The board of the newentity would emphasize lowering the costs of usingthe infrastructure but also have to ensure that itcharges enough to maintain, replace and renew itsinfrastructure. On this basis, the new entity wouldnot be able to function effectively if it inheritedall or most of the staff of the historic operator. Ifthere was interest, it would be possible to take intothe structure a private operator who would alsoinvest in the infrastructure. Return would be basedon scale of shareholding relative to investment andother contributions to service and efficiency.

At a city level, municipal networks may offer auseful addition to infrastructure development.These may be appropriate in the two to threelargest cities in the larger country markets, butwill very much need to be driven by local politi-cal and private sector champions. Jigawa State inNigeria has already put in place a satellite networkfor the state government50 and others in a public-private partnership, and Kano has similar plans.In South Africa, both Tshwane and Johannesburghave plans to develop networks as and when itbecomes a legal possibility. At least one othersmaller municipality is considering setting up aWi-Fi network.

Although the subject of fierce policy discussions,municipal networks exist in a number of countries(France, Finland, Germany, Netherlands, Sweden,and the United States) and in certain circumstanceshave been quite effective in promoting the develop-ing of city or municipality-wide infrastructuregrowth (see Appendix A5). Countries with severaldense urban population centers will lend them-selves to the development of advanced municipalnetworks at a city level. However, the urban sprawland large rural areas of the United States (wherewireless is often used as a strong complement tofibre) may provide a better guide to successfulapproaches, for say the rural areas of Africa, thanthe more densely populated city conurbations ofEurope, Hong Kong, and Korea.

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 23

48 Existing mobile operators might be encouraged to build infrastructure capable of meeting wider needs through offering them tax concessions.49 Three companies or less can shadow each other’s pricing or form uncompetitive price groupings. 4–5 players offers the possibility of a greater degree of

price and service competition.50 Operated under a domestic data license.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 23

Within this overall change, there would be a numberof different options: a single, trusted nationwideinfrastructure provider at all levels; trusted infrastruc-ture providers at two different levels (national anddistrict/municipal); and the encouragement of twocompeting infrastructure providers in every area, thealternative infrastructure provider using the assets ofthe utilities and railway organizations. The choicebetween these options is largely a function of scalebut also might include considerations of governance.

Existing mobile operators might choose to developtheir own trunk networks or simply use those providedby the new infrastructure provider.48 Also, if there aremore than two mobile operators, there would be goodcase for network sharing with new entrants underagreed terms as the market matures. This might lead tonew entrants focusing more on under-serviced areas orthe addition of MVNO competitors competing fornew customers in a price band not currently offered.In this way it would be possible to share costs withoutlosing overall business potential and in either case,there would be a higher level of competition on price,added services, and packages.

Infrastructure and services would over time be large-ly separated. In this circumstance, a country mighthave anything from 30 to several hundred serviceproviders. These would provide the following kindsof services: voice (mobile and fixed), data, Internetand content and consumer services. In each servicearea, competition would best be maximized by theexistence of 4–5 companies.49 The strong growth ofnational providers wholesaling services would in turnfeed into the further growth of privately run cyber-cafes and phone shops. The offerings made by theseservice providers would be aimed at every level ofthe millions of people currently using mobile voice.

The structural creation of an infrastructureprovider will not by itself lead to an effective mar-ket dynamic. There are historic trust issues thatneed to be dealt with. Service providers need toknow that they will get equal, non-discriminatoryaccess to the infrastructure, and the infrastructureoperator must have this cardinal principle put intoits founding constitution.

In addition, the governance structure for thesetypes of entities needs to include the key stake-holders at the board level: business users, con-sumers, and government. The board of the newentity would emphasize lowering the costs of usingthe infrastructure but also have to ensure that itcharges enough to maintain, replace and renew itsinfrastructure. On this basis, the new entity wouldnot be able to function effectively if it inheritedall or most of the staff of the historic operator. Ifthere was interest, it would be possible to take intothe structure a private operator who would alsoinvest in the infrastructure. Return would be basedon scale of shareholding relative to investment andother contributions to service and efficiency.

At a city level, municipal networks may offer auseful addition to infrastructure development.These may be appropriate in the two to threelargest cities in the larger country markets, butwill very much need to be driven by local politi-cal and private sector champions. Jigawa State inNigeria has already put in place a satellite networkfor the state government50 and others in a public-private partnership, and Kano has similar plans.In South Africa, both Tshwane and Johannesburghave plans to develop networks as and when itbecomes a legal possibility. At least one othersmaller municipality is considering setting up aWi-Fi network.

Although the subject of fierce policy discussions,municipal networks exist in a number of countries(France, Finland, Germany, Netherlands, Sweden,and the United States) and in certain circumstanceshave been quite effective in promoting the develop-ing of city or municipality-wide infrastructuregrowth (see Appendix A5). Countries with severaldense urban population centers will lend them-selves to the development of advanced municipalnetworks at a city level. However, the urban sprawland large rural areas of the United States (wherewireless is often used as a strong complement tofibre) may provide a better guide to successfulapproaches, for say the rural areas of Africa, thanthe more densely populated city conurbations ofEurope, Hong Kong, and Korea.

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 23

48 Existing mobile operators might be encouraged to build infrastructure capable of meeting wider needs through offering them tax concessions.49 Three companies or less can shadow each other’s pricing or form uncompetitive price groupings. 4–5 players offers the possibility of a greater degree of

price and service competition.50 Operated under a domestic data license.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 23

24 . Open Access Models

2.6 KEEPING TRAFFICLOCAL AND REGIONAL TOSAVE MONEY – NATIONALAND REGIONAL INTERNETEXCHANGE POINTS (IXPs)AND INTER-COUNTRY LINKSThe Open Access approach emphasizes the impor-tance of effective traffic exchange at national andregional levels to save money (in order to give cheap-er access to users) and to encourage local servicedevelopments in the applications and content layers.

The local traffic flowing through national IXPs as aproportion of overall traffic varies from country tocountry. In broad terms, the more developed acountry’s economy, the cheaper and more availablethe connectivity, the greater the proportion of traf-fic that will remain at a local level. For example,most estimates of local traffic in South Africa goingvia the Johannesburg exchange (JINX) are around50 percent of total traffic. Whereas in Kenya, theproportion of local traffic is between 25–30 percent.But by contrast, just 10 percent of Internet trafficgenerated in Latin America has a destination inanother country within the region. In a competitiveenvironment, exchanging traffic at local levelshould be cheaper than doing it internationally andtherefore, it is not hard to see that substantial cost-savings can be made with national IXPs.

But IXPs also reduce the time needed to send andreceive data. With better access speeds, a range ofnew economic opportunities open up at the local level,including web browsing, streaming and e-commerce.There is likely to be a steady increase in the numberof local domain names and more importantly, locallyhosted sites. New services like video-conferencing,telemedicine and e-learning become possible.

The idea of keeping regional traffic within thecontinent will only be a practical reality if theprice of doing so is cheaper than sending it inter-nationally to achieve the same result. This has tobe the fundamental business case for achievingthis objective whatever other political considera-tions may apply.

For this to occur, there must be a number of com-petitive regional carriers whose role is both to

exchange traffic between countries and to aggregateinternational traffic that can then be peered withtheir equivalents on other continents. Regionallicensing templates under discussion in variousparts of the world provide one approach to thistask. Likewise, there is nothing to stop govern-ments and their regulators offering simple andcheap licenses to build bilateral links betweencountries if the services offered are on Open Accessprinciples. These licenses can then be bid for bywhoever has the money and expertise to build andrun them. A tender process of this kind wouldinclude the historic operators but would also beopen to anyone else with the right expertise andfinance.

Historic operators from two different countriesmight come together to bid. Alternatively a historicoperator might work with a private partner. Or theroute might simply go to a wholly private partner.Governments would stimulate the roll-out of theroutes they considered a priority and these wouldthen be “filled in” by creating a series of bilateral orsub-regional licenses by simply announcing a desireto see the routes built.

2.7 BRINGING DOWN THEPRICE OF INTERNATIONALCONNECTIVITYThe Open Access approach emphasizes the impor-tance of bringing the cost of international band-width down to cut the cost of communicating fordeveloping countries (particularly Sub-SaharanAfrica), help spread national infrastructure, and toencourage the growth of new global businesses suchas call centers and outsourcing.

The overall aim would be to provide more compet-itive rates for international bandwidth: for example,donors in Africa might set as an objective the desireto lower international rates by one-fifth to one-tenth.On the terrestrial stretches it would be possible toreserve a certain number of fibers for national use,thus pushing out the reach of individual countries’national infrastructure.

There is currently not enough private sector interest inbuilding international infrastructure. On the supply

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 24

24 . Open Access Models

2.6 KEEPING TRAFFICLOCAL AND REGIONAL TOSAVE MONEY – NATIONALAND REGIONAL INTERNETEXCHANGE POINTS (IXPs)AND INTER-COUNTRY LINKSThe Open Access approach emphasizes the impor-tance of effective traffic exchange at national andregional levels to save money (in order to give cheap-er access to users) and to encourage local servicedevelopments in the applications and content layers.

The local traffic flowing through national IXPs as aproportion of overall traffic varies from country tocountry. In broad terms, the more developed acountry’s economy, the cheaper and more availablethe connectivity, the greater the proportion of traf-fic that will remain at a local level. For example,most estimates of local traffic in South Africa goingvia the Johannesburg exchange (JINX) are around50 percent of total traffic. Whereas in Kenya, theproportion of local traffic is between 25–30 percent.But by contrast, just 10 percent of Internet trafficgenerated in Latin America has a destination inanother country within the region. In a competitiveenvironment, exchanging traffic at local levelshould be cheaper than doing it internationally andtherefore, it is not hard to see that substantial cost-savings can be made with national IXPs.

But IXPs also reduce the time needed to send andreceive data. With better access speeds, a range ofnew economic opportunities open up at the local level,including web browsing, streaming and e-commerce.There is likely to be a steady increase in the numberof local domain names and more importantly, locallyhosted sites. New services like video-conferencing,telemedicine and e-learning become possible.

The idea of keeping regional traffic within thecontinent will only be a practical reality if theprice of doing so is cheaper than sending it inter-nationally to achieve the same result. This has tobe the fundamental business case for achievingthis objective whatever other political considera-tions may apply.

For this to occur, there must be a number of com-petitive regional carriers whose role is both to

exchange traffic between countries and to aggregateinternational traffic that can then be peered withtheir equivalents on other continents. Regionallicensing templates under discussion in variousparts of the world provide one approach to thistask. Likewise, there is nothing to stop govern-ments and their regulators offering simple andcheap licenses to build bilateral links betweencountries if the services offered are on Open Accessprinciples. These licenses can then be bid for bywhoever has the money and expertise to build andrun them. A tender process of this kind wouldinclude the historic operators but would also beopen to anyone else with the right expertise andfinance.

Historic operators from two different countriesmight come together to bid. Alternatively a historicoperator might work with a private partner. Or theroute might simply go to a wholly private partner.Governments would stimulate the roll-out of theroutes they considered a priority and these wouldthen be “filled in” by creating a series of bilateral orsub-regional licenses by simply announcing a desireto see the routes built.

2.7 BRINGING DOWN THEPRICE OF INTERNATIONALCONNECTIVITYThe Open Access approach emphasizes the impor-tance of bringing the cost of international band-width down to cut the cost of communicating fordeveloping countries (particularly Sub-SaharanAfrica), help spread national infrastructure, and toencourage the growth of new global businesses suchas call centers and outsourcing.

The overall aim would be to provide more compet-itive rates for international bandwidth: for example,donors in Africa might set as an objective the desireto lower international rates by one-fifth to one-tenth.On the terrestrial stretches it would be possible toreserve a certain number of fibers for national use,thus pushing out the reach of individual countries’national infrastructure.

There is currently not enough private sector interest inbuilding international infrastructure. On the supply

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 24

side, there has to be an increase in the amount of traf-fic brought about by lowering prices. On the demandside, there have to be improvements in national infra-structure that will connect users more effectively atregional and international levels. To break out of the“chicken-and-egg” situation described in section one,there may need to be an injection of public (donor)funds to create an international infrastructure thatwill bring prices down to European levels. This willencourage what is already happening elsewhere:high-volume, low-margin traffic growth rather thanthe reverse.

The traditional route for financing internationalfiber cables – club consortia – do not have eithertradable shares or bandwidth. Because they operateat an international level, it is much harder to developrules of trade that operate elsewhere. For instance, inAfrica there is no equivalent to the EuropeanCommission to deal with international entities.Competition law at a national level is currently onlya viable recourse in a limited number of countries,including Namibia, South Africa, and Zambia.51

The challenge is to create structures that maximizeprivate investment, while acknowledging risk andthat allow open access to all on a fair and equalbasis. How infrastructure is delivered will varyaccording to the traffic and circumstances of differ-ent continents. For example, while fiber in Africa isundoubtedly a cheaper method of delivering high-volume traffic, satellite and microwave will continueto play a significant role in reaching geographicallydistributed populations.

For international infrastructure, there are three broadoptions: a special purpose company (for projects notyet developed); a hybrid company (for projectsalready seeking finance); and more ambitious, conti-nent-wide entity to bring together disparate infra-structure projects. Each addresses different require-ments and can be nuanced in a number of ways.

For projects that have yet to start, the special pur-pose company would make it possible to follow theprecedents set by the oil and gas industries whenbuilding pipelines. A special purpose company

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 25

Africa: The challenge of financing international bandwidth

Because there is significant bandwidth demand both with in Africa and internationally52, there are now a number of major infrastructureprojects designed to meet this growth. These include an African satellite consortium called RASCOM and a number of different fiber proj-ects to connect East and Central Africa including EASSy, Comtel53 and Com-7. With the exception of COM-7 which involves regionalpower companies, these projects are almost entirely supported by the historic operators.

But this time there is a key difference to how SAT3 was financed. Many of the incumbent telephone companies participating in EASSy54

and Comtel may require direct donor funding so they can meet their financial contribution to the project. If external donor funding sup-ports a closed Club Consortium structure, it will be financing infrastructure in a way that does not necessarily accelerate the lowering ofbandwidth costs or encourage the growth of new opportunities.

Most of the projects identified will require some element of donor funding if they are to be implemented. However the total cost of all theprojects may well exceed the resources the donor community can make available. Most of the historic operators requiring money to getinvolved in infrastructure have not been privatized. Because of their financial situation and a lack of adherence to international accountingstandards, they are not an attractive proposition for commercial finance. By contrast, publicly traded historic operators such as Sonateland Telkom South Africa have been successful in raising project capital. Even if one or more gets commercial investment, the financingissue will remain for the creation of the backhaul links between different countries.

As a result, private finance opportunities are available but are not maximized. This is particularly true of soft-loan finance and local stockexchanges. There have been a number of market placings and the sums raised have been substantial. Furthermore, potential alternativeinfrastructure providers such as power and railway companies have in most instances been excluded from seriously participating in thisprocess of developing new infrastructure at both regional and international levels.

A number of these projects have substantial areas of overlap. To address this problem, the New Partnership for Africa’s Development’s (NEPAD’s)e-Africa Commission called a meeting in July 2004. Out of this and subsequent smaller meetings came a network map that NEPAD feels repre-sents the network that it would like to see built. This network seeks to create at least two connections for each country in Sub-Saharan Africa toother countries but also a similar choice for connecting the continent to the rest of the world. This level of choice is essential for all operators inthe region. It is also adopting the same approach in West Africa. A meeting will be held in July 2005 to try and agree to a network map.

51 Botwana has plans to introduce competition legislation52 See Forecasts cited in A1.53 Comtel looks less likely as in mid 2005 Ericsson decided not to be one of the main private sector investors. http://www.balancingact-

africa.com/news/back/balancing-act_262.html54 At the time this paper was completed, early indications were that EASSy would get its financing completely from private sources. They have been able to

achieve this through the involvement of a number of private sector companies.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 25

side, there has to be an increase in the amount of traf-fic brought about by lowering prices. On the demandside, there have to be improvements in national infra-structure that will connect users more effectively atregional and international levels. To break out of the“chicken-and-egg” situation described in section one,there may need to be an injection of public (donor)funds to create an international infrastructure thatwill bring prices down to European levels. This willencourage what is already happening elsewhere:high-volume, low-margin traffic growth rather thanthe reverse.

The traditional route for financing internationalfiber cables – club consortia – do not have eithertradable shares or bandwidth. Because they operateat an international level, it is much harder to developrules of trade that operate elsewhere. For instance, inAfrica there is no equivalent to the EuropeanCommission to deal with international entities.Competition law at a national level is currently onlya viable recourse in a limited number of countries,including Namibia, South Africa, and Zambia.51

The challenge is to create structures that maximizeprivate investment, while acknowledging risk andthat allow open access to all on a fair and equalbasis. How infrastructure is delivered will varyaccording to the traffic and circumstances of differ-ent continents. For example, while fiber in Africa isundoubtedly a cheaper method of delivering high-volume traffic, satellite and microwave will continueto play a significant role in reaching geographicallydistributed populations.

For international infrastructure, there are three broadoptions: a special purpose company (for projects notyet developed); a hybrid company (for projectsalready seeking finance); and more ambitious, conti-nent-wide entity to bring together disparate infra-structure projects. Each addresses different require-ments and can be nuanced in a number of ways.

For projects that have yet to start, the special pur-pose company would make it possible to follow theprecedents set by the oil and gas industries whenbuilding pipelines. A special purpose company

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 25

Africa: The challenge of financing international bandwidth

Because there is significant bandwidth demand both with in Africa and internationally52, there are now a number of major infrastructureprojects designed to meet this growth. These include an African satellite consortium called RASCOM and a number of different fiber proj-ects to connect East and Central Africa including EASSy, Comtel53 and Com-7. With the exception of COM-7 which involves regionalpower companies, these projects are almost entirely supported by the historic operators.

But this time there is a key difference to how SAT3 was financed. Many of the incumbent telephone companies participating in EASSy54

and Comtel may require direct donor funding so they can meet their financial contribution to the project. If external donor funding sup-ports a closed Club Consortium structure, it will be financing infrastructure in a way that does not necessarily accelerate the lowering ofbandwidth costs or encourage the growth of new opportunities.

Most of the projects identified will require some element of donor funding if they are to be implemented. However the total cost of all theprojects may well exceed the resources the donor community can make available. Most of the historic operators requiring money to getinvolved in infrastructure have not been privatized. Because of their financial situation and a lack of adherence to international accountingstandards, they are not an attractive proposition for commercial finance. By contrast, publicly traded historic operators such as Sonateland Telkom South Africa have been successful in raising project capital. Even if one or more gets commercial investment, the financingissue will remain for the creation of the backhaul links between different countries.

As a result, private finance opportunities are available but are not maximized. This is particularly true of soft-loan finance and local stockexchanges. There have been a number of market placings and the sums raised have been substantial. Furthermore, potential alternativeinfrastructure providers such as power and railway companies have in most instances been excluded from seriously participating in thisprocess of developing new infrastructure at both regional and international levels.

A number of these projects have substantial areas of overlap. To address this problem, the New Partnership for Africa’s Development’s (NEPAD’s)e-Africa Commission called a meeting in July 2004. Out of this and subsequent smaller meetings came a network map that NEPAD feels repre-sents the network that it would like to see built. This network seeks to create at least two connections for each country in Sub-Saharan Africa toother countries but also a similar choice for connecting the continent to the rest of the world. This level of choice is essential for all operators inthe region. It is also adopting the same approach in West Africa. A meeting will be held in July 2005 to try and agree to a network map.

51 Botwana has plans to introduce competition legislation52 See Forecasts cited in A1.53 Comtel looks less likely as in mid 2005 Ericsson decided not to be one of the main private sector investors. http://www.balancingact-

africa.com/news/back/balancing-act_262.html54 At the time this paper was completed, early indications were that EASSy would get its financing completely from private sources. They have been able to

achieve this through the involvement of a number of private sector companies.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 25

26 . Open Access Models

would be created that might issue shares but couldalso receive debt securities. The main purpose ofthe special purpose company would not be for it tomake a profit but to facilitate profits to be madeelsewhere by the participating companies. As withthe club consortia, there should be a managingagent and as with that structure there is a potentialof a conflict of interest: within reason, the partnerinvestors want to keep managing agent fees as lowas possible whereas the managing agent wants toincrease them. This would be covered by a trans-parent payment and a contract that would be per-formance-related and have an incentive frameworkthat maximized both traffic and income.

The contributors would enter into a multi-partycontract that defined the following:■ Contributions from the participating investors.■ A pricing framework designed to cover costs,

and a reasonable return (as defined in the con-tract but in the light of the fact that the companyis not designed to be a profit-generator).

■ Access to the capacity by others on non-discrim-inatory terms, taking initial investment and riskinto account.

For existing projects, a hybrid company might beset up. Those able to raise a proportion of a fiberproject privately would create an entity that wouldhave two owners: the commercial investors and thedonor investment. The latter company wouldinvest in an international fiber project on the basisthat its fiber capacity was open to all and that itscapacity would be offered at successively lowerprices for a period of time to encourage downwardprice movement in prices.

The hybrid company would offer to finance theportion of the project that cannot get fundingthrough the market. To make the period in whichthe prices were held down more acceptable to thosefunding their investment through the market, theOpen Fiber Access company might take a largerpercentage of the overall risk (possibly 75–80 percentof the overall risk). In effect, a hybrid financingsolution would be created in which those capableof finding market funding could set up a club con-sortium that would invest alongside the donorfunded company.

The final option would be to set up an overallholding company that would act as the custodian

for all the infrastructure projects. In this way, allthe disparate infrastructure projects could be used,if not brought together into a single network. Thepurpose of such a structure would be to overcomethe kinds of licensing and charging difficulties thatterrestrial projects (like Comtel in Africa) haveencountered.

The key stakeholders for Board representation foreach of these different options would be a mix ofthe following (depending on particular circum-stances): service operators, infrastructure operators,mobile phone companies, and large corporate cus-tomers like banks and multinationals.

2.8 IMPLICATIONS FORPOLICYMAKERS AND REGULATORSThe approach suggested above has the followingimplications for policymakers and regulators:■ There has been an understandable need to

respond to issues raised by consumers andindustry, often focusing solely around issues ofprice. With any new approach it will be impor-tant to identify what the bottlenecks andrestrictions are within the sector itself: what ispreventing the development of the market?Who is withholding access for new players?Each of these bottlenecks can be addressedthrough either competition or regulatory mech-anisms. Where competition legislation does notexist, it is important to put it in place toaddress issues of significant market power thatexisting regulatory frameworks may not be ableto deal with.

■ Current regulation is created around a num-ber of structural frameworks that are oftentechnologically defined. The three-layer IPnetwork definition – the physical infrastruc-ture, transmission, and services – offers a newframework. It allows regulators to make aclear assessment of who holds market powerin a world of converging technologies and willreflect the underlying reality of the new IPnetwork paradigm.

■ There must be a successful separation of servicesand infrastructure to create greater clarity aboutmarket pricing and access to infrastructure. Theprinciple of open access to infrastructure for all

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 26

26 . Open Access Models

would be created that might issue shares but couldalso receive debt securities. The main purpose ofthe special purpose company would not be for it tomake a profit but to facilitate profits to be madeelsewhere by the participating companies. As withthe club consortia, there should be a managingagent and as with that structure there is a potentialof a conflict of interest: within reason, the partnerinvestors want to keep managing agent fees as lowas possible whereas the managing agent wants toincrease them. This would be covered by a trans-parent payment and a contract that would be per-formance-related and have an incentive frameworkthat maximized both traffic and income.

The contributors would enter into a multi-partycontract that defined the following:■ Contributions from the participating investors.■ A pricing framework designed to cover costs,

and a reasonable return (as defined in the con-tract but in the light of the fact that the companyis not designed to be a profit-generator).

■ Access to the capacity by others on non-discrim-inatory terms, taking initial investment and riskinto account.

For existing projects, a hybrid company might beset up. Those able to raise a proportion of a fiberproject privately would create an entity that wouldhave two owners: the commercial investors and thedonor investment. The latter company wouldinvest in an international fiber project on the basisthat its fiber capacity was open to all and that itscapacity would be offered at successively lowerprices for a period of time to encourage downwardprice movement in prices.

The hybrid company would offer to finance theportion of the project that cannot get fundingthrough the market. To make the period in whichthe prices were held down more acceptable to thosefunding their investment through the market, theOpen Fiber Access company might take a largerpercentage of the overall risk (possibly 75–80 percentof the overall risk). In effect, a hybrid financingsolution would be created in which those capableof finding market funding could set up a club con-sortium that would invest alongside the donorfunded company.

The final option would be to set up an overallholding company that would act as the custodian

for all the infrastructure projects. In this way, allthe disparate infrastructure projects could be used,if not brought together into a single network. Thepurpose of such a structure would be to overcomethe kinds of licensing and charging difficulties thatterrestrial projects (like Comtel in Africa) haveencountered.

The key stakeholders for Board representation foreach of these different options would be a mix ofthe following (depending on particular circum-stances): service operators, infrastructure operators,mobile phone companies, and large corporate cus-tomers like banks and multinationals.

2.8 IMPLICATIONS FORPOLICYMAKERS AND REGULATORSThe approach suggested above has the followingimplications for policymakers and regulators:■ There has been an understandable need to

respond to issues raised by consumers andindustry, often focusing solely around issues ofprice. With any new approach it will be impor-tant to identify what the bottlenecks andrestrictions are within the sector itself: what ispreventing the development of the market?Who is withholding access for new players?Each of these bottlenecks can be addressedthrough either competition or regulatory mech-anisms. Where competition legislation does notexist, it is important to put it in place toaddress issues of significant market power thatexisting regulatory frameworks may not be ableto deal with.

■ Current regulation is created around a num-ber of structural frameworks that are oftentechnologically defined. The three-layer IPnetwork definition – the physical infrastruc-ture, transmission, and services – offers a newframework. It allows regulators to make aclear assessment of who holds market powerin a world of converging technologies and willreflect the underlying reality of the new IPnetwork paradigm.

■ There must be a successful separation of servicesand infrastructure to create greater clarity aboutmarket pricing and access to infrastructure. Theprinciple of open access to infrastructure for all

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 26

DIAGRAM 2: Place for donor sup-port in different layers and areas

players is a central part of this change.Regulators need to ensure that larger entitiesoperate services and infrastructure at “arms-length” from each to ensure equity and trans-parency in the market.

■ Policymakers and regulators as the referees of dif-ferent interests have a key role to play in creatingtrust in the marketplace. In practical terms, theOpen Access approach suggested frequently needsthe setting up of bodies that represent both thepublic interest and the industry. It is important toensure that these kinds of bodies contain a widerange of qualified representatives at board level,particularly the newer parts of the industry (theISPs) and consumers. Policymakers and regulatorsmust deal fairly with the tensions created by theexistence of dominant players in the market.

Donors will probably contribute most by loweringthe structural thresholds for local and nationalprovider of services, not by involving themselves inlarge numbers of local players. Local players havethe least expertise and influence in infrastructureissues, where sharing of facilities is most needed.Any donor support of infrastructure, in particularfor the large international projects (but also forcross-border and other national backbones) mustbe conditional on Open Access principles, withnon-discriminatory access for anyone in differentlayers.

Donors should refrain from supporting any marketactivity at the service level since this would just distortthe development of markets. If infrastructure is madeavailable cheaply, donors should support end-usersand local demand. Equally, they must abandon theidea of supporting any separate, dedicated networksbeing set up for “anchor” customers like schools,health care facilities, and government administrationdepartments. This just undermines the futurefunctioning of the market in the higher levels ofthe network model.

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 27

The potential of Open Access in Sub-Saharan Africa

An Open Access approach has the potential to allow:

■ Governments to focus on infrastructure needs in ways thatdo not simply entrench the historic operator or other domi-nant players. A few countries have already realized it is pos-sible to bring together a range of state assets (includingthose outside of the historic operator) in the service of thistask. Open Access suggests ways of creating new modelsthrough which this might occur.

■ Faster market development through the creation of higher lev-els of trust and cooperation among competing players. Inparticular, it seeks to end the sterile arguments about whatthe historic operator should or should not do and its capacityto put a brake on speedier development of the market.

■ Strong local champions to play a role in infrastructure develop-ment at the city and district level, in ways that will encouragelocal African governments to think about what makes its differ-ent cities and towns competitive in a modern information era.

■ An emphasis on business models that will address low-incomeusers in rural areas. It will bring together existing entrepreneur-ial energy, new local investment and the creation of employ-ment where countries need it most, in the rural areas.

■ A means of maximizing public and private finance in infrastruc-ture without public involvement forcing out much-needed com-mercial financing. It offers new models for investment ininfrastructure, particularly in international infrastructure. In thisway, it will create cheap, widely available bandwidth to deliveron a wide range of development objectives.

InternationalNationalLocal

Physical layer,passiveinfrastructure

Transport layer,transmissionelectronics

Services

End-user demand

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 27

DIAGRAM 2: Place for donor sup-port in different layers and areas

players is a central part of this change.Regulators need to ensure that larger entitiesoperate services and infrastructure at “arms-length” from each to ensure equity and trans-parency in the market.

■ Policymakers and regulators as the referees of dif-ferent interests have a key role to play in creatingtrust in the marketplace. In practical terms, theOpen Access approach suggested frequently needsthe setting up of bodies that represent both thepublic interest and the industry. It is important toensure that these kinds of bodies contain a widerange of qualified representatives at board level,particularly the newer parts of the industry (theISPs) and consumers. Policymakers and regulatorsmust deal fairly with the tensions created by theexistence of dominant players in the market.

Donors will probably contribute most by loweringthe structural thresholds for local and nationalprovider of services, not by involving themselves inlarge numbers of local players. Local players havethe least expertise and influence in infrastructureissues, where sharing of facilities is most needed.Any donor support of infrastructure, in particularfor the large international projects (but also forcross-border and other national backbones) mustbe conditional on Open Access principles, withnon-discriminatory access for anyone in differentlayers.

Donors should refrain from supporting any marketactivity at the service level since this would just distortthe development of markets. If infrastructure is madeavailable cheaply, donors should support end-usersand local demand. Equally, they must abandon theidea of supporting any separate, dedicated networksbeing set up for “anchor” customers like schools,health care facilities, and government administrationdepartments. This just undermines the futurefunctioning of the market in the higher levels ofthe network model.

Unlocking Wider Access to ICT . 27

The potential of Open Access in Sub-Saharan Africa

An Open Access approach has the potential to allow:

■ Governments to focus on infrastructure needs in ways thatdo not simply entrench the historic operator or other domi-nant players. A few countries have already realized it is pos-sible to bring together a range of state assets (includingthose outside of the historic operator) in the service of thistask. Open Access suggests ways of creating new modelsthrough which this might occur.

■ Faster market development through the creation of higher lev-els of trust and cooperation among competing players. Inparticular, it seeks to end the sterile arguments about whatthe historic operator should or should not do and its capacityto put a brake on speedier development of the market.

■ Strong local champions to play a role in infrastructure develop-ment at the city and district level, in ways that will encouragelocal African governments to think about what makes its differ-ent cities and towns competitive in a modern information era.

■ An emphasis on business models that will address low-incomeusers in rural areas. It will bring together existing entrepreneur-ial energy, new local investment and the creation of employ-ment where countries need it most, in the rural areas.

■ A means of maximizing public and private finance in infrastruc-ture without public involvement forcing out much-needed com-mercial financing. It offers new models for investment ininfrastructure, particularly in international infrastructure. In thisway, it will create cheap, widely available bandwidth to deliveron a wide range of development objectives.

InternationalNationalLocal

Physical layer,passiveinfrastructure

Transport layer,transmissionelectronics

Services

End-user demand

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 27

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 28 Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 28

Taking Advantage of the Opportunity . 29

3. TAKINGADVANTAGE OFTHE OPPORTUNITY

3.1 GOVERNMENT POLICYMAKERS AND REGULATORSWith an Open Access approach, government – at anational or local level – represents the public inter-est, particularly for the growth of the economy anda social responsibility for the less well-off. It needsto act as a fair referee on competition issues andcreate a level playing field for providers. It alsoensures that the interests of the users of the infra-structure (both consumers and service companies)are well represented in any governance mechanism.

In this new light touch role government (and theautonomous regulators that implement its policies)have several key roles: to lower the barriers tomarket entry by removing as many unnecessaryregulatory barriers as possible; to create a favor-able business environment that offers investorsenough certainty to develop their businesses andget a fair chance at a reasonable rate of return;and where necessary, to provide short-term “seed-funding” to encourage the risk-taking needed toexpand the market.

The main purpose of this seed-funding would be tostimulate initial demand from public sector “anchor”customers, such as schools, health care facilities, andadministrative departments on the basis of a sustain-able, low recurrent cost infrastructure. This approachdiffers considerably from previous government expec-tations of telecoms licensing as a “cash cow.”

If large-scale private sector companies will not or can-not provide service, government must offer thisopportunity to local small – or medium-sized organi-zations in a supportive way to create the conditionsfor Open Access. Faced with this competitive alterna-tive, the large-scale private sector company maydecide to provide service to that area. If so, the gov-ernment is then free to move on to focusing on

another under-serviced area. In this sense, OpenAccess is both a strategic and tactical mechanism.

The government must be willing to underwrite theshort-term risks involved in this “market-stretching”for either new entities or existing large-scale opera-tors on an equal basis. There may also be parallels inthe field of power provision where the same process-es might be used to provide incentives to powerroll-outs and investment. Indeed, it might be possi-ble to bundle together incentives for both.

3.2 INTERNATIONALDONORSFinancing Open Access calls for new ways ofapproaching the task. In the developing country con-text, the market will not necessarily by itself delivercheap, widely accessible communications to all.

For donors, it is likely to be support for increasingdemand where their funding may be relevant. Oncethey see that private sector funding has been maxi-mized, they might get involved to provide part ofthis seed-funding. At a national level, they mightunderwrite activities that widen market entry andinvest locally. Or at an international level, theymight underwrite medium – to long-term risk onlarge-scale projects like infrastructure.

At the national level, donor money may be neededto assist with the transition from the current his-toric operator to the proposed infrastructureprovider. This might simply be used to help clarifya strategic approach or be used for the purpose ofmore fundamental restructuring.

At the city level, municipal fiber network might befunded by private investment that simply connect-ed business and high-income districts. If there was a“market-stretch” case for extending to a wider rangeof businesses and SMEs, this might be funded bythe developing world version of a municipal bond.There are several sources of soft finance includingthe U.K. Department for InternationalDevelopment (DfID) and the Development Bankof South Africa that have loan schemes that wouldfit this category. A bonus included as part of thescheme might be a social dividend clause that wouldallow a percentage of the fiber to be accessible at

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 29

Taking Advantage of the Opportunity . 29

3. TAKINGADVANTAGE OFTHE OPPORTUNITY

3.1 GOVERNMENT POLICYMAKERS AND REGULATORSWith an Open Access approach, government – at anational or local level – represents the public inter-est, particularly for the growth of the economy anda social responsibility for the less well-off. It needsto act as a fair referee on competition issues andcreate a level playing field for providers. It alsoensures that the interests of the users of the infra-structure (both consumers and service companies)are well represented in any governance mechanism.

In this new light touch role government (and theautonomous regulators that implement its policies)have several key roles: to lower the barriers tomarket entry by removing as many unnecessaryregulatory barriers as possible; to create a favor-able business environment that offers investorsenough certainty to develop their businesses andget a fair chance at a reasonable rate of return;and where necessary, to provide short-term “seed-funding” to encourage the risk-taking needed toexpand the market.

The main purpose of this seed-funding would be tostimulate initial demand from public sector “anchor”customers, such as schools, health care facilities, andadministrative departments on the basis of a sustain-able, low recurrent cost infrastructure. This approachdiffers considerably from previous government expec-tations of telecoms licensing as a “cash cow.”

If large-scale private sector companies will not or can-not provide service, government must offer thisopportunity to local small – or medium-sized organi-zations in a supportive way to create the conditionsfor Open Access. Faced with this competitive alterna-tive, the large-scale private sector company maydecide to provide service to that area. If so, the gov-ernment is then free to move on to focusing on

another under-serviced area. In this sense, OpenAccess is both a strategic and tactical mechanism.

The government must be willing to underwrite theshort-term risks involved in this “market-stretching”for either new entities or existing large-scale opera-tors on an equal basis. There may also be parallels inthe field of power provision where the same process-es might be used to provide incentives to powerroll-outs and investment. Indeed, it might be possi-ble to bundle together incentives for both.

3.2 INTERNATIONALDONORSFinancing Open Access calls for new ways ofapproaching the task. In the developing country con-text, the market will not necessarily by itself delivercheap, widely accessible communications to all.

For donors, it is likely to be support for increasingdemand where their funding may be relevant. Oncethey see that private sector funding has been maxi-mized, they might get involved to provide part ofthis seed-funding. At a national level, they mightunderwrite activities that widen market entry andinvest locally. Or at an international level, theymight underwrite medium – to long-term risk onlarge-scale projects like infrastructure.

At the national level, donor money may be neededto assist with the transition from the current his-toric operator to the proposed infrastructureprovider. This might simply be used to help clarifya strategic approach or be used for the purpose ofmore fundamental restructuring.

At the city level, municipal fiber network might befunded by private investment that simply connect-ed business and high-income districts. If there was a“market-stretch” case for extending to a wider rangeof businesses and SMEs, this might be funded bythe developing world version of a municipal bond.There are several sources of soft finance includingthe U.K. Department for InternationalDevelopment (DfID) and the Development Bankof South Africa that have loan schemes that wouldfit this category. A bonus included as part of thescheme might be a social dividend clause that wouldallow a percentage of the fiber to be accessible at

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 29

30 . Open Access Models

mechanisms in particular: the role of municipalnetworks, open access and regulatory approaches,and the business model for rural micro-operators.This might be done at the national or interna-tional level in response to demand.

■ At the local level, it will be necessary to createincentives for the development of local networkequipment that will lower business entry costs.The most likely developers of these products areIP equipment vendors who are used to workingwith small-scale IP local area networks (LAN),open source and transmission control protocol(TCP)/IP. Whatever is created has to be openand well defined, which may make proprietaryvendors less likely to be the driving force.Donors or others may need to seed a competi-tion or incentive scheme to encourage thesedevelopments.

3.3 THE PRIVATE SECTORThe private sector might be expected to do what itdoes best: innovate in ways that will help reducethe cost to users (and thereby increase its own prof-its); emphasize the widest use possible of differentforms of communications and make investments(from local and national sources) where marketopportunities exist. In exchange, it has the right toexpect that government will create the kind of con-ditions described in 3.1 on the previous page.

At national, regional, and international levels, theprivate sector remains the investor of choice. It isimportant that donor money does not displaceinvestment from the private sector but that the twoare used differently to maximize overall investmentin the sector. When the market risk is too great,new relationships with this division of responsibili-ties between governments and donors can create“market-stretch” funding that will speed up thepace of infrastructure development.

cost for hospitals, health clinics, universities andschools, providing a driver for them as customers ofadvanced services.

At the regional level for inter-country connections,private funding will be used, either in the form ofbank loan or local equity. There will be a number ofroutes that do not attract commercial interestbecause the markets are too small and/or the politi-cal risks are too high. On these routes where com-mercial operators do not come forward, govern-ments can then work with both soft loan institutionsand donors to provide anything from 25 percent ofsoft loan funding to 100 percent donor payment ona given route. This process would be somewhat akinto the “reverse auctions” pioneered in the field ofuniversal access in various developing countries.

At an international level, a number of differentmethods of structuring financial support aredescribed in 2.7.

Support at all these different levels needs to emphasizethe importance of the projects adhering to an OpenAccess approach with fair and transparent access beingprovided to all users. Overall, donors need to supportboth open, cheap backbones (supply) and userdemand locally.

There are three ways in which the internationalcommunity might play a role in furthering thepractical development of these ideas:

■ The changes that have created the potential forOpen Access are relatively recent. Therefore,there is a need for an awareness-raising processamong policymakers and regulators to helpthem understand what is happening in order toaddress its implications in ways that reflect therealities of their national situation.

■ In order to generate impetus for the Open Accessapproach, it would be helpful to look at ways ofprototyping the business models and financial

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 30

30 . Open Access Models

mechanisms in particular: the role of municipalnetworks, open access and regulatory approaches,and the business model for rural micro-operators.This might be done at the national or interna-tional level in response to demand.

■ At the local level, it will be necessary to createincentives for the development of local networkequipment that will lower business entry costs.The most likely developers of these products areIP equipment vendors who are used to workingwith small-scale IP local area networks (LAN),open source and transmission control protocol(TCP)/IP. Whatever is created has to be openand well defined, which may make proprietaryvendors less likely to be the driving force.Donors or others may need to seed a competi-tion or incentive scheme to encourage thesedevelopments.

3.3 THE PRIVATE SECTORThe private sector might be expected to do what itdoes best: innovate in ways that will help reducethe cost to users (and thereby increase its own prof-its); emphasize the widest use possible of differentforms of communications and make investments(from local and national sources) where marketopportunities exist. In exchange, it has the right toexpect that government will create the kind of con-ditions described in 3.1 on the previous page.

At national, regional, and international levels, theprivate sector remains the investor of choice. It isimportant that donor money does not displaceinvestment from the private sector but that the twoare used differently to maximize overall investmentin the sector. When the market risk is too great,new relationships with this division of responsibili-ties between governments and donors can create“market-stretch” funding that will speed up thepace of infrastructure development.

cost for hospitals, health clinics, universities andschools, providing a driver for them as customers ofadvanced services.

At the regional level for inter-country connections,private funding will be used, either in the form ofbank loan or local equity. There will be a number ofroutes that do not attract commercial interestbecause the markets are too small and/or the politi-cal risks are too high. On these routes where com-mercial operators do not come forward, govern-ments can then work with both soft loan institutionsand donors to provide anything from 25 percent ofsoft loan funding to 100 percent donor payment ona given route. This process would be somewhat akinto the “reverse auctions” pioneered in the field ofuniversal access in various developing countries.

At an international level, a number of differentmethods of structuring financial support aredescribed in 2.7.

Support at all these different levels needs to emphasizethe importance of the projects adhering to an OpenAccess approach with fair and transparent access beingprovided to all users. Overall, donors need to supportboth open, cheap backbones (supply) and userdemand locally.

There are three ways in which the internationalcommunity might play a role in furthering thepractical development of these ideas:

■ The changes that have created the potential forOpen Access are relatively recent. Therefore,there is a need for an awareness-raising processamong policymakers and regulators to helpthem understand what is happening in order toaddress its implications in ways that reflect therealities of their national situation.

■ In order to generate impetus for the Open Accessapproach, it would be helpful to look at ways ofprototyping the business models and financial

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 30

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 31 Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 31

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 32 Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 32

Appendices . 33

4. APPENDICES

APPENDIX A1:BACKGROUND READINGAfrica: The Impact of Mobile Phones, VodafonePolicy Paper Series No 2, March 2005

African ICT infrastructure investment options,Balancing Act for DFID, 2004

Balancing Act Voice and Data Bandwidth Forecasts(2005-2008), Paul Hamilton and RussellSouthwood, May 2005

Contact Centres and Business Process Outsourcingin Cape Town – Indicators 2004, Deloitte forCalling the Cape, 2004

Cross-Border Connectivity Initiative in theECOWAS Region, Spintrack for ECOWAS and theWorld Bank, July 2004

E-Usage Survey, The Link Centre, University ofWitwatersrand, Forthcoming

The EU Regulatory Perspective on VoIP – ASubstantial Change to the Landscape, a presenta-tion by Alain Van Gaever, DG Information Society,European Commission, November 2004

The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid –Eradicating Poverty through Profits: Enabling dig-nity and choice through markets, C.K.Prahalad,Wharton School Publishing, 2005

A Horizontal Leap Forward: Formulating a NewPublic Policy Framework based on a NetworkLayers Model (an MCI Public Policy Paper),Richard S Whitt, Senior Director of Global Policyand Planning, MCI, March 2004

Innovative Models for Telecommunications, Gamosfor the CTO, 2004 (www.telefrica.org)

Innovative Technologies and CommunityOwnership: A New Model of ICT Access for theRural Poor, Seán Ó Siochrú and Bruce Girard forUNDP, March 2005

Open and Closed Skies, Satellite Access in Africaby GVF for CATIA and IDRC (www.gvf.org)

The Open Public Local Access Network – Theconcept and emerging realization, MalcolmMatson, June 2004

An Overview of VoIP regulation in Africa: PolicyResponses and Proposals for the CommonwealthTelecommunications Organisation, Tracey Cohenand Russell Southwood, June 2004

Profitable Universal Access Providers, Scanbi-Invest,http://www.scanbi-invest.com/reports/? PHPSES-SID=1f55cc163493307483587175bbd39c51

Promoting Telecommunications BackboneDevelopment in Africa – Global lessons and busi-ness strategies, World Bank, June 2005

Providing Low-Cost ICT Access to Low-IncomeCommunities in Developing Countries – WhatWorks? What pays? http://www.oecd.org/LongAbstract/0,2546,en_2649_37441_7112509_119684_1_1_37441,00.html

Strategic Review of Telecommunications Phase 2Proposals, Ofcom (http://www.ofcom.org.uk/media_office/latest_news/nr20041118)

Study of Telecoms Infrastructure and DevelopmentInitiatives in Southern and East Africa, MikeJensen for NEPAD, July 2004

Telecommunications and Economic Developmentin New York City – A Plan for Action, prepared bythe New York City Economic DevelopmentCorporation, the New York City Department ofInformation Technology and Telecommunicationand the New York Department of Small Businesses,March 2005, http://www.nycedc.com/about_us/TelecomPlanMarch2005.pdf

Via Africa: Creating local and regional IXPs to savemoney and bandwidth, Draft discussion paper pre-pared by Balancing Act for IDRC and ITU for the5th Annual Global Symposium of Regulators, 2004

Wireless Networks for the Developing World: TheRegulation and Use of Licence-Exempt RadioBands in Africa, Isabel Neto, MIT – Seewww.afridigital.net

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 33

Appendices . 33

4. APPENDICES

APPENDIX A1:BACKGROUND READINGAfrica: The Impact of Mobile Phones, VodafonePolicy Paper Series No 2, March 2005

African ICT infrastructure investment options,Balancing Act for DFID, 2004

Balancing Act Voice and Data Bandwidth Forecasts(2005-2008), Paul Hamilton and RussellSouthwood, May 2005

Contact Centres and Business Process Outsourcingin Cape Town – Indicators 2004, Deloitte forCalling the Cape, 2004

Cross-Border Connectivity Initiative in theECOWAS Region, Spintrack for ECOWAS and theWorld Bank, July 2004

E-Usage Survey, The Link Centre, University ofWitwatersrand, Forthcoming

The EU Regulatory Perspective on VoIP – ASubstantial Change to the Landscape, a presenta-tion by Alain Van Gaever, DG Information Society,European Commission, November 2004

The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid –Eradicating Poverty through Profits: Enabling dig-nity and choice through markets, C.K.Prahalad,Wharton School Publishing, 2005

A Horizontal Leap Forward: Formulating a NewPublic Policy Framework based on a NetworkLayers Model (an MCI Public Policy Paper),Richard S Whitt, Senior Director of Global Policyand Planning, MCI, March 2004

Innovative Models for Telecommunications, Gamosfor the CTO, 2004 (www.telefrica.org)

Innovative Technologies and CommunityOwnership: A New Model of ICT Access for theRural Poor, Seán Ó Siochrú and Bruce Girard forUNDP, March 2005

Open and Closed Skies, Satellite Access in Africaby GVF for CATIA and IDRC (www.gvf.org)

The Open Public Local Access Network – Theconcept and emerging realization, MalcolmMatson, June 2004

An Overview of VoIP regulation in Africa: PolicyResponses and Proposals for the CommonwealthTelecommunications Organisation, Tracey Cohenand Russell Southwood, June 2004

Profitable Universal Access Providers, Scanbi-Invest,http://www.scanbi-invest.com/reports/? PHPSES-SID=1f55cc163493307483587175bbd39c51

Promoting Telecommunications BackboneDevelopment in Africa – Global lessons and busi-ness strategies, World Bank, June 2005

Providing Low-Cost ICT Access to Low-IncomeCommunities in Developing Countries – WhatWorks? What pays? http://www.oecd.org/LongAbstract/0,2546,en_2649_37441_7112509_119684_1_1_37441,00.html

Strategic Review of Telecommunications Phase 2Proposals, Ofcom (http://www.ofcom.org.uk/media_office/latest_news/nr20041118)

Study of Telecoms Infrastructure and DevelopmentInitiatives in Southern and East Africa, MikeJensen for NEPAD, July 2004

Telecommunications and Economic Developmentin New York City – A Plan for Action, prepared bythe New York City Economic DevelopmentCorporation, the New York City Department ofInformation Technology and Telecommunicationand the New York Department of Small Businesses,March 2005, http://www.nycedc.com/about_us/TelecomPlanMarch2005.pdf

Via Africa: Creating local and regional IXPs to savemoney and bandwidth, Draft discussion paper pre-pared by Balancing Act for IDRC and ITU for the5th Annual Global Symposium of Regulators, 2004

Wireless Networks for the Developing World: TheRegulation and Use of Licence-Exempt RadioBands in Africa, Isabel Neto, MIT – Seewww.afridigital.net

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 33

34 . Open Access Models

APPENDIX A2: OPENACCESS MODELS FORINFORMATION ANDCOMMUNICATIONINFRASTRUCTURE – SOMEBASIC PRINCIPLESThe Open Access approach suggests a number ofkey principles:

A2.1 Anyone can playOpen Access models should assure that anyprovider willing to play by the rules can “plug andplay” in the network, particularly because of thepotential for locally-provided services and networkgrowth “at the edges” made possible by flexibletechnology and open network models.

A2.2 Technological NeutralityRegulation should be technology-neutral, takinginto account the cost and physical properties of thetechnologies themselves. No one should be stoppedfrom using a particular technology and indeed aprogressive regulator would encourage cost reduc-tion through technology innovation.

One needs to recognize that in future a wide rangeof applications will require higher bandwidth. Butthere may be no significant (order of magnitude)improvements in the performance of fiber, particu-larly its installation. However with wireless therewill be significant improvements in performanceand cost/capacity ratio and therefore wireless solu-tions will become more attractive to the end user.

A2.3 Fair and non-discriminatory competition at all layersA player at one layer of the network is free, withinthe framework of appropriate regulation, to dowhatever it sees as most expedient within its ownlayer, as long as it provides the correct specificationsto layers with which it interfaces. This allows a widevariety of physical networks and a large variety ofapplications to interact in an open architecture.

Competition should be fair and non-discriminatory.There should be no predatory pricing, cross-subsi-dization or aggressive cross-ownership. Regulatorswill need to be capable of dealing with a range ofcompetition issues to ensure a genuine level playing

field, and to prevent market strength in one layerfrom creating unfair competitive advantage atanother layer.

For all services at a given layer, there ought to be atleast two providers. Whenever there are not morethan 4–5 providers of a particular service, issues ofcompetitive position would need to be examined.

What is true for countries at a national level holdstrue at regional and international levels. Ideally, any country should have a choice of at least twoproviders to connect to neighbors and the rest ofthe world. The EU competition policy formulationof “significant market power” provides a usefulbenchmark against which competitive positionmight be examined.

A2.4 Transparency to ensure fair trading within and between layersCompetitive markets thrive on transparent infor-mation about market prices and service. Internalaccounting processes in companies need to be suffi-ciently transparent to enforce fair trading. If thereis tradable bandwidth – particularly at an interna-tional level – it will allow clear comparisons to bemade between different providers. There needs tobe greater levels of consumer information to allowcomparisons between “offers,” including offers atthe interface between layers.

The different roles of players need to be transpar-ent. In order to create trust in the market, infra-structure providers need to be clear that they willnot enter service markets to compete with theircustomers. The regulator exists to encourage com-petition rather than restrict it but to do so in a waythat genuinely encourages increased investment andlower access costs to communications technology.Where appropriate, regulation becomes “light-touch” rather than prohibitive or restrictive.Government exists to create the legal frameworkthrough which competition issues can be mediated.

A2.5 Everyone can connect to everyone else at the layer interfaceIn order for a competitive market to function,everyone must be able to connect to everyone else.Service providers would be able to get access toinfrastructure from the local to the internationallevel, whether they were small or large entities.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 34

34 . Open Access Models

APPENDIX A2: OPENACCESS MODELS FORINFORMATION ANDCOMMUNICATIONINFRASTRUCTURE – SOMEBASIC PRINCIPLESThe Open Access approach suggests a number ofkey principles:

A2.1 Anyone can playOpen Access models should assure that anyprovider willing to play by the rules can “plug andplay” in the network, particularly because of thepotential for locally-provided services and networkgrowth “at the edges” made possible by flexibletechnology and open network models.

A2.2 Technological NeutralityRegulation should be technology-neutral, takinginto account the cost and physical properties of thetechnologies themselves. No one should be stoppedfrom using a particular technology and indeed aprogressive regulator would encourage cost reduc-tion through technology innovation.

One needs to recognize that in future a wide rangeof applications will require higher bandwidth. Butthere may be no significant (order of magnitude)improvements in the performance of fiber, particu-larly its installation. However with wireless therewill be significant improvements in performanceand cost/capacity ratio and therefore wireless solu-tions will become more attractive to the end user.

A2.3 Fair and non-discriminatory competition at all layersA player at one layer of the network is free, withinthe framework of appropriate regulation, to dowhatever it sees as most expedient within its ownlayer, as long as it provides the correct specificationsto layers with which it interfaces. This allows a widevariety of physical networks and a large variety ofapplications to interact in an open architecture.

Competition should be fair and non-discriminatory.There should be no predatory pricing, cross-subsi-dization or aggressive cross-ownership. Regulatorswill need to be capable of dealing with a range ofcompetition issues to ensure a genuine level playing

field, and to prevent market strength in one layerfrom creating unfair competitive advantage atanother layer.

For all services at a given layer, there ought to be atleast two providers. Whenever there are not morethan 4–5 providers of a particular service, issues ofcompetitive position would need to be examined.

What is true for countries at a national level holdstrue at regional and international levels. Ideally, any country should have a choice of at least twoproviders to connect to neighbors and the rest ofthe world. The EU competition policy formulationof “significant market power” provides a usefulbenchmark against which competitive positionmight be examined.

A2.4 Transparency to ensure fair trading within and between layersCompetitive markets thrive on transparent infor-mation about market prices and service. Internalaccounting processes in companies need to be suffi-ciently transparent to enforce fair trading. If thereis tradable bandwidth – particularly at an interna-tional level – it will allow clear comparisons to bemade between different providers. There needs tobe greater levels of consumer information to allowcomparisons between “offers,” including offers atthe interface between layers.

The different roles of players need to be transpar-ent. In order to create trust in the market, infra-structure providers need to be clear that they willnot enter service markets to compete with theircustomers. The regulator exists to encourage com-petition rather than restrict it but to do so in a waythat genuinely encourages increased investment andlower access costs to communications technology.Where appropriate, regulation becomes “light-touch” rather than prohibitive or restrictive.Government exists to create the legal frameworkthrough which competition issues can be mediated.

A2.5 Everyone can connect to everyone else at the layer interfaceIn order for a competitive market to function,everyone must be able to connect to everyone else.Service providers would be able to get access toinfrastructure from the local to the internationallevel, whether they were small or large entities.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 34

Appendices . 35

There will be inevitable interconnection rate issueswhere the interests of the infrastructure provider inkeeping re-investing in the network need to beweighed against the opportunities that can be creat-ed for greater levels of new business.

A2.6 Devolved rather than centralizedsolutionsIt is important to ensure that the “intelligence” inthe network is to be found at the edges of theinfrastructure rather than at its center. In otherwords, the infrastructure provider should not beallowed to reserve for itself all of the functions thatcreate value in the market.

In practical terms, it should be possible to create alocal entity that can operate on the small or medi-um-scale and can “plug into” the network withoutneeding to cede control over its activities to theinfrastructure provider. Local operators need to beable to own and control a significant level of “intel-ligence” in the system (e.g. billing, features, etc) toencourage open access.

APPENDIX A3: ORIGINS OFTHE TERM OPEN ACCESSThe term Open Access means different things todifferent people and it is important to provide asummary of its origins before specifying how we aregoing to use the term. Different regulatory circum-stances in the developed world account for severalof the main differences in the way the term is used.

In the United States, the expression “Open Access”has been very much tied in a fairly narrow way to the debate about the role of Regional BellOperating Companies (RBOCs): Will they beimposed (at cost) to provide different forms ofunbundled capacity to competitors, particularlyin terms of roll-out to the home? And why aren’tcable TV companies being forced to meet a similarrequirement as they roll out Triple Play?

In Europe the term has been used to address widerissues around access to the network and how thenetwork might be financed and operated. SeveralOpen Access initiatives (for example, municipaltelecom networks) were started from the realizationthat it would not be financially possible to haveseveral infrastructures in parallel in the local network.

Despite this limitation, those involved still wantedto have competitive offers from several serviceproviders. If there is only one network, then theterms under which companies can access itbecomes a vital part of the argument.

However, the ideas are not just limited to the localnetwork. Some nationwide power companies andother utilities have built substantial networks toowithin this framework of ideas, even if their inter-ests are largely commercial: they only wish tobecome carriers’ carriers, leveraging existing assetslike power lines. They realize that they may nothave the skills to enter the telecoms market excepton a wholesale basis. Even some cross-border linkswere created within this same set of arguments.

In Europe regulators and operators have traveled aconsiderable distance in Open Access terms.Separation of services and infrastructure were initiallyviewed as impossible. Because of the way networkswere previously technically structured, services andinfrastructure were like Siamese twins that sharedcommon organs. In Europe, Open Network Provisionwas a term that was first used in EuropeanCommission documents in the early 1990s, whenrules were put in place to make sure other operatorswere able to get the most basic services from use ofthe historic operator’s facilities. But issues like localloop unbundling were seen as too radical 10 years ago.

The separation of the network infrastructure wasprobably first discussed at length in markets thatwere early liberalizers such as Sweden and theUnited Kingdom. However, these ideas werequickly rejected at this time in France andGermany where the policy debate and the pace ofchange in the historic operator had not reached asimilar point. The increasing introduction of IP-based networks and thinking means that even inthe more traditional telephony world this separa-tion is now occurring as a tool for rationalizing theoperation of the business.

These discussions had their parallel in the UnitedStates where individuals and operators in theInternet sector began to talk about Open Access.The discussion focused on access to whatever net-work equipment was available (copper or cable) asa broadband delivery mechanism. Proponents ofgreater competition wanted access on a carriers’carrier basis with no price discrimination. This

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 35

Appendices . 35

There will be inevitable interconnection rate issueswhere the interests of the infrastructure provider inkeeping re-investing in the network need to beweighed against the opportunities that can be creat-ed for greater levels of new business.

A2.6 Devolved rather than centralizedsolutionsIt is important to ensure that the “intelligence” inthe network is to be found at the edges of theinfrastructure rather than at its center. In otherwords, the infrastructure provider should not beallowed to reserve for itself all of the functions thatcreate value in the market.

In practical terms, it should be possible to create alocal entity that can operate on the small or medi-um-scale and can “plug into” the network withoutneeding to cede control over its activities to theinfrastructure provider. Local operators need to beable to own and control a significant level of “intel-ligence” in the system (e.g. billing, features, etc) toencourage open access.

APPENDIX A3: ORIGINS OFTHE TERM OPEN ACCESSThe term Open Access means different things todifferent people and it is important to provide asummary of its origins before specifying how we aregoing to use the term. Different regulatory circum-stances in the developed world account for severalof the main differences in the way the term is used.

In the United States, the expression “Open Access”has been very much tied in a fairly narrow way to the debate about the role of Regional BellOperating Companies (RBOCs): Will they beimposed (at cost) to provide different forms ofunbundled capacity to competitors, particularlyin terms of roll-out to the home? And why aren’tcable TV companies being forced to meet a similarrequirement as they roll out Triple Play?

In Europe the term has been used to address widerissues around access to the network and how thenetwork might be financed and operated. SeveralOpen Access initiatives (for example, municipaltelecom networks) were started from the realizationthat it would not be financially possible to haveseveral infrastructures in parallel in the local network.

Despite this limitation, those involved still wantedto have competitive offers from several serviceproviders. If there is only one network, then theterms under which companies can access itbecomes a vital part of the argument.

However, the ideas are not just limited to the localnetwork. Some nationwide power companies andother utilities have built substantial networks toowithin this framework of ideas, even if their inter-ests are largely commercial: they only wish tobecome carriers’ carriers, leveraging existing assetslike power lines. They realize that they may nothave the skills to enter the telecoms market excepton a wholesale basis. Even some cross-border linkswere created within this same set of arguments.

In Europe regulators and operators have traveled aconsiderable distance in Open Access terms.Separation of services and infrastructure were initiallyviewed as impossible. Because of the way networkswere previously technically structured, services andinfrastructure were like Siamese twins that sharedcommon organs. In Europe, Open Network Provisionwas a term that was first used in EuropeanCommission documents in the early 1990s, whenrules were put in place to make sure other operatorswere able to get the most basic services from use ofthe historic operator’s facilities. But issues like localloop unbundling were seen as too radical 10 years ago.

The separation of the network infrastructure wasprobably first discussed at length in markets thatwere early liberalizers such as Sweden and theUnited Kingdom. However, these ideas werequickly rejected at this time in France andGermany where the policy debate and the pace ofchange in the historic operator had not reached asimilar point. The increasing introduction of IP-based networks and thinking means that even inthe more traditional telephony world this separa-tion is now occurring as a tool for rationalizing theoperation of the business.

These discussions had their parallel in the UnitedStates where individuals and operators in theInternet sector began to talk about Open Access.The discussion focused on access to whatever net-work equipment was available (copper or cable) asa broadband delivery mechanism. Proponents ofgreater competition wanted access on a carriers’carrier basis with no price discrimination. This

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 35

36 . Open Access Models

demand echoed early U.S. legislation on accessprices to railways. The counter argument is that theindustry is now a liberalized, commercial market:different technical platforms are available that pro-vide choice, however limited the scope. Demandingaccess at cost is nothing but theft of legitimatecommercial profits, removing all incentives to fur-ther invest in new equipment.

Outside of these discussions within the Internetand telecoms industries, there is perhaps a widerecho of the use of the term in the debates aroundproprietary against open source software. TheOpen Source software arguments contain the ideaof an accessible public core around which softwareservices are built. The logical extension of thesearguments has been into the field of intellectualproperty with the discussions around the CreativeCommons approach to these issues. Open Accessacademic journals might be seen as a practicaldevelopment of these arguments relating to intel-lectual property.

APPENDIX A4: BUSINESSMODEL AND TECHNOLOGYAPPROACHES FOR SMALL-SCALE RURAL OPERATORSThis section looks at the contributory costs thatwould underlie any business model for a small-scalerural operator and examines a couple of technologicalapproaches. Further work needs to be done in bothareas but this material is provided as a starting point.

For well over 10 years, the cost of provided fixedwireline connections has been identified as aroundUS$1000 per subscriber. One caveat to this figurehas been that it is usually far more expensive toconnect rural subscribers. Another caveat concernswhat has been included in the figure.

In almost all cases, it has included the handset asso-ciated customer premises equipment (CPE), inter-nal wiring, and the Central Office MainDistribution Frame. As networks – both at thelocal and distribution level – have been equippedwith Remote Subscriber Stages (RSS), includingthe allocated cost of these items becomes moreblurred: in particular as Central Offices becomebigger and fewer.

The big cost driver in that part of the network isthe length of the cable where 1–10 users are shar-ing. Obviously a low density of users is going torequire more cabling. Buried cabling is three timesmore expensive than poles, and pole lines them-selves are not cheap. At current prices in Tanzania,a low voltage pole line costs US$4,000 per km andbuilding its telephone equivalent would cost rough-ly the same price. The average line length is above1,500 meters in rural networks. Low customer den-sity may also mean that the average for customersper household is not 0.5 as might be expected butcloser to 0.1. This also tends to increase the cost ofthe non-shared parts of the line.

Another useful metric is financial sustainabilitybased on Average Revenue Per User. Prior to themobile explosion, various ITU studies identified anARPU of US$300 being necessary for financial sus-tainability on fixed lines. This is quite close to theUS$276 per year for Indian operators quoted inA.4.1 which follows this section.

With a 1000 sq km flat GSM site, the economicsare very different. The key issues are: the construc-tion costs; the backbone cost to reach the site; thesharing of operational systems and their scalability;upstream/interconnect costs; and probably mostimportantly, the cost of powering a local site.Maintaining diesel generators (particularly withback-up capacity) is expensive. This tends to bewhy operators such as Vodacom and others havebeen looking at solar-powered sites.

On this basis, the average capex per GSM subscriberin Africa is in the order of US$250 per subscriber.Therefore, any competing small-scale operation willneed to be significantly below that price or offeradded functionality to its users. However, this isagainst the backdrop that GSM equipment price hasfallen by 15-20 percent over 5–10 years but Africancalling prices remain (on a per minute level) the sameor higher than European prices during that period.

An attempt to lower the cost per subscriber belowthe threshold quoted above has to deal with threesets of costs:■ Transport from the town upstream and the cost

of central systems. ■ Local access, from a hub/node/base station

site/CO in town and out to the user premises.■ Customer Premises Equipment (CPE).

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 36

36 . Open Access Models

demand echoed early U.S. legislation on accessprices to railways. The counter argument is that theindustry is now a liberalized, commercial market:different technical platforms are available that pro-vide choice, however limited the scope. Demandingaccess at cost is nothing but theft of legitimatecommercial profits, removing all incentives to fur-ther invest in new equipment.

Outside of these discussions within the Internetand telecoms industries, there is perhaps a widerecho of the use of the term in the debates aroundproprietary against open source software. TheOpen Source software arguments contain the ideaof an accessible public core around which softwareservices are built. The logical extension of thesearguments has been into the field of intellectualproperty with the discussions around the CreativeCommons approach to these issues. Open Accessacademic journals might be seen as a practicaldevelopment of these arguments relating to intel-lectual property.

APPENDIX A4: BUSINESSMODEL AND TECHNOLOGYAPPROACHES FOR SMALL-SCALE RURAL OPERATORSThis section looks at the contributory costs thatwould underlie any business model for a small-scalerural operator and examines a couple of technologicalapproaches. Further work needs to be done in bothareas but this material is provided as a starting point.

For well over 10 years, the cost of provided fixedwireline connections has been identified as aroundUS$1000 per subscriber. One caveat to this figurehas been that it is usually far more expensive toconnect rural subscribers. Another caveat concernswhat has been included in the figure.

In almost all cases, it has included the handset asso-ciated customer premises equipment (CPE), inter-nal wiring, and the Central Office MainDistribution Frame. As networks – both at thelocal and distribution level – have been equippedwith Remote Subscriber Stages (RSS), includingthe allocated cost of these items becomes moreblurred: in particular as Central Offices becomebigger and fewer.

The big cost driver in that part of the network isthe length of the cable where 1–10 users are shar-ing. Obviously a low density of users is going torequire more cabling. Buried cabling is three timesmore expensive than poles, and pole lines them-selves are not cheap. At current prices in Tanzania,a low voltage pole line costs US$4,000 per km andbuilding its telephone equivalent would cost rough-ly the same price. The average line length is above1,500 meters in rural networks. Low customer den-sity may also mean that the average for customersper household is not 0.5 as might be expected butcloser to 0.1. This also tends to increase the cost ofthe non-shared parts of the line.

Another useful metric is financial sustainabilitybased on Average Revenue Per User. Prior to themobile explosion, various ITU studies identified anARPU of US$300 being necessary for financial sus-tainability on fixed lines. This is quite close to theUS$276 per year for Indian operators quoted inA.4.1 which follows this section.

With a 1000 sq km flat GSM site, the economicsare very different. The key issues are: the construc-tion costs; the backbone cost to reach the site; thesharing of operational systems and their scalability;upstream/interconnect costs; and probably mostimportantly, the cost of powering a local site.Maintaining diesel generators (particularly withback-up capacity) is expensive. This tends to bewhy operators such as Vodacom and others havebeen looking at solar-powered sites.

On this basis, the average capex per GSM subscriberin Africa is in the order of US$250 per subscriber.Therefore, any competing small-scale operation willneed to be significantly below that price or offeradded functionality to its users. However, this isagainst the backdrop that GSM equipment price hasfallen by 15-20 percent over 5–10 years but Africancalling prices remain (on a per minute level) the sameor higher than European prices during that period.

An attempt to lower the cost per subscriber belowthe threshold quoted above has to deal with threesets of costs:■ Transport from the town upstream and the cost

of central systems. ■ Local access, from a hub/node/base station

site/CO in town and out to the user premises.■ Customer Premises Equipment (CPE).

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 36

Appendices . 37

If the local fixed hub/CO/base station site cost ishigh, it will have to serve many users to be able tolower the CAPEX cost per user. And we have not yetdiscussed maintenance and operating costs. Ifbackbone transport demand at a district level islow (or very expensive or scarce), it is more likelythat cheaper wireless transmission links will makefinancial sense.

Assuming fiber-based transport being made availableto towns as part of a backbone structure at pricescompetitive to wireless links, the question stillremains: Are the Optical Termination points (theends of the fiber network) spaced a few kilometersapart? Several tens of kilometers apart? Or even sever-al hundreds of kilometers apart?

In the last two cases, there would need to be addi-tional wireless extensions to local hubs/base stationsor very big footprints like CDMA 450.

Therefore, a cost-effective basis for small-scale localdeployments is cheap, upstream transport to apoint not more than 10–20 kms away, reachable byinexpensive wireless links and a local wireless hubat a significantly lower CAPEX than US$250 peruser and Maintenance and Operating costs of thesame magnitude as GSM. This includes centralservices for billing, etc., from a sub-contractedprovider.

Currently there is a race between GSM andCDMA software and equipment providers to getmore bandwidth out of their systems (thus delivermore subscribers at a lower cost) and the WILANproviders to scale-up various “bare-bones” IP-centric transport systems to provide both Internetconnectivity and voice as an application.

Provided there are enough users in the town tosustain the broadband Internet service, then anyaccess to individual users away from this centrewill be on a cost basis that is lower than GSMcosts. With a 3–5-km radius of coverage, individ-ual users will be reached for a cost in the order ofUS$100 per subscriber (excluding CPE). Thecheaper the upstream connection and the localhub, the wider the coverage possible through a“string-of-pearls” footprint.

If as is suggested below, a GSM front-end hub isused to enable subscribers to use the standard GSM

phones (dominant in Africa), it will provide a voiceand low bit rate data service. The question then iswhether there are enough users to pay for such aservice: either calculated on the basis of a monthlypre-paid ARPU or on the basis of a monthly pre-paid, flat-fee and with or without an internationalcalling service, using VOIP.

Sharing a number of requirements is an importantingredient of the business model. Putting fiber onpower lines (for monitoring and maintenance) thatcan also be used by any telecoms system will greatlylower the cost of roll-out and keep Maintenanceand Operating costs down. A fiber connection to atown can also be used to distribute television andradio programming.

If the electrical power companies can see the senseof including fiber for their own control and meter-ing purposes on the High-Voltage grid, it will bepossible to get fiber out to the towns. If in place, itwould add the potential for two additional incomestreams: leased capacity revenue on the fiber net-work and added power sales from a more dynamiclocal community that has access to ICT tools. Thelink between spreading power and telecomstogether to outlying areas is not much discussedin either sector.

A small-scale, rural operator will need to have thefollowing:■ Cheap backhaul/upstream, raw IP-transport,

possibly shared on the transport level. Thismight be provided through: shared fiber cable;piggybacked on power grid; or by using Wi-Fifor transmission links.

■ Electrical power, which means piggybacking onelectrification initiatives at least the local gridlevel, if not at the national level.

■ Local deployment (no truck rolls from town).■ Anchor customers from local public sector (any

private networks for administrative purposes,including police, military, healthcare and educa-tion needs).

■ An upstream service choice provided by localentrepreneurs.

■ Wireline broadband as a minimum to the localtown centre.

■ Wireless for local access.

Two approaches to creating small-scale rural dataand voice operations are described below. We are

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 37

Appendices . 37

If the local fixed hub/CO/base station site cost ishigh, it will have to serve many users to be able tolower the CAPEX cost per user. And we have not yetdiscussed maintenance and operating costs. Ifbackbone transport demand at a district level islow (or very expensive or scarce), it is more likelythat cheaper wireless transmission links will makefinancial sense.

Assuming fiber-based transport being made availableto towns as part of a backbone structure at pricescompetitive to wireless links, the question stillremains: Are the Optical Termination points (theends of the fiber network) spaced a few kilometersapart? Several tens of kilometers apart? Or even sever-al hundreds of kilometers apart?

In the last two cases, there would need to be addi-tional wireless extensions to local hubs/base stationsor very big footprints like CDMA 450.

Therefore, a cost-effective basis for small-scale localdeployments is cheap, upstream transport to apoint not more than 10–20 kms away, reachable byinexpensive wireless links and a local wireless hubat a significantly lower CAPEX than US$250 peruser and Maintenance and Operating costs of thesame magnitude as GSM. This includes centralservices for billing, etc., from a sub-contractedprovider.

Currently there is a race between GSM andCDMA software and equipment providers to getmore bandwidth out of their systems (thus delivermore subscribers at a lower cost) and the WILANproviders to scale-up various “bare-bones” IP-centric transport systems to provide both Internetconnectivity and voice as an application.

Provided there are enough users in the town tosustain the broadband Internet service, then anyaccess to individual users away from this centrewill be on a cost basis that is lower than GSMcosts. With a 3–5-km radius of coverage, individ-ual users will be reached for a cost in the order ofUS$100 per subscriber (excluding CPE). Thecheaper the upstream connection and the localhub, the wider the coverage possible through a“string-of-pearls” footprint.

If as is suggested below, a GSM front-end hub isused to enable subscribers to use the standard GSM

phones (dominant in Africa), it will provide a voiceand low bit rate data service. The question then iswhether there are enough users to pay for such aservice: either calculated on the basis of a monthlypre-paid ARPU or on the basis of a monthly pre-paid, flat-fee and with or without an internationalcalling service, using VOIP.

Sharing a number of requirements is an importantingredient of the business model. Putting fiber onpower lines (for monitoring and maintenance) thatcan also be used by any telecoms system will greatlylower the cost of roll-out and keep Maintenanceand Operating costs down. A fiber connection to atown can also be used to distribute television andradio programming.

If the electrical power companies can see the senseof including fiber for their own control and meter-ing purposes on the High-Voltage grid, it will bepossible to get fiber out to the towns. If in place, itwould add the potential for two additional incomestreams: leased capacity revenue on the fiber net-work and added power sales from a more dynamiclocal community that has access to ICT tools. Thelink between spreading power and telecomstogether to outlying areas is not much discussedin either sector.

A small-scale, rural operator will need to have thefollowing:■ Cheap backhaul/upstream, raw IP-transport,

possibly shared on the transport level. Thismight be provided through: shared fiber cable;piggybacked on power grid; or by using Wi-Fifor transmission links.

■ Electrical power, which means piggybacking onelectrification initiatives at least the local gridlevel, if not at the national level.

■ Local deployment (no truck rolls from town).■ Anchor customers from local public sector (any

private networks for administrative purposes,including police, military, healthcare and educa-tion needs).

■ An upstream service choice provided by localentrepreneurs.

■ Wireline broadband as a minimum to the localtown centre.

■ Wireless for local access.

Two approaches to creating small-scale rural dataand voice operations are described below. We are

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 37

38 . Open Access Models

not endorsing either approach as there are also anumber of other approaches. But we provide thesedescriptions – one operational and the other poten-tially possible – to illustrate that it is technicallypossible to create the small-scale rural operationswe describe.

A.4.1 n-Logue, India (CorDECT wireless local loop)Small towns and rural areas in India have very lit-tle connectivity. With the cost of providing tele-phone and Internet connections being aroundUS$800 per line, a revenue of about US$23 permonth is required for an operator to break even.Access is affordable to barely 2–3 percent ofIndian households, the majority already located inmajor cities

n-Logue is an Indian company that has spun offfrom work and research at and around The IndianInstitute of Technology Madras (Chennai). Its deliv-ers low-cost Internet and telephone services to ruralvillage-based operators. n-Logue’s business model isalready available in large numbers of villages acrossIndia. The system is also in use in Nigeria,Madagascar, and Tunisia.

At the local level in India n-Logue identifies andpartners with local entrepreneurs. These local serv-ice providers find subscribers, provide services, andcollect payments. At the village level there arekiosks, which provide services and informationaimed at the rural market.

The technology n-Logue uses – corDECT WirelessLocal Loop – provides a simultaneous telephoneand 35/70 kbps Internet connection to a user at aper-line access cost of about US$180. The next ver-sion of corDECT will deliver 256 kbps. It can alsooffer a “Minnow” ISP-in-a-box software, whichrequires a considerably lower initial investment.These cost savings enable a small operator to investand provide services in a limited area, and makeincremental expenditures as the total number ofsubscribers grows. The system can serve between1,000–1,500 people in a radius of 25 km.

Each Access Centre includes:■ a leased Internet connection to the nearest

Internet gateway, ■ a 60’ tower with multiple Compact Base

Stations to transmit the corDECT signal,

■ a DECT Interface Unit and Remote AccessServer for routing Internet and voice data,

■ radius, Network Address Translation andDomain Name System servers, and

■ software to bill customers on a monthly basisand track the payments.

Each village kiosk costs approximately US$1200 toset up, and includes:■ a wall set that receives the wireless corDECT

signal,■ branded PC with 15" color monitor,■ computer peripherals including speaker, micro-

phone, CD-ROM, digital camera, inkjet printerand sound card,

■ UPS with battery providing 4 hours of back-uppower for PC, and

■ an application suite consisting of word-processing,browsing and e-mail software all in local languageas well as in English.

If telephony is available in the project area, thecost of the kiosk increases by USD$110. A num-ber of the village kiosks provide a phone service,often the only one in the village. At a villagelevel the operation reaches breakeven at aremarkably low revenue level: just over US$3 perday. At the local service provider level, the busi-ness risk is shared between n-Logue and the localoperator.

Small capacity GSM base stations can be installedat the village kiosks with a maximum signal rangeof in the order of 2 km. A business model for thedeployment is under development, but services willbe offered at extremely low per minute charges – aslow as US0.5–1 cent per minute. This is less thanhalf the current fixed line tariff in India. The localservice providers will accommodate the GSM net-work centre, using the existing CorDECT wirelessfacilities to carry the telephone signals from thevillages to the switching centre.

The village operators will be given a new role asagents of the GSM operator, providing customersupport, managing accounts and payments etc.This will improve their revenue base and add totheir financial stability. Similarly, the n-Logue thelocal service providers will act as agents of theGSM operator, providing connectivity servicesbetween the village BTS, the switching centre andthe national networks. Needless to say, this new

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 38

38 . Open Access Models

not endorsing either approach as there are also anumber of other approaches. But we provide thesedescriptions – one operational and the other poten-tially possible – to illustrate that it is technicallypossible to create the small-scale rural operationswe describe.

A.4.1 n-Logue, India (CorDECT wireless local loop)Small towns and rural areas in India have very lit-tle connectivity. With the cost of providing tele-phone and Internet connections being aroundUS$800 per line, a revenue of about US$23 permonth is required for an operator to break even.Access is affordable to barely 2–3 percent ofIndian households, the majority already located inmajor cities

n-Logue is an Indian company that has spun offfrom work and research at and around The IndianInstitute of Technology Madras (Chennai). Its deliv-ers low-cost Internet and telephone services to ruralvillage-based operators. n-Logue’s business model isalready available in large numbers of villages acrossIndia. The system is also in use in Nigeria,Madagascar, and Tunisia.

At the local level in India n-Logue identifies andpartners with local entrepreneurs. These local serv-ice providers find subscribers, provide services, andcollect payments. At the village level there arekiosks, which provide services and informationaimed at the rural market.

The technology n-Logue uses – corDECT WirelessLocal Loop – provides a simultaneous telephoneand 35/70 kbps Internet connection to a user at aper-line access cost of about US$180. The next ver-sion of corDECT will deliver 256 kbps. It can alsooffer a “Minnow” ISP-in-a-box software, whichrequires a considerably lower initial investment.These cost savings enable a small operator to investand provide services in a limited area, and makeincremental expenditures as the total number ofsubscribers grows. The system can serve between1,000–1,500 people in a radius of 25 km.

Each Access Centre includes:■ a leased Internet connection to the nearest

Internet gateway, ■ a 60’ tower with multiple Compact Base

Stations to transmit the corDECT signal,

■ a DECT Interface Unit and Remote AccessServer for routing Internet and voice data,

■ radius, Network Address Translation andDomain Name System servers, and

■ software to bill customers on a monthly basisand track the payments.

Each village kiosk costs approximately US$1200 toset up, and includes:■ a wall set that receives the wireless corDECT

signal,■ branded PC with 15" color monitor,■ computer peripherals including speaker, micro-

phone, CD-ROM, digital camera, inkjet printerand sound card,

■ UPS with battery providing 4 hours of back-uppower for PC, and

■ an application suite consisting of word-processing,browsing and e-mail software all in local languageas well as in English.

If telephony is available in the project area, thecost of the kiosk increases by USD$110. A num-ber of the village kiosks provide a phone service,often the only one in the village. At a villagelevel the operation reaches breakeven at aremarkably low revenue level: just over US$3 perday. At the local service provider level, the busi-ness risk is shared between n-Logue and the localoperator.

Small capacity GSM base stations can be installedat the village kiosks with a maximum signal rangeof in the order of 2 km. A business model for thedeployment is under development, but services willbe offered at extremely low per minute charges – aslow as US0.5–1 cent per minute. This is less thanhalf the current fixed line tariff in India. The localservice providers will accommodate the GSM net-work centre, using the existing CorDECT wirelessfacilities to carry the telephone signals from thevillages to the switching centre.

The village operators will be given a new role asagents of the GSM operator, providing customersupport, managing accounts and payments etc.This will improve their revenue base and add totheir financial stability. Similarly, the n-Logue thelocal service providers will act as agents of theGSM operator, providing connectivity servicesbetween the village BTS, the switching centre andthe national networks. Needless to say, this new

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 38

Appendices . 39

business model presents Indian regulators at theTelecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI)with a new licensing challenge. Although it haspublished papers in support of the idea the issuehas not yet been resolved.

n-Logue’s business model depends heavily on therelatively high rural population density found inIndia. As many as 480,000 people can be foundwithin the 25-km radius that can be reached bythe CorDECT local wireless loop. Many of thesevillages have access to a local electricity supply.Rural population density in Africa is typicallymuch lower and local electricity supply is theexception rather than the rule. Small scale entre-preneurship is less developed in Africa and localcapital is not easily available.

A.4.2 A “GSM-lite” network utilizingIP technologyGSM-Lite is not yet fully operational but describeshow it would be possible to build small yet scalablecellular networks using off-the-shelf IP hardwareand standard GSM terminals. It is inspired by twomarket trends. The first is the unquestionable suc-cess of the GSM standard as the dominant technol-ogy for cellular networks. The second trend is thegrowth of use VoIP or session initiation protocol(SIP) for carrying calls. In comparison to themodel in 3.1.1, it connects a local GSM celldirectly to a generic wireless (or other) IP network.

The latest GSM specification allows IP to be usedfor part of the core network and future upgradeswill include IP for all or part of the backbone.There also products that will allow the creation ofa radio access network using IP. However, these

innovations only go part of the way towards build-ing the network envisaged.

A GSM network is expensive to deploy because it isset up for hundred of thousands of subscribers ratherthan for micro-operation, is extremely fault tolerant,and built using hardware that is produced in lowquantities.

Therefore, to achieve a “GSM-lite” network oneneeds to be able to produce something that will workwith only a few hundred subscribers and uses cheap,off-the-shelf software and existing or new IP net-works that can run other services like Internet access.As it runs on the dominant technology, second-handhandsets can be sourced at between US$20–$25.

To achieve this, it would be possible to create whatmight be called a GSM access point (GSM-AP).The GSM-AP connected to an IP network andtranslates from GSM to VoIP/SIP. An overview ofthe system is shown in diagram 3.

The access point will act on the wireless side as aGSM base station but also terminate all GSM sig-naling. On the network side it communicates usingSIP based VoIP. This would allow building of avery small network and use of regular CPUs and anEthernet network card. The only dedicated GSMhardware would be the base station.

A GSM terminal attached to the access point willbe represented as a SIP client on the network side.The SIP client will do authentication, call request,and negotiate media codecs. This means that theinfrastructure needed on the network side to han-dle call management is not much different fromany other SIP infrastructure.

DIAGRAM 3: GSM lite overview

GSM

GSMstack

Mobile stations GSM access point IP network SIP servers

SIPstack

VoIP/SIP

IP

Translation

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 39

Appendices . 39

business model presents Indian regulators at theTelecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI)with a new licensing challenge. Although it haspublished papers in support of the idea the issuehas not yet been resolved.

n-Logue’s business model depends heavily on therelatively high rural population density found inIndia. As many as 480,000 people can be foundwithin the 25-km radius that can be reached bythe CorDECT local wireless loop. Many of thesevillages have access to a local electricity supply.Rural population density in Africa is typicallymuch lower and local electricity supply is theexception rather than the rule. Small scale entre-preneurship is less developed in Africa and localcapital is not easily available.

A.4.2 A “GSM-lite” network utilizingIP technologyGSM-Lite is not yet fully operational but describeshow it would be possible to build small yet scalablecellular networks using off-the-shelf IP hardwareand standard GSM terminals. It is inspired by twomarket trends. The first is the unquestionable suc-cess of the GSM standard as the dominant technol-ogy for cellular networks. The second trend is thegrowth of use VoIP or session initiation protocol(SIP) for carrying calls. In comparison to themodel in 3.1.1, it connects a local GSM celldirectly to a generic wireless (or other) IP network.

The latest GSM specification allows IP to be usedfor part of the core network and future upgradeswill include IP for all or part of the backbone.There also products that will allow the creation ofa radio access network using IP. However, these

innovations only go part of the way towards build-ing the network envisaged.

A GSM network is expensive to deploy because it isset up for hundred of thousands of subscribers ratherthan for micro-operation, is extremely fault tolerant,and built using hardware that is produced in lowquantities.

Therefore, to achieve a “GSM-lite” network oneneeds to be able to produce something that will workwith only a few hundred subscribers and uses cheap,off-the-shelf software and existing or new IP net-works that can run other services like Internet access.As it runs on the dominant technology, second-handhandsets can be sourced at between US$20–$25.

To achieve this, it would be possible to create whatmight be called a GSM access point (GSM-AP).The GSM-AP connected to an IP network andtranslates from GSM to VoIP/SIP. An overview ofthe system is shown in diagram 3.

The access point will act on the wireless side as aGSM base station but also terminate all GSM sig-naling. On the network side it communicates usingSIP based VoIP. This would allow building of avery small network and use of regular CPUs and anEthernet network card. The only dedicated GSMhardware would be the base station.

A GSM terminal attached to the access point willbe represented as a SIP client on the network side.The SIP client will do authentication, call request,and negotiate media codecs. This means that theinfrastructure needed on the network side to han-dle call management is not much different fromany other SIP infrastructure.

DIAGRAM 3: GSM lite overview

GSM

GSMstack

Mobile stations GSM access point IP network SIP servers

SIPstack

VoIP/SIP

IP

Translation

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 39

40 . Open Access Models

The GSM-AP must of course emulate a wholeGSM network as the GSM terminal will thereforenot need to be changed to accommodate intercon-nection. This mainly involves it being able to han-dle radio resource issues, authentication, mobility,paging, and call management. The other issue ishow to do hand-over from one GSM-AP to anoth-er since the system should not be limited to onebase station. Preliminary studies indicate that thisfunctionality can be implemented in the GSM-AP.

This example illustrates that it may be possible tocreate a technological solution to create an evenlower cost-entry model than for the previousexample. And although there is no working busi-ness model, many of the same approaches used inIndia can be used or modified for implementation.Local service providers can get roaming agreementswith national operators to extend their coverageand allow local users to go to other places and usetheir phone.

However, the lack of entrepreneurial capacity inrural Sub-Saharan Africa remains an issue. It wouldbe necessary to negotiate a GSM software licenseand intellectual property will be a major issue.Current GSM license costs reflect market realitiesof much larger subscriber bases. Nevertheless, thelicense cost exemptions negotiated by developingcountries to produce HIV/AIDS drugs clearly sets aprecedent that can be pursued. From initial discus-sions we believe that there would be a rapid techni-cal development. The take-up of services may notrecapitalize first generation capital investment butthat after that point would begin to become self-sustaining. The aim would be to build a market asit went into its second generation based on around30 percent of rural users.

APPENDIX A5: MUNICIPALNETWORKS —BACKGROUNDINFORMATIONMunicipal networks exist in a number of countries(a few examples include France, Germany,Netherlands, Finland, Sweden, and the UnitedStates) and in certain circumstances have beenquite effective in promoting the developing of cityor municipality-wide infrastructure growth.

A5.1 How municipal networks aroseand their characteristicsThere are no markets with more than two fibercables because, from a business point of view, it isdifficult to justify duplication. As any new system,whether mobile or fixed (narrow or broadband),depends on fiber in the backbone, the unlocking ofthe market starts here. Although piecemeal duplica-tion (and swapping) in some U.S. and Europeanmetro areas sometimes give the impression thatthere is more than one fiber system, fibers oftendescribed as separate networks end up being in thesame cable.

Although it is not clear what drew all of the playersinto the market, most have sought through swap-ping capacity to try and become vertically integratedand put themselves in a dominant market position.Or the players were providers of Open Access darkfiber who later decided to enter other markets.Whatever their motivations, they both added capaci-ty to the market in such a way that fiber became acommodity in and between metro areas and peoplebegun to trade it.

However, outside of the financial districts of metro-politan authorities, there may be only the historicoperator or the choice between it and a cable TVcompany. In rare instances, there is an occasionalOpen Access provider like a local utility company.For understandable reasons, private investors donot seem to favor putting money into broadbandprovision beyond metropolitan areas.

U.S. studies indicate a correlation between beingclose to a metropolitan area and local utility interestin telecoms. They highlight the importance of ashorter and cheaper backhaul to a node in the city,and demand from a wealthier and better paid popu-lation. Other studies take a very different view. Theyfocus on rural communities that consider being con-nected to broadband as a matter of survival: they donot want to be left out of the information society.Rural development funds and other support mecha-nisms have tended to encourage these broadbanddevelopments.

Depending upon where the champions of an alter-native telecom infrastructure come from, the formof the operation, its organizational framework andgoals may differ. The majority of alternative tele-com infrastructure initiatives are locally driven by a

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 40

40 . Open Access Models

The GSM-AP must of course emulate a wholeGSM network as the GSM terminal will thereforenot need to be changed to accommodate intercon-nection. This mainly involves it being able to han-dle radio resource issues, authentication, mobility,paging, and call management. The other issue ishow to do hand-over from one GSM-AP to anoth-er since the system should not be limited to onebase station. Preliminary studies indicate that thisfunctionality can be implemented in the GSM-AP.

This example illustrates that it may be possible tocreate a technological solution to create an evenlower cost-entry model than for the previousexample. And although there is no working busi-ness model, many of the same approaches used inIndia can be used or modified for implementation.Local service providers can get roaming agreementswith national operators to extend their coverageand allow local users to go to other places and usetheir phone.

However, the lack of entrepreneurial capacity inrural Sub-Saharan Africa remains an issue. It wouldbe necessary to negotiate a GSM software licenseand intellectual property will be a major issue.Current GSM license costs reflect market realitiesof much larger subscriber bases. Nevertheless, thelicense cost exemptions negotiated by developingcountries to produce HIV/AIDS drugs clearly sets aprecedent that can be pursued. From initial discus-sions we believe that there would be a rapid techni-cal development. The take-up of services may notrecapitalize first generation capital investment butthat after that point would begin to become self-sustaining. The aim would be to build a market asit went into its second generation based on around30 percent of rural users.

APPENDIX A5: MUNICIPALNETWORKS —BACKGROUNDINFORMATIONMunicipal networks exist in a number of countries(a few examples include France, Germany,Netherlands, Finland, Sweden, and the UnitedStates) and in certain circumstances have beenquite effective in promoting the developing of cityor municipality-wide infrastructure growth.

A5.1 How municipal networks aroseand their characteristicsThere are no markets with more than two fibercables because, from a business point of view, it isdifficult to justify duplication. As any new system,whether mobile or fixed (narrow or broadband),depends on fiber in the backbone, the unlocking ofthe market starts here. Although piecemeal duplica-tion (and swapping) in some U.S. and Europeanmetro areas sometimes give the impression thatthere is more than one fiber system, fibers oftendescribed as separate networks end up being in thesame cable.

Although it is not clear what drew all of the playersinto the market, most have sought through swap-ping capacity to try and become vertically integratedand put themselves in a dominant market position.Or the players were providers of Open Access darkfiber who later decided to enter other markets.Whatever their motivations, they both added capaci-ty to the market in such a way that fiber became acommodity in and between metro areas and peoplebegun to trade it.

However, outside of the financial districts of metro-politan authorities, there may be only the historicoperator or the choice between it and a cable TVcompany. In rare instances, there is an occasionalOpen Access provider like a local utility company.For understandable reasons, private investors donot seem to favor putting money into broadbandprovision beyond metropolitan areas.

U.S. studies indicate a correlation between beingclose to a metropolitan area and local utility interestin telecoms. They highlight the importance of ashorter and cheaper backhaul to a node in the city,and demand from a wealthier and better paid popu-lation. Other studies take a very different view. Theyfocus on rural communities that consider being con-nected to broadband as a matter of survival: they donot want to be left out of the information society.Rural development funds and other support mecha-nisms have tended to encourage these broadbanddevelopments.

Depending upon where the champions of an alter-native telecom infrastructure come from, the formof the operation, its organizational framework andgoals may differ. The majority of alternative tele-com infrastructure initiatives are locally driven by a

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 40

Appendices . 41

combination of broadband activists, politicians,and utility executives. The balance among thesegroups can differ. Activists tend to argue for theimportance of the issue but it is the politicians andutility executives who have the means to imple-ment initiatives.

The involvement of electricity utility companiescomes from the fact that it often operates a fiber-based communications network to run its ownbusiness (controlling the electricity grid) acrossa range of different sites. They can see that, froma technical point of view, they could supply thesame bandwidth to others, particularly to thosewith whom they already have a closer businessrelationship. If, as in some cases, the utility com-pany is owned by the municipal authority, thereis often a mutual relationship that has a similarbasis. But the next step – supplying a wider set ofcustomers – is more complicated from a businessmodel, regulator, and charter point of viewbecause of the following factors:■ The utility company may not have its Rights

of Way for any other purpose than providingelectricity.

■ The utility company may violate other legalrequirements like the separation of businesses,prohibiting the use of its funds for telecoms, orthe use of its data from its customer base forother purposes.

■ The company’s charter may not allow it to offerexternal telecom services.

■ Other legislation may prevent it from going intotelecoms.

■ Separate accounting, or other administrativedemands may be mandatory to the point thatthe associated costs and the requirement toaccount separately for them may be a disincen-tive.

■ Almost no utility company has any experiencein telecommunications.

A5.2 An early municipal networkdevelopment (Stokab)Stockholm municipality set up Stokab in 1994 tomeet the demand for fiber that was generated bythe complete liberalization of the Swedish market.Dozens of new operators set up because they didnot need a license. Because they were not in adominant position and had no need of spectrum,they just had to register their company and get aVAT number. All the new entrants needed fiber

that the Swedish historic operator initially refusedto provide. A major factor in this initial growth indemand was a desire by private sector players totest what was possible in a completely liberalizedenvironment where anyone could offer any service.

Therefore, the purpose of Stokab was to facilitateand stimulate sector investment and innovation inthe region. Once set up, the company expandedthe network into 27 surrounding municipalities.A strategic decision taken when operations werecommenced was that Stokab would only offer themarket the fiber-optic infrastructure (“dark fiber”),the asset that is most difficult to replicate and leaveservices and innovation using the fiber to the newtelecommunications companies. This decision wasa key guiding principle of the company.

The slow decision-making process of the publicsector municipality would never cope with therapid changes needed to enter other markets. Alsothe existence of other potential players higher upthe value chain would have politically killed anyattempt to move beyond this original purpose.

Initial network deployment responded to a pent upmarket demand in the more lucrative commercialareas, first in Stockholm’s inner city (only a fewsquare miles). Subsequently, it expanded to anincreasing number of surrounding areas.Competition soon made its final consumers the realwinners. Big commercial customers such as bankshad more negotiating powers than consumers, oncethey were given a choice. Stokab’s roll-out was a mix-ture of guessing where demand might be and antici-pating it through a Master Plan. In the mid-1990sthere was not a strong demand for fiber-basedbroadband services for the consumer market: videoon demand in its early form had just failed in testdeployments. No one was expecting IP to be theuniversal platform among the service providers.

Today it has connection points in all municipali-ties in the county, covering 6,500 sq kms withspurs into neighboring counties. The network istoday more or less developed within a number ofmunicipalities to provide an alternative fiberoption to areas with commercial customers. It alsooffers a backbone structure to rural areas, reachingschools and housing complexes, and connectingwireless sites. After the initial creation of a back-bone “footprint” and commercial district access, it

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 41

Appendices . 41

combination of broadband activists, politicians,and utility executives. The balance among thesegroups can differ. Activists tend to argue for theimportance of the issue but it is the politicians andutility executives who have the means to imple-ment initiatives.

The involvement of electricity utility companiescomes from the fact that it often operates a fiber-based communications network to run its ownbusiness (controlling the electricity grid) acrossa range of different sites. They can see that, froma technical point of view, they could supply thesame bandwidth to others, particularly to thosewith whom they already have a closer businessrelationship. If, as in some cases, the utility com-pany is owned by the municipal authority, thereis often a mutual relationship that has a similarbasis. But the next step – supplying a wider set ofcustomers – is more complicated from a businessmodel, regulator, and charter point of viewbecause of the following factors:■ The utility company may not have its Rights

of Way for any other purpose than providingelectricity.

■ The utility company may violate other legalrequirements like the separation of businesses,prohibiting the use of its funds for telecoms, orthe use of its data from its customer base forother purposes.

■ The company’s charter may not allow it to offerexternal telecom services.

■ Other legislation may prevent it from going intotelecoms.

■ Separate accounting, or other administrativedemands may be mandatory to the point thatthe associated costs and the requirement toaccount separately for them may be a disincen-tive.

■ Almost no utility company has any experiencein telecommunications.

A5.2 An early municipal networkdevelopment (Stokab)Stockholm municipality set up Stokab in 1994 tomeet the demand for fiber that was generated bythe complete liberalization of the Swedish market.Dozens of new operators set up because they didnot need a license. Because they were not in adominant position and had no need of spectrum,they just had to register their company and get aVAT number. All the new entrants needed fiber

that the Swedish historic operator initially refusedto provide. A major factor in this initial growth indemand was a desire by private sector players totest what was possible in a completely liberalizedenvironment where anyone could offer any service.

Therefore, the purpose of Stokab was to facilitateand stimulate sector investment and innovation inthe region. Once set up, the company expandedthe network into 27 surrounding municipalities.A strategic decision taken when operations werecommenced was that Stokab would only offer themarket the fiber-optic infrastructure (“dark fiber”),the asset that is most difficult to replicate and leaveservices and innovation using the fiber to the newtelecommunications companies. This decision wasa key guiding principle of the company.

The slow decision-making process of the publicsector municipality would never cope with therapid changes needed to enter other markets. Alsothe existence of other potential players higher upthe value chain would have politically killed anyattempt to move beyond this original purpose.

Initial network deployment responded to a pent upmarket demand in the more lucrative commercialareas, first in Stockholm’s inner city (only a fewsquare miles). Subsequently, it expanded to anincreasing number of surrounding areas.Competition soon made its final consumers the realwinners. Big commercial customers such as bankshad more negotiating powers than consumers, oncethey were given a choice. Stokab’s roll-out was a mix-ture of guessing where demand might be and antici-pating it through a Master Plan. In the mid-1990sthere was not a strong demand for fiber-basedbroadband services for the consumer market: videoon demand in its early form had just failed in testdeployments. No one was expecting IP to be theuniversal platform among the service providers.

Today it has connection points in all municipali-ties in the county, covering 6,500 sq kms withspurs into neighboring counties. The network istoday more or less developed within a number ofmunicipalities to provide an alternative fiberoption to areas with commercial customers. It alsooffers a backbone structure to rural areas, reachingschools and housing complexes, and connectingwireless sites. After the initial creation of a back-bone “footprint” and commercial district access, it

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 41

42 . Open Access Models

sought to increase the number of individual cus-tomers using the network. This needed a muchbigger investment to also reach more price sensi-tive residential users.

Fiber grew out into residential areas, first intomulti-dwelling houses, where the service operatortypically provided a basement router, and theninto central points in single family house areas,where it fed wireless and other access points. Theseaccess points were also provided by other serviceproviders and real estate developers. It is interest-ing to note how it also tied in with local roll-outsmade by others. In one suburban municipality ofaround 17,000 single family homes, the local elec-tricity distributor added a fiber on an open accessbasis to every house on their grid.

What was argued by the historic operator (in early1995) to be a deterrent for any roll-out of fiber in thelocal network became the opposite. The supply-and-demand chain became more vital and the historicoperator was pushed by market forces to roll outmore fiber too, further fuelling the process. Serviceproviders all of a sudden had a choice, lowering theirperceived risk in buying infrastructure capacity. Thebenefit of this is clear today when some customers are able to make a less emotional evaluation of theirchoices in a competitive market. The historic opera-tor is looked at very differently, particularly as Stokabhas suffered from a period of management-relatedproblems. This has not really dented the market butmany have changed fiber supplier.

The key issue for both fiber providers is to expandthe fiber network closer to the single end user, ulti-mately the residential customer, with one eye onthe growth of high-bandwidth hungry services andanother on wireless access developments.

In more rural areas in this 6,500 sq km county,Stokab did not see itself as a provider of transportservices over any wireless network. With a fiberbackbone over the entire area, the question cameup after a few years how several providers couldprovide wireless access in competition. However, asspectrum allocation was based upon an old model,Stokab applied for, and got, a slot for broadbandwireless spectrum, which it opened to SMEproviders in the more rural part of its area.Progress with this initiative has been stalled partlyfor internal reasons but also because products such

as Wi-MAX still have teething problems.Furthermore, asymmetric digital subscriber line(ADSL) is now available as an unbundled service,and this lowers the entry cost for any contenderwanting to build market share.

The expected driver of growth is “triple play”(phone, Internet and broadcast) to the residentialmarket. Low-speed broadband access for voice andsurfing has become a mature market. The nextmajor driver for greatly increased capacity will bedigital HDTV as a part of a triple play bundle thatwill trigger the next development phase. And thismay encourage both Stokab and the historic opera-tor to enter the market to fulfill this demand.

During its first years, Stokab was not buildingaccess to every home, speculating on a futuredemand. Instead, it sought to develop in step withdemand. It went first to commercial users in thedowntown area, then to smaller users and fartherout into less dense areas. In this it was differentfrom some of the more recent proposed alternativeinfrastructure providers (see below) who are prom-ising a “fiber to all buildings in town” approach.This approach responds to the anticipation of newapplications and more widely available broadbandmass market equipment.

A5.3 Rural municipal providers(UTOPIA, iProvo, and Zipp)Alternative service providers in the United Statesprovide an interesting contrast to the Swedish expe-rience. Several municipalities in Utah created whatis known as the UTOPIA network through build-ing a mixture of fiber and wireless infrastructurewith some transport services on top. The networkrequired cooperation among several municipalities.This has been complicated by two factors. First,there has been a mismatch between the aspirationsfor a network and the political situation in differentmunicipalities: not all shared the same understand-ing of what they were trying to achieve and how farthey wanted to commit themselves. Secondly, therewere a series of legal battles with incumbent operators,mainly arguing that it was a risky gamble with tax-payers money into an area where there were severalprivate investors to find. The argument was alsothat financing through municipal bonds was anunfair advantage, providing cheaper access to capi-tal than that available to a listed company.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 42

42 . Open Access Models

sought to increase the number of individual cus-tomers using the network. This needed a muchbigger investment to also reach more price sensi-tive residential users.

Fiber grew out into residential areas, first intomulti-dwelling houses, where the service operatortypically provided a basement router, and theninto central points in single family house areas,where it fed wireless and other access points. Theseaccess points were also provided by other serviceproviders and real estate developers. It is interest-ing to note how it also tied in with local roll-outsmade by others. In one suburban municipality ofaround 17,000 single family homes, the local elec-tricity distributor added a fiber on an open accessbasis to every house on their grid.

What was argued by the historic operator (in early1995) to be a deterrent for any roll-out of fiber in thelocal network became the opposite. The supply-and-demand chain became more vital and the historicoperator was pushed by market forces to roll outmore fiber too, further fuelling the process. Serviceproviders all of a sudden had a choice, lowering theirperceived risk in buying infrastructure capacity. Thebenefit of this is clear today when some customers are able to make a less emotional evaluation of theirchoices in a competitive market. The historic opera-tor is looked at very differently, particularly as Stokabhas suffered from a period of management-relatedproblems. This has not really dented the market butmany have changed fiber supplier.

The key issue for both fiber providers is to expandthe fiber network closer to the single end user, ulti-mately the residential customer, with one eye onthe growth of high-bandwidth hungry services andanother on wireless access developments.

In more rural areas in this 6,500 sq km county,Stokab did not see itself as a provider of transportservices over any wireless network. With a fiberbackbone over the entire area, the question cameup after a few years how several providers couldprovide wireless access in competition. However, asspectrum allocation was based upon an old model,Stokab applied for, and got, a slot for broadbandwireless spectrum, which it opened to SMEproviders in the more rural part of its area.Progress with this initiative has been stalled partlyfor internal reasons but also because products such

as Wi-MAX still have teething problems.Furthermore, asymmetric digital subscriber line(ADSL) is now available as an unbundled service,and this lowers the entry cost for any contenderwanting to build market share.

The expected driver of growth is “triple play”(phone, Internet and broadcast) to the residentialmarket. Low-speed broadband access for voice andsurfing has become a mature market. The nextmajor driver for greatly increased capacity will bedigital HDTV as a part of a triple play bundle thatwill trigger the next development phase. And thismay encourage both Stokab and the historic opera-tor to enter the market to fulfill this demand.

During its first years, Stokab was not buildingaccess to every home, speculating on a futuredemand. Instead, it sought to develop in step withdemand. It went first to commercial users in thedowntown area, then to smaller users and fartherout into less dense areas. In this it was differentfrom some of the more recent proposed alternativeinfrastructure providers (see below) who are prom-ising a “fiber to all buildings in town” approach.This approach responds to the anticipation of newapplications and more widely available broadbandmass market equipment.

A5.3 Rural municipal providers(UTOPIA, iProvo, and Zipp)Alternative service providers in the United Statesprovide an interesting contrast to the Swedish expe-rience. Several municipalities in Utah created whatis known as the UTOPIA network through build-ing a mixture of fiber and wireless infrastructurewith some transport services on top. The networkrequired cooperation among several municipalities.This has been complicated by two factors. First,there has been a mismatch between the aspirationsfor a network and the political situation in differentmunicipalities: not all shared the same understand-ing of what they were trying to achieve and how farthey wanted to commit themselves. Secondly, therewere a series of legal battles with incumbent operators,mainly arguing that it was a risky gamble with tax-payers money into an area where there were severalprivate investors to find. The argument was alsothat financing through municipal bonds was anunfair advantage, providing cheaper access to capi-tal than that available to a listed company.

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 42

Appendices . 43

After a couple of years of debate, including modifi-cations of the initial plans, the first phase is nowunder construction. To ensure service providersfind the 750,000-person market viable, UTOPIAwent up the value chain offering not only darkfiber but a transport network, hubs and head-ends.In this way they lowered the entry cost for poten-tial service providers and in so doing reduced theperceived risk of entering the market. Even so, it isan Open Access model at higher network level.

A major setback was that the largest city – SaltLake City – opted out, leaving just 14 cities and aconsiderable smaller customer base. UTOPIA isinteresting as it has been one of the best document-ed prominent battlefields between incumbent inter-ests and local Open Access approaches in theUnited States. It illustrates how the U.S.-specificregulatory framework, governance, and marketlegacy tend to restrict or actively run counter toOpen Access ideas. However it has also seen arehearsal for some of sharpest proponents both forand against the idea of municipal networks.

In the case of the town of Provo, it decided to go italone (calling its network i-Provo) after a series oflegal battles. The key internal issues in the disputewere about where resources might be invested andwhich areas would be first to see benefits fromthem. But these internal issues have been ratherovershadowed by the broader dispute aboutwhether municipal networks should exist or not.

Provo shows the difference a strong local powerdistribution utility can make under otherwisesimilar conditions. The iProvo network is notonly operationally, but also financially under theutility’s wing. A well-functioning utility as achampion and home for the new venture is prob-ably an easier “sell” to the public than “a newpolitical pet project in City Hall.” The fact thatsome real savings in local electrical grid upgradescan be done simultaneously with building outfiber is definitely a plus as this is the most expen-sive part of both operations.

Both UTOPIA and iProvo are still in early phasesso it is too early to judge their future success. Thefact that the two have similar attitudes on how torelate to the market, and have agreed to co-utilizesome head-end equipment, indicate that they willhave the advantage of a combined customer base,

when evaluated by prospective service providers.Comments from a few of these service providersindicate that the two together reach the criticalmass of 200,000 to 250,000 people.

The case of Grant County, WA, with its Zipp net-work, is illustrative as an example of an area withlarge rural portions where a power utility was alsothe starting point for a fiber roll-out. In an area ofapproximately the same size as Stokab, Grant Countyhas a population of 78,000 against 1.3 million forthe Stockholm area. As a result, it has been muchmore of a challenge to make it work.

The average cable length per home, and associatedcost is correspondingly much higher. It is also visiblein the fact that the Zipp network is needed to investhigher up the value chain. The market was probablynot big enough for investor-driven companies totake all the risk as service providers by themselves.Some commentators claim that a high turnoveramong Zipp’s service providers also relates to thesmall market. In its sharpest form, the dilemma forZipp is how to get its12,000 or so users to pay for a US$1 million investment in network head-ends.Perhaps this illustrates the limits of municipal fiberroll-out where subscriber numbers do not yet pro-vide the ability to repay investment to the publicsector. Core equipment, head-ends and hubs need tobe cheaper per user, and the cost per home passedneeds to come down, suggesting more wireless foraccess in rural areas.

A5.4 A recent municipal networkinitiative (Amsterdam)Recently, the Amsterdam Municipal DevelopmentCorp. put out a tender for private companies tocompete for connecting the city’s 450,000 compa-nies, organizations and homes. Although local pri-vate operators believe that it will destroy the market(or at least their position in it), discussions continue.The situation is markedly different to that of Stokab,even if the two operate under the same EU regula-tory framework and both address a 1.5–2 millionmetropolitan population.

The process has been started much later and thereare now a greater number of new operators,although their networks do not meet the aspira-tions of the municipality. There are not only com-petitive tensions with the telco incumbent but alsowith cable TV networks, as you might expect in a

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 43

Appendices . 43

After a couple of years of debate, including modifi-cations of the initial plans, the first phase is nowunder construction. To ensure service providersfind the 750,000-person market viable, UTOPIAwent up the value chain offering not only darkfiber but a transport network, hubs and head-ends.In this way they lowered the entry cost for poten-tial service providers and in so doing reduced theperceived risk of entering the market. Even so, it isan Open Access model at higher network level.

A major setback was that the largest city – SaltLake City – opted out, leaving just 14 cities and aconsiderable smaller customer base. UTOPIA isinteresting as it has been one of the best document-ed prominent battlefields between incumbent inter-ests and local Open Access approaches in theUnited States. It illustrates how the U.S.-specificregulatory framework, governance, and marketlegacy tend to restrict or actively run counter toOpen Access ideas. However it has also seen arehearsal for some of sharpest proponents both forand against the idea of municipal networks.

In the case of the town of Provo, it decided to go italone (calling its network i-Provo) after a series oflegal battles. The key internal issues in the disputewere about where resources might be invested andwhich areas would be first to see benefits fromthem. But these internal issues have been ratherovershadowed by the broader dispute aboutwhether municipal networks should exist or not.

Provo shows the difference a strong local powerdistribution utility can make under otherwisesimilar conditions. The iProvo network is notonly operationally, but also financially under theutility’s wing. A well-functioning utility as achampion and home for the new venture is prob-ably an easier “sell” to the public than “a newpolitical pet project in City Hall.” The fact thatsome real savings in local electrical grid upgradescan be done simultaneously with building outfiber is definitely a plus as this is the most expen-sive part of both operations.

Both UTOPIA and iProvo are still in early phasesso it is too early to judge their future success. Thefact that the two have similar attitudes on how torelate to the market, and have agreed to co-utilizesome head-end equipment, indicate that they willhave the advantage of a combined customer base,

when evaluated by prospective service providers.Comments from a few of these service providersindicate that the two together reach the criticalmass of 200,000 to 250,000 people.

The case of Grant County, WA, with its Zipp net-work, is illustrative as an example of an area withlarge rural portions where a power utility was alsothe starting point for a fiber roll-out. In an area ofapproximately the same size as Stokab, Grant Countyhas a population of 78,000 against 1.3 million forthe Stockholm area. As a result, it has been muchmore of a challenge to make it work.

The average cable length per home, and associatedcost is correspondingly much higher. It is also visiblein the fact that the Zipp network is needed to investhigher up the value chain. The market was probablynot big enough for investor-driven companies totake all the risk as service providers by themselves.Some commentators claim that a high turnoveramong Zipp’s service providers also relates to thesmall market. In its sharpest form, the dilemma forZipp is how to get its12,000 or so users to pay for a US$1 million investment in network head-ends.Perhaps this illustrates the limits of municipal fiberroll-out where subscriber numbers do not yet pro-vide the ability to repay investment to the publicsector. Core equipment, head-ends and hubs need tobe cheaper per user, and the cost per home passedneeds to come down, suggesting more wireless foraccess in rural areas.

A5.4 A recent municipal networkinitiative (Amsterdam)Recently, the Amsterdam Municipal DevelopmentCorp. put out a tender for private companies tocompete for connecting the city’s 450,000 compa-nies, organizations and homes. Although local pri-vate operators believe that it will destroy the market(or at least their position in it), discussions continue.The situation is markedly different to that of Stokab,even if the two operate under the same EU regula-tory framework and both address a 1.5–2 millionmetropolitan population.

The process has been started much later and thereare now a greater number of new operators,although their networks do not meet the aspira-tions of the municipality. There are not only com-petitive tensions with the telco incumbent but alsowith cable TV networks, as you might expect in a

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 43

44 . Open Access Models

more developed market. The cable TV companies,like the telco, wish to modernize their networks tooffer “triple play”. The upgrades are more related tothe electronics than a massive transition from twist-ed pair or coaxial cable to fiber. A competing fiberstructure will no doubt remove any relative advan-tage the two have over non-facilities based competi-tors but also change their relative positions.

With HDTV being close to deployment over IP infiber-based alternative networks elsewhere, includ-ing in Amsterdam suburbs, it is easy to understandthe cable operators’ fears. Their old networks willhave a hard time once this happens, as they canhardly carry 30–100 Mb/s per household.

The city has taken on the responsibility for settingup an independent legal entity – CitynetAmsterdam – which will be the vehicle for theinvestment and own the passive network and willalso invest in the transport layer. Private partnershave been invited to supply the infrastructureequipment and operate the transport layer of thenetwork on an Open Access basis. The structure isno doubt influenced by the debate around cityinvolvement, but also EU state aid rules and EUdevelopment funds. An express part of the pur-pose of creating the network is to create low pricesfor users.

As the cases of Amsterdam and UTOPIA show,municipal networks are the subject of intense policydebates. However the ideas can be adjusted to dif-ferent competition rules and other national andinternational requirements, making whatever theydo not only legal but also eligible for developmentfunding.

Besides making fiber available for other serviceproviders, there is also a growing trend amongheavy users of communication services, such asbanks, data processing centers and universities, torun their own operations by just renting the “dark”fiber. Several EU universities actually run consider-able research traffic entirely on their own betweencampuses and often across borders. The volumesmay be low or sporadic, but their capacities are insome cases far more than what their entire countryhad in Internet traffic just a few years ago.

In many cases this is no more complex than run-ning the LAN inside the campus. For a heavy user

with the required skills, there is no point in involvingan operator to connect a few sites that are relativelyclose (20–50 km apart) if there is a competitivelypriced dark fiber around. Stokab, mentioned above,has business with 50 plus operators, but also con-siderable business with end customers just wantinga dark fiber from A to B in the metro area. This isan example of how customers are integrating back-wards when technology becomes cheap. A pair of20 km 1 Gigabyte (Gb) communication cards is nomore expensive than an operator sales call. Serviceoperators cannot take anything for granted abouttheir market position even if they have been helpedwith cheap fiber.

It is also notable that many U.S. municipal initia-tives being contemplated do not tend to deploymuch fiber and are more likely to use wireless as ameans of access than their European counterparts.U.S. demographics are no doubt a strong elementin this: U.S. suburbs sprawl out and rural areas arethinly populated. In that sense the parallels withrural Africa are closer than with say, the denselypopulated urban Netherlands. Also with places likethe rural inland area of northern Sweden andFinland, where population density equals thatfound in the Sahara desert, wireless is a strongcomplement to fiber as the means of access.

A5.5 The case of state finance(ATLAS)In Europe, the case of the ATLAS network inScotland is also illustrative of the policy issuesinvolved. The investment of state aid through aScottish development agency for a business-parkoriented broadband roll-out, an associated regionalhub and back-haul to a major hub, spurred formalquestions to the European Commission (EC). Itsimmediate response was that any network usingstate aid needed to be for “the common good” andwas only justifiable if no one else was going tobuild the network. It later also reiterated that theremust be open access to the infrastructure built toall players on an equal basis and that structuralfunds must only be used to build the lower layers,essentially the physical layer. This prompted con-siderable redesign and a more limited scope.

The EC is expected to publish a policy paper laterthis year addressing questions of how to define theextent of market failure and the involvement ofpublic money in these instances. In the meantime,

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 44

44 . Open Access Models

more developed market. The cable TV companies,like the telco, wish to modernize their networks tooffer “triple play”. The upgrades are more related tothe electronics than a massive transition from twist-ed pair or coaxial cable to fiber. A competing fiberstructure will no doubt remove any relative advan-tage the two have over non-facilities based competi-tors but also change their relative positions.

With HDTV being close to deployment over IP infiber-based alternative networks elsewhere, includ-ing in Amsterdam suburbs, it is easy to understandthe cable operators’ fears. Their old networks willhave a hard time once this happens, as they canhardly carry 30–100 Mb/s per household.

The city has taken on the responsibility for settingup an independent legal entity – CitynetAmsterdam – which will be the vehicle for theinvestment and own the passive network and willalso invest in the transport layer. Private partnershave been invited to supply the infrastructureequipment and operate the transport layer of thenetwork on an Open Access basis. The structure isno doubt influenced by the debate around cityinvolvement, but also EU state aid rules and EUdevelopment funds. An express part of the pur-pose of creating the network is to create low pricesfor users.

As the cases of Amsterdam and UTOPIA show,municipal networks are the subject of intense policydebates. However the ideas can be adjusted to dif-ferent competition rules and other national andinternational requirements, making whatever theydo not only legal but also eligible for developmentfunding.

Besides making fiber available for other serviceproviders, there is also a growing trend amongheavy users of communication services, such asbanks, data processing centers and universities, torun their own operations by just renting the “dark”fiber. Several EU universities actually run consider-able research traffic entirely on their own betweencampuses and often across borders. The volumesmay be low or sporadic, but their capacities are insome cases far more than what their entire countryhad in Internet traffic just a few years ago.

In many cases this is no more complex than run-ning the LAN inside the campus. For a heavy user

with the required skills, there is no point in involvingan operator to connect a few sites that are relativelyclose (20–50 km apart) if there is a competitivelypriced dark fiber around. Stokab, mentioned above,has business with 50 plus operators, but also con-siderable business with end customers just wantinga dark fiber from A to B in the metro area. This isan example of how customers are integrating back-wards when technology becomes cheap. A pair of20 km 1 Gigabyte (Gb) communication cards is nomore expensive than an operator sales call. Serviceoperators cannot take anything for granted abouttheir market position even if they have been helpedwith cheap fiber.

It is also notable that many U.S. municipal initia-tives being contemplated do not tend to deploymuch fiber and are more likely to use wireless as ameans of access than their European counterparts.U.S. demographics are no doubt a strong elementin this: U.S. suburbs sprawl out and rural areas arethinly populated. In that sense the parallels withrural Africa are closer than with say, the denselypopulated urban Netherlands. Also with places likethe rural inland area of northern Sweden andFinland, where population density equals thatfound in the Sahara desert, wireless is a strongcomplement to fiber as the means of access.

A5.5 The case of state finance(ATLAS)In Europe, the case of the ATLAS network inScotland is also illustrative of the policy issuesinvolved. The investment of state aid through aScottish development agency for a business-parkoriented broadband roll-out, an associated regionalhub and back-haul to a major hub, spurred formalquestions to the European Commission (EC). Itsimmediate response was that any network usingstate aid needed to be for “the common good” andwas only justifiable if no one else was going tobuild the network. It later also reiterated that theremust be open access to the infrastructure built toall players on an equal basis and that structuralfunds must only be used to build the lower layers,essentially the physical layer. This prompted con-siderable redesign and a more limited scope.

The EC is expected to publish a policy paper laterthis year addressing questions of how to define theextent of market failure and the involvement ofpublic money in these instances. In the meantime,

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 44

Appendices . 45

becomes more of an issue for central governmentand implementation a local responsibility. In coun-tries with weak structures this may be both goodand bad. The championing of networks of thiskind may help to drive broader competition andmodernization agendas at city and district levels.On the down side, there are awkward issues aroundpolitical patronage and corruption that will need tobe looked at when considering the success of anymodel proposed. The most obvious route is toensure that end-users are involved in the gover-nance, giving them a strong incentive not to cheat.

A5.6 Arguments for and againstmunicipal networksIn the United States, there are bills mandating localreferendums. Others under consideration wouldforce the municipalities to ask the historic opera-tors “permission” to build the networks to substan-tiate that there is “market failure.” But because ofambiguities surrounding the circumstances whenthis is deemed to have occurred, it may not actuallyencourage roll-out from either party. Those arguingagainst municipal networks in the United States saythat there is no market failure whatsoever and themunicipalities (and others) should allow the marketto operate effectively by just staying out of it.

The fact that municipalities are more involved inthe lower layers of telecommunication is also illus-trated by a recent report to the mayor of New York,the world’s most dense telecom market. This reportcalls for the city’s involvement, including makingfunds available, in creating lateral conduit in thestreets of Manhattan for all operators to use, sup-porting hubs and redundant fiber rings, and alsoproviding tax breaks for dual fiber cable entries andrisers in large buildings.

The debate over the financial effectiveness ofmunicipal build-outs has clearly been clearly dis-torted by supporters and opponents, each having aproblem with the view the other takes of the U.S.telecoms industry.

Opponents claim that municipal networks are afinancial disaster since they are not generatingimmediate profits. Also, as they have access tocheaper funds than private investors, they haveunfair advantage of cheap Right-of -Way, less redtape in the administration, and so on.

the ATLAS ruling and the EU DG RegionalGuidelines must be considered key elements in the use of any EU public funds into telecoms forregional development. Both stress involvement inlower layers only and open access.

For the purposes of developing country discussions,the key policy issues are clear. In most developingcountries (particularly in Africa) there are no com-peting infrastructure providers: for example, cableTV operators. If a municipal network is considereda useful option, it would be important to tenderfor its development to allow any potential privateinvestors to step forward and clarify their inten-tions at that point. In addition, mergers of the stateassets of other fiber providers and those of the his-toric operator should be considered.

If the network constructed stays at the transportlayer, or below, and if it offers open and fair accessto all then it would clear the two policy tests set bythe European Commission. Circumstances in theUnited States are much more complicated for thepurposes of comparison because of the existence offederal, state and local levels of government andalso separate regulatory frameworks for each sector(phone, cable TV, and broadcast).The Open Accessapproach does not seek to emulate particularnational circumstances but draws upon best practiceas it develops.

For European donors, the issues raised by the EUjudgment on ATLAS are important. Any contribu-tion they make to infrastructure developmentwould have to follow the principles outlined bybroader EC policy on these issues.

However, in the new market with an ever-increasingvertical separation; fixed and wireless access;bundling of services in new ways; and a growingnumber of players in complex relations, donors mustfind sustainable principles when considering sectorsupport. It is highly unlikely that these will differ agreat deal from what has been found in those coun-tries where public money has been injected to speedup Broadband availability after the liberalization ofthe market.

Supporting local involvement in roll-out will alsocreate a different division of roles for central andlocal governments. The rules and regulation

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 45

Appendices . 45

becomes more of an issue for central governmentand implementation a local responsibility. In coun-tries with weak structures this may be both goodand bad. The championing of networks of thiskind may help to drive broader competition andmodernization agendas at city and district levels.On the down side, there are awkward issues aroundpolitical patronage and corruption that will need tobe looked at when considering the success of anymodel proposed. The most obvious route is toensure that end-users are involved in the gover-nance, giving them a strong incentive not to cheat.

A5.6 Arguments for and againstmunicipal networksIn the United States, there are bills mandating localreferendums. Others under consideration wouldforce the municipalities to ask the historic opera-tors “permission” to build the networks to substan-tiate that there is “market failure.” But because ofambiguities surrounding the circumstances whenthis is deemed to have occurred, it may not actuallyencourage roll-out from either party. Those arguingagainst municipal networks in the United States saythat there is no market failure whatsoever and themunicipalities (and others) should allow the marketto operate effectively by just staying out of it.

The fact that municipalities are more involved inthe lower layers of telecommunication is also illus-trated by a recent report to the mayor of New York,the world’s most dense telecom market. This reportcalls for the city’s involvement, including makingfunds available, in creating lateral conduit in thestreets of Manhattan for all operators to use, sup-porting hubs and redundant fiber rings, and alsoproviding tax breaks for dual fiber cable entries andrisers in large buildings.

The debate over the financial effectiveness ofmunicipal build-outs has clearly been clearly dis-torted by supporters and opponents, each having aproblem with the view the other takes of the U.S.telecoms industry.

Opponents claim that municipal networks are afinancial disaster since they are not generatingimmediate profits. Also, as they have access tocheaper funds than private investors, they haveunfair advantage of cheap Right-of -Way, less redtape in the administration, and so on.

the ATLAS ruling and the EU DG RegionalGuidelines must be considered key elements in the use of any EU public funds into telecoms forregional development. Both stress involvement inlower layers only and open access.

For the purposes of developing country discussions,the key policy issues are clear. In most developingcountries (particularly in Africa) there are no com-peting infrastructure providers: for example, cableTV operators. If a municipal network is considereda useful option, it would be important to tenderfor its development to allow any potential privateinvestors to step forward and clarify their inten-tions at that point. In addition, mergers of the stateassets of other fiber providers and those of the his-toric operator should be considered.

If the network constructed stays at the transportlayer, or below, and if it offers open and fair accessto all then it would clear the two policy tests set bythe European Commission. Circumstances in theUnited States are much more complicated for thepurposes of comparison because of the existence offederal, state and local levels of government andalso separate regulatory frameworks for each sector(phone, cable TV, and broadcast).The Open Accessapproach does not seek to emulate particularnational circumstances but draws upon best practiceas it develops.

For European donors, the issues raised by the EUjudgment on ATLAS are important. Any contribu-tion they make to infrastructure developmentwould have to follow the principles outlined bybroader EC policy on these issues.

However, in the new market with an ever-increasingvertical separation; fixed and wireless access;bundling of services in new ways; and a growingnumber of players in complex relations, donors mustfind sustainable principles when considering sectorsupport. It is highly unlikely that these will differ agreat deal from what has been found in those coun-tries where public money has been injected to speedup Broadband availability after the liberalization ofthe market.

Supporting local involvement in roll-out will alsocreate a different division of roles for central andlocal governments. The rules and regulation

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 45

46 . Open Access Models

APPENDIX A6: GLOSSARYOF TERMSTerms are listed in alphabetical order:

Accounting rate system: This is the mechanismfor sharing the cost for international calls betweenthe sending and receiving carriers in each country,so that each side pays half of the cost of the inter-national circuit.

IP network: Short for Internet Protocol. IP speci-fies the format of packets, also called datagrams,and the addressing scheme. Most networks combineIP with a higher-level protocol called TransmissionControl Protocol (TCP), which establishes a virtualconnection between a destination and a source. IPby itself is something like the postal system. Itallows you to address a package and drop it in thesystem, but there’s no direct link between you andthe recipient. TCP/IP, on the other hand, establishesa connection between two hosts so that they cansend messages back and forth for a period of time.The current version of IP is IPv4. A new version,called IPv6 or IPng, is under development.

CDMA: Short for Code-Division Multiple Access, adigital cellular technology that uses spread-spectrumtechniques. Unlike competing systems, such asGSM, that use TDMA, CDMA does not assign aspecific frequency to each user. Instead, every chan-nel uses the full available spectrum. Individual con-versations are encoded with a pseudo-random digitalsequence.

EDGE: Acronym for Enhanced Data GSMEnvironment. EDGE is a faster version of GSMwireless service. EDGE enables data to be deliveredat rates up to 384 Kbps on a broadband. The stan-dard is based on the GSM standard and usesTDMA multiplexing technology.

Triple-play: Internet, TV and telephony.

VoIP: Voice over Internet Protocol which allowspeople to use the internet as a transmission medi-um for telephone connections.

VSAT: Short for very small aperture terminal, anearthbound station used in satellite communicationsof data, voice and video signals, excluding broadcasttelevision. A VSAT consists of two parts, a transceiver

Supporters point out that it is a long term invest-ment in passive infrastructure over 15–25 years andthat it will take 5–7 years to start making money.Furthermore, they cite the example of Cable TVoperators who needed 5–10 years to get profitable.Their key point is that you simply cannot getimmediate profitability in a network industry untilthe larger part of the network is built and there is acritical volume of customers as takers of the service.

The other key difference between the two sides isthat the overall goal for the municipal network isnot to maximize profit for its owner as soon as pos-sible, but to keep its own profits low in order tooffer low rates to users. In effect, the municipal net-works see themselves as acting as proxies for users.

The financial benefit of cheaper capital was ofmore importance in the high interest rate economyof a decade ago. Today it is overshadowed bydemographics (average cable length per homepassed), take rate and operational efficiency. It istrue that there is a cost advantage to close opera-tional cooperation with another network utility inthe area, but civil works remain the lion’s share ofthe investment.

However, the key issue remains whether the munici-pal network can generate enough trust with the otherplayers higher up the value chain to make theminvest and compete on their levels. If it can, the accu-mulated revenues of all the service providers will behigher than for an individual provider because endusers want to have choices. Therefore the co-utilizationof the underlying infrastructure will be better for acommonly-held municipal network.

This is the main factor that significantly influencesthe equation one way or the other. Technologychoices and operational skills will be less significantif it is assumed that the operation will be run byprofessionals. A poor level of revenue in low popu-lation density areas cannot be compensated for byother factors. As making ends meet is difficult evenin high income, high density areas it is an issue inmany places as to how to proactively get a betterinfrastructure out for all private investor serviceoperators to compete on. The inevitable question isto what extent should this be subsidized when thebusiness plans for this type of municipal networklacks short-term revenues and may even have rev-enue difficulties in the medium to long-term?

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 46

46 . Open Access Models

APPENDIX A6: GLOSSARYOF TERMSTerms are listed in alphabetical order:

Accounting rate system: This is the mechanismfor sharing the cost for international calls betweenthe sending and receiving carriers in each country,so that each side pays half of the cost of the inter-national circuit.

IP network: Short for Internet Protocol. IP speci-fies the format of packets, also called datagrams,and the addressing scheme. Most networks combineIP with a higher-level protocol called TransmissionControl Protocol (TCP), which establishes a virtualconnection between a destination and a source. IPby itself is something like the postal system. Itallows you to address a package and drop it in thesystem, but there’s no direct link between you andthe recipient. TCP/IP, on the other hand, establishesa connection between two hosts so that they cansend messages back and forth for a period of time.The current version of IP is IPv4. A new version,called IPv6 or IPng, is under development.

CDMA: Short for Code-Division Multiple Access, adigital cellular technology that uses spread-spectrumtechniques. Unlike competing systems, such asGSM, that use TDMA, CDMA does not assign aspecific frequency to each user. Instead, every chan-nel uses the full available spectrum. Individual con-versations are encoded with a pseudo-random digitalsequence.

EDGE: Acronym for Enhanced Data GSMEnvironment. EDGE is a faster version of GSMwireless service. EDGE enables data to be deliveredat rates up to 384 Kbps on a broadband. The stan-dard is based on the GSM standard and usesTDMA multiplexing technology.

Triple-play: Internet, TV and telephony.

VoIP: Voice over Internet Protocol which allowspeople to use the internet as a transmission medi-um for telephone connections.

VSAT: Short for very small aperture terminal, anearthbound station used in satellite communicationsof data, voice and video signals, excluding broadcasttelevision. A VSAT consists of two parts, a transceiver

Supporters point out that it is a long term invest-ment in passive infrastructure over 15–25 years andthat it will take 5–7 years to start making money.Furthermore, they cite the example of Cable TVoperators who needed 5–10 years to get profitable.Their key point is that you simply cannot getimmediate profitability in a network industry untilthe larger part of the network is built and there is acritical volume of customers as takers of the service.

The other key difference between the two sides isthat the overall goal for the municipal network isnot to maximize profit for its owner as soon as pos-sible, but to keep its own profits low in order tooffer low rates to users. In effect, the municipal net-works see themselves as acting as proxies for users.

The financial benefit of cheaper capital was ofmore importance in the high interest rate economyof a decade ago. Today it is overshadowed bydemographics (average cable length per homepassed), take rate and operational efficiency. It istrue that there is a cost advantage to close opera-tional cooperation with another network utility inthe area, but civil works remain the lion’s share ofthe investment.

However, the key issue remains whether the munici-pal network can generate enough trust with the otherplayers higher up the value chain to make theminvest and compete on their levels. If it can, the accu-mulated revenues of all the service providers will behigher than for an individual provider because endusers want to have choices. Therefore the co-utilizationof the underlying infrastructure will be better for acommonly-held municipal network.

This is the main factor that significantly influencesthe equation one way or the other. Technologychoices and operational skills will be less significantif it is assumed that the operation will be run byprofessionals. A poor level of revenue in low popu-lation density areas cannot be compensated for byother factors. As making ends meet is difficult evenin high income, high density areas it is an issue inmany places as to how to proactively get a betterinfrastructure out for all private investor serviceoperators to compete on. The inevitable question isto what extent should this be subsidized when thebusiness plans for this type of municipal networklacks short-term revenues and may even have rev-enue difficulties in the medium to long-term?

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 46

Appendices . 47

802.11 network, whether 802.11b, 802.11a, dual-band, etc. The term is promulgated by the Wi-FiAlliance. Any products tested and approved as“Wi-Fi Certified” (a registered trademark) by theWi-Fi Alliance are certified as interoperable witheach other, even if they are from different manufac-turers. A user with a “Wi-Fi Certified” product canuse any brand of access point with any other brandof client hardware that also is certified. Typically,however, any Wi-Fi product using the same radiofrequency (for example, 2.4 GHz for 802.11b or11g, 5 GHz for 802.11a) will work with any other,even if not “Wi-Fi Certified.”

Wi-MAX: Wi-MAX is the trade name for a familyof new technologies related to the IEEE 802.16wireless standards. Wi-MAX has the potential forvery long range (5–30 miles) and high speeds.

that is placed outdoors in direct line of sight to thesatellite and a device that is placed indoors to inter-face the transceiver with the end user’s communica-tions device, such as a PC. The transceiver receivesor sends a signal to a satellite transponder in the sky.The satellite sends and receives signals from aground station computer that acts as a hub for thesystem. Each end user is interconnected with thehub station via the satellite, forming a star topology.The hub controls the entire operation of the net-work. For one end user to communicate withanother, each transmission has to first go to the hubstation that then retransmits it via the satellite to theother end user’s VSAT. Although this is the mostcommon topology, others have been developed.

Wi-Fi: Short for wireless fidelity and is meant to beused generically when referring of any type of

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 47

Appendices . 47

802.11 network, whether 802.11b, 802.11a, dual-band, etc. The term is promulgated by the Wi-FiAlliance. Any products tested and approved as“Wi-Fi Certified” (a registered trademark) by theWi-Fi Alliance are certified as interoperable witheach other, even if they are from different manufac-turers. A user with a “Wi-Fi Certified” product canuse any brand of access point with any other brandof client hardware that also is certified. Typically,however, any Wi-Fi product using the same radiofrequency (for example, 2.4 GHz for 802.11b or11g, 5 GHz for 802.11a) will work with any other,even if not “Wi-Fi Certified.”

Wi-MAX: Wi-MAX is the trade name for a familyof new technologies related to the IEEE 802.16wireless standards. Wi-MAX has the potential forvery long range (5–30 miles) and high speeds.

that is placed outdoors in direct line of sight to thesatellite and a device that is placed indoors to inter-face the transceiver with the end user’s communica-tions device, such as a PC. The transceiver receivesor sends a signal to a satellite transponder in the sky.The satellite sends and receives signals from aground station computer that acts as a hub for thesystem. Each end user is interconnected with thehub station via the satellite, forming a star topology.The hub controls the entire operation of the net-work. For one end user to communicate withanother, each transmission has to first go to the hubstation that then retransmits it via the satellite to theother end user’s VSAT. Although this is the mostcommon topology, others have been developed.

Wi-Fi: Short for wireless fidelity and is meant to beused generically when referring of any type of

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 47

48 . Open Access Models

About infoDev

infoDev is a partnership of international development agencies, coordinated and served by an expert Secretariathoused at the World Bank, one of its key donors and founders. It acts as a neutral convener of dialogue, and as acoordinator of joint action among bilateral and multilateral donors—supporting global sharing of information on ICT fordevelopment (ICT4D), and helping to reduce duplication of efforts and investments. infoDev also forms partnerships withpublic and private-sector organizations who are innovators in the field of ICT4D.

For more information visit www.infoDev.org or send an email to [email protected]

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 48

48 . Open Access Models

About infoDev

infoDev is a partnership of international development agencies, coordinated and served by an expert Secretariathoused at the World Bank, one of its key donors and founders. It acts as a neutral convener of dialogue, and as acoordinator of joint action among bilateral and multilateral donors—supporting global sharing of information on ICT fordevelopment (ICT4D), and helping to reduce duplication of efforts and investments. infoDev also forms partnerships withpublic and private-sector organizations who are innovators in the field of ICT4D.

For more information visit www.infoDev.org or send an email to [email protected]

Open access 2-27-07.qxd 2/27/07 1:11 PM Page 48

www.infoDev.org

Information for Development Program

www.infoDev.org

OPEN ACCESS MODELS Options for Improving Backbone Access in Developing Countries

OPEN

AC

CESS M

OD

ELS

+ ACCESS FOR ALL