money, money, money: monopoly issues in collecting society · 2020. 1. 10. · universiti...

16
International Journal of Business and Society, Vol. 21 S1, 2020, 110-125 MONEY, MONEY, MONEY: MONOPOLY ISSUES IN COLLECTING SOCIETY Mardiah Hayati binti Abu Bakar Universiti Teknologi MARA Nazura binti Abdul Manap Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia Farizah binti Mohamed Isa Universiti Teknologi MARA ABSTRACT Competition law and intellectual property law has been evolving separately and has been conflicting with each other in various aspects Nevertheless, both laws have the same aim that is to spur economic growth and also encouraging innovation. Copyright law is a subset of intellectual property law, and the central conflict between copyright and competition law is in the case of collecting societies. Collecting society works as the mediator between the copyright holders and the copyright users which include authors, artists and others who benefit from collective management of their works, recordings, and performances. Collecting societies are said to be by nature monopolistic in the relevant market, and the question here is whether that market is being exploited or abused in a manner contrary to public interest. The struggling relationship between the collecting societies and the user of the works who becomes a rightsholder/member of the society, to safeguard the copyright, may result in the collecting societies to set excessive fees or to impose restrictive terms and conditions in the licensing agreement. Hence, this paper will discuss the position of collecting societies on monopoly in light of competition law and copyright law from a few perspectives from various jurisdictions. This paper employs a doctrinal analysis using secondary data. The findings will respond to the monopoly position of collecting societies and will also provide a basis for the policy makers in Malaysia to consider whether it is necessary to adopt a new framework to monitor the governance of the collecting societies in competition issues. Keywords: Collecting society; Monopoly; Licensing; Copyright law; Competition law ___________________________________ Received: 11 February 2019 Accepted: 20 August 2019 Corresponding author: Mardiah Hayati Binti Abu Bakar, Faculty of Law, Universiti Teknologi MARA, 40450 Shah Alam Selangor, Malaysia. Email : [email protected]

Upload: others

Post on 30-Jan-2021

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • International Journal of Business and Society, Vol. 21 S1, 2020, 110-125

    MONEY, MONEY, MONEY: MONOPOLY ISSUES IN COLLECTING SOCIETY

    Mardiah Hayati binti Abu Bakar

    Universiti Teknologi MARA

    Nazura binti Abdul Manap Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia

    Farizah binti Mohamed Isa

    Universiti Teknologi MARA

    ABSTRACT

    Competition law and intellectual property law has been evolving separately and has been conflicting with

    each other in various aspects Nevertheless, both laws have the same aim that is to spur economic growth and

    also encouraging innovation. Copyright law is a subset of intellectual property law, and the central conflict

    between copyright and competition law is in the case of collecting societies. Collecting society works as the

    mediator between the copyright holders and the copyright users which include authors, artists and others who

    benefit from collective management of their works, recordings, and performances. Collecting societies are

    said to be by nature monopolistic in the relevant market, and the question here is whether that market is being

    exploited or abused in a manner contrary to public interest. The struggling relationship between the collecting

    societies and the user of the works who becomes a rightsholder/member of the society, to safeguard the

    copyright, may result in the collecting societies to set excessive fees or to impose restrictive terms and

    conditions in the licensing agreement. Hence, this paper will discuss the position of collecting societies on

    monopoly in light of competition law and copyright law from a few perspectives from various jurisdictions.

    This paper employs a doctrinal analysis using secondary data. The findings will respond to the monopoly

    position of collecting societies and will also provide a basis for the policy makers in Malaysia to consider

    whether it is necessary to adopt a new framework to monitor the governance of the collecting societies in

    competition issues.

    Keywords: Collecting society; Monopoly; Licensing; Copyright law; Competition law ___________________________________

    Received: 11 February 2019

    Accepted: 20 August 2019

    Corresponding author: Mardiah Hayati Binti Abu Bakar, Faculty of Law, Universiti Teknologi MARA, 40450 Shah Alam Selangor, Malaysia. Email : [email protected]

  • Integrating Farmers’ Right To Traditional Agricultural Knowledge Into Malaysia Plant Variety Law 111

    1. INTRODUCTION

    1.1. Copyright Law (Intellectual Property Law) Versus Competition Law

    Intellectual property laws provide incentives for innovation and creation in the form of exclusive

    rights such as private monopolies, either limited in time (patents, copyright, or related rights), or

    for a potentially unlimited duration (indefinitely renewable trademark registrations, or trade names

    (Cottier & Germann, 2008). Whereas, the main objectives of competition law are to encourage

    consumer welfare and healthy competition among players (Kats, 2005). Competition law involves

    in formulating a set of rules near monopolies, mergers and commercial agreements (Patel, Panda,

    Deo, Khettry, & Matthew, 2011) which promote competition in the market. It also encourages the

    best quality of goods and services at the lowest costs for end users, as well as making sure that the

    suppliers have freedom of access to the market and the demands associated with freedom of choice

    by preserving a useful competitive framework (Cottier & Germann, 2008). Copyright law is a

    subset of intellectual property law, and the central conflict between copyright and competition law

    is highlighted in the case of collecting societies. Collecting society works as the mediator between

    the copyright holders and the copyright users which include the authors, artists and others who

    benefit from collective management of their works, recordings, and performances (Luise Schild,

    2012). Rights related to copyright include those of performing artists in their performances,

    producers of phonograms in their recordings, and those of broadcasters in their radio and television

    programs. In copyright law, when the rights involve the economic rights from the work that has

    been produced, the right owner has the option to exercise the right individually or with the

    assistance of collective management (Olatunji, Adam, & Aboyeji, 2017). It is unreasonable for the

    author to keep track of the use of their works on their capacity, since exploitation occurs

    everywhere, almost regularly. Hence, when the user violates the copyrighted works, it is impossible

    for them to manage their rights and uphold it legally all at once (Handke, 2013).

    Both areas of laws have contradictory aims. When there is a boundary for the competitors to have

    their exclusive rights to their innovation or works within the intellectual property rights, the

    monopoly is actually against the underlying competitive market sought by competition rules.

    Intellectual property is a natural monopoly as the law guarantees an exclusive right to the creators

    and owners of work which is a result of human intellectual creativity.(Patel et al., 2011) Under

    competition law, if there are no substitutes in the similar market, it may lead to market power and

    monopoly and hence, gives an advantage to the right holder of the intellectual property against the

    rest of other players in the industry (Kretschmer, 2005). The conflict between both intellectual

    property law and competition law creates the outcome of the advantage or the abuse of a dominant

    position (Patel et al., 2011)

    1.2. Issues

    The operational management of a collecting society works like this; typically one collecting society

    supplies licenses to the user of copyright works in one particular domain of rights, for example,

    public performances (Kretschmer, 2005). One license grants through reciprocal agreements with

    other societies in other countries in order to have access to the world repertoire. Hence, for the

    individual owners of copyright works, they have no choice but to be part of a collecting society in

    order to gain access and be appropriately remunerated. As such, the monopolistic structure gives

    the control to the collecting society and exploit its position versus rights holders/members

  • 112 Murshamshul Kamariah Musa, Zuhairah Ariff Abdul Ghadas, Abdul Majid Tahir Mohamed, Abdul Majid Hafiz Mohamed

    concerning access and also royalty distribution. The collecting society could abuse its market

    power to raise prices for its administration services over marginal costs or to run its operations

    inefficiently. This will adversely affect users whose access will be restricted by monopoly pricing.

    Monopolistic collective administration promotes social welfare only if the benefits from fully

    exploiting economies of scale are more significant than the adverse effects of monopoly pricing

    (Handke, 2013).

    1.3. Aim and Purpose

    In view of the above, this paper aims at examining the interface of the conflict between competition

    law and intellectual property law in highlighting the current legal position governing the

    monopolistic nature of the collecting society in various jurisdictions and intends to fill in gaps in

    the literature. For this paper, the discussion is divided into five parts:

    i) the overview of the conflicts between intellectual property and competition law; ii) the background and characteristics of collecting societies within the context of

    copyright law and also reviews on monopoly;

    iii) the methodology of this paper; iv) on the other jurisdictions in relating to the issues of monopoly in collecting societies

    including Malaysia; and

    v) conclusion.

    2. LITERATURE REVIEW

    2.1. Historical Background of Collecting Societies

    The system of collective management of rights historically has existed for more than 100 years in

    other countries and as copyright law gradually developed, the traditional principles of the system

    of collective rights management remain unchanged. The aims mainly are to protect authors' rights,

    to secure a way by which they are rewarded, and at the same time to provide the means by which

    music finds its way legally and smoothly to users, hence to the public.

    It was said that the collective administration started with an argument which resulted in a fight

    relating to drinks that a French composer, Ernest Bourget did not want to pay – since his work was

    played without his authorisation in one of the cafés in Paris. He debated, “you consume my music,

    I consume your wares”(Rodger & Ungureanu, 2010) and he won the argument before the Tribunal

    de Commerce de la Seine which for the first time, recognised a right to public performance (Chin,

    2014).. He then realised and understood that he has his right to the originality of his masterpiece

    that he composed, and therefore it is entirely absurd for him to dedicate his life in chasing

    unauthorised performances of his music. Besides, he also needed a considerable cost to track and

    negotiate with other various holders and end users. So Ernest Bourget, his colleagues Victor Parizot

    and Paul Henrion as well as the publisher Jules Colombier founded an Agence Centrale, which was

    the direct predecessor of the first modern collecting society, Societe des Auteurs et Compositeurs

    et Editeurs de Musique (SACEM). SACEM, established in 1851, became the European model,

    collecting at times even in Switzerland, Belgium, and the UK. With the establishment of SACEM,

    it had solved the issues on individual contracting and also offered other facilities for the benefits

    of the right-holders (Gervais, 2011).

  • Integrating Farmers’ Right To Traditional Agricultural Knowledge Into Malaysia Plant Variety Law 113

    In terms of the development of music copyright, it can be organised into three different periods,

    each one associated with a different international agreement. First, was through the Berne

    Convention for the Protection of Literary and Artistic Works, to which 172 countries have become

    signatories. Next, the World Trade Organisation (WTO) that administers the Agreement on Trade-

    Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights ("the TRIPs Agreement"), with the aim to have a

    robust focus on the commercial significance of cultural industries. In between the two was an era

    of increasing emphasis on the rights of "performers, producers of phonograms, and broadcasting

    organisations," which reached an apex with the signing of the Rome Convention for the Protection

    of Performers, Producers of Phonograms, and Broadcasting Organisations ("the Rome

    Convention") in 1961 where Malaysia is not a party. Nevertheless, there are two international

    treaties that Malaysia has deposited its instrument of accession in 2012, that is the WIPO Copyright

    Treaty (WCT) and WIPO Performances & Phonograms Treaty (WPPT) which lead to the

    protection of copyright and related rights in the digital age. Malaysia adapts to the treaties in

    facilitating the dissemination of protected material over the internet and also amends the law

    accordingly about legal remedies against the circumvention of technological measures used by

    authors(Tseneva - Sapoundjieva, 2008). Hence, it is a necessary task for management of the work

    that has been published to avoid any alteration of information of such data and at the same time

    brings benefits to the original author in exercising their rights in exploiting their work(Tseneva -

    Sapoundjieva, 2008).

    2.2. Characteristic of Collecting Society

    Collecting societies are organisations usually set up by right holders to manage their rights mainly

    for economic rights or also used to refer to all types of collective rights management organisations

    or in short CMOs, irrespective of the precise rights or bundle of rights they manage according to

    Luise Schild (2012). It is a common practice that copyright holders' assignment other organisations

    to jointly administer some of their copyrights which are referred to as ‘collective administration'

    of copyrights, or ‘collective rights management.' The organisations that conduct collective

    administration are known as ‘collecting societies,' ‘copyright collectives,' or ‘copyright

    management organisations’ (CMO) according to Handke (2013). Today collecting societies

    operate in more than one hundred countries, and there are dozens of these organisations in some

    highly developed economies (Gervais, 2010).

    Luise Schild (2012) discussed the role of collecting societies in which there is more than one

    category of right holders within the collecting societies; because of this, more rights will be

    aggregated for licensing purposes. As they also provide services such as auditing and monitoring

    of the use of rights and collecting and distribution of royalties, it is crucial for the collecting

    societies to make sure that the right holders are reasonably and appropriately remunerated

    regardless of whether they are individuals or from other related companies (Luise Schild, 2012).

    Riis et al (2016) highlight the mode of CMOs whereby the expectation of benefits is an essential

    element for right holders when they decide on the mode of rights management. The underlying

    factors that determine whether the expectations of users are best met by collective rights

    administration or by the individual administration are not constant. Growing opportunities to

    contract individually may be turning the tide against the collective models (Riis, Rognstad, &

    Schovsbo, 2016).

  • 114 Murshamshul Kamariah Musa, Zuhairah Ariff Abdul Ghadas, Abdul Majid Tahir Mohamed, Abdul Majid Hafiz Mohamed

    Collective management of rights is an essential mechanism carried out by Collective Management

    Organisations (CMOs). It enables creators and rights owners to exercise their rights efficiently in

    their country and abroad, in their interests and those of commercial users, consumers, and the

    general public. These aims, functions and the operational manner of collecting societies remained,

    despite all the technological changes and the advancement of the cyberspace. Collective

    management organisations or copyright societies work as private, not-for-profit, legal entities that

    are established under governmental supervisions. They work as the mediator between the copyright

    holders and the copyright users. Any individual entity having copyrighted works is eligible to be a

    member of the societies. The collection of royalties and the overall right management has become

    a complicated issue in the absence of a CMO. Authors are clueless as to how they can best exploit

    their music rights and also with regard to their likely action when their rights are violated or

    infringed.

    However, it needs to be stated that one of the prime duties of the CMO members is to update the

    society on their available copyrighted works and the deals or agreements they have signed or the

    license they have issued to the users of their work. The societies obtain exclusive authorised rights

    to the copyrighted works from the members by way issuing license (Faiz, 2015). Collecting

    societies, as a result, hold the ultimate right to grant a license of the copyrighted works for different

    purposes and in return collect royalties from the same entities or individuals. In addition, collecting

    societies has the mandate (Colangelo & Lincesso, 2012) to track and identify infringements or

    right violations and initiate appropriate legal action.

    Faiz (2015) further explains the type of copyright society that involves and responsible in the

    management of authors that has one or more than one unique genre. For exploitation, it is the

    copyright collectives as an association that the authors transfer copyrights with. Generally,

    collectives have these roles in granting licenses for the use of works in their repertory, besides that

    they also negotiate and collect royalties, and distribute them to their members, and lastly they will

    take legal action against those who infringe the copyrights to which they hold the title (Fox, 2000).

    2.3. Monopoly

    The monopoly power of copyright collectives can be restricted in several ways. First, on the side

    of rights holders, collecting societies are usually run as non-profit collectives. Members have

    voting rights similar to shareholders, which gives them some control over the operations of the

    collecting society. Second, collecting societies are subject to statutory regulation. In most territories,

    there are specific regulations regarding, for instance, the pricing of licenses, collectives'

    membership policy and investments in culture (Faiz, 2015). Third, collecting societies often trade

    with commercial users who enjoy some market power themselves. Collective bargaining may

    protect rights holders from market power on the user side. Before the liberalisation of broadcasting

    in the UK, for instance, the constellation between public broadcasters and collecting societies was

    akin to a bilateral monopoly. Today, many markets for Internet-based services seem prone to

    dominant, multinational firms such as Amazon, Google or Apple with its iTunes store. What is

    more, users tend to form trade organisations that bargain on their behalf. Several economists see

    negotiations in bilateral monopolies as the primary process to approximate socially efficient

    licensing arrangements (Handke, 2013; Watt, 2010). Lastly, price discrimination by collecting

    societies could approximate a socially efficient outcome according to standard welfare economics,

    even if collectives were to enjoy almost unrestricted market power on the user side (Handke, 2013).

  • Integrating Farmers’ Right To Traditional Agricultural Knowledge Into Malaysia Plant Variety Law 115

    Under exceptional circumstances, the refusal of IP licenses may be considered an abuse of

    dominant position, as competition law intervenes as a last resource to control the potential

    monopolistic power of IP holders(Pereira, 2011). There are the three pillars of modern competition

    law are prohibitions against in the United States which are first, the coordinated anti-competitive

    conduct, secondly, the unilateral conduct that abuses a dominant market position and lastly mergers

    and other transactions aggregating assets that may create a monopoly (Hollander, 1984).

    3. METHODOLOGY

    This study adopts a qualitative methodology using library-based research method to critically

    review the literature on the conflicts between intellectual property law and competition law, in

    particular, the collecting society under copyright law. The primary and secondary sources of data

    will be examined through the content analysis method. The former relates to Competition Act 2010

    and also other jurisdiction law from United States, European Union, Australia and Canada. The

    latter refers to the content analysis of textbooks, journal articles, government reports, working

    papers, commentaries on case laws and online databases such as Emerald, Hein Online and Sage

    Publication which is done to support the primary sources of data.

    4. DISCUSSIONS

    This part of this paper will discuss the position of collecting societies on monopoly in the light of

    competition law and copyright law from a few perspectives from various jurisdictions.

    4.1. United States

    U.S. antitrust law stems (Cross & Yu, 2008). These provisions state in relevant part:

    ....§ 1. Trusts, etc., in restraint of trade illegal; penalty

    Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or

    conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or

    with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal. Every person who shall

    make any contract or engage in any combination or conspiracy hereby

    declared to be illegal shall be deemed guilty of a felony.

    § 2. Monopolising trade a felony; penalty

    Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or

    combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any

    part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign

    nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony .... (Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.

    §§ 1-2 (Supp. 2007))

    However, there are no special provisions dealing with rights granted by intellectual property law

    under U.S. antitrust law. Hence, courts have had to balance the competing policies in the two legal

    regimes to arrive at a proper weigh(Cross & Yu, 2008).

  • 116 Murshamshul Kamariah Musa, Zuhairah Ariff Abdul Ghadas, Abdul Majid Tahir Mohamed, Abdul Majid Hafiz Mohamed

    Amongst all the significant creative rights producing and exporting nations, the United States is

    unique in that its law of copyright is virtually silent as to issues relating to collective administration

    (Sinacore-guinn, 1993). In the United States, authors' societies have been in existence since the

    19th Century, and their development is marked by the societies in the field of music(Riccio &

    Codiglione, 2013). The US record companies have never had any experience in licensing radio or

    other performance of their sound recordings. Under the copyright laws of the United States, there

    is no recognition of a broadcasting or public performance right in sound recordings(Band & Butler,

    2013). U.S. Government has given little or no support to their development of collecting societies

    such as the American Society of Composers, Authors and Publishers (ASCAP), Broadcast Music

    Inc. (BMI) and Society of European Stage Authors and Composers (SESAC).

    American CMOs ASCAP and BMI have been operating pursuant to an antitrust consent decree

    with the U.S. Department of Justice since 1941 and 1966 respectively(Hillman, 1998). The decrees

    reflect concerns about possible abuses of both monopoly and monopsony power. In the case of

    monopsony, the concern was the possible abuse of members even though both ASCAP and BMI

    are membership organisations.

    The Department of Justice brought the actions in response to ASCAP and BMI requiring

    broadcasters and other licensees to obtain a blanket license covering all performances of their entire

    catalogue. Under the consent decrees, the broadcaster can obtain a blanket license on a per program

    basis as opposed to a blanket license for all programs (Kretschmer, 2005). Due to allegedly

    monopolistic conduct, both CMOs have been sued multiple times in the aftermath of the consent

    decrees, but courts have been unwilling to restrain them. The US broadcasting company CBS

    brought an action against the two major collecting societies ASCAP and BMI, alleging that their

    blanket licenses and the composition of the fees were indeed to be regarded as a violation of the

    per se prohibition of price‐fixing agreements(Drexl, Antony, Kim, & Muchiri, 2013). The Court explained that the practice is per se illegal under the antitrust laws only if it is so anticompetitive

    and without redeeming virtue that it warrants a presumption of illegality. In Broadcast Music, Inc.

    v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc. (1979), the Court found that the blanket license policy did

    not meet that definition. Noel Hillman, an Assistant U.S. Attorney in the Fraud and Public

    Protection Division of the Department of Justice, recounts several instances of ASCAP or BMI

    abusing their market power and even violating the consent decrees under which they both still

    operate (Hillman, 1998). Despite the consent decrees' goal of encouraging fair pricing and choice,

    the two CMOs still drive the vast majority of licensees into purchasing expensive blanket licenses

    (Hillman, 1998). The US decision in BMI v. CBS, however, does not exempt CMOs from

    competition law. It only established the rule that the grant of blanket licenses would not be per se

    illegal as a price-fixing agreement. Collecting societies and their contractual relationships are

    controlled under the rule of reason of US antitrust law (Drexl et al., 2013).

    Professor Ivan Reidel (2011) discussed that if the licensing market is not subject to monopoly, the

    pricing for broadcasters would be lowered and therefore having aired more entertainment content

    for the viewers. Hence, due to the high pricing of blanket licensing fees, the U.S consumers are

    forced to watch all the excessive advertising on broadcast media. Under the current system, Reidel

    (2011) argues, "Audiences and broadcasters are necessarily worse off: Audiences are served more

    annoying ads than a competitive market would provide and broadcasters pay artificially inflated

    prices for songs."

  • Integrating Farmers’ Right To Traditional Agricultural Knowledge Into Malaysia Plant Variety Law 117

    In contrast, (Fox, 1997, 1998, 2000) had commented on the issues on the case of CMOs in the U.S

    mainly ASCAP and BMI. She explains that the case was appealed to the Supreme Court and the

    court in principle examine the market before deciding whether the case is anticompetitive or not.

    The court observed that there are thousands of composers and more than 20,000 in ASCAP and

    also BMI. Therefore, it showed a fragmented market, and with the need to police infringements,

    pooling of compositions was necessary to make the market work. Hence, it was decided by the

    Supreme Court that defendants' methods of licensing could not be a per se violation of the antitrust

    laws because they were not explicitly anti-competitive, and they had healthy pro-efficiency aspects.

    Eleanor further explains that basically, the rule of law in the United States enforced it as per se

    illegal only on a plainly anti-competitive practice (Kretschmer, 2005). She suggested having a

    framework agreement, (Cross & Yu, 2008) such as in TRIP as per Section 8, Article 40 on control

    of anti-competitive practices in contractual licences, with requirements on nations for transparency,

    non-parochialism, obligations to have and apply competition law, rules for choice of national law,

    and dispute resolution to solve remaining conflicts (Fox, 1997, 1998).

    The ASCAP and BMI decrees are about the transaction between the applicant and CMOs involving

    the tariff or rate of each agreement, and if the user (applicant) fails to agree on a fee, the applicant

    may ask the District Court in the Federal Southern District of New York to set a ‘reasonable'

    rate(Watt, 2010). The decrees are said to be the only permanent antitrust decrees issued that remain

    in effect(Greaves, 2004). This persistence may indicate that the collecting societies remain natural

    monopolies in some areas. A new CMO was established under the Digital Performance Right in

    Sound Recordings Act of 1995, a regulatory system was established outside of antitrust scrutiny in

    order to manage the rights in digital uses of sound recordings, and it has been regulated like a

    utility rather than within the antitrust standards since collecting society is said to be a natural

    monopoly. However, DiLorenzo (1996) discussed that a natural monopoly can still turn on to other

    circumstances, for example, the landline telephone systems. Hence it is crucial to re-look from

    time to time any claim of natural monopoly (Kon, 2000). A natural monopoly forms when a single

    entity can supply a good or service to an entire market at a lower cost (Mankiw, 2009) than could

    two or more entities (DiLorenzo, 1996).

    Zhang (2016) suggests a way to deal with the problem of monopoly is by regulating the behaviour

    of monopolistic collecting societies (Tomain, 2002). This solution is particularly prevalent in the

    case of a natural monopoly. Therefore, the regulatory control of natural monopoly can be

    acknowledged by limiting the entry; setting prices; controlling profits; and imposing a service

    obligation (Chin, 2014). In United States antitrust law, it focuses on the whole market rather an

    individual actor within the market hence, it is said to be a drastic decision to penalize the copyright

    abuse for violating competition act. Therefore, the United States court is exploring other ways in

    combatting copyright abuse (Cross & Yu, 2008).

    4.2. Canada

    In Canada, the government has observed collective administration to be a necessary practice for a

    range of copyrights and a series of revisions to Canada's Copyright Act (Zhang, 2016) has led to

    the establishment of a world record 36 collective organisations representing a diversity of copyright

    holders and administering a variety of rights (Gervais & Maurushat, 2003). The proliferation of

    collecting societies in Canada has created a system of taxing the public for private benefit, a system

  • 118 Murshamshul Kamariah Musa, Zuhairah Ariff Abdul Ghadas, Abdul Majid Tahir Mohamed, Abdul Majid Hafiz Mohamed

    that answers directly to neither market competition nor democratic processes(Band & Butler, 2013).

    In Canada, its competition law is detailed and complexed with a few different types of

    anticompetitive acts. However, the Act unearths a subtle balance between society's need for free

    competition and a seller's need for flexibility in the ways it markets its services and goods(Cross

    & Yu, 2008). As intellectual property is concerned; however, the balance clearly favours sellers of

    intellectual property at the expense of the public interest in competition and free trade. Two

    provisions explicitly govern how the Competition Act 1985 applies to patents, copyrights and other

    forms of intellectual property. The rule is under section 79(5). Although section 79, taken as a

    whole, deals with situations in which a party abuses its dominant position in a market, subsection

    5 creates a broad exception for the enforcement of intellectual property rights. This subsection

    provides:

    ...(F)or the purpose of this section, an act engaged in pursuant only to

    the exercise of any right or enjoyment of any interest derived under

    the Copyright Act, Industrial Design Act, Integrated Circuit

    Topography Act, Patent Act, Trade-marks Act or any other Act of

    Parliament pertaining to intellectual or industrial property is not an

    anti-competitive act.

    This provision recognises the fundamental conflict between the law of monopolies and copyright

    law. A certain degree of market power has been given to the copyright owners by the Parliament.

    Any act taken solely to protect that privileged position cannot run afoul of the Competition Act

    1985, even if it results in higher prices or limits the ability of other firms to compete. However, the

    section 79(5) exception does not apply if the act involves something more than the exercise of an

    intellectual property right, and the act may be challenged as an abuse of the intellectual property

    owner's dominant position(Cross & Yu, 2008).

    4.3. Australia

    In Australia, with reference to the review of intellectual property legislation under the Competition

    Principles Agreement and the committee suggests ministerial revocation (s. 135ZZC of the

    Australian Copyright Act 1968) be broadened to cover all collecting society arrangements, both

    input, and output, including the disclosure of information to members and the public. It is also

    suggested that guidelines be issued to each collecting society, in the spirit of a contract between

    the society and the community, that specify the Government's expectations regarding the society's

    conduct, including in terms of the information required to be disclosed and the process for

    disclosure. The Arts Law Centre of Australia submitted that:

    ...Without these collective agencies, there would be very little

    return for artists and creators, given their lack of finances to

    police and enforce copyright, and the cost of pursuing

    copyright infringements. (p.8)

    One commentator has stated that ‘the interaction of copyright law and markets in the arts and

    cultural industries, propelled by technological developments that have both reduced the cost of

    copying and vastly extended markets, have led to the growth and formation of collecting societies

  • Integrating Farmers’ Right To Traditional Agricultural Knowledge Into Malaysia Plant Variety Law 119

    (Ergas, McKeough, & Stonier, 2000). They are natural monopolies, and their operations have

    added to existing concerns regarding the statutory monopoly created by copyright law(Towse,

    1999).

    4.4. European Union

    Collecting societies in all EU Member States has the responsibility to make sure that they cannot

    neglect to license their repertoire, they have to disclose to their members on specific threshold rules,

    and they will have to be transparent in their finances. It is an interesting attribute of collective

    administration in the event of music performing right and mechanical reproduction societies,

    whereby as a representative for both authors (composers and lyricists) and publishers, changes to

    membership and distribution rules can only be executed if there is consent by both groups.(Kats,

    2005).

    In BRT v. SABAM (1974), the first collecting society case before the European Courts, the ECJ

    characterised the Belgian performing right society as “an undertaking to which the state has not

    assigned any task, and which manages private interest, including intellectual property rights

    protected by law”. This was confirmed in 1979 and 1983 in the Greenwich and GVL Cases. BRT

    v. SABAM is among the first case encounters collecting societies on competition issues which both

    United Kingdom (U.K) and European competition authorities take into account the need to ensure

    balance between the requirement of a maximum freedom of right owners to dispose of their own

    works and that of the effective management of those rights by an undertaking that in practice, and

    failing which it will lead to a monopoly position(Chin, 2014).

    The EC competition rules support the principle of the internal market by preventing private parties

    from erecting barriers to trade by entering restrictive agreements (Art.81 EC Treaty) or abusing

    their dominant position on the market (Art.82 EC Treaty). Article 82 EC was also interpreted as

    meaning that by calculating the royalties with respect to remuneration paid for the broadcast of

    musical works protected by copyright in a different manner according to whether the companies

    (Kon, 2000) concerned are commercial companies or public service undertakings, a copyright

    management organisation is likely to exploit in an abusive manner its dominant position within the

    meaning of that article if it applies with respect to those companies dissimilar conditions to

    equivalent services and if it places them as a result at a competitive disadvantage, unless such a

    practice may be objectively justified"(Watt, 2010).

    There are a few cases in EU that involve abusive conduct towards members, and abusive conduct

    towards users within Article 82. In GEMA I, the Commission recognised seven categories of rights

    members might assign separately: (1) broadcasting, (2) public performance, (3) mechanical

    reproduction, (4) film performance, (5) video reproduction and performance, (6) film

    synchronization, (7) new categories of right. This is due to the act by GEMA in making a

    compulsory for the members to assign all their categories of rights in an agreement. Collecting

    societies who give no choice to the copyright owners as to where to place the management of their

    rights abuse their dominant position and are in breach of Art.82 EC Treaty(Watt, 2010). In GEMA

    II, the minimum membership allowed by the commission is for a term of three years. Retaining

    right for five years after a member's withdrawn is likely to be unjust. In GEMA III the Commission

  • 120 Murshamshul Kamariah Musa, Zuhairah Ariff Abdul Ghadas, Abdul Majid Tahir Mohamed, Abdul Majid Hafiz Mohamed

    decided that a clause in GEMA's statutes which was designed to prevent GEMA members from

    making payments to broadcasters and others to play particular recordings was not abused and the

    Commission authorised the societies statutes imposing uniform effective rates of remuneration

    (thus stopping members from making payments to users).

    The first step taken by the European Commission to reform the way the collecting societies in

    handling their business is by adopting a Communication on the Management of Copyright and

    Related Rights in the Internal Market ("the 2004 Communication"). A Recommendation on the

    cross-border management of copyright in respect of online music services ("the 2005

    Recommendation") was adopted a year later. The favorable option in the recommendation states

    that the right-holders should have the right to entrust the management of any of the online rights

    necessary to operate legitimate online music services, on a territorial scope of their choice, to a

    collective rights manager of their choice, irrespective of the Member State of residence or the

    nationality of either the collective rights manager or the right-holder (Luise Schild, 2012). Their

    primary concerns are on good internal governance and licensing of rights on behalf of copyright

    owners (Hollander, 1984).

    4.5. Malaysia

    Copyright collecting societies came into existence in Malaysia in the late 1980s after the Malaysian

    Copyright Act came into force on 1 December 1987. In the beginning, the public did not realise

    and was not aware of the fact that royalties within the licensing agreement need to be paid for the

    commercial use of copyright material, and therefore the collections are very minimal, and the

    societies were actually operating at a loss. However, with the assistance of the stakeholders, the

    current scenario has changed as there is a higher awareness of copyright and more enforcement

    actions supported by the government for using the copyrighted music and sound recordings.

    With reference to Section 3 of Copyright Act 1987, an author is defined as the writer or the maker

    of the work for the literary work, the composer for musical work, the artist for the artistic works

    other than photographs and all persons who are involve with the arrangement of the film or

    recording, the broadcasting and in relation to any case, by whom the work was done. The authors

    have exclusives rights to do specific acts in particular with regard to their work. Exclusive here

    means as a general rule they have the right to forbid others to exploit the work without their express

    consent. They also can decide on the mechanism of work that can be used and also be giving

    permission for the use of work in return for remuneration. Other than that, the rights granted to

    authors include the economic rights of reproduction, translation, broadcasting, public performance,

    adaptation, rental, distribution and making the work available over the Internet. The moral rights

    for the authors commonly include the right to claim authorship of the work and to object to any

    distortion, mutilation or other modification of the right owner's work that might be prejudicial to

    his honour or reputation (CISAC, 2015).

    The law which relates to collecting society in Malaysia, are found under Part IVA of the Copyright

    Act 1987 and the Regulations, which explain the establishments of licensing bodies to protect the

    work of the right holders. It also explains the declaration of the establishment and MYIPO as the

    Controller under the law has the discretion to notify the licensing bodies that is in compliance with

    the law. The Controller also may revoke a declaration given to a licensing body if he is satisfied

    that the licensing body act within Section 27A (6), i.e. (a) is not functioning adequately as a

  • Integrating Farmers’ Right To Traditional Agricultural Knowledge Into Malaysia Plant Variety Law 121

    licensing body; (b) no longer has the authority to act on behalf of all its members; (c) is not acting

    in accordance with its rules or in the best interests of its members, or their agents; (d) has altered

    its rules so that it no longer complies with any provision of this Act; (e) has refused, or failed,

    without reasonable excuse, to comply with the provisions of this Act; or (f) has been dissolved.

    The first collecting society in Malaysia was the Public Performance Malaysia Sdn Bhd (PPM),

    founded in 1988 which was then followed by Music Authors’ Copyright Protection Bhd (MACP)

    in 1989. For many years PPM and MACP were the only two collecting societies in Malaysia, but

    this changed in 2001 when a third and fourth agency, called Performers’ and Artists’ Rights (M)

    Sdn Bhd (PRISM) and Recording Performers Malaysia Berhad (RPM) was incorporated. With

    effect from 1 June 2012, the Copyright (Licensing Body) Regulations 2012 came into force in

    Malaysia whereby all new and existing Collective Management Organisations(CMOs) need to

    apply for declarations to commence or continue with collective licensing operations for and on

    behalf of their authorised members. Officially by 2013, all four collecting societies have been

    legitimately recognised by MyIPO.

    Music Authors’ Copyright Protection (MACP) Bhd represent 2 million international composers,

    lyricists, and publishers from all over the world. It collects royalties for the songwriters and

    publishers when their works are used. On the other hand, the Public Performance (Malaysia) or

    PPM works for the protection of the rights of recording companies (Faiz, 2015). Besides that, there

    is Performer’s Rights and Interest Society Malaysia Bhd (PRISM) and Record Performance

    Malaysia Bhd (RPM) which both works for the singers and musician of sound recordings.

    Interestingly, both CMOs protect the same type of works, and therefore it is up to the singer or

    musician to be a member of either one of the collecting societies. Collecting societies in Malaysia

    are very much self-regulated. With reference to the guideline by World Intellectual Property

    Organization (WIPO) and also international collecting society like International Confederation of

    Societies of Authors and Composers (CISAC) and International Federation of the Phonographic

    Industry (IFPI) regarding collecting societies, the collecting societies in Malaysia set their own

    rules. In the event of dispute for example over unreasonable terms or a license being unfairly

    declined, the parties have recourse to the Copyright Tribunal that was established under the new

    Part IVA of the Act which deals with copyright licensing.

    In 2016, PRISM has about 1,600 members and RPM about 700 members. It was reported that in

    2016, there are complaints with regard to the distribution of royalties which led to about 40 PRISM

    members were left disappointed when, after waiting for three years for royalties, they were only

    given token sums of between RM400 and RM600 (Kon, 2000). These members were very

    disappointed that over RM1.4 million operating costs were deducted from PRISM’s royalty

    collection of RM1.5 million. The musicians have become victims of circumstances since two

    licenses have been granted to two bodies to collect royalties(Kon, 2000). The end result of this was

    that consumers who play music in public places have chosen not to pay royalties(Band, Jonathan;

    Butler, 2013). Thus, far no cases involving the collective administration of copyright have been

    determined by the Copyright Tribunal. That does not mean there are no complaints from the end

    users or the rightsholders from the facilities offered within the collecting societies, but instead,

    these complaints have been settled internally without going through the Copyright Tribunal.

    In 2017, Music Rights Malaysia Berhad (MRM) a non-profit organisation and the sole licensing

    body designated by the Intellectual Property Corporation of Malaysia (MyIPO), an agency under

  • 122 Murshamshul Kamariah Musa, Zuhairah Ariff Abdul Ghadas, Abdul Majid Tahir Mohamed, Abdul Majid Hafiz Mohamed

    the Ministry of Domestic Trade, Co-operative and Consumerism (MTDCC) is established to carry

    out collective music license issuance and fee collection activities in Malaysia effective 1 January

    2017 on behalf of and in place of the following music licensing bodies which include MACP,

    PRISM, RPM and PPM. It is an excellent move in order to harmonise the collection of licensing

    payments from the public.

    In Malaysia, the Competition Act 2010 which came into force on 1 January 2012 provides a

    regulatory framework in matters relating to competition in commercial activities. The preamble of

    the Competition Act 2010 sets several aims of the Competition Act 2010 which are, among others,

    to promote economic development by promoting and protecting the process of competition. Under

    the Malaysian Competition Act 2010, section 10 prohibits the abuse of a dominant position. With

    reference to Section 3, dominant position means a situation in which one or more enterprises

    possess such significant power in a market to adjust prices or outputs or trading terms, without

    useful constraint from competitors or potential competitors. Chapter 2 of the Act prohibits an

    enterprise from engaging (whether independently or collectively with other enterprises) in any

    conduct which amounts to an abuse of a dominant position in any market for goods or services in

    Malaysia.

    On that note, the question is, would the collecting societies in Malaysia have the natural monopoly

    within the context of the Malaysian Competition Law Act 2010, and would it fall under such power

    in a market and leads to abuse of dominant position? Knowing the nature of intellectual property,

    mainly copyright, most of the dealings may involve exclusivity to the rights which will lead to a

    private monopoly. Hence, under Guidelines of Abuse of Dominant Position issued under Malaysia

    Competition Commission (MyCC), there will be two stages of assessment by MyCC on whether

    there has been breach of Chapter 2 ie firstly whether the collecting society reported is dominant in

    a relevant market in Malaysia and secondly, if the collecting society is dominant, whether the

    collecting society is abusing that dominant position. With the establishment of MRM, the agency

    is the sole licensing body for collective music royalty collection activities in Malaysia. The said

    agency is formed by the four other main licensing bodies in Malaysia, i.e. MACP, RPM, PPM and

    PRISM and since copyright is a private property right, the Government cannot fix the rates, and

    the copyright owner will determine their own rates with the assistance of all the collecting societies.

    The establishment of MRM solves the confusion for the end users in payment of fees collection

    for copyrighted work. Prior, they will have to refer to 4 different agencies in terms of payment.

    Since the establishment of MRM is relatively new, there is still a long way to discuss the issues of

    fairness further mainly the dominant position of MRM and whether there are competition issues

    among the collecting societies. One example of abuse that can occur in collecting society situation

    is with regard to its excessive fees its service. As for now, there is no reported complain to MyCC

    with regard to the abusive conduct. In adopting the recommendation by the EU Commission, the

    collecting societies need to oblige to grant a license with reasonable conditions, i.e. transparent

    with the activities in the society in order to remedy the abusive conduct. There is also a possibility

    that collecting society in Malaysia is under the purview of Second Schedule ie the exclusion for

    Chapter 2 of Competition Act. It may fit the characteristic of collecting society as the only body

    that entrusted with the operation of services of general economic that is collecting payments of

    licences for the benefit of copyright owners. Therefore, as mention above, it possesses the

    monopolistic in nature. However, since there is no decided case on collecting society, the issue is

    open for debate. Competition Act 2010 is a statute which is general in application, applies all

  • Integrating Farmers’ Right To Traditional Agricultural Knowledge Into Malaysia Plant Variety Law 123

    matters excluding sectoral matters for example telecommunication and energy. Since copyright

    law is an intellectual property matter, it has not been regulated separately as compared to the above

    mentioned sectoral matters. Therefore, The Competition Act 2010 is the only law applicable

    relating to competition issues. Currently, MyCC is in progress of endorsing the guideline between

    intellectual property law and competition law. It is hoped that the guideline will assist in striking a

    balance of both laws mainly in copyright law.

    5. CONCLUSION AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS

    In the last two decades, the awareness of copyright protection has become more widespread than

    ever before. That includes the payment of royalty fees to the copyright owners via the collecting

    societies. Collecting societies have the monopolistic nature in assisting the flow of commercial

    exploitation values to the right owners. However, there are circumstances where the collecting

    societies’ conduct can be abusive and affects the economics of the industry, and therefore

    safeguards are needed particularly in such contexts to protect members and absent right-holders

    against abuse by the CMO and that relates to the case in Germany. In the United States, although

    there is no specific provision in regulating their antitrust law and intellectual property, the judge

    concurs in monitoring the behavioural of the natural monopolistic of the collecting societies in

    order to avoid any abuse. Both Canadian and Australian law acknowledge the conflicts of

    competition law and copyright law, give a certain market power for the copyright owners, and

    recognize the natural monopoly. However, in Canada, if the abuse act is done other than for the

    exercising intellectual property rights, then the court will take action under an abuse of dominant

    position. Meanwhile in Malaysia, due to the unreported complains about the distribution of

    royalties from the public and also abusive act from the collecting societies, it shows the lack of

    transparency within the management of collecting societies. Malaysia acknowledges the natural

    monopoly behavior of collecting society but however will still closely monitor the dealings among

    the collecting societies in Malaysia in order to avoid abuse of dominant positions. Hence there is

    a need for strict supervision by the government especially when it involves the nature of the

    agreement signed between the collecting societies and copyright holders and the distribution of

    royalty rates among the members.

    ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

    This work was supported by Research Grant RAGS/1/2015/ssi0/uitm/03/3 by the Institute of

    Research Management And Innovation (IRMI) Universiti Teknologi MARA and the Ministry of

    Higher Education, Malaysia.

    REFERENCES

    Band, J., & Butler, B. (2013). Some Cautionary Tales about Collective Licensing. Michigan State

    International Law Review, 21(3), 687. https://doi.org/10.3366/ajicl.2011.0005

    Chin, Y. W. (2014). Copyright collective management in the twenty-first century from a

    competition law perspective. In S. Frankel & D. Gervais (Eds.), The Evolution and

    Equilibrium of Copyright in the Digital Age (pp. 269–284). Cambridge: Cambridge

    University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107477179.018

    CISAC. (2015). The Role of Collective Management Organisations. Retrieved 20 December 2016,

  • 124 Murshamshul Kamariah Musa, Zuhairah Ariff Abdul Ghadas, Abdul Majid Tahir Mohamed, Abdul Majid Hafiz Mohamed

    from https://www.cisac.org/CISAC-University/Library/Expert-Articles/The-Role-of-

    Collective-Management-Organisations

    Colangelo, G., & Lincesso, I. (2012). Law versus technology: Looking for a solution to the orphan

    works’ problem. International Journal of Law and Information Technology, 20(3), 178–

    202. https://doi.org/10.1093/ijlit/eas012

    Cottier, T., & Germann, C. (2008). Teaching intellectual property ,unfair competition and anti-trust

    law. In Y. Takagi, L. Allman, & M. A. Sinjela (Eds.), Teaching of Intellectual Property -

    Principles and Methods (pp. 130–165). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139168687

    Cross, J. T., & Yu, P. K. (2008). Competition law and copyright misuse. Drake Law Review, 56,

    427–462. https://doi.org/10.3366/ajicl.2011.0005

    DiLorenzo, T. J. (1996). The myth of natural monopoly. The Review of Austrian Economics, 9(2),

    43–58. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01103329

    Drexl, J., Antony, D., Kim, D., & Muchiri, M. (2013). Copyright , Competition and Development.

    Munich.

    Ergas, H., McKeough, J., & Stonier, J. (2000). Review of intellectual property legislation under

    the Competition Principles Agreement. Canberra.

    Faiz, T. (2015, August 31). Collective management organisation : A society of its kind. Intellect

    Issue, 1–9. Retrieved from http://www.intellect.com.bd/details/52/collective-

    management-organisation-a-society-of-its-kind

    Fox, E. (1997). Toward world antitrust and market access. The American Journal of International

    Law, 91(1), 1–25.

    Fox, E. (1998). International antitrust: Against minimum rules; for Cosmopolitan principles.

    Antitrust Bulletin, 43, 5–13.

    Fox, E. (2000). Commentary: Collecting societies and competition. International Intellectual

    Property Law & Policy, 4(95), 1–3. https://doi.org/10.3366/ajicl.2011.0005

    Gervais, D. (2010). Collective management of copyright: Theory and practice in the digital age. In

    D. Gervais (Ed.), Collective Management of Copyright and Related Rights (2nd ed.).

    Great Britain: Wolters Kluwer. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107415324.004

    Gervais, D. (2011). Keynote: The landscape of collective management schemes. Columbia Journal

    of Law and The Arts, 34, 591–617. https://doi.org/10.3366/ajicl.2011.0005

    Gervais, D., & Maurushat, A. (2003). Fragmented copyright, fragmented management: proposals

    to defrag copyright management. Canadian Journal of Law and Technology, 2(1), 15–33.

    Greaves, R. (2004). Collecting societies and EC law. Irish Jurist (N.S), 40, 42.

    https://doi.org/10.3366/ajicl.2011.0005

    Handke, C. (2013). The Economics of Collective Copyright Management.

    https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2256178

    Hillman, N. (1998). Intractable Consent : A Legislative Solution to the Problem of the Aging

    Consent Decrees in United States v. ASCAP and United States v. BMI. Fordham Intell.

    Prop. Media & Ent. LJ, 8(3), 733–771.

    Hollander, A. (1984). Market structure and performance in intellectual property :The case of

    copyright collectives. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 2, 199–216.

    Kats, A. (2005). The potential demise of another natural monopoly: Rethinking the collective

    administration of performing rights. Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 1(3),

    541–593. https://doi.org/10.3868/s050-004-015-0003-8

  • Integrating Farmers’ Right To Traditional Agricultural Knowledge Into Malaysia Plant Variety Law 125

    Kon, S. (2000). Collecting societies and competition. International Intellectual Property Law &

    Policy, 4(94), 1–16. https://doi.org/10.3366/ajicl.2011.0005

    Kretschmer, M. (2005). The Aims of European Competition Policy towards Copyright Collecting

    Societies. Society for Economic Research on Copyright Issues. Montreal. Retrieved from

    http://www.serci.org/2005/kretchmer.pdf

    Luise Schild, A. (2012, May). Collecting Societies and competition law: An overview of EU and

    national case law. Competition Law Bulletin, 1–17. Retrieved from

    http://www.concurrences.com

    Mankiw, N. G. (2009). Principles of Economics (5th ed.). Cengage Learning Asia Pte Ltd.

    https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199687114.013.32

    Olatunji, O. A., Adam, K. I., & Aboyeji, F. O. (2017). Collective management of rights in musical

    works and sound recordings: A critique of the copyright society of Nigeria. International

    Review of Intellectual Property and Competition Law, 48(7), 838–863.

    Patel, A., Panda, A., Deo, A., Khettry, S., & Matthew, S. P. (2011). Intellectual property law &

    competition law. Journal of International Commercial Law and Technology, 6(2), 120–

    130.

    Pereira, A. L. D. (2011). Software interoperability, intellectual property and competition law -

    Compulsory licenses for abuse of market dominance. Computer Law and Security Review,

    27(2), 175–179. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.clsr.2011.01.001

    Riccio, G. M., & Codiglione, G. (2013). Copyright collecting societies, monopolistic positions and

    competition in the EU single Market. Masaryk University Journal of Law and Technology,

    7, 287–302. https://doi.org/10.3366/ajicl.2011.0005

    Riis, T., Rognstad, O. A., & Schovsbo, J. H. (2016). Collective Agreements for the Clearance of

    Copyrights – The Case of Collective Management and Extended Collective Licenses (No.

    2016–16). Copenhagen.

    Rodger, B., & Ungureanu, D. (2010). Article 234 EC and Competition Law. RRDE, 1, 79–91.

    https://doi.org/10.3366/ajicl.2011.0005

    Sinacore-guinn, D. (1993). International Guide to Collective Administration Organizations

    Administration Organizations. Boston Little, Brown and Co.

    Tomain, J. P. (2002). The persistence of natural monopoly. American Bar Association, 16(4), 242–

    246.

    Towse, R. (1999). Copyright and economic incentives: An application to performers’ rights in the

    music industry. KYKLOS, 52(March 1994), 369–390.

    Tseneva - Sapoundjieva, D. (2008). Licensing of Music Online – Collective Management Problems

    and Perspectives. In V. Tsakova, G. Damianov, S. Stefanov, A. Ivanova, & I. Ivanov (Eds.),

    IP Overview 2007 (Vol. 2, pp. 41–46). Bulgaria: Publishing house IP Bulgaria.

    Watt, R. (2010). Copyright and contract law: Economic theory of copyright contracts. Journal of

    Intellectual Property Law, 18, 173–206. https://doi.org/10.3366/ajicl.2011.0005

    Zhang, Z. (2016). Rationale of collective management organizations: An economic perspective.

    Masaryk University Journal of Law and Technology, 10(1), 73–111.

    https://doi.org/10.5817/MUJLT2016-1-4