mgi us imbalancing act full report

Upload: rrafeh119

Post on 14-Apr-2018

222 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    1/112

    MKise G Istitute

    The US Imbalancing Act:Can the Current AccountDecit Continue?

    June 2007

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    2/112

    2

    MKise G Istitute

    The McKinsey Global Institute (MGI), ounded in 1990, is McKinsey &

    Companys economics research arm. MGIs mission is to help business and

    government leaders develop a deeper understanding o the evolution o the

    global economy, and provide a act-base that contributes to decision making

    on critical management and policy issues.

    MGIs research is a unique combination o two disciplines: economics and

    management. By integrating these two perspectives, MGI is able to gain

    insights into the microeconomic underpinnings o the broad trends shaping

    the global economy. MGI has utilized this micro-to-macro approach in

    research covering over 15 countries and 28 industry sectors, on topics that

    include economic productivity, global economic integration, oshoring, capital

    markets, health care, energy, demographics, and consumer demand.

    MGIs research is conducted by a group o ull-time MGI Fellows based in

    oces in San Francisco, Washington, DC, London, and Shanghai and led

    by MGIs director Diana Farrell. MGI project teams also include consultants

    drawn rom McKinseys oces around the world, and are supported by

    McKinseys network o industry and management experts and worldwide

    partners. In addition, MGI teams work with leading economists, including

    Nobel laureates and policy experts, who act as advisors to MGI projects.

    MGIs research is unded by the partners o McKinsey & Company and not

    commissioned by any business, government, or other institution. Further

    inormation about MGI and copies o MGIs published reports can be oundat www.mckinsey.com/mgi.

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    3/112

    The US Imbalancing Act:Can the Current AccountDecit Continue?

    Diana Farrell

    Susan LundAlexander Maasry

    Sebastian Roemer

    McKinsey Global Institute

    June 2007

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    4/112

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    5/112

    5

    Preace

    This report is the product o a six-month research project by the McKinsey Global

    Institute (MGI). The research builds on MGIs previous research in global capital

    markets, and draws on the unique perspectives o our colleagues who work with

    nancial institutions and companies in the United States and around the world.

    Susan Lund, a senior ellow at MGI based in Washington, DC, worked closely

    with me to provide leadership or the project. The team also included Alexander

    Maasry and Sebastian Roemer, both MGI ellows. In addition, we would like to

    recognize the support given by Tim Beacom, a senior analyst at MGI, and Moira

    Soronas, a senior analyst at the McKinsey Knowledge Center.

    We have beneted enormously rom the thoughtul contribution o our academic

    advisors. Martin N. Baily, an advisor to McKinsey and a senior ellow at the Pe-

    terson Institute or International Economics, provided valuable input throughout

    the project. Richard Cooper, proessor o international economics at Harvard

    University, and Kenneth Rogo, a proessor o public policy and economics at

    Harvard University, oered insightul comments on the report. William Cline, a

    senior ellow at the Peterson Institute or International Economics, gave helpul

    eedback on our economic modeling.

    We would also like to thank Janet Bush or her editorial eorts, Rebeca Robboy

    or leading external communications, and Deadra Henderson or managing report

    production. Sara Larsen, executive assistant, provided the team with supportthroughout the project.

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    6/112

    Our goal in this report is to provide business leaders and policy makers witha act-base and insights into one o the most important issues in the world

    economy todaythe growing US current account decit. As with all MGI projects,

    this work is independent and has not been commissioned or sponsored by any

    business, government, or other institution.

    Diana Farrell

    Director, McKinsey Global Institute

    June 2007

    San Francisco

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    7/112

    7

    Table o contents

    Preace 5

    Executive summary 9

    1. Understanding the US current account decit 17

    2. Could the world und a larger US current account decit? 35

    3. Export growth: The key to closing the US decit? 9

    . Potential dollar depreciation and impact on trade patterns 1

    5. Opportunities and challenges or business and policy

    makers 75

    Appendices

    A. Technical notes 81

    B. Methodology or modeling a dollar depreciation and impact

    on the current account 89

    C. Scenarios or dollar depreciation and impact on US trade

    patterns 97

    Bibliography 107

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    8/112

    8

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    9/112

    9

    Executive summary

    Many economists believe that the United States current account decit is on

    an unsustainable path.1 Economic alarm bells started ringing in the late 1990s,

    and yet the decit has continued to grow unabated.2 In modern times, no large

    economy has run a decit o this size or such a prolonged period o time. This

    unprecedented situation is now commanding the attention o business leaders,

    investors, and policy makers around the world.

    When the annual US current account decit reached 3 percent o GDP in 1999,

    economists warned that the trend was worrisome. In 200, the annual decit

    reached .5 percent o GDP a record $857 billion thus compounding economists

    concerns (Exhibit 1). To und its chronic decit, the United States now absorbs a

    majority o net capital outfows rom other regions o the world (Exhibit 2). The

    total US net oreign debt has swollen to $2.7 trillion, leaving the United States

    vulnerable to changes in global investors sentiment. I oreign investors were to

    lose their appetite or dollar-denominated assets, US interest rates would prob-

    ably rise substantially, at least in the short run, thus restraining overall economic

    growth. Many economists and commentators believe a major correctioninvolving

    a signicant depreciation o the dollaris looming.

    This prompted the McKinseyGlobal Institute (MGI) to consider the US currentaccount decit under two very dierent scenarios over the next ve years: the

    decit continuing to expand; and the current account coming into balance. On

    one hand, could the world und an ever-growing US decit? On the other, i the

    1 For example, see Maurice Obsteld and Kenneth Rogo, The unsustainable US current account

    position revisited, 2005; Martin Baily, Dollar Adjustment to Reduce US Imbalance, 2007;William Cline, The United States as a Debtor Nation: Risks and Policy Reorm, 2005.

    2 Among others, Catherine Mann in Is the US Trade Decit Sustainable?, 1999.

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    10/112

    10

    Eiit 1

    THE US CURRENT ACCOUNT DEFICIT REACHED$857 BILLION OR 6.5 PERCENT OF GDP IN 2006

    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; International Monetary Fund; Global Insight; McKinsey Global Institute GlobalCapital Flows Database

    US current account balance$ billion

    $ billion

    % of GDP

    % of GDP

    -1,000

    -800

    -600

    -400

    -200

    0

    200

    1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

    -10

    -8

    -6

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    Eiit 2

    THE UNITED STATES ABSORBS MOST OF THE WORLD'S NETCAPITAL FLOWS

    * Total net inflows exceed net outflows by $148 billion due to statistical errors and omissions; some of this could reflect "gray market"money as well as the fact that some countries do not report inflows and outflows.

    Source: International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital Flows Database

    UnitedStates

    JapanOtherWesternEurope

    Africa EurozoneLatinAmerica

    Australia-Pacific

    UnitedKingdom

    Unattri-butedflows*

    MiddleEast

    EasternEurope

    Russia

    %of GDP

    5.0 1.8 4.9 0.43.5 -1.6 -2.1 -6.6 -5.1 N/A-8.9 -2.8

    Canada

    -0.7

    OtherAsia

    -3.4

    Average annual net capital inflows minus net capital outflows, 20012005$ billion

    -148-137-119

    -96-61-52

    -32-20-3

    9303235

    562

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    11/112

    11

    decit were eliminated, what would be the impact on the value o the dollar andon US trade patterns? A number o surprising results emerge that challenge

    conventional wisdom.

    We nd there is nothing inevitable about a correction in the US current account

    decit over the next ve years. It could instead continue to grow, and the world

    would have enough capital to und it. At current exchange rates, the United

    States could trim the decit slightly by increasing service and manuacturing

    exportsbut not enough to reverse its current trajectory. I a large dollar depre-

    ciation were to occur, we believe it would more likely be gradual than sudden.

    Nonetheless, our analysis illustrates how a very large and rapid dollar deprecia-tion could bring the decit back towards balance with signicantly altered trade

    patterns. Irrespective o whether the adjustment process is gradual or rapid,

    however, business leaders and policy makers should start considering what a

    post-devaluation world would mean or them.

    ThE US cUrrEnT accoUnT dEIcIT coUld conTInUE To Grow

    Our analysis shows that a correction in the US decit is neither imminent nor

    inevitable. Under the current pattern o the US current account, world growth and

    exchange rates, the US current account decit would reach $1. trillion in 2012,or 9 percent o GDP . For this to happen, however, the current account surpluses o

    other countries would also have to grow suciently large to und the decit.We nd

    that under reasonable assumptions, these surpluses would reach $2.1 trillion in

    2012, providing the capital required. US net oreign debt would reach percent

    o GDP , but the United States would still be able to nance the decit because the

    implied net oreign interest payments would remain at less than 1 percent o GDP .

    That said, there are several scenarios that could limit growth in the global net

    capital outfows necessary to und the US decit. For instance, i China were to

    increase domestic consumption and reduce its savings signicantly, net capital

    outfows rom Chinacurrently a signicant source o unding or the US de-

    citcould all dramatically. In our model, this would leave the US decit equiva-

    lent to 90 percent o the remaining global net capital outfows, a gure that is

    implausibly high. However, we consider this scenario unlikely. MGIs research on

    Chinas consumer market shows that although domestic demand will account or

    a greater share o GDP , its expansion will come largely rom growth in incomes

    and there will be only a slight all in the national savings rate. 3 Other scenarios,

    in isolation, would not limit growth in the US decit.

    3 From Made in China to Sold in China: The Rise o the Chinese Urban Consumer, McKinsey

    Global Institute, November 200.

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    12/112

    12

    Neither will the ability o the United States to und its current account decit dependon the price o oil. Oil imports are the largest single component o the US trade

    decit. However, although a higher oil price increases the value o US imports, it

    also increases the current account surpluses in oil-exporting economies. This

    capital is then recycled into global nancial markets. It doesnt matter whether

    these petrodollars are invested in Europe or Asia rather than being invested directly

    in the United States; by increasing the capital available in the global nancial

    system, they still contribute to unding the US current account decit.

    ElIMInaTInG ThE cUrrEnT accoUnT dEIcIT woUld EnTaIl a larGE

    dollar dEprEcIaTIon

    Although our research shows that the US current account decit could plausibly

    continue to grow over the next ve years, the United States cannot continue to

    build up oreign liabilities orever. Eventually the decit will need to stabilize, or

    even decline, relative to the size o the US economy. A major rebalancing o global

    demand and a dollar depreciation o historic proportions would be required or

    this to happen over the next ve years.

    To balance the US current account by 2012, we nd that the dollar would need to

    depreciate by 30 percent rom its January 2007 level. Reducing the decit to 3

    percent o GDP , a level that many economists believe to be sustainable,5 would

    require a 23 percent depreciation. Only once over the last 35 years has the

    dollar depreciated by 30 percent within a ve-year periodin 198588. However,

    in 1985 the dollar was at its highest level since 1970, whereas today the dollar

    is already below its average post-1970 value, and a urther 30 percent all would

    leave it at its lowest level since 1970.

    In the absence o a depreciation in the dollar, we nd it likely that the United States

    could do little more than slow the growth o the decit. Based on a detailed micro-economic analysis o US exports, our ndings suggest that at current exchange

    rates the United States could potentially increase its share o service and manu-

    acturing exports to other countries by $25 billion and $20 billion respectively.

    However, this would require either much aster GDP growth in the rest o the world

    than is currently projected, or the United States to win share o imports rom other

    Improving energy eciency in the United States could reduce its oil imports and lower the trade

    decit. We calculate that the United States could reduce oil imports by 10 percent by 2012 just

    by implementing technologies available today that improve energy productivity. See chapter 3

    or more detail.5 For instance, see Ahearne, Alan, William Cline, et al., Global Imbalances: Time or Action, IIE

    Policy Brie, Peterson Institute or International Economics, Washington, DC, orthcoming in

    2007

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    13/112

    13

    countries. Even so, at best this increase would merely hold the US current accountdecit to its current level relative to GDP , or .5 percent.

    I the dollar were to depreciate, a 30 percent decline could play out in dierent

    ways, since currencies rarely move evenly against all others. We modeled three

    depreciation scenarios: rst, an even depreciation against all currencies; second,

    a scenario under which Asian currencies adjust the most; and third, a scenario

    under which Asian currencies maintain their current value and the adjustment

    takes place in Europe, Canada and Mexico, and the rest o the world. While the

    eects o these scenarios dier, a number o changes in trade patterns appear

    under all three.

    aTEr dEprEcIaTIon, a larGE US TradE dEIcIT pErSISTS

    parTIcUlarly wITh chIna

    Surprisingly, even i the United States were to balance its current account, it would

    still continue to run a large trade decit. Under all three depreciation scenarios,

    the US trade decit in goods would stand at around $720 billion in 2012only

    slightly smaller than it is today. However, this decit on merchandise trade would

    be oset by a $30 billion surplus on trade in services and by positive net

    oreign-income payments. The latter is due to a turnaround in the US oreign debt

    position. I current trends were to continue, US net oreign debt would rise to

    $8.1 trillion in 2012. However, i the dollar were to depreciate by 30 percent, the

    United States would become a net oreign creditorto the tune o $.8 trillion,

    generating $35 billion a year in net interest payments to the United States.

    Under all depreciation scenarios, the United States would continue to run a

    large bilateral trade decit with China. The bilateral decit was $198 billion in

    2005more than one-quarter o the total US trade decit. Even i the dollar

    were to depreciate by 5 percent against the yuan (as it does under our seconddepreciation scenario), however, the US trade decit with China would still be

    $87 billion. The huge cost advantage that China enjoys in producing goods such

    as toys and clothing means that the yuan would need to appreciate by more than

    50 percent to eliminate the US trade decit with China.

    In contrast, US trade with Canada and Mexicocountries oten overlooked in the

    current debatewould improve dramatically. Our model shows that the US trade

    balance with NAFTA would swing rom a decit o $109 billion to a surplus o

    Our model assumes that the dollar depreciates against all Asian currencies by the sameamount. I the yuan appreciated more than other Asian currencies, some production o low-costgoods could shit, over time, rom China to other countries, such as Vietnam or Cambodia. This

    could reduce the bilateral decit with China.

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    14/112

    1

    $100 billion or more. This would hit the Canadian and Mexican economies hard,and the United States would have to work with them to ease the transition.

    SErvIcES and hIGh-TEch ExporTS Show bIGGEST opporTUnITy or

    IMprovEMEnT

    Although, with a balanced current account, the United States would still have

    a trade decit, in the years ollowing a large dollar depreciation US exports

    across a range o products would increase dramatically. US services exports

    could increase by 30 percent, or $107 billion, rom todays level. Current US

    trade surpluses in nancial services, royalties and licenses, business services,travel, and education would grow dramaticallyparticularly to Europe, the United

    Kingdom, Japan, and Canada.

    Also receiving a strong boost rom depreciation would be US exports o high-tech

    machinery, such as computers and semiconductors, medical devices, electrical

    appliances and machinery, oce and telecommunications equipment, and arm

    and construction equipment. Todays $13 billion US trade decit in this cat-

    egory would turn into a surplus o as much as $51 billion. This growth potential

    highlights the importance o continued productivity improvements in a sector

    that not only generates exports directly but also enables the United States to

    produce other technologically sophisticated products, rom surgical equipment

    to computerized arm machinery.

    an aGEnda or bUSInESS lEadErS and polIcy MaKErS

    Although the US current account decit could possibly be reversed over the next

    ve years and spark a major decline in the value o the dollar, we believe that the

    adjustment is more likely to be gradual. The world could und a larger decit, and

    a reversal need not be immediate. Capital infows into the United States have

    grown continuously despite the decit, the war in Iraq, the 9/11 terrorist attacks

    and other adverse events. Fundamentally, the US economy is strong and oers

    an attractive risk-adjusted return or investors. Nonetheless, business leaders

    and policy makers should start planning or the possibility that a large dollar all

    might unold more rapidly.

    Business leaders would do well to consider how a large decline in the dollar

    would aect their income statements and balance sheets and what actions

    they can take today to prepare or this possibility. Our research yields detailed

    insights into what a post-devaluation world would look like. China, or example,would retain its costs advantage as an export location, but Canada and Mexico

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    15/112

    15

    could lose theirs. US companies would see growing oreign demand or manytypes o nancial and business services but, to capture this opportunity, they

    would have to acquire the requisite language skills and develop products that

    meet oreign standards. US companies producing computers, semiconductors,

    medical devices, and construction equipment would benet disproportionately.

    Much o the public debate over the current account decit, including concern over

    the bilateral trade decit with China, is misplaced. There are other more realistic

    options or balancing the current account decit, such as improving the US trade

    balance with NAFTA and with other Asian economies and expanding service and

    high-tech exports.

    The primary policy ocus should be on areas oering the United States oppor-

    tunities to improve its trade balance signicantly. Service exports clearly have

    signicant growth potential, and trade negotiators should continue to reduce bar-

    riers to global trade in services. The United States must retain the competitive

    environment necessary or its high-tech sectors to drive innovation and R&D in

    order to develop the next generation o cutting-edge products. And policy makers

    should recognize that trade with Canada and Mexico is at least as important as

    that with Europe and Asia, and consequently they should step up eorts within

    NAFTA to enhance the areas competitive advantage.

    The ollowing chapters discuss these ndings in more detail. Chapter 1 proles

    the US current account decit and explores who is unding it. Chapter 2 assesses

    how large the decit would be by 2012 i current trends continued, and explores

    whether the world could plausibly und an even larger US decit. In chapter 3

    a microeconomic approach is employed to examine the potential or the United

    States to increase exports o services and manuactured goods without a change

    in the value o the dollar. Chapter explores scenarios or dollar depreciation to

    reduce the size o the decit and their implications or trade patterns. Chapter

    5 outlines the opportunities and challenges acing business leaders and policy

    makers.

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    16/112

    1

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    17/112

    17

    The United States record-breaking current account decit has triggered alarm

    bells concerning the health o the US economy and the potential risks to the

    United States and other countries o a sudden reversal in the capital infows

    needed to und it.

    Beore exploring whether the decit could continue to grow over the next ve

    years and what actors might reverse the trend, we rst assess its components,

    what has caused the decit to reach its current size, patterns o oreign invest-

    ment in the United States, and the dierent ways in which the US decit is

    nanced. Readers who are already acquainted with these topics can move on to

    chapter 2.

    ThE US cUrrEnT accoUnT dEIcIT

    A countrys current account is made up o our components: trade in goods,

    trade in services, transer payments, and oreign-income payments. In the United

    States the trade decit is the largest and astest-growing part o the overall cur-

    rent account decit (Exhibit 1.1). Although a great deal o attention is currently

    ocused on the bilateral decit with Chinawhich is indeed the largest decit

    with a single countrythe United States runs trade decits with virtually every

    region o the world. China accounts or roughly 25 percent o the total decit.

    (See Box 1 or more detail on the source o US imports.)

    Nations trade in both goods and services. The US trade decit in goods is

    enormous. It reached $83 billion in 200, or more than $2 billion per day. Thelargest component o this is imported oil and other mineral uels (Exhibit 1.2). As

    1. Understanding the US current

    account decit

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    18/112

    18

    Eiit 1.1

    % ofnominalGDP

    -4.5 -4.8 -5.7 -6.3 -6.5-3.8-4.2-3.2-2.4

    THE TRADE DEFICIT IS THE LARGEST COMPONENT OF THE CURRENTACCOUNT DEFICIT

    Note: Figure may not sum to 100% due to rounding.

    Source: International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital Flows Database

    5.8

    N/A

    7.4

    13.5

    -1.4 -1.7-1.6-1.5-1.7-1.3-0.80.0

    Compound annualgrowth rate,19902006

    %

    $ billion (nominal)

    -40-40 -38

    -43 -45

    -53

    -50

    -59-51

    -64

    -69

    -82

    -86

    -84

    10 1112

    24

    29

    -27-110

    -35

    29

    -79

    1990

    -76

    45

    3

    1991

    24

    -95

    56

    -50

    1992

    25

    -131

    60

    1993

    17

    -164

    65

    -665

    51

    -662

    28

    2003

    -527

    49

    -544

    25 37

    2002

    -473

    58

    -479

    2001

    -389

    61

    -424

    2000

    -416

    72

    -450

    21

    1999

    -300

    80

    Transfers

    -344

    14

    1998

    -214

    80

    -245

    4

    1997

    -140

    88

    -196

    13

    1996

    -125

    85

    -189

    22

    1995

    -114-85

    76

    -172

    21

    1994

    -122

    2004

    -779

    62

    -792

    2005

    -7

    -836

    72

    -8552006

    Services

    Goods

    Income

    Eiit 1.2

    MINERAL FUELS AND MANUFACTURED GOODS CONTRIBUTE MOSTTO THE US TRADE DEFICIT

    * Includes low-value imports, trade not classified elsewhere, and non-monetary gold and coin.

    Source: United States International Trade Commission; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    US trade balance, 2006$ billion

    4

    Chemicals

    6

    Food &agriculture

    -836Goodstrade

    72

    Services

    -764

    Tradebalance

    280

    Other*

    299

    Manu-facturedgoods

    44

    -299

    122

    Vehicles &machines

    Mineralfuels

    Auto-mobiles

    93

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    19/112

    19

    the price o oil has risen over the last several years this portion o the US tradedecit has soared. Since 200, growth in the cost o oil imports has accounted

    or 5 percent o the deterioration in the US trade decit. The United States

    also runs large trade decits in manuactured goodsclothes, plastics, toys,

    consumer electronics, and urnitureas well as vehicles and machines.

    In contrast the United States has consistently run a surplus in services trade

    over the last 15 years (Exhibit 1.3). However, at $72 billion in 200, this surplus

    is very small in comparison to the goods trade decit. The positive balance in

    services was composed o surpluses in business proessional services, royalties

    and licenses, and nancial services, with decits in other categories such as

    insurance and transportation services.

    The overall US trade balance improved between November 200 and February

    2007. Over this our-month period the decit was $1 billion smaller than a year

    earlier. This was explained primarily by a smaller bill or mineral uels ($1 billion)

    refecting a lower oil price; by contrast, the manuacturing trade decit continued

    to grow. The trade decit with China deteriorated by $15 billion compared with a

    year earlier but improved with all other regions. It remains to be seen whether or

    not these improvements continue throughout 2007. Trade fows can be volatile

    on a month-to-month but an increase in the US trade decit in March 2007

    compared with year earlier gave grounds or caution.

    Eiit 1.3

    34

    27

    13

    10

    25

    18

    72

    35

    Businessservices*

    Financialservices

    Royaltiesandlicenses

    Travel TotalOthertransport

    1

    Passengerfares

    Education

    5

    Insuranceservices

    Tele-communi-cations

    US SERVICE TRADE SURPLUS IS MAINLY IN BUSINESS SERVICES,ROYALTIES, AND FINANCIAL SERVICES

    US services-trade surplus, 2006$ billion

    * Computer and information services, management and consulting services, R&D, operational leasing film andother.

    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    20/112

    20

    Tse mets et ime

    The second component o the current account is transer payments. These

    represent transers to and rom the United States o unds that are not being

    exchanged or nancial assets or goods. The largest types o transers are remit-

    tancesmoney sent home by immigrant workersand tax payments to oreign

    governments by workers in the United States. The US decit in net transer

    payments has grown steadily larger over time, reaching $8 billion in 200.

    The nal component o the current account is income payments on oreign invest-

    ments. These include interest on bond and bank deposits, dividends on stocks,

    and prots earned by oreign subsidiaries.1 Every country has both oreign-income

    payments (money sent abroad on oreign-owned assets within the economy) and

    oreign-income receipts (money received rom oreign assets owned abroad).

    Traditionally the United States has had positive net oreign-income payments.

    However, in 200 the United States experienced negative net income or the rst

    time ever (Exhibit 1.).

    It is astonishing that the United States has been a net oreign debtor to the world

    since 198 but has still managed to earn positive net oreign income until last

    1 Income earned by subsidiaries abroad is counted as a net income receipt in the currentaccount, whether or not that prot is repatriated to the parent company. I it is reinvested

    abroad, then it also generates a new FDI outfow.

    Eiit 1.4

    -50

    -40

    -30

    -20

    -10

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

    -3,500

    -2,500

    -1,500

    -500

    500

    1,500

    2,500

    3,500

    US net foreign income$ billion

    US net foreign-asset position$ billion

    Net foreign-asset position

    US NET FOREIGN INCOME WAS POSITIVE UNTIL

    2006, DESPITE GROWING NET DEBT

    Net foreign income

    Source: International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital Flows Database; McKinsey GlobalInstitute Cross-Border Investments Database

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    21/112

    21

    year. The reason or this highly unusual situation is that the United States hasearned a higher rate o return on its investments abroad than oreigners earn in

    the United States. Since 1990 the dierence between the two has averaged 1.3

    percent (Exhibit 1.5). However, the true spread is likely to be even larger because

    oreign-interest payments do not capture unrealized capital gains on equity and

    oreign direct investments (FDI)and these make up a larger share o US invest-

    ments abroad than oreign investments in the United States (Exhibit 1.).2

    All in all, the United States obtains a very good deal on its oreign borrowing. In

    200 US net oreign income nally became negative due to the size o the US

    net oreign debtnow at $2.7 trillionand to the declining spread on returns o

    US assets versus liabilities. I the current account decit were to persist in the

    years ahead, US net oreign income would deteriorate urther as it borrows more

    each year to nance the decit.

    w us te US uet ut eit?

    A nations current account refects the dierence between domestic savings and

    investment. Any decit must be unded through borrowing abroad. This shows

    up in the capital account in the national balance o payments, which refects

    the dierence between capital infows into a country and outfows rom that

    2 In What explains the US net income balance? 2007, Alexandra Heath estimates that the real

    spread on returns o US oreign assets and liabilities has been .7 percent.

    Eiit 1.5

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    RETURNS ON US FOREIGN ASSETS HAVE EXCEEDED

    RETURNS PAID ON US LIABILITIES BY 1.3 PERCENT

    * Calculated from foreign income receipts and payments. Does not include appreciation of value of assets orliabilities.

    Source: International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital Flows Database; McKinsey GlobalInstitute Cross-Border Investments Database; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    Foreign assets: 5.4%

    Average spread,19902006: 1.3%

    Average annualreturns, 19902006

    Foreign liabilities: 4.1%

    US foreign income returns on assets and liabilities*%

    Foreign liabilities

    Foreign assets

    Spread on return

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    22/112

    22

    country. In principle the sum o the capital account balance and the currentaccount balance should be zero. However, in practice errors in reporting and

    statistical discrepancies in data result in dierences.3 In 200, or instance, the

    United States had oreign capital infows o $1,75 billion and capital outfows

    o $1,0 billion (Exhibit 1.7). This resulted in a capital account surplus o $721

    billion compared with a current account decit o $857 billion. The $13 billion

    gap was due to errors and omissions.

    To understand which countries are unding the US current account decit, we

    consider two dierent perspectives.

    eig iestmet i te Uite Sttes

    In order to understand who is unding the US decit one must rst look at oreign

    investors in the United States. In 2005 they purchased $1.2 trillion o US assets

    (equal to US capital infows). This includes oreign direct investment (FDI) into US

    companies, purchases o equity, private debt, and government debt securities,

    oreign lending to the United States, and deposits into US banks and nancial

    institutions (see Box 2 or more detail on capital fows into the United States).

    3 Since 2001, the sum o all countries oreign capital infows has exceeded reported capital

    outfows by an average o $18 billion per year.

    Eiit 1.6

    US FOREIGN ASSETS ARE MAINLY IN EQUITY AND FDI,WHILE LIABILITIES ARE IN DEBT AND LENDING/DEPOSITS

    * Foreign direct investment.

    Note: Figure may not sum to 100% due to rounding.

    Source: International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Cross-Border Investments Database

    US foreign assets and liabilities, 2005%, $ billion

    3220

    28

    17

    9

    34

    30 28

    FDI*

    100%13,68710,894

    Equity

    Debt

    Lending/deposits

    LiabilitiesAssets

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    23/112

    23

    The US Bureau o Economic Analysis collects data on the countries that are the

    source o these investments. These data do not give an entirely accurate viewo oreign investments, however, because some oreign investors use nancial

    intermediaries in the Caribbean, London, and other oshore centers. We develop

    a methodology to estimate the true source o these unds as described in

    appendix A.

    Ater adjusting the data we see that Japan and other Asian nations provide the

    largest source o capital infows to the United States, averaging $50 billion per

    year rom 200205 (Exhibit 1.8). Over the same period the United Kingdom and

    continental European nations together invested just over $00 billion annually.

    The remainder o capital infows came rom Canada, the Middle East, and the

    rest o the world.

    Investors rom dierent regions exhibit preerences or dierent types o US as-

    set. While two-thirds o Asian investments are in US government debt, Europeans

    invest a larger portion o their unds in US corporate debt and loans and deposits,

    while Middle Eastern investors enter US markets through corporate-debt securi-

    ties, FDI, and deposits into banks and other nancial institutions such as private

    equity unds (Exhibit 1.9).

    Most o the money we attribute to the rest o the world was channeled through Caribbeannations. Some o this money may, in act, have originated in the Middle East, Europe, Asia, or

    even the United States itsel.

    Eiit 1.7

    IN 2006, US CAPITAL INFLOWS WERE $1.8 TRILLION,COMPARED TO $1.0 TRILLION OF CAPITAL OUTFLOWS

    * Includes foreign direct investment, purchases of equity and debt securities, foreign loans and deposits, andforeign reserve asset purchases.

    Source: International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital Flows Database

    865798783

    740

    424

    707551

    439 427

    868

    326295383

    561504

    354413

    352

    1995 1996

    485

    1997 1998 1999

    1,047

    2000 2001 2002 2003

    1,450

    2004

    1,212

    2005

    1,765

    1,046

    2006

    Capital outflows

    Capital inflows

    US capital inflows and outflows,* 19952006$ billion

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    24/112

    2

    Eiit 1.8

    ASIA HAS BEEN THE LARGEST SOURCE OF CAPITAL INFLOWSTO THE UNITED STATES SINCE 2002

    * After attributing funds channeled through the UK, Caribbean and Switzerland back to their original source.Bilateral capital inflows do not match total capital inflows due to statistical discrepancy.

    ** Includes Latin America, Africa, and unattributed flows.

    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; US Treasury Department; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    Average20022005

    $ billion

    272

    261

    69

    86

    141

    51

    203

    US bilateral capital inflows*$ billion

    80 123166 124 152

    177 110

    121

    120

    203

    210

    279

    7774

    7

    140

    66

    221

    50

    424

    1998

    165

    2722

    390

    5

    740

    1999

    207

    1355

    73

    484

    50

    1,047

    2000

    151

    13

    70

    306

    47

    783

    2001

    27

    236

    279

    59

    798

    2002

    7943

    231

    137

    20

    865

    2003

    262

    287

    406

    43

    1,450

    1258

    2004

    52

    290

    264

    1,212

    2005

    Rest of world**

    Middle East

    Other Asia

    Japan

    Europe

    United Kingdom

    Canada

    Eiit 1.9

    FOREIGN INVESTORS FROM EACH REGION BUY DIFFERENT TYPES OFUS ASSETS

    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; US Treasury Department; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    Inflows to the US by region, 20022005 average%, $ billion

    24

    69

    37

    23

    6

    46

    18

    12

    61

    70

    12

    17

    18

    32

    Rest of

    world

    57

    3 5

    Middle

    East

    33

    7

    2203261

    Lending/deposits

    Government debt

    Asia

    16

    53

    Japan

    1015

    0

    100% = 27214151

    Private debt

    Equity

    FDI

    United

    Kingdom

    25

    86

    Europe

    19

    44

    8

    21

    23

    4

    69

    Canada

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    25/112

    25

    This picture o oreign investment in the United States does not, however, revealthe whole story about who is unding the US current account decit. Although

    many European investors are buying US equities and bonds, their countries may,

    in act, be running current account decits themselves. The United Kingdom,

    or instance, has invested an average o $11 billion in the United States rom

    200205 while at the same time running its own current account decit. This

    meant that the United Kingdom was a net importer o capital rom the world

    during this period.

    cuties it uet ut suuses

    The ultimate answer as to who is unding the US current account decit is

    countries with current account surpluses. Even i these countries do not invest

    directly in the United States, their surpluses add to global liquidity and their

    capital outfows lter through global nancial markets, ultimately enabling capital

    infows to countries running current account decits.

    Western Europe, Asia, and the oil-exporting economies are the main sources o

    current account surpluses in the world today. In 200 net capital outfows rom

    these countriescapital outfows minus their capital infowsreached $1.3

    trillion (Exhibit 1.10).5 Oil exporters including the Middle East, Norway, Russia,

    Nigeria, and Venezuela had the largest share ($8 billion), ollowed by East Asia

    ($ billion) and Western Europe ($308 billion).

    The worlds net suppliers o capital have shited over time. Petrodollars rom

    oil-exporting nations are a new and growing provider o the capital to the world as

    a result o the increased price o oil in recent years. Over the past 15 years it was

    East Asia that was the largest provider o capital to the world. During the 1990s

    the net capital outfows rom East Asia came largely rom Japan. However, since

    the nancial crises o 199798 many other Asian countries have started to run

    current account surpluses and are today major providers o capital.

    Some countries in Western Europe have also been large net exporters o capital

    over the last 15 years, including Germany, Switzerland, and the Netherlands.

    Unlike Asia, where capital outfows are largely in the orm o oreign-reserve

    assets owned by central banks, European capital outfows come mainly rom the

    private sector and have been invested broadly across debt and equity classes.

    Many other countries in Western Europe run current account decits, notably

    Spain, Ireland, Greece, and Portugal. Within the eurozone some o the capital

    5 This is equal to the size o their current account surpluses, except or errors and omissions,

    debt orgiveness, and other capital transers.

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    26/112

    2

    outfows rom surplus countries have undoubtedly gone to other countries within

    the monetary union.

    At $8 billion, the US current account decit is now equal to nearly 70 percent o

    the net capital outfows rom countries with current account surpluses. This very

    high proportion is historically unprecedented over the last 35 years (Exhibit 1.11).

    h eig it ifs eet te Uite Sttes

    Running a current account decit allows the United States to consume more

    than it otherwise could while maintaining a high investment rate. It also keeps

    interest rates lower than they might have been in the absence o these capital

    fows. Academic researchers have conrmed that oreign capital infows into the

    United States have lowered interest rates.7

    The downside o the US current account decit is that the United States is

    running up a large oreign debt. As in any household, a decit allows a country

    In MGIs report Mapping Global Capital Flows: Third Annual Update, we report that the USabsorbs 85 percent o the worlds net capital fows. The reason or this discrepancy is that,

    in that analysis, we looked at the current account positions o regions rather than countries.

    This produces a smaller gure or global net capital fows, since some regionsnotably

    Europehave both countries with current account surpluses and countries with decits that

    cancel each other out.7 For example, Francis Warnock in How might a disorderly resolution o global imbalances aect

    global wealth? 200, or Francis Warnock and Veronica Cacdac Warnock, International capitalfows and interest rates, September 200.

    Eiit 1.10

    ASIA, EUROPE, AND THE OIL ECONOMIES ARE THE WORLD'SNET CAPITAL EXPORTERS

    Note: Only includes countries in any given year with a current account surplus/capital account deficit.

    * Includes Algeria, Indonesia, Iran, Nigeria, Norway, Kuwait, Libya, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Syria, United ArabEmirates, Venezuela and Yemen.

    Source: International Monetary Fund; Global Insight; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital Flows Database

    Net capital outflows from countries with current account surpluses$ billion

    133 98 156240

    218

    198

    169 224

    292

    359

    435

    446

    110 132151

    121125

    89

    91129

    184

    273

    268

    308

    926

    1,319

    371

    301

    691

    351

    1,199

    2006E200520042003

    503509417412

    484

    81

    429

    WesternEurope

    Petro-dollars*

    Rest ofworld

    EastAsia

    2002

    69

    238

    56

    167

    49

    8

    35

    4

    1995

    9

    62

    1996

    2

    42

    1997

    3282

    1998

    60

    1999

    30

    192

    7

    30

    127

    2001

    42

    108

    2000

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    27/112

    27

    to shit consumption rom the uture to the presentbut creates liabilities that

    need to be paid later. Interestingly, however, the US net debt position has not

    deteriorated as quickly as the sum o these cumulative current account decits

    would normally indicate. Since 2002 the US net debt position has risen by only

    $275 billion while the current account decits over the period totaled $2,88

    billion. This is because US oreign assets have appreciated in value at a higher

    rate than oreign liabilities due to a small decline in the dollar over the period,

    higher returns on oreign than US stock markets, and very high returns earned

    by US companies on their oreign investments abroad. Overall then, the United

    States has ound a way to consume more than it otherwise couldand to do so

    relatively cheaply.

    Running a persistent current account decit also risks aecting adversely the

    mix o jobs available in the economy. While running a decit, the United States

    is exporting less and importing more than it otherwise would. Where jobs in

    tradable sectors such as manuacturing, automotive, and high-tech are well-paid

    or otherwise desirable, the risk is that the quality o these jobs erodes. This

    may partly explain why, even at a time o ull employment, many US workers still

    express concern about oshoring and trade.

    Finally, running a current account decit requires the United States to attract

    oreign capital infows each year. I capital infows were to experience a sudden

    Eiit 1.11

    THE UNITED STATES HAS ABSORBED ~70 PERCENT OF NET GLOBALCAPITAL FLOWS SINCE 2001

    * Line shows value of US current account deficit divided by the sum of net capital outflows minus inflows forcountries with a current account surplus in that year.

    Source: International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital Flows Database

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

    US current account deficit as % of global net capital outflows, 19702005%

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    28/112

    28

    stop, or even i oreign investors had less appetite or dollar assets in comingyears, the United States could potentially see interest rates rise and economic

    growth slow down.

    wt s use te US uet ut eit t g?

    Several explanations have been oered or the growth in the United States cur-

    rent account decit, and each contributes a part o the story. One explanation is

    that the United States spends too much and saves too little. A current account

    decit represents the gap between what a country saves and what it invests.

    While US private and government investment rates have been relatively stable

    over the past decade, the national savings rate has decreased. US corporations

    have maintained healthy savings rates, but the US household savings rate has

    allen by 5 percent over the past 15 years as consumers have gained greater

    access to all kinds o credit productscredit cards, car nancing, mortgages,

    home equity loans, and student loans. In addition, the large government scal

    decits o recent years have caused government saving to turn negative, urther

    lowering the national savings rate. A low level o domestic savings has allowed

    the United States to consume more than it otherwise would. By running a current

    account decit, the United States has generated enormous demand, oering

    other countries opportunities to export.

    An alternative explanation, amously asserted by chairman o the US Federal

    Reserve Benjamin Bernanke, is that a global savings glut has caused oreign

    investments to fow into the United States.8 This has caused the dollar and other

    asset prices to rise, allowing the United States to run a current account decit.

    Despite the relatively low interest paid to oreigners, the United States oers an

    attractive risk-return prole. It has robust GDP - and productivity-growth rates or

    a mature economy; deep and liquid nancial markets with strong creditor and

    shareholder rights; a stable macroeconomic environment; and a currency thathas de acto been the global reserve currency and has provided a sae store

    o value. One estimate has capital infows to the United States in recent years

    amounting roughly to 1015 percent o oreign savingsabout the allocation to

    dollar assets that one might expect.9

    A nal explanation is that the growth in the US current account decit is a natural

    consequence o the integration o world nancial markets. This process has

    started to sever the link between domestic savings and investment, allowing

    8 Benjamin Bernanke makes this point in The Global Savings Glut and the US Current Account

    Decit, 2005; and in Financial Regulation and the Invisible Hand, April 11, 2007.

    9 This estimate appears in Richard Cooper, Living with Global Imbalances: A Contrarian View,

    2005.

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    29/112

    29

    many more companies and households to invest abroad. The corollary o this isthat more countries than ever beore are running larger current account decits

    and surpluses.10

    A related actor is the impact o globalization o industries. As companies ex-

    pand into oreign markets and restructure their operations internationally, they

    trade goods and services with their oreign subsidiaries. Such transactions are

    counted as imports and exports even though these subsidiaries are owned by

    parent companies within the country. Theoretically the sum o these oreign-

    aliate imports and exports could balance out. However, in the case o the

    United States, whose companies are expanding abroad more quickly than oreign

    companies are expanding in the United States, previous MGI research has ound

    that trade with oreign aliates accounted or one-third o the US current account

    decit in 200.11

    These explanations are complementary, and all play a part in the rise in the US

    current account decit to its present level.

    10 Although there is still a strong correlation between domestic savings and investment or large

    economies, it has eroded over the last ten years or smaller countries. See Martin Feldstein,Monetary policy in a changing international environment: The role o capital fows, 2005.

    11 Farrell, Diana, Sacha Ghai, and Tim Shavers, A silver lining in the United States trade decit,

    2005.

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    30/112

    30

    a se k t US imts

    The United States imported $2.2 trillion o goods and services in 200. O

    this, $32 billion was in services and $1,85 billion was in goods. The US

    International Trade Commission tracks the source o these imports to the

    United States. In 200, the United Kingdom, Germany, Japan, and Canada

    were the top our sources o service imports (Exhibit 1.12). The story or

    goods imports is somewhat dierent. Here, the largest sources o US goods

    imported were Canada ($303 billion), China ($287 billion), Mexico ($197

    billion), and Japan ($18 billion).

    However, this picture o the source o US goods imports is somewhat skewed.

    Countries oten import components o the goods that they export. Previous

    MGI research has shown, or instance, that as much as 70 percent o the

    value o Mexicos electronics exports comprises imported components and

    other inputs rom elsewhere in world.12 Thus, to understand precisely how

    much the United States imports rom each country, the value added o goods

    should be attributed back to its original source.

    12 Farrell, Diana et al., New Horizons: Multinational Company Investment in Developing Economies,McKinsey Global Institute, October 2003.

    Eiit 1.12

    THE UNITED KINGDOM AND GERMANY ARE THE LARGEST SOURCE OFSERVICE IMPORTS TO THE UNITED STATES

    * Includes Latin America, Caribbean, Middle East, Africa and unattributed services imports.

    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    US services imports$ billion, 2006

    40

    28

    25

    25

    83

    55

    70

    Japan

    Other Europe

    Germany

    Other Asia

    Rest of world*

    Canada

    Mexico 16

    United Kingdom

    342

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    31/112

    31

    MGI looked at the United States three largest trading partners in goodsCanada, China, and Mexicoto develop a better picture o bilateral imports

    into the United States. We chose the top three because Canada is the largest

    and thus the most important trading partner, and because we oten think

    o China and Mexico as assembly locations with actories assembling

    imported components or export. For these three countries, we determined

    what percentage o their exports to the United States, on average, were due

    to imported inputs. We then attributed the value o those imported inputs to

    an estimate o their original source. See appendix A or more detail on the

    methodology.

    Ater making this adjustment, we see that while Canada remains the single

    largest source o imports to the United States, Japan surpasses Mexico and

    becomes nearly as large as China (Exhibit 1.13). Europes share o US imports

    increases as well. Finally, we see that the United States itsel accounts or

    nearly $100 billion o imports. This refects the trend or US companies

    to set up oshore production acilities, particularly in Mexico and Canada.

    Parent companies oten send components and other services to their oreign

    subsidiaries, and then import nished goods back into the United States.

    Eiit 1.13

    MEXICO AND CHINA CONTRIBUTE LESS TO US IMPORTS WHENACCOUNTING FOR THE VALUE OF IMPORTED COMPONENTS

    US goods imports input imports accounted for$ billion, 2005

    US goods imports direct view$ billion, 2006

    303

    197

    287

    148

    187

    347

    170

    206

    Canada

    1,845

    Mexico

    Japan

    China

    Rest of world*

    Oil-exporters**

    Europe

    Other Asia

    * Includes Latin America, Caribbean, Africa, non-oil exporting Middle East and unattributed imports.

    ** Includes Algeria, Indonesia, Iraq, Iran, Nigeria, Norway, Kuwait, Libya, Oman, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Syria,United Arab Emirates, Venezuela and Yemen.

    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    259

    101

    198

    175

    225

    380

    185

    232

    91

    Canada

    1,845

    United States

    Rest of world*

    Petrol**

    Europe

    Other Asia

    Japan

    Mexico

    China

    Re-attribute

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    32/112

    32

    a se k t US it ifs

    The majority o oreign capital infows into the United States today is invested

    in debt securities. In 2005 oreign purchases o US bonds amounted to $822

    billion. O this $31 billion went into corporate bonds while $50 billion went

    into treasury bills and other government bonds. Foreign investors have their

    largest debt holdings in US retail, manuacturing, and media companies (Exhibit

    1.1). I we compare the size o these holdings with the entire debt issued by

    S&P 500 companies, we nd that oreign holdings are disproportionately high

    in media, chemicals, computers, and retail while they are disproportionately

    low in automotive, oil, and telecom.

    Equity investments into the United States, including purchases o equity shares

    and FDI into companies, totaled $197 billion in 2005. Foreign purchases o

    equity shares have been concentrated in nancial institutions, computers and

    electronics, and health care. FDI has been most prominent in manuacturing

    and, more recently, in nancial institutions (Exhibit 1.15). Equity investments

    benet the United States in many ways. They have created 5 million jobs over

    the past 20 years; they have provided $27 billion or research and development

    and $112 billion in private-sector capital investment; they account or roughly

    20 percent o US exports; and they account or percent o US private-sector

    Eiit 1.14

    THE MAJORITY OF FOREIGN CAPITAL INFLOWS TO THE UNITED STATESIS INVESTED IN DEBT SECURITIES

    Note: Numbers do not sum due to rounding.

    Source: International Monetary Fund; US Treasury; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital Flows Database

    Net investments in US assets by foreigners$ billion, 2005

    Foreign private debt holdings by sector, 2005%, 100% = $1.7 trillion*

    Foreign equity holdings by sector, 2005%, 100% = $2.0 trillion*

    194

    287

    219

    316

    87

    110

    1,212

    2005

    FDI

    Equity

    Private debt

    Other govtdebt

    Treasurybills

    Lending/deposits

    26

    5

    7

    10 11

    12

    29

    Financialinstitutions

    All others

    Healthcare/pharma

    Retail

    Media

    Oil

    Computers &

    electronics

    23

    6

    7

    78

    14

    14

    21All others Retail

    Manufacturing

    MediaAutomotive

    Utilities

    Computers &electronics

    Healthcare/pharma

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    33/112

    33

    labor compensation at an average compensation level 31 percent higher thanthe national average.13

    13 Matthew J. Slaughter, Insourcing Jobs: Making the Global Economy Work or America, Organiza-

    tion or International Investment, Washington, DC, October 200.

    Eiit 1.15

    FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN THE UNITED STATES IS DIVERSIFIEDACROSS SECTORS

    FDI inflows to the United States by sector$ billion

    Other sectorsincludeagriculture,mining,utilities,construction,transportation,and real estate

    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital Flows

    Database; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    38

    84107

    5329 22

    57

    20

    58

    26

    40

    37

    26

    28

    144

    22

    14

    15 6

    1

    35

    2

    21

    315

    8

    12

    123

    179

    1997

    413

    2

    1998

    6

    56

    84

    1999

    58

    26

    2000

    10

    26

    54

    290

    2001

    11

    10

    2002

    12228

    2

    -1

    2003

    2

    51

    9

    Manufacturing

    2004

    123

    Services

    Financial institutions

    Information

    Trade

    11

    27

    106

    12

    131

    83

    65

    321

    167

    2005

    12

    Other

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    34/112

    3

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    35/112

    35

    2. Could the world und a larger US

    current account decit?

    For many years now economists and policy makers have been saying that the

    US current account decit is unsustainably largeand yet it has continued to

    grow. This prompted MGI to analyze whether the US current account decit could

    continue to increase urther over the next ve years. I current trends persisted,

    how large would it become? Would there be enough global capital to und a largerUS decit? Would the implied US net oreign-debt position be sustainable?

    We consider it plausible that the US current account decit could continue to

    grow or another ve years. I current trends were to continue, we nd that the

    US current account decit would reach $1. trillion or 9 percent o GDP in 2012.

    Although this is very large, we nd that under most scenarios a decit o this

    size would be quite possible. Current account surpluses in other countries could

    conceivably grow large enough to und a US decit o this size, and the result-

    ing level o US oreign debt would still be manageable. In this chapter we also

    consider a variety o downside scenarios that could limit growth in the current

    account surpluses in other countries necessary to und a larger US decit.

    US dEIcIT woUld rEach $1.6 TrIllIon In 2012 UndEr cUrrEnT

    TrEndS

    I current trends in global savings and investment continued or another ve years,

    and i there were no adjustments in exchange rates, the US current account

    decit would reach $1. trillion by 2012, or 9.0 percent o GDP (see appendix

    A or the methodology used to arrive at this projection) (Exhibit 2.1). Under thisscenario the United States would have a trade decit in goods and mineral uels

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    36/112

    3

    o $1,2 billion, a surplus in services trade o $138 bill ion, negative net transerpayments o $15 billion, and negative net oreign income o $122 billion.

    To und this growing current account decit the US net oreign debt would triple,

    reaching $8.1 trillion in 2012, up rom $2.7 trillion in 200 (Exhibit 2.2). This

    implies much aster growth o US net oreign debt than we have seen in the past

    and may overstate the true gure. As explained in chapter 1, over the last ve

    years the US net oreign debt has risen much less than the cumulative current

    account decits would imply. This is due to the depreciation o the dollar over

    that period, which raises the value o US oreign assets, and to the appreciation

    o US oreign assets in oreign direct investment and equity markets abroad.Going orward, our orecast assumes no change in the value o the dollar and

    takes the average rate o appreciation o US oreign assets and liabilities over

    the last 15 years.1

    Even so, the implied level o US net oreign debt in 2012 percent o

    GDPis not unprecedented. Several countries currently have net external debt

    o a similar size relative to GDP including Mexico, Australia, and Ireland (Exhibit

    2.3). Countries experiencing nancial crises over the last ten years usually had

    higher levels o debt. Examples include Argentina at 7 percent o GDP in 2002,

    1 For more on why the US oreign debt has not risen aster, see the IMFWorld Economic Outlook,

    April 2007.

    Eiit 2.1

    % ofGDP -4.5 -4.8 -5.7 -6.3 -6.5 -6.7 -7.2 -7.7 -8.1 -8.6 -9.0

    IF CURRENT TRENDS CONTINUED, THE US CURRENT ACCOUNT DEFICITWOULD REACH $1.6 TRILLION BY 2012

    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital FlowsDatabase; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    -479 -544-662

    -779

    -122

    -100

    -108

    -116

    -125

    -134

    -145

    122 122 138

    -91

    -911-836

    1089685

    72-65

    -84-855

    2006

    -41

    -931

    2007

    -1,305

    Goodstrade

    12

    Servicetrade

    -1,590

    -1,452 Transfers

    Income

    2012

    -1,462

    37

    2011

    -1,349

    28

    2010

    -2258 -5

    -64

    -473

    2002

    49-7

    -69-527

    2003

    5111

    -82

    62

    2004

    -1,014

    -1,178

    2009

    -1,048

    -665

    2008

    -1,238

    -86-792

    2005

    -1,129

    Forecast$ billion (nominal)

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    37/112

    37

    Eiit 2.2

    THE US NET FOREIGN DEBT WOULD REACH TO $8.1 TRILLION IN 2012,OR 46 PERCENT OF GDP

    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Cross-Border InvestmentsDatabase; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    -24 -32-21 -28-20 -36 -40-21-23 -21 -46

    Forecast

    % ofGDP

    -8,107

    -6,961

    -5,918

    -4,974

    -4,128

    -2,729-2,546-2,449

    -2,340-2,454

    -3,384

    2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

    Eiit 2.3

    LEVEL OF US EXTERNAL DEBT IN 2012 WOULD BE HIGHBUT NOT UNPRECEDENTED

    Source: International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Cross-Border Investments Database; McKinsey GlobalInstitute analysis

    Net foreign debt, % of GDP%

    4645

    51545456

    64

    74

    78

    85

    Brazil2002

    Ireland2005

    Argentina2002

    Sweden1993

    Mexico2005

    Thailand1997

    Australia2005

    UnitedStates2012

    Hungary2005

    Malaysia1997

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    38/112

    38

    Sweden at 5 percent in 1993, and Thailand at 78 percent in 1997. The UnitedStates is unique, however, in that its oreign debt is denominated in its own cur-

    rency, thereby eliminating currency risk. Moreover the size and productivity o the

    US economy, combined with the role that the United States plays as a hub to the

    world nancial system, mean that it is an attractive place or oreign investors.

    All these actors suggest that the United States may well be able to maintain a

    larger oreign debt than other countries have in the past.

    Nor would the implied interest payments on an external debt o this size be large

    relative to the US economy. The United States has consistently earned superior

    returns on its oreign assets compared with what it pays out on its oreign li-

    abilities. Even using a smaller spread on returns going orward than the 15-year

    average would imply, US net oreign-income payments in 2012 would, at $122

    billion, be less than 1 percent o GDP (Exhibit 2.).2 Projecting current trends

    even urther, we nd that it would take until 2020 beore US net oreign-income

    payments would reach even the relatively modest level o 3 percent o GDP .

    Furthermore a larger US decit would not imply a dramatic increase either in the

    share o gross world savings being invested in the United States or in the propor-

    tion o US nancial assets owned by oreign investors. Under current trends

    2 In this calculation we use the 200 spread o 0.9 percent, rather than the 1.3 percent average

    over the last 15 years.

    Eiit 2.4

    US NET FOREIGN INTEREST PAYMENTS WOULD AMOUNTTO LESS THAN 1 PERCENT OF GDP IN 2012

    0.1 -0.1 0.0 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 -0.5 -0.7

    Source: International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Cross-Border Investments Database; McKinsey GlobalInstitute Global Capital Flows Database; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    Net interestpayments%

    Income receipts and payments as a % of GDP

    3.8 4.65.0 5.3 5.6 5.9

    6.3 6.6

    10

    2012

    -7.3

    2011

    -6.8

    2010

    -6.3

    2009

    -5.9

    2008

    -5.5

    -10

    -5.0

    2006

    -4.7

    2005

    -3.7

    2007

    Incomereceipts

    Incomepayments

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    39/112

    39

    gross capital infows into the United States would rise to 23 percent o projectedgross savings in the rest o the world, up only slightly rom the share in 200

    (Exhibit 2.5). Foreigners would own 1 percent o US equities and 2 percent

    o US bonds in 2012, up rom 1 percent and 20 percent respectively in 2005

    (Exhibit 2.). Overall, while an increasing level o debt and oreign ownership in

    the United States is less than desirable, a growth in debt over the next ve years

    remains possible.

    From the perspective o oreign indebtedness, then, there is no reason to believe

    that the US current account decit could not continue to grow over the next ve

    years. However, the question remains as to whether it is plausible that other

    countries would have suciently large current account surpluses to und a US

    decit o $1. trillion.

    Global nET capITal oUTlowS woUld Top $2.1 TrIllIon In oUr baSE

    caSE

    To run a current account decit the United States must borrow rom abroad.

    As we explain in chapter 1, net capital outfows rom countries with current ac-

    count surpluses und the US decit. Under reasonable assumptions these could

    indeed grow enough over the next ve years to und a $1. trillion US current

    account decit. In our base case global current account surpluses would grow

    to $2.1 trillion in 2012 barring major changes in exchange rates and oreign

    savings rates. East Asia would account or $799 billion o this, Western Europe

    $23 billion, and oil exporters $387 billion (Exhibit 2.7).3

    We arrive at this projection by developing a base case or each o the three

    major capital-exporting regions and then considering downside scenarios or

    each. In East Asia, we base our projection on the average annual growth rate

    o current account surpluses in the region between 1998 (the year ollowingthe Asian nancial crisis) and 200. At this growth rate, however, several East

    Asian countries would have very large current account surpluses relative to their

    GDP . China, or instance, would have a surplus o 17.2 percent o GDP compared

    with 7. percent in 200. Although some smaller economies such as Singapore

    currently have much larger current account surpluses than this, it seems unlikely

    that either China or oreign governments would nd a Chinese surplus o this

    3 This includes Algeria, Iran, Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, Syria, Yemen, UAE, Oman, Qatar, Indonesia,

    Nigeria, Norway, Russia, Venezuela. Using the growth rate since 1998 also produces a lower, more conservative projection than i

    we were to take growth since 2000 or 2002. The same is true or Europe, or which we use the

    same methodology.

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    40/112

    0

    Eiit 2.5

    THE US SHARE OF REST OF WORLD GROSS SAVINGS WOULDINCREASE SLIGHTLY OVER THE NEXT FIVE YEARS

    Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Global Insight; International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute GlobalCapital Flows Database; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    22.822.221.5

    20.819.9

    19.119.7

    15.1

    20.0

    14.015.215.6

    20.4

    2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007E 2009E 2010E2008E 2012E2011E

    Rest of worldgross savings$ trillion

    US capital inflows as a share ofrest of world gross savings%

    12.15.1 5.0 5.3 6.2 7.3 8.0 9.0 9.4 9.9 10.4 10.9 11.5

    Forecast

    Eiit 2.6

    FOREIGN OWNERSHIP OF EQUITIES AND BONDS WOULD INCREASEONLY SLIGHTLY OVER THE NEXT FIVE YEARS

    Source: McKinsey Global Institute Global Financial Stock Database; McKinsey Global Institute Cross-Border InvestmentsDatabase

    92 88 86 8074

    100%

    9

    7.6

    1990

    12

    10.8

    1995

    14

    16.0

    2000

    20

    23.8

    2005

    26

    41.6

    2012

    Domestic-ownedbonds

    Foreign-ownedbonds

    Projected foreign ownership of US bonds, 2012%, $ trillion

    92 92 89 86 84

    100%

    8

    3.1

    1990

    8

    6.9

    1995

    11

    15.1

    2000

    14

    17.0

    2005

    16

    32.1

    2012

    Domestic-ownedequities

    Foreign-ownedequities

    Projected foreign ownership of US equities, 2012

    %, $ trillion

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    41/112

    1

    size desirable. To make our projection plausible we thereore limit the amount bywhich a countrys current account surplus can grow.5 For most countries the cap

    is 10 percent o GDP , which is exceeded today only by small economies. For very

    small economies like Singapore and Hong Kong we set the cap at 27 percent o

    GDP , the level in Singapore today. We use the same methodology or Western

    Europe.

    We project net capital outfows rom oil-exporting economies based on the uture

    price o oil. In our base case their capital outfows amount to $387 billion in

    2012slightly lower than the outfows o $8 billion seen in 200. The reason

    or this decline is that we assume an oil price o $50 per barrel compared with

    nearly $0 per barrel in 200. These assumptions are those used in MGIs

    proprietary model o global energy demand. We translate oil revenues into net

    capital outfows rom these economies based on a methodology developed by

    Brad Setser (see appendix A or details).7

    5 We assume smooth growth between now and 2012 or countries whose surpluses reach 10

    percent o GDP. For nancial hubs, such as Singapore and Hong Kong, we cap current account

    surpluses to 27 percent o GDP, the level o Singapores current account surplus in 200.

    Curbing Global Energy Demand Growth: The Energy Productivity Opportunity, McKinsey Global

    Institute, May 2007.

    7 Brad Setser, Oil and Global Adjustment, 2007.

    Eiit 2.7

    WITH CURRENT TRENDS CONTINUING, GLOBAL CURRENT ACCOUNTSURPLUSES WOULD REACH $2.1 TRILLION IN 2012

    * Includes Algeria, Indonesia, Iran, Nigeria, Norway, Kuwait, Libya, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Syria, United ArabEmirates, Venezuela and Yemen.

    Source: International Monetary Fund; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital Flows Database; McKinsey GlobalInstitute analysis

    346388

    437491

    553623

    121148

    180

    219

    267

    308

    99

    440

    488

    1,373

    2007E

    432

    536

    1,477

    2008E

    426

    590

    1,600

    2009E

    406

    651

    1,728

    2010E

    393

    721

    1,886

    81

    387

    799

    2,077

    2012E

    Rest of world

    Western Europe

    2011E

    East Asia

    484

    446

    1,319

    2006E

    Petrodollars*

    Projection of global current account surpluses$ billion

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    42/112

    2

    Countries in the rest o the world also run current account surpluses that contributeto global net capital outfows. These include Canada, Brazil, Israel, Argentina, and

    Chile, to name a ew. We project their current account surpluses using the same

    methodology as that used or East Asia and Western Europe. In 2012 their current

    account surpluses would reach $27 billion, up rom $81 billion in 200.

    US SharE o Global capITal lowS woUld IncrEaSE

    Even i global net capital outfows were to grow to $2.1 trillion in 2012, the US

    current account decit would absorb a historically unprecedentedand perhaps

    implausibleshare o this. With a decit o $1. trillion, the United States wouldtake up 77 percent o the worlds net capital outfows. In chapter 1 we saw that,

    since 2001, the US decit has absorbed around 70 percent o the net capital

    fows rom countries with current account surplusesitsel a new high (Exhibit

    1.12). In the late 1980s the United States took up around 0 percent o global

    net capital outfows or a ew years, but ater this the share ell. I the United

    States continued to run very large current account decits or ve more years, it

    would be the rst time in modern history that a single country continued to absorb

    such a large share o the worlds capital outfows over such a prolonged period.

    Is this scenario plausible? On one hand, larger current account decits in other

    countries could limit the ability o the United States to und its decit. Australia

    has had a current account decit or more than 25 years now, and the United

    Kingdom also runs a sizeable decit. Some economies in Europe such as Spain,

    Portugal, and Greece run decits too, unded in large part by those o their

    eurozone neighbors with surpluses. On the other hand, our orecast o global

    net capital outfows is conservative since we constrain the size o uture current

    account surpluses relative to GDP . Moreover, the US decit has already broken

    all historical precedents since 2001. With that in mind, a urther rise in the share

    o world capital that the decit absorbs could be possible.

    downSIdE ScEnarIoS or Global nET capITal oUTlowS

    There are several downside scenarios that could limit global net capital outfows

    in the years to come. We consider our o these scenarios in an attempt to gauge

    the ability o the United States to und a decit o $1. trillion and to identiy

    where the most important sensitivities lie.

    1. ci ses ess; J ges

    Today Asia, and particularly China and Japan, plays a key role in supplying the

    worldand the United Stateswith capital. There are several scenarios under

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    43/112

    3

    which the current account surpluses o China and Japan could be reduced overthe next ve years, however, thus lowering their net capital outfows.

    Many economic orecasters are predicting that Chinas current account surplus

    will decline in years to come as domestic consumption rises and its savings

    rate declines. Ater all Chinas current account surplus is a relatively new

    phenomenon, growing rom just 1.3 percent o GDP in 2001 to 7. percent in

    2005. Policy makers both in China and abroad have argued recently that Chinas

    economy would benet rom a rebalancing away rom investment and exports

    and towards a higher rate o domestic consumption. The widespread assumption

    has been that this rebalancing will occur at least partly through a all in Chinas

    historically high savings rate. Alternatively, China could ollow the advice o many

    economists and global policy makers and allow the yuan to appreciate more

    rapidly over the coming years. In either case Chinas current account surpluses

    would grow more slowly.

    Japans current account surpluses could decline i its aging households save

    less. Japans household saving rate is already declining and, as more Japanese

    retire, it will likely all urther. The combined eect o a lower level o savings in

    both China and Japan would reduce East Asian net capital outfows. Instead o

    reaching $799 billion in 2012, as in our base case, net capital outfows rom East

    Asia would total only $27 billion (Exhibit 2.8).8 This would mean that the world

    supply o capital would be only $150 billion larger than the US current account

    decit in 2012, pushing US uptake o world capital to 91 percent. This level is

    implausible given the preerence o oreign investors to vary their portolios in

    terms o both geography and currencies.

    We consider this outcome rather unlikely, however. MGIs research on Chinas

    evolving consumer market nds that, although Chinas domestic consumption

    will indeed rise strongly in coming years, the rise will derive largely rom rising in-

    comes rather than rom alling savings.9 Indeed MGI projects only a slight decline

    in Chinas national savings rate. Although Japans population is clearly aging, the

    impact on savings rates over the next ve years will be minimal.

    2. Suuses i Eue g me s

    There are two scenarios under which net capital outfows rom Europe might be

    smaller than projected over the next ve years. First, what i current account

    8 We arrive at this gure by using Global Insights orecast or current account surpluses in Chinaand Japan, rather than our projection o continued growth.

    9 From Made in China to Sold in China: The Rise o the Chinese Urban Consumer,McKinsey

    Global Institute, November 200.

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    44/112

    surpluses within Europe were to grow more slowly in the uture? Ater all, thesesurpluses are already becoming large relative to GDP in many o the main

    economies. For instance, in 200 the Netherlands, Sweden, and Germany had

    surpluses o 7.5 percent, 7. percent, and .7 percent o GDP respectively. I we

    assume that uture current account surpluses in Western Europe grow in line with

    projected GDP growth (2.1 percent annually)rather than at the growth rate o

    their current account surpluses (15.1 percent annually) as in our base casenet

    capital outfows rom Europe would be reduced by $270 billion in 2012.

    An alternative downside scenario or Europe takes account o capital fows be-

    tween eurozone countries. Given the common currency, it is likely that countries

    with current account surpluses such as Germany are sending much o their or-

    eign investment to countries with decits, such as Spain, Portugal, and Italy. One

    study has estimated that around hal o the increase in eurozone current account

    surpluses and decits over the last eight years was due to capital fows within

    the eurozone.10 I we assume that 50 percent o eurozone surpluses remain

    within the region and we exclude these rom our sum o global net capital fows,

    Western Europes net capital outfows in 2012 would be reduced by $223 bil-

    lionrom $23 billion to $00 billion. Thus Western Europes capital outfows

    10 Alan Ahearne et al., Internal and External Current Account Balances in the Eurozone, February

    2007.

    Eiit 2.8

    UNDER DOWNSIDE SCENARIO, EAST ASIAN CURRENT ACCOUNTSURPLUS WOULD SHOW NO GROWTH THROUGH 2012

    Source: Global Insight; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital Flows Database; McKinsey Global Institute analysis

    200

    300

    400

    500

    600

    700

    800

    2 00 6 2 00 7E 2 00 8E 2 00 9E 2 01 0E 2 01 1E 2 01 2E

    Base caseCapital projected supplygrowing in line with 19982006compound annual growth rateof current account surplus

    Aging JapanReduced capital supply fromJapan; all other countries

    according to base case

    Adjusting ChinaReduced capital supply fromChina; all other countriesaccording to base case

    Scenarios

    372

    799

    427

    Projection of East Asian current account balances$ billion

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    45/112

    5

    over the next ve years could be reduced by $220 billion to $270 billion lessthan we project in our base case. This would raise the US absorption o world

    capital to a very high 88 percent.

    3. ee ets ue t ie i

    Another possibility causing concern among commentators and economists is

    reduced net capital outfows rom oil-exporting economies in uture years as a

    result o lower oil prices. However, we nd that changes in the price o oil would

    not signicantly aect the extent to which there is sucient capital to und a US

    current account decit. This is because o petrodollar recycling. I the price o

    oil increases the US trade decit rises, but net capital outfows rom oil-exporting

    countries rise too. At the same time, current account surpluses in Europe and

    Asia all somewhat due to more costly oil impor ts. Conversely, i the oil price alls

    the decline in capital outfows rom oil-exporters is oset by a reduction in the

    US current account decit and by current account surpluses in Asia and Europe

    rising on the back o cheaper oil imports. We nd that the US share o net capital

    outfows varies by less than 5 percentage points between conditions under which

    oil is priced at $30 per barrel and at $70 per barrel (Exhibit 2.9).

    Even so, a higher price o oil does make it slightly more dicult or the United

    States to und a decit. Under the downside scenario we posit oil prices rising

    to $70 per barrel instead o $50 per barrel as in our base case. I this were to

    Eiit 2.9

    860 9671,107 1,263

    1,416 1,5801,720

    2,1551,9711,8071,6611,5171,3961,320

    0500

    1,0001,5002,0002,500

    VARYING THE OIL PRICE HAS MINIMAL IMPACT ON THE RATIOOF THE US CURRENT ACCOUNT TO WORLD CAPITAL

    US CA deficit

    World capital

    US current account deficit vs. world supply of capital$ billion

    69

    $70 per barrel scenario

    US % of total 73 76 78 80 8065

    2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 20122006

    1,5911,4521,3051,1781,047931864

    1,320 1,373 1,4771,600 1,728

    1,886 2,077

    0500

    1,0001,500

    2,0002,500

    68

    Base case $50 per barrel

    US % of total 71 74 76 77 7765

    860 891 9801,107 1,178

    1,306 1,443

    2,0171,8181,6631,5631,4081,3551,320

    0500

    1,0001,500

    2,0002,500

    $30 per barrel scenario

    US % of total 66 70 71 71 72 7265

    Source: McKinsey Global Institute GEM model; McKinsey Global Institute Global Capital-Flows Database; McKinseyGlobal Institute analysis

  • 7/27/2019 MGI US Imbalancing Act Full Report

    46/112

    happen, net capital outfows rom oil-exporting countries would increase by $21billion, but the US decit would also grow by an additional $129 billion. Current

    account surpluses in Western Europe and East Asia would be reduced by $1

    billion and $102 billion respectively. The overall eect is that global net capital

    fows would increase by $78 billion and the US decit would rise by $129 billion.

    This would barely aect the ability o the United States to und a larger current

    account decit.

    4. rest s sme suuses

    Our nal downside scenario considers other countries in the world that are run-

    ning current account surpluses such as Canada, Brazil, and Argentina. Construct-

    ing a rational downside scenario or the rest o the world is dicult since such

    a group includes a large and diverse set o countries (15 countries in 2005).

    Even i one or more o them experienced slower growth in their current account

    surpluses over the next ve years, other countries might see their surpluses grow

    aster than in recent years. Moreover, some countries current account decits

    might turn into surpluses. Indeed, we nd that surpluses in our rest o the

    world category have grown steadily since 1998 despite changes in individual

    countries in that group.

    Despite recent historical experience, we still decided to test slower growth in the

    current account surpluses o this group in order to understand the sensitivity to

    this o the US decit. In our base case we assumed that their current account

    surpluses grow at the same rate as they have since 1998. However, i we project

    a slower growth rate usin