museum_networks

Upload: batakoja-meri

Post on 06-Apr-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    1/30

    MUSEUM AND THEATRE NETWORKS IN

    ITALY:DETERMINANTS AND TYPOLOGY

    By Silvia Bagdadli

    Working Paper N. 86/03

    February 2003

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    2/30

    MUSEUM AND THEATRE NETWORKS IN ITALY:

    DETERMINANTS AND TYPOLOGY

    bySilvia Bagdadli

    Working Paper N. 86/03

    February 2003

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    3/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division1

    Museum and Theatre Networks in Italy:

    Determinants and Typology

    Silvia Bagdadli

    Working paper

    Bocconi University

    Tel. 0039-02-5836.2629

    [email protected]

    Abstract

    This study is about cooperation among cultural organizations and specifically among

    Italian museums and theatres. Thanks to a research carried out through multiple case

    studies, we defined a typology of cultural networks, comparing museum and theatrical

    networks. In order to define a typology we refer to different organisational variables,

    including: coordination mechanisms, size, centralisation and density. Then we studied

    the determinants of cultural networks and again we compared museum and theatrical

    networks. In order to understand the determinants we tested three different theories or

    explanations: 1) efficiency; 2) process theory and institutional theory and 3) resource

    complementarity. Results showed two very different forms of networks. The first one,

    defined as vertical network, centralised, formalised, scarcely connected, often

    motivated by surviving needs of each individual organisation and allowing members to

    obtain cost advantages and this is in effect the main reason for aggregation. The second

    one, the horizontal network, diffused only among theatres, motivated by the possibility

    of improving the systems quality and of innovating and exchanging resources.

    Keywords: networks; cultural organizations; museums; theatres; determinants;

    typology.

    JEL Codes: M19, Z11.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    4/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division2

    1. Introduction (1)

    It seems ridiculous that if you have a dozen organisations, each producing a small

    number of events every year, you also have a dozen executive directors, a dozen office

    leases, a dozen marketing department. None of the organisations can really afford to

    engage as much staff as it needs. These words belong to Eugene Carr, Director of the

    American Symphony Orchestra (ASO) in San Francisco (Scheff and Kotler, 1996: 6). If

    this is true for an organisation of such dimension and prestige, it will also certainly be

    true for each of the about 2,000 Italian theatres (SIAE 1998), most of which located in

    small urban areas. The same might be said for Italian museums: approximately 3,450,

    excluding archaeological sites, most of which are of a small dimension and located not

    only in the famous and large monumental cities (Florence, Venice or Rome) but

    virtually in all towns (Bagdadli, 1997).

    This concise picture, concerning two of the most important Italian cultural

    sectors, allows us to introduce the theme of cooperation among cultural institutions

    achieved through networks. The term network has come into vogue in describing

    contemporary organisations, from large multinationals to small entrepreneurial firms,

    from emerging industries such as entertainment or bio-technology to more traditional

    industries. In this research we consider networks as modes of organising economic

    activities through inter-firm coordination and cooperation. A network is defined as a set

    of cooperative relations connecting autonomous entities (Powell and Smith Doerr,

    1994).

    This phenomenon has reached, during the last 20 years, a remarkable level of

    empirical relevance in all economic sectors (Soda, 1998). In this work we aim atunderstanding if networks may represent a possible solution to some of the Italian

    cultural sectors many problems and critical areas.

    2. Research objectives and main propositions

    Research on networks, also called inter-organisational relations (IORs) has

    developed for years and has produced interesting and robust results in different

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    5/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division3

    disciplinary areas. Previous research on cultural networks (Paulus, 1993; Bagdadli,

    1995, 1997; Salvemini et al ,1999; Scheff and Kotler, 1996) has showed some important

    results; but, as far as Italian cultural networks are concerned, more systematic research

    is needed in order to understand if the network form has actually developed and, if so,

    how and why it has developed.

    The objective of the present research is twofold. First of all, given the scarcity of

    specific research, the study has the preliminary purpose of understanding if and how the

    network organisation is utilised in the cultural sector and, specifically, among Italian

    museums and theatres. We will try, in this direction, to define a typology of cultural

    networks, comparing museum and theatrical networks. In order to define a typology we

    refer to different organisational variables, including: coordination mechanisms

    (Grandori and Soda, 1995), size, centralisation and density.

    The studys second objective is to understand the determinants of cultural

    networks and to compare the determinants in the two sectors. In order to understand the

    determinants we tested three different theories or explanations: 1) efficiency; 2) process

    theory and institutional theory and 3) resource complementarity.

    The research areas and the propositions formulated in this work derive from an

    analysis of the theoretical and empirical literature on networks, and from specific

    research on theatre and museum networks.

    A recent research on 13 production theatres located in Milan (Salvemini et al.,

    1999), undertaken with the purpose of investigating the potential for development of a

    city network, allowed US to understand the specific characteristics of large production

    theatres, to explain the complexities and rigidities that may prevent theatres from acting

    as a system, and also to identify areas for potential cooperation. A case study research,Accademia Perduta Romagna Teatri (Bagdadli, 1995) provided an analysis of the

    potential benefits generated by the network form, and a better understanding of the

    complexities affecting Italian small and medium-sized provincial theatres.

    As far as museums are concerned, a research carried on in France (Paulus, 1993), a

    different one carried on in England (AA.VV., 2000) and some case studies concerning

    museum networks previously analysed by the author of this work (Bagdadli 1995 and

    1997) allowed the development of specific hypotheses in the museums field.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    6/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division4

    2.1 A typology of cultural networks

    A first objective of this work is to define a typology of theatre networks, by utilising

    the classification proposed by Grandori and Soda (1995) based on the coordination

    mechanisms utilised. Based on such approach, networks may belong to three different

    typologies: social networks, bureaucratic networks or proprietary networks.

    Bureaucratic networks are those inter-firm coordination modes that are formalised

    in exchange or associational contractual agreements (ibidem: 201). In general,

    bureaucratic networks are developed for the purpose of managing information

    complexity (Grandori, 1995). In the Italian cultural industry, considering the size and

    relevance of public financing, one might expect a bureaucratic network to be more

    frequently used in those cases where the adoption of a particular contractual form is

    prescribed by law or anyway necessary to gain access to public funds. The bureaucratic

    network, therefore, is a need imposed by the regulatory environment rather than a

    reaction to information complexity.

    When such conditions do not occur we hypothesise the existence of networks based

    on pre-existing interpersonal and social relations, characterised by reciprocity,

    information sharing and trust (Barney and Ouchi, 1985).

    P1. Bureaucratic networks become necessary for cultural organisations when

    such is a condition for access to public (often, government) financing, or when

    this is imposed by specific legislation. In all other cases social-type networks,

    scarcely formalised, will prevail.

    Previous research in the performing art sector (Salvemini et al., 1999; Bagdadli,

    1995; Scheff and Kotler, 1999) and in the cultural sector (museums, monuments andgalleries) (Bagdadli, 1997 and 2001) allowed the identification of two macro-areas for

    potential cooperation: the artistic area and the administrative area. Within theatres, the

    first one includes the planning of performance seasons, the selection of artists and all

    decisions concerning the shows arrangement; within museums, it includes study and

    research, the set up of inventories and catalogues, preservation and restoration, the

    exhibition of the permanent collection, temporary exhibitions, and education. The

    second one includes personnel administration, the management of the administrative

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    7/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division5

    aspects associated with exhibitions and theatre performances, promotion,

    communication and fund raising, distribution and hospitality and general services. The

    above mentioned studies shown how theatres and museums may generally tend to avoid

    cooperation when their artistic decisions and choices are in play. In Van de Vens

    words, organisations do not coordinate for coordinations sake. Instead, organisation

    strain to maintain their autonomy (Van de Ven, 1976: 28). This is particularly true

    when the critical function is in play, the artistic function in our case.

    In this research we hypothesise that organisations will externalise more

    frequently to the network all those activities that are not related to the artistic function,

    obviously provided the theatre or the museum does have an artistic director and an

    operating structure.

    P2. Cooperation will more frequently take place for those activities or services

    which are not related to artistic decisions, provided the skills necessary to take

    choices in the artistic area are available to the organisation.

    We have, in addition, tried to characterise the network in terms of dimension

    (number of nodes linked to the network), to identify the possible existence of central

    agents making a distinction between centralised and parithetic networks, to measure

    the intensity of the relations among nodes (connectivity) (Bavelas, 1951) and to

    understand if there is a relation between the organisational form adopted and the type

    of activities that are jointly managed (ibidem).

    P3. Networks that provide services in areas where economies of scale are

    possible (structured activities), and mainly in the administrative area, will be

    more frequently associated with large dimensions, centralisation and low

    connectivity. To the contrary, networks that are more innovation-oriented (non-structured activity) and whose aim is to stimulate cooperation in the artistic area

    will more frequently be smaller, balanced and more intensely connected.

    2.2 Network determinants: a comparison among different theories

    A large part of the research on networks has investigated the reasons and

    determinants that lead to the creation of networks. Different organisational theories have

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    8/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division6

    formulated explanations that appear sometimes conflicting, sometimes complementary

    (see Soda, 1998, chapter 4, for a complete review of such theories). For the purposes of

    this research we have made a comparison among three principal categories, each of

    them comprising one or more theoretical explanations. Our objective is to understand

    whether a prevailing one exists, i.e. one capable of better explaining the phenomenon of

    cooperation among theatres and museums, or if to the contrary all three explanations

    are equally viable.

    a) Economic efficiency

    The first category explains the adoption of a network form on the basis of a rationale

    related to economic and organisational efficiency. It has been developed, among various

    authors, by Williamson (1975 and 1985), Teece (1980), Barney and Ouchi (1985),

    Mariotti and Cainara (1986). The key parameter is organisational efficiency, in terms of

    production costs as well as in terms of transaction costs.

    The structural lack of resources in the sector, the weakness of economic results,

    the lack of productivity improvements across centuries (Baumol and Baumol, 1993) and

    the small dimension of many Italian cultural institutions often associated with the

    absence of personnel with management skills bring to think that this explanation may

    be the one most frequently applicable, especially for small institutions and in those

    cases where a standardisation of activities is possible.

    P4. Cooperation among cultural organisations is determined by the search for a

    higher level of economic efficiency through economies of scale.

    b) Process explanation

    The theory oriented towards a process explanation of cooperation affirms that theadoption of a network form is the result of processes of isomorphism, natural selection

    or mutual assistance based on organisational conditions such as similarity, reciprocity or

    the pre-existence of social relations (Wholey and Huonker, 1993; Baum and Oliver,

    1991). Similarity may concern various aspects: base values, product system,

    governance, geographic proximity. This similarity generates, among organisations, a

    fertile process for cooperation (Soda 1998). Based on the institutional theory (Zolber,

    1986; DiMaggio, 1991; DiMaggio and Powell, 1991; Scott, 1995) companies more

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    9/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division7

    frequently cooperate and take similar forms (isomorphism) when a specific purpose

    exists, such as obtaining authorisations, complying with rules (North, 1990) or gaining

    legitimacy and prestige (Oliver, 1990).

    As said, given the high level of bureaucracy in the sector, the recent tendency of

    cultural administrations to grant financing to projects jointly proposed by two or more

    institutions, and the existence of certain rules that push towards the creation of

    particular network forms (for instance, the distribution circuits for theatres

    Ministerial circular n. 25/1998), we expect to frequently observe that the creation of

    networks originates from the need to comply with specific legal requirements or to gain

    access through cooperation to financing otherwise not obtainable.

    P5a. The existence of rules at national level will facilitate the creation of

    networks, and will also generate a similarity among the forms of cooperation

    originated by this factor. The existence of rules at local level (region, province)

    will facilitate the creation of networks among cultural organisations located in a

    specified geographic area (in the same region or province).

    Furthermore, we expect a higher level of cooperation among similar institutions,

    for the following reasons. First of all a similarity in the form of governance simplifies

    cooperation, especially in a legislative context which is highly bureaucratic and that

    establishes different rules for different categories of institution; in addition, a similar

    economic and organisational structure (the absence of an artistic director, and of

    personnel dedicated to the management and administration of the theatre or museum)

    will normally facilitate cooperation as this will probably appear as the only way to carry

    on an organisations cultural activity; finally, proposing similar types of performances

    (for instance, drama) or having a homogeneous collection might facilitate forms of

    cooperation aimed at innovation or at improving the quality of the proposed shows andevents; sharing the same production ideals may generate a fall of the cultural barriers

    that prevent cooperation, hence a reduction of the pressure towards autonomy.

    P5b. Similarity among institutions facilitates cooperation among theatres.

    c) Availability of complementary resources

    In economic and strategic studies the existence of complementary resources is

    considered a key factor towards the formation of alliances. When complementary

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    10/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division8

    resources are idiosyncratic and indivisible, therefore not readily available in the market,

    alliances become a primary mean for the acquisition of such resources (Chung et al.,

    2000). Companies tend to cooperate to gain access to complementary resources or

    knowledge, for competitive purposes, to develop internal competencies or to share the

    risks of innovative activities (Haiken and Hage, 1968; Harrigan 1985; Gulati, 1995). A

    higher tendency to cooperate derives from the perception that sharing resources

    generates value for the organisations involved.

    As far as theatres are concerned, we hypothesise that such tendency is not

    particularly diffused for the reasons that follow. First of all, the sectors critical

    competencies i.e. the artistic competencies (scene designers, directors, actors) are

    readily available in the market on a temporary basis, provided the theatre does not

    already possess such resources on a stable basis; in this field we often observe a high

    level of similarity of resources, rather than complementarity, and this results in a

    reduced interest for cooperation. In the case of museums, on the one hand their

    resources profile tends to be similar and scarce, especially with respect to technical

    resources (space, machinery, etc.) and human resources; on the other hand, there is a

    potential complementarity with respect to their collections, resources that tend to be

    unique and therefore not readily available in the market.

    Therefore, a motivation to cooperate might be given by the possibility to organise

    events and exhibitions showing a larger and more complete range of works. Other

    critical resources, such as space, often are already saturated by the institutions

    production capacity and therefore they can seldom represent a reason to join forces. In

    addition, empirical research has shown that such determinant is particularly relevant in

    high tech industries (Sinha and Cusumano, 1991), where companies tend to seek

    alliances to innovate and reduce competitive pressures; on the contrary, as wementioned, personnel is the most important resource in the cultural sector, and the role

    played by technology is marginal. Furthermore, artistic creativity is conceived as an

    individual resource, sometimes not even belonging to an institution as a whole but just

    to an individual in that institution (as an example, we often mention the Streheler

    theatre, the Ronconi theatre and so on).

    P6. Complementarity in the resource profile facilitates cooperation among

    institutions.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    11/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division9

    In synthesis, we have hypothesised that in the cultural sector the economic and process

    determinants tend to prevail, whereas resource complementarity is less relevant.

    2.3 Methodology

    To explain how and why cultural networks developed in Italy we did a multiple

    case study research (Yin, 1994). This methodology, frequently utilised in the research

    on networks (among others, Alexander, 1981), is particularly helpful when the

    researcher is trying to address how and why type of issues (determinants and typology

    in our study) (ibidem: 6). The research included 18 cultural networks: 8 museum

    networks and 10 theatre networks.

    For each case study, different sources were examined: structured interviews and

    document sources. For each of the networks analysed we interviewed the network

    coordinator (if existing) and people in some of the systems nodes; the number of

    interviews was variable as a function of the type of system. We chose to carry on

    structured interviews rather than send questionnaires, considering that obtaining

    information in this sector may be complex given the little amount of time normally

    made available by the personnel involved, their scarce propensity to be the object of a

    research and the difficulties associated with the interpretation of some categories of

    analysis.

    The most complex part of the research was the identification of the networks

    existing in the Italian territory and therefore their selection. For identification purposes,

    we conducted a preliminary analysis that involved:

    persons responsible of the cultural sector in all Italian regions;

    persons responsible for the cultural sector in all provinces and municipalities wherea network or circuit exists;

    information gathered through the world wide web;

    interviews of various other players and institutional bodies;

    interviews of all those persons that were indicated as potential members of a

    network.

    The identification of the cases that we might study was very complex. According to

    the interviewed personnel, cooperation among cultural organisations is particularly

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    12/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division10

    difficult and this explains why the mere identification of forms of cooperation may be

    complex. Some of them see this as a form of parochialism typical of the Italian

    environment; others believe that, given the strong efforts dedicated to mere survival,

    little energies remain available for cooperation and innovation.

    As far as theatres are concerned, in almost all Italian regions (excluding Lombardy)

    we could find a specific form of network, below described in more detail, called

    Distribution circuit - recognised by the Ministry of Culture - and some other non-

    recognised Distribution circuits. We decided to analyse two of the circuits recognised

    by the Ministry, indicated by many sources as high quality circuits. We had to consider

    that, according to some experts from the sector, many circuits do not function properly;

    in fact, some of them have been put under administrative control, and some others are

    capable of providing just mediocre services. Some production companies have

    confirmed this information and therefore, considering that all circuits have similar ways

    of operating, we have chosen to investigate those that seem to operate with high

    managerial quality and efficiency; we also hope, thanks to such selection, to have

    minimised the likelihood of possible misrepresentations of reality by the interviewed

    persons. Similar criteria have been applied for the selection of non-recognised circuits.

    We have identified a small number of cases outside the world of recognised or non-

    recognised circuits, and we have excluded those that seemed to cooperate just for

    marginal activities. We also decided to include a network of opera theatres, although

    obviously such institutions activities are of a different nature; we did this mainly for the

    purpose of identifying the possible similarities between theatre and lyrical institutions

    and, on the other hand, the peculiarities associated with their different performances.

    The Lombardy Region Opera Circuit is anyway unique in the Italian landscape and

    may therefore be considered an exemplary case. This preliminary research, however,did not involve the various cases of co-production, that are widely diffused in the whole

    country, where two or more institutions agree to share the costs associated with

    planning, preparation and production but mainly for the purpose of reducing costs.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    13/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division11

    Exhibit 1 Theatre networks included in the research.

    THEATRE NETWORK LOCATION

    Arteven Region Veneto

    Amat Region Marche

    Teatro Stabile di Torino Region Piemonte

    Coordinamento teatrale trentino Region Trentino alto Adige

    Associazione teatrale pistoiese Province of Pistoia

    Altri percorsi Region Lombardia

    Sistema teatrale cremonese Province of Cremona

    Teatri metropolitani fiorentini City of Firenze

    Circuito di Rigo Sinfonico Region Lombardia

    Metropoli Province of Milan

    As far as museums are concerned, we have identified several initiatives,

    although most of them are still in the project phase. We have therefore decided to

    include only those cases that seemed beyond the project stage.

    Exhibit 2 Museum networks included in the research.

    MUSEUM NETWORKS LOCATION

    Il sistema museale carnico Province of Carnia

    Il circuito dei musei del centro di Milano City of Milano

    Bologna dei Musei City of Bologna

    Il sistema museale provinciale di Ravenna Province of Ravenna

    Il sistema dei musei senesi Province of Siena

    Musei della provincia di Modena Province of Modena

    Il sistema museale trentino Province of Trento

    Il sistema museale umbro Region Umbria

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    14/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division12

    3. Results and discussion

    3.1 Cultural networks: a typology

    It is appropriate, in elaborating a typology of cultural networks, to distinguish

    between museums and theatres.

    3.1.1Theatre networks

    For theatres, our analysis has identified the presence of two very different typical

    forms: centralised (vertical) networks, i.e. recognised and non-recognised distribution

    circuits, and parithetic (horizontal) networks. They are described in more detail here

    below.

    Centralised (vertical) networks: distribution circuits

    Distribution networks, historically, have been created and operate with the

    objective of diffusing culture in the country. Such networks may be created through

    private initiative (individuals whose aim is to provide a service to the various theatres)

    or through public initiative (two or more municipalities establish a consortium). Once

    the network is in place, any individual theatre may join by asking to do so and paying

    for the services that are necessary in the specific situation. This specific form of

    coordination, whose object is the distribution of shows, generates a multiplication of

    opportunities proportional to the number of theatres that form part of the circuit, to the

    advantage of production companies. Each of the theatres that participate into the circuit

    could not, in fact, afford on its own the costs of professional companies of a highquality; by joining a distribution circuit the theatre may externalise all the activities for

    which an ad hoc internal structure would be economically unfeasible. Generally,

    considerable cost savings are achieved by carrying on certain activities through an

    external structure operating for many theatres, thanks to the obvious economies of scale.

    Distribution networks normally provide the following services to their members:

    planning of the season for each individual theatre;

    promotion (joint as well as individual);

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    15/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division13

    supply of technical personnel for the opening of each hall;

    administrative management of the shows;

    reservations.

    The members require different services depending on their specific needs.

    In order to perform their tasks, circuits receive financing from private individuals,

    from the local authority, from the municipalities associated with them (often

    proportionally to the number of their inhabitants) and from the Ministry (provided they

    are recognised). Circuits may benefit from State grants provided they may satisfy the

    requirements established by art. 19 of the Circular n. 25/1998. Given such legal

    requirements, all recognised regional circuits tend to have the same characteristics and

    coordination mechanisms. They, in fact, take the form of bureaucratic networks, linked

    by association or consortium contracts, formalised through ministerial recognition,

    centralised, and characterised by a low level of connectivity between the systems

    members; only dual links appear to exist between the coordination unit (the circuit)

    and the individual theatres.

    Picture 1 Recognised circuits.

    The circuit normally tries to design the performing season in each individual

    theatre as a function of the perceived preferences of the local audience and of the

    requirements of the institution that owns the theatre; the circuit, in other words, does not

    try to impose a pre-packaged program. Normally a list of the possible performances is

    completed, and the list is sent to the municipalities that may propose a number of works

    Circuit

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    16/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division14

    within the list; a final choice is made on this basis, also in an attempt to optimise the

    program at the system level. Once the seasonal program is defined, the circuit may also

    follow the execution phase by ensuring that the companies perform their activities in

    appropriate locations, and by providing technical personnel if necessary.

    Two regional circuits in the Veneto (Arteven) and Marche (Amat) regions

    belong to this typology.

    Other non recognised circuits, therefore not entitled to government financing,

    operate as networks for performance distribution; they may utilise as coordinating entity

    a production structure, for instance a production theatre such as the theatre in the city of

    Torino, or a production company, such as the Pistoia system, or a local authority, as in

    the case of the Altri Percorsi circuit which is coordinated by the Lombardia regional

    authority.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    17/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division15

    Picture 2 Non recognised circuits.

    In terms of organisational typology, non recognised circuits are very similar to

    recognised circuits; they show a similar level of centralisation, a similarly low level of

    connectivity, and an almost total absence of relationship among the associated theatres.

    Their level of formalisation and the similarity of the organisational forms adopted are

    lower, as the absence of government recognition allows a higher level of autonomy.

    However, such circuits involve private theatres as well as theatres owned by local

    administrations, therefore in almost all cases the resulting relationships are formalised

    through conventions in order to facilitate the exchange of services. From this

    perspective, also non recognised circuits appear to be bureaucratic networks.

    With respect to the propositions that were formulated above (P1 and P2), this

    form of network confirms the presence of bureaucratic mechanisms in order to comply

    with existing rules; its high level of centralisation and low level of connectivity reflect

    the type of activities that are centralised.

    Parithetic (horizontal) networks

    As opposed to circuits, we may identify forms of cooperation among theatres

    that do not involve only the process of seasonal event planning for each individual

    theatre, carried on by an entity recognised as Circuit or by a different entity, or the

    circulation of shows within the circuit.

    The cases that are presented in this section are considerably different from the preceding

    ones, first of all based on the organisational form which is actually used.

    Production

    theatre

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    18/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division16

    Picture 3 Horizontal networks

    These networks normally show a low level of centralisation (2), they mainly

    represent forms of association between equals, they show a high level of connectivity,

    and the exchanges between members are frequent and involve all the systems nodes. In

    addition one may note a wider variety of forms, and a higher differentiation in the

    theatres dimensions and in the organisational solutions adopted. They normally involve

    a lower number of parties (typically between 3 and 10) (3) whereas the cases discussed

    before normally involved a number of parties comprised between 15 and 40. The areas

    of activity may also include the artistic function with respect to staging (Lombardia

    regional Opera Circuit, Teatri Metropolitani Fiorentini, Metropoli), the coordination of

    performing seasons (Sistema Cremonese, Teatri Metropolitani Fiorentini), and the

    selection of artists (Lombardia regional Opera Circuit). The relationships between

    members are often of an informal nature and project, idea and value sharing is strong.

    These networks have the shape of social rather than bureaucratic networks. This is inline with the type of activity that they carry on, which is less structured and more

    innovation-oriented (propositions P1 and P3 confirmed).

    Our analysis does not confirm the hypothesis that networks among those theatres

    that do have an artistic direction do not share artistic decisions; on the contrary, the level

    of cooperation is particularly high in the case of Lombardia regional Opera Circuit and

    in the Teatri Metropolitani Fiorentini case, networks where each theatre has a director.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    19/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division17

    Certainly, however, these two cases represent an exception, rather than the rule, in the

    Italian landscape.

    3.1.2 Museum networks

    As far as museums are concerned, eight cases analysed show many similarities;

    one might even say that they belong to one typology, with minimal variance in the

    sample. The main characteristics may be summarised as follows. First of all, we are

    dealing with bureaucratic networks, within which the relationships among the different

    parties are normally formalised through a convention an instrument that facilitates the

    access to public financing and, in general, the relationship among the institutions that

    are part of the public sector (P1 confirmed). The networks dimension is medium or

    large, with 25 museums for each system on average, with a minimum of 5 (Milano) and

    a maximum of 54 (Modena). They tend to be highly centralised, and are centred on a

    local authority which is also the main sponsor; for 5 systems the level of connectivity

    observed is low (semi-annual meetings) and medium for 3 systems (at least quarterly

    meetings). The networks mainly carry on activities aimed at valorisation, promotion,

    information and communication; in some cases the initial task of the system has been

    restoring, restructuring or re-opening museums (in this case with standardised settings)

    and publishing catalogues; the network normally carries on management and

    administration activities with respect to common projects. A centralisation of scientific

    activity appears to exist only for those systems whose organizations are not staffed with

    artistic personnel, as for instance in the Umbria system (P2 and P3 confirmed). Joint

    exhibitions are rare.

    The network which does not seem to fit the above description is the Milano Centronetwork, which is jointly promoted by museum directors and by the public

    administration, small, more connected and parithetic.

    3.2 Tests of propositions concerning determinants of cultural networks

    The proposition that economic efficiency is an important determinant for the

    establishment of networks is confirmed (P4). In all the 18 networks considered each

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    20/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division18

    individual organisation and the systems centre affirm that one of the reasons for the

    creation of the circuit is the possibility to achieve economic advantages; this, thanks to

    the economies of scale deriving from the centralisation of services, or thanks to the

    possibility of providing a larger range of services without a proportional increase in

    costs.

    Participating in the network is often the only possibility for the members to pursue

    their cultural objectives with acceptable quality standards; this is a consequence of the

    small scale of most of the associated institutions. Many of the interviewed institutions

    admit their inability to provide, on their own, the same services and the same quality

    standards; in many cases, without the participation in the network, they would simply

    not be capable to perform any activity (most museums and theatres were closed before

    the creation of the network).

    The possibility to share their audiences (therefore achieving a scale effect due to a

    higher number of visitors, or to a larger public) is a determinant indicated by all the

    museum networks; for theatres, it is indicated by the Teatri Metropolitani Fiorentini

    network, by the Cremona network and by the various Poles belonging to Metropoli; for

    the remaining theatre networks, the physical distance existing between the participating

    institutions does not allow an exchange. Certainly the exchange of the audience

    resource has an impact on economic efficiency, but we have interpreted it as an

    indicator of resource complementarity too, as the shared audience is certainly a critical

    resource.

    The propositions concerning the process explanation are also verified in all the

    cases analysed.

    Participating in the network normally determines a preferential access to public

    resources, granted in accordance with national and local laws that assign a priority tojoint projects.

    Also the proposition that the similarity between institutions is a facilitating

    condition for the creation of networks is confirmed (P5b). Similarity may concern

    different aspects. First of all, the analysed networks are homogeneous with respect to

    their geographic location we have regional or provincial or municipal networks, and

    this allows them to get the benefits of financing granted by the respective local authority

    (P5a). The sharing of common values is expressed, by the founders or members, as an

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    21/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division19

    intention to achieve a larger diffusion of culture in their territories without incurring

    often unbearable costs. Networking organisations are similar also with respect to their

    institutional characteristics: most theatres or museums are directly managed by

    municipalities, and many of them do not have personnel capable of contributing to the

    institutions cultural activities or to organisational tasks. For museums, the similarity

    between different networks is also a consequence of an isomorphism process (Baum and

    Oliver, 1991) and of a process of imitation between different cultural administrations;

    when designing local systems, the cultural administrators take decisions also by making

    comparisons with systems already existing in their region or in different regions.

    Resource complementarity, in the case of museums, does not represent a

    determinant for cooperation, also considering that networks are often sponsored by local

    administrators and include museums whose collections are not homogeneous.

    Identifying general conditions seems harder in the case of the four parithetic

    (horizontal) theatre networks. Despite some legal similarities between the networks

    theatres (for instance, belonging to the same category the theatres of tradition in the

    Lombardia regional Opera Circuit), the similarity often concerns the product system, i.e.

    the specific niche occupied (Van de Ven and Walker, 1984; Gulati, 1995). This

    facilitates the aggregation process through the sharing of common values, but the reason

    for aggregation is often identified as the complementarity of resources and the

    possibility to share a common know how (jointly with similarity or as an alternative to

    it). Complementarity of resources is, in effect, a reason for aggregation only in the case

    of horizontal theatre networks. In the case of Metropoli, for example, complementarity

    exists with respect to the cultural goods owned by other municipalities (churches,

    castles) that may be valorised through performances organised by other municipalities.In the case of the Teatri Metropolitani Fioentini system, space and competencies for

    production and distribution are complementary resources. In the Lombardia regional

    Opera Circuit, the chorus and the orchestra are complementary resources for the entire

    artistic production. For the Cremona system, the complementary resource is in a sense

    the audience; considering that the performed genres are different, but the theatres are

    geographically close and an incentive therefore exists to coordinate programs with the

    aim of increasing the systems overall audience. The same may be said for museum

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    22/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division20

    systems that try to share audience through forms of joint promotion. In most cases,

    however, the general scarcity of resources and the similarity of the resources available

    make this a secondary determinant.

    4. Conclusions

    As a conclusion, and to summarise the results of this work (Exhibit 3), two

    forms seem to surface from the cases analysed, very different between them in terms of

    both organisational type and determinants.

    Exhibit 3 Summary of the researchs results

    CASE STUDY TYPOLOGY RESEARCH PROPOSITIONS

    THEATRE NETWORKS

    ARTEVEN Vertical network (VN); high

    formalised (HF); low connectivity

    (LC); Bureaucratic network (BN); big

    dimension (BD)

    All confirmed

    AMAT VN; HF; LC; BN; BD All confirmed

    CIRCUITO TEATRALE DI TORINO VN; HF; LC; BN; BD All confirmed

    COORDINAMENTO TRENTINO VN; HF; LC; BN; BD All confirmed

    ASSOCIAZIONE PISTOIESE VN; HF; LC; BN; BD All confirmed

    ALTRI PERCORSI VN; HF; LC; BN; BD All confirmed

    SISTEMA CREMONESE Parithetic network (PN); LF; MC; SN;

    SD

    All confirmed except P2

    TEATRI METROPOLITANI

    FIORENTINI

    PN; LF; HC; SN; SD All confirmed except P2

    CIRCUITO D RIGO SINFONICO PN; LF; HC; SN; SD All confirmed except P2

    METROPOLI VN; LF; HfC; SN; BD All confirmed except P2

    MUSEUM NETWORKS

    CARNIA VN; HF; LC; BN; MD All confirmed

    REGIONE UMBRIA VN; HF; LC; BN; BD All confirmed

    SBOLOGNA VN; HF; LC; BN; BD All confirmed

    RAVENNA VN; HF; LC; BN; BD All confirmed

    PROVINCIA DI SIENA VN; HF; LC; BN; BD All confirmed

    MODENA VN; HF; LC; BN; BD All confirmed

    PROVINCIA DI TRENTO VN; HF; LC; BN; MD All confirmed

    MILANO PN; LF; HC; BN; SD All confirmed

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    23/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division21

    On the one side the study highlights those networks that we have defined

    vertical, theatre circuits, recognised or non-recognised, and museum systems. These

    centralised networks, formalised and scarcely connected are often motivated by

    surviving needs of each individual organisation. A participation in the network is, in

    many cases, the only possibility to perform an activity with continuity and with

    acceptable quality standards. The system allows members to obtain cost advantages and

    this is in effect the main reason for aggregation.

    On the other side, but only for theatres, we find horizontal networks, motivated

    by the possibility of improving the systems quality, of innovating and exchanging

    resources. Networks were created not only just for a survival strategy but for a

    competitive strategy at the systems level. Innovation and exchange of resources are

    part of the reasons that push in the aggregation direction. The logic is a systemic one.

    To this last category, as already noted, belong a minority of the analysed systems

    and anyway the cases identified in Italy are rather rare. We believe that, as of today, this

    form is not largely developed and that therefore strategies based on complementarity of

    resources are still not widely pursued (although they are not entirely absent); this will

    probably represent the evolution of networks in the cultural field; this will happen as

    soon as the sector reaches a more mature stage, and provided cooperation is perceived

    as a tool for innovation, success and access to critical resources.

    This second form of cooperation among institutions is certainly less diffused but

    probably it is also harder to identify, because of the small dimension of the entities

    involved and of the overall lower level of formalisation. We believe that future research

    should focus on the study of this second type of networks, trying to identify them by

    getting in direct contact with the cultural organisations. As a matter of fact, the mainlimit of this work lies in the means utilised for the identification of the cultural networks

    that operate in the Italian territory; as we said before, we used mainly contacts with

    local administration (region, province, municipalities); this limit is mitigated, however,

    by the fact that joint projects are often financed through public resources and therefore

    known to the local administrations.

    We believe that future research will be able to highlight many different examples

    of cooperation, beyond those analysed in this study; we also believe that the innovation

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    24/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division22

    capabilities of the Italian cultural sector will be largely improved by forms of

    cooperation among different cultural institutions. Some of the professionals operating in

    the cultural sector, trying to explain the low cooperation propensity that may be

    observed in the sector, believe that the interest to form strategic alliances is reduced by

    the same existence of public financing, and that this in turn is a limit to the sectors

    innovation potential. This because often the institutions efforts are mainly aimed at

    complying with the regulatory requirements imposed as a condition for access to public

    resources, which make survival possible; little room is therefore left for efforts aimed at

    generating new ideas and projects, closer to the potential audiences interests. This, in

    turn, reduces the institutions potential for true income generation, in a vicious circle

    that in the end frustrates the overall systems potential for development through

    cooperation strategies. The local administrations present approach, based on allowing

    preferential treatment to joint projects, represents a move in the right direction; public

    support per se is not reduced, but simply channelled towards common initiatives, whose

    success will be an incentive for spontaneous cooperation in a virtuous circle perhaps

    capable of changing the overall sectors shape.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    25/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division23

    End Notes

    (1) This work has been financed by Bocconi University in the frame of the Support to

    basic research year 2000 program. We wish to express our gratitude to those

    institutions that have provided information for our empirical research, and to the

    representatives of such institutions. We also wish to thank Roberta Landini and Elena

    Lesmo for their relevant and critical work in collecting information and data from

    museums and theatres.

    (2) An exception is Metropoli, with the Centro-Polo municipalities.

    (3) Metropoli involves a total of 61 municipalities, but a maximum of 10 (7.5 in

    average) in each of the 8 Poles.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    26/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division24

    References

    Alexander, E.R. 1981. "Effectiveness in Interorganizational Coordination - a

    comparative case analysis". Publications in Architecture and Urban Planning,

    University of Wisconsin.

    Bagdadli, S. 1995.Accademia Perduta Romagna Teatri. Faenza: SDA Bocconi - EDIT

    Faenza.

    Bagdadli, S. 1997. Il museo come azienda. Management e organizzazione al servizio

    della cultura. Milano: Etas Libri.

    Bagdadli, S. 2001. Le reti di musei. Lorganizzazione a rete per i beni culturali in Italia

    e allestero. Milano: Egea.

    Barney, J.B. and Ouchi, W.G. 1985. Costi delle informazioni e strutture economiche di

    governo delle transazioni, in Organizzazione e Mercato, R.C.D. Nacamulli e A.

    Rugiadini, a cura di, Bologna: Il Mulino, p. 349-372.

    Baum, A.C. and Oliver, C. 1990. "Institutional Linkages and Organizational Mortality.

    Administrative Science Quarterly, 36, p. 187-218.

    Bavelas, A. 1951. Communication Patterns in Task-Oriented Groups, in The Policy

    Sciences, D. Lerner and H.K. Lasswell, eds., Stanford (CA): Stanford University Press,

    p. 193-202.

    Boni, M. 1989.Leconomia dietro il sipario: teatro, opera, cinema, televisione. Torino:

    EDT.

    Chung, S.A., Singh H. and Lee K. 2000. Complementarity, Status Similarity and

    Social Capital as Drivers of Alliance Formation. Strategic Management Journal, 21, p.

    1-22.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    27/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division25

    Danilov, V J. 1990. "Museums Systems and How They Work". Curator, 33, 4.

    DiMaggio, P. J. 1991. Constructing an Organizational Field as a Professional Project:

    US Art Museums 1920-40, in The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis,

    W. W. Powell and P. J. DiMaggio, eds., Chicago: Chicago University Press, p. 267-

    292.

    DiMaggio P. J., Powell W.W. 1991. The Iron Cage Revisited: Istitutional Isomorphism

    and Collective Rationality, in The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis,

    W. W. Powell and P. J. DiMaggio, eds., Chicago: Chicago University Press, p. 63-107.

    Grandori, A. and Soda, G. 1995. Inter-firm Networks. Antecedents, Mechanisms and

    Forms. Organization Studies, 16, p. 183-214.

    Friedman, M. 1986. The Elusive Promise of Management Cooperation in the Arts, in

    Nonprofit Enterprise in the Arts, P.J. DiMaggio, ed., New York: Oxford University

    Press, p. 212 e ss.

    Gualazzi, L., a cura di, 1994. Lombardia Spettacolo. Milano: Regione Lombardia

    Settore Cultura e Informazione e AGIS Lombardia.

    Deepak, K., Singh, H. and Lee, K. 2000. Complementarity, Status Similarity and

    Social Capital as Drivers of Alliance Formation. Strategic Management Journal, 21, p.

    1-22.

    Harrigan, R. 1985. Strategies for Joint Ventures. London: Lexington.

    Oliver, C. 1990. "Determinants of Interorganizational Relationship: Integration and

    Future Directions". Academy of Management Review, 15, 2, p. 241-265.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    28/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division26

    Mariotti, S. and Cainarca, G.C. 1986. "The Evolution of Transaction Governance in the

    Textile-Clothing Industry. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 7, p.

    351-374.

    North, D.C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance,

    Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Paulus, O. 1993. " Approche economique", inNote d'information concernant le rappot

    sur le reseux de musees, G. Duprat (Direction du Rapport), Strasbourg : Institut

    d'Etudes Politiques de Strasbourg.

    Powell, W.W and Smith-Doerr, L. 1994. "Networks and Economics Life", in The

    Handbook of Economic Sociology, N.J. Smelser and R. Swedberg, eds., Princeton

    University Press.

    Salvemini, S., Bagdadli, S., Dubini, P. e Soda, G. 1999. I teatri milanesi in rete

    cooperare per competere, rapporto di ricerca, Milano: Crora - Universit Bocconi.

    Scheff, J. and Kotler, P. 1996. How the Arts Can Prosper Through Strategic

    Collaborations.Harvard Business Review, 74, p. 4-11.

    Scott, R. W. 1995.Institutions and Organizations. Thousands Oaks (CA): Sage.

    SIAE 1988. Censimento dei teatri. Roma: SIAE.

    Sinha, D.K. and Cusumano, M.A. 1991. Complementary Resources and Cooperative

    Research: A Model of Research Joint Ventures among Competitors. Management

    Science, 37, 9, p. 1091-1106.

    Soda, G. 1998.Reti tra imprese: modelli e prospettive per una teoria del coordinamento

    tra imprese. Roma: Carrocci.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    29/30

    SDA Bocconi Research Division27

    Teece, D. J. 1980. "Economies of Scope and the Scope of Enterprise. Journal of

    Economic Behaviour and Organization, 1, p. 223-247.

    Van de Ven, A.H. 1976. On the Nature, Formation and Maintenance of Relations

    Among Organizations. The Academy of Management Review,p. 84-96.

    Van De Ven, A.H., Walker, G. and Liston, J. 1979. "Coordination Patterns Within an

    Interorganizational Network". Human Relations, 32, 1.

    Van de Ven, A.H. and Walker, G. 1984. The Dynamics of Interorganizational

    Coordination,Administrative Science Quarterly, 29, 4 (pp. 598-621).

    Williamson, O. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Anti-trust Implications.

    New York: Free Press.

    Williamson, O. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets,

    Relational Contracting.New York: Free Press.

    Wholey, D.R. and Huonker, J.W. 1993. Effects of Generalism and Niche Overlap on

    Network Linkages among Youth Service Agencies.Academy of Management Review,

    36, 2, p. 349-371.

    Yin, R.K. 1994. Case Study Research. Thousands Oaks (CA): Sage Publications.

    Zolber V. L. 1986. Tensions of Missions in American Art Museums, in NonprofitEntreprise in the Arts: Studies in Mission and Constraints, P. J. DiMaggio, ed., New

    York: Oxford University Press, p. 184-198.

  • 8/3/2019 museum_networks

    30/30

    Silvia Bagdadli is Associate Professor of Organization at Bocconi University, Milan,

    Italy. She teaches courses at undergraduate and graduate level in Organization Theory,

    Human Resource Management and Arts Management and executive courses at the

    Business School of Management of Bocconi University. She did several researches

    related to the cultural sector, presented several papers at International conferences on

    Arts Management (AIMAC) and published two books: the first one in 1997 on Museum

    Management in Italy and the second one in 2001 on Museum Networks.

    Bocconi University has several degree in Economics, Management, and Law, both at

    undergraduate and graduate level, including a degree in The Economic and

    Management of the Arts (CLEACC).