loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: banks that are known for...

70
Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? Working Paper Series No. 64 / 2019

Upload: others

Post on 11-Mar-2021

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief?

Working Paper Series

No. 64 / 2019

Page 2: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

ISSN 2029-0446 (online) Working Paper Series

No. 64 / 2019

Karolis Liaudinskas (Universitat Pompeu Fabra)†

Kristina Grigaitė (Bank of Lithuania)‡

July 2019§

† Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, Spain. Email: [email protected].‡ Bank of Lithuania, Vilnius, Lithuania. Email: [email protected].§ We would like to thank José-Luis Peydró, Xavier Freixas, Filippo Ippolito, Andrea Polo, Paul Wachtel, Randall K. Filer, Victoria Vanasco, RubenDurante, Marius Jurgilas, Tomas Garbaravičius, Romain Veyrune, Enrico Sette, Puriya Abbassi, Vicente Bermejo, Gergely Ganic, Artūras Juodis,Guillermo Hausmann, Mihnea Constantinescu and the whole research team at the Bank of Lithuania for their helpful comments andsuggestions.

Page 3: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

© Lietuvos bankas, 2019

Reproduction for educational and non-commercial purposes is permitted provided that the source is acknowledged.

Gedimino pr. 6, LT-01103 Vilnius

www. lb.lt

Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to stimulate discussion and critical comments.

The series is managed by Applied Macroeconomic Research Division of Economics Department and the Center for Excellence in Finance and Economic Research.

All Working Papers of the Series are refereed by internal and external experts.

The views expressed are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the Bank of Lithuania.

Page 4: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

ABSTRACT

We use loan-level data and a novel identification setting – closures of banks – to study how forced break-ups

of lending relationships affect firms’ borrowing costs. We find that after a financially distressed bank closed

and its best borrowers were exogenously forced to switch, their borrowing costs dropped steeply and

converged to the market’s average. We document no such effect when a healthy bank closed. This suggests

that distressed banks can use informational monopoly power to hold up and exploit their best borrowers.

Apparently, closures of such banks can release the best-quality firms from the hold-up and allow borrowing

cheaper elsewhere.

Keywords: relationship lending, hold-up, asymmetric information, bank closures, financial distress, switching costs.

JEL codes: D82, E51, G20, G21, G30, G33, L14.

Page 5: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

5

1. Introduction

The 2007-9 financial crisis exposed the importance of firm-bank relationships. While they

generally helped firms access credit (Bolton et al., 2016; Beck et al., 2017), relationships with

severely hit banks were less helpful. Distressed banks cut lending (Ivashina and Scharfstein, 2008)

and raised interest rates (Santos, 2011), and since lending relationships were sticky and switching

banks was costly, firms dependent on the distressed banks were forced to lay off staff (Chodorow-

Reich, 2014), cut investment (Carvalho et al., 2015), and even shut down (Jiménez et al., 2017).

The following twofold question thus arises: are relationships with financially distressed banks

overall beneficial or harmful, and what makes it so difficult to switch banks? Existing theories

explain sources of switching costs and how lending relationships can both help and harm firms

(Sharpe, 1990; Rajan, 1992; Bolton et al., 2016). However, endogeneity makes empirical

identification difficult. The ideal way to gauge firms’ benefits derived from relationships is to

compare the ease with which firms access credit in two, otherwise identical, cases: when they have

relationships and when they do not, but normally firms begin and end relationships endogenously.

We contribute to the literature by tackling this endogeneity problem with a novel setting – closures

of banks – which terminated firms’ lending relationships and exogenously forced them to switch

banks. Lithuania offers an ideal setting for identification due to its exhaustive credit register and

simultaneous closures of two banks in the aftermath of the financial crisis. First, “Healthy bank”

– a healthy1 subsidiary of an international parent bank – unexpectedly left Lithuania as part of its

parent’s global cost optimization plan. Second, “Distressed bank” 2 shut down after the regulator

unexpectedly uncovered severe misreportings of the bank’s asset values. We exploit this setting to

study how firms’ loan rates changed when their banks closed. We find that loan rates of “Healthy

bank’s” clients remained unchanged while loan rates of “Distressed bank’s” highest credit quality

borrowers dropped sharply and immediately converged to the market’s average. In line with

Sharpe’s (1990) model, these results suggest that while “Distressed bank” was functioning, its best

clients incurred high switching costs stemming from interbank information asymmetries: i.e.

firms’ attempts to switch falsely signaled their inferiority (e.g. inability to borrow from the

1 Borrowers of “Healthy bank” had less frequent repayment delays and lower loan rates than clients of most other

banks operating in Lithuania (Figures 1.1 and 1.2). 2 Borrowers of “Distressed bank” had more frequent repayment delays and higher loan rates (Figures 1.1 and 1.2) than

clients of most other banks in Lithuania.

Page 6: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

6

informed inside bank) to uninformed outside banks. In turn, the inside bank could hold up these

firms and extract rents from them. When the bank closed, firms could switch without giving the

false signal and thus received average market rates. We also find that relationships with healthy

banks neither helped nor harmed firms on average, but there was a differential effect: banks raised

loan rates at the beginning of relationships but, possibly due to reputational concerns, reduced

them later.

While previous studies have examined the effects of bank closures on aggregate economic

outcomes (Bernanke, 1983; Ashcraft, 2005) and subsequent firms’ investments (Minamihashi,

2011; Korte, 2015), to the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper to address the following

research questions. How do closures of banks affect the loan rates of their customers? Does this

effect depend on the closed bank’s health and the lost relationships’ length? Intuitively, if lending

relationships helped firms borrow cheaper, then losing them would increase firms’ borrowing

costs, while if relationships made borrowing more expensive, escaping them would make

borrowing cheaper. Thus, by asking the aforementioned questions we also tackle the following

broader ones. How do lending relationships with banks affect firms’ borrowing costs? Does this

effect depend on the banks’ health and the relationships’ length? What makes switching between

banks costly?

In theory, lending relationships can make borrowing both cheaper and more expensive. On the one

hand, repeated interactions reduce information asymmetries between firms and banks, which may

alleviate firms’ borrowing costs (e.g. Diamond, 1984). On the other hand, firm-bank relationships

create information asymmetries across banks. These asymmetries generate switching costs for

good-quality firms and lead to an adverse selection of firms willing to switch banks (Sharpe, 1990).

Thus, by trying to switch voluntarily good firms would wrongly signal inferior quality.3 As a result,

banks gain monopoly power to hold up their current good customers and to extract rents from them

(Rajan, 1992; Von Thadden, 2004). The decision to do so, however, depends on banks’ concerns

3 For example, suppose that informed inside banks (those that have relationships with firms) lend at 5% interest rate

to good firms and at 15% to bad firms. Assume that when a firm approaches an uninformed outside bank, the bank

cannot identify the firm’s quality and thus charges an average of 10%. In this case, only bad firms would switch (and

pay 10% instead of 15%) because for good firms switching is costly (they would pay 10% instead of 5%). If only bad

firms switch, outside banks can assume that every switcher is bad. If a good firm tried to switch, it would be assumed

to be bad and charged 15% by outside banks. In other words, a voluntary firm’s attempt to switch signals that the firm

is unable to borrow or can borrow at high rates from its better-informed inside bank. This gives monopoly power to

inside banks. For example, in this case, they could hold-up good customers and extract rents by charging them 14%.

Page 7: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

7

about their own reputation (Sharpe, 1990).4 Financially distressed banks lack resources and

incentives to care about reputation (Boot et al., 1993) and thus are more likely to exploit hold-up.

According to this theoretical framework, involuntary losses of lending relationships can lead to

both a drop and a hike in borrowing costs of high-quality firms, thus, we have the following two

empirically testable predictions. (1) If lending relationships help firms borrow cheaper via the

reduction of information asymmetries between them and their banks, losses of such relationships

would increase firms’ borrowing costs. (2) If relationships make borrowing more expensive

because reputationally unconcerned banks exploit their customers’ switching costs stemming from

interbank information asymmetries, closures of such banks would force all good and bad firms to

switch, and thus would allow good firms to switch without giving the wrong signal of inferiority.

This would enable the best firms to borrow cheaper than before from healthier and more

reputationally concerned banks. Other factors, addressed in detail with robustness tests in section

4.3, may also explain why borrowing costs of the affected firms change after the “Distressed

bank’s” closure; e.g. (1) the deterioration of the firms’ credit quality could have caused the bank’s

closure; (2) the bank’s closure could have affected other lenders’ perceptions of the firms’ true

quality; or (3) a reduction in interbank competition could have complicated borrowing to all, but

particularly to firms lacking lending relationships. However, these scenarios would push

borrowing costs of the affected firms upwards, while we find the opposite. Thus, we may

underestimate the downward impact on borrowing costs caused by the relationship break-up.

We exploit the credit registry provided by the Bank of Lithuania, which contains quarterly data on

all loans outstanding between 2011 q4 and 2018 q1 among all firms and banks registered in

Lithuania. We also observe lenders, borrowers, initiation dates and termination dates of all loans

issued between 1995 and 2011, which allows us to measure complete lengths of all firm-bank

relationships. We analyze jointly leasing contracts, term loans and credit lines which make up 86%

of all contracts in the database, but our findings are robust to using term loans (13% of

observations) and leasing contracts (69% of observations) separately. We disregard credit unions

and other small lenders and consider the 12 largest banks, which account for 95% of observations.

Our sample period is marked by an economic recovery after the 2007-9 crisis. In 2011 Lithuania’s

4 Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers.

Page 8: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

8

GDP grew by 6%, the financial system was stable and total profits in the banking sector almost

reached a record-high pre-crisis level (Bank of Lithuania, 2011).

We analyze the closures of two banks5. First, on January 30, 2013, “Healthy bank” – a healthy

branch of a foreign bank – announced its strategic decision to leave the Lithuanian and Estonian

markets as part of a global cost-saving plan and to concentrate its business in Latvia, where the

head office of the Baltic region was located. Second, “Distressed bank” closed two weeks later, in

February 2013 due to risk mismanagement and the misreporting of asset values. The closure came

as a surprise even to governmental institutions, which lost large uninsured deposits. Three weeks

later, an auditor completed a review of the bank’s assets and split them into a “good bank” (loans

that were likely to function normally) and a “bad bank” (loans that were likely to default, and likely

caused the bank’s failure). The “good bank’s” loans were assigned to another bank, and the “bad

bank” was liquidated. To identify the best-quality firms, which are the most subject to hold-up

(Sharpe, 1990), we consider firms that: (1) survived, i.e. borrowed again after the shock, (2) were

assigned to the “good bank”, (3) did not delay any repayment throughout the whole sample period,

and (4) after the shock switched to banks other than the acquiring bank, which ex-ante was

considered similar to “Distressed bank”. The latter criterion, satisfied by the majority of firms, also

assures that our results are unaffected by pricing policies of this one bank. In order to alleviate

concerns that our estimated drop in borrowing costs is explained by the auditors’ conclusions, we

show that the results are qualitatively similar when considering only those post-shock loans that

were issued within the three weeks after the shock, i.e. before the auditor split “Distressed bank”.

Results. Our analysis is divided into three parts. In the first part, we examine how firms’ borrowing

costs changed when their banks closed. We find that the closure of the “Healthy bank” did not

affect its clients’ borrowing costs (Figure 4.1.), while the closure of the “Distressed bank” led to

an average drop of 1.1 percentage point in its customers’ borrowing costs, which immediately

converged to the market’s average (Figure 2.1.). The drop was even larger for firms lacking other

lending relationships (Figure 2.2.) but less dramatic for firms that had very long (>6 years)

relationships with the failed bank (Figure 2.3.). These findings suggest that relationships with the

5 During the time period of our data sample, three banks ceased to exist. One more bank was closed in November 2011

due to fraud – the owners were discovered to have tunneled assets. Due to structural changes in the database, the

failure of this bank coincides with the beginning of our data sample period. As we cannot observe pre-closure loans

of this bank, we do not use this bank’s closure. This means that throughout our sample period we mostly use 11 banks.

Page 9: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

9

healthy bank on average neither benefited nor hurt its borrowers, while relationships with the

financially distressed bank were costly and not easy to escape. Furthermore, it appears that long-

term relationships were relatively beneficial as compared to short-term relationships.

We then test formally if the drops observed in graphs are statistically significant. We use a

difference-in-difference analysis to compare borrowing costs of a treatment group and a control

group before and after the closures of the two banks. A treatment group comprises customers of a

closed bank (first “Distressed” and then “Healthy”), while a control group is formed of customers

of all other banks. The findings confirm the results drawn from the graphical analysis. These results

are robust to different error clustering, using term loans and leasing contracts separately, relaxing

firm-quality criteria, and using a different control group (i.e. customers of the most similar bank).

In the second part, we test if borrowing costs of the “Distressed bank’s” customers after the closure

indeed converged to the market’s average, as suggested by the graphical analysis. We follow

Ioannidou and Ongena (2010) and Bonfim et al. (2018) to match forced-switching loans (i.e. the

first loans issued to former “Distressed bank’s” customers by their new banks) with non-switching

loans (i.e. similar loans issued at the same time by the same banks to similar old customers of those

banks) and to compare interest rates between them. We find that, on average, forced-switchers

borrowed at the same rates as old customers at the same banks. As old customers had no advantage,

this again implies that, on average, relationships with healthy banks neither benefited nor hurt

firms. Moreover, in line with Von Thadden (2004) and Bonfim et al. (2018), this finding provides

evidence that switching costs primarily stem from interbank information asymmetries6. We find,

however, a differential effect – old customers (>6 years) received 20 bps lower rates than forced-

switchers, and short-term customers (<6 years) received 24 bps higher rates than forced-switchers.

This suggests that short-term relationships are costly while long-term relationships are beneficial.

In the third part, we test if longer relationships with banks indeed help firms borrow cheaper. We

use two methods: a non-parametric loan matching, which tackles endogeneity between the interest

6 In line with the authors, we find that regular-switchers receive discounts on loans issued by their new banks, while

forced-switchers do not. In Von Thadden’s (2004) model, switching discounts are explained by randomized attempts

of uninformed outside banks to outbid informed inside banks. Thus, a forced-switcher that had lost its inside bank

would have no reason to receive a discount. If, instead of information asymmetries, the shoe-leather switching costs

and the competition for market share was causing switching discounts, a switcher should receive such a discount

whether or not it still has an inside bank (Klemperer, 1987).

Page 10: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

10

rate and other loan characteristics as in Ioannidou and Ongena (2010), and a parametric panel

regression similar to Lopez-Espinosa et al. (2017), which uses loan-level data and allows us to

control for firm-specific-time-varying, bank-specific-time-varying and firm-bank-specific-time-

invariant characteristics. Partially in line with Ioannidou and Ongena (2010), we find that when

firms switch banks voluntarily, they receive a discount of 25 bps7 on average, but, in the next 2-3

years, rates increase by around 50 bps. In contrast to the authors, our longer sample period allows

us to uncover that rates decrease in the later years and drop below initial levels after 5 years.

Results of the panel regression confirm this pattern.

Literature and contribution. Empirical evidence in the relationship lending literature suggests

that switching costs do stem primarily from interbank information asymmetries and create hold-

up opportunities (Bonfim et al., 2018), while evidence on whether banks abuse hold-up is mixed

and varies with circumstances (see, e.g., Petersen and Rajan, 1994; Angelini et al., 1998; Berlin

and Mester, 1999; Dahiya et al., 2003; Schenone, 2009; Ioannidou and Ongena, 2010; Kysucky

and Norden, 2015; Gobbi and Sette, 2015; Bolton et al., 2016; Botsch & Vanasco, 2019). Another

related branch of literature studies how bank lending depends on banks’ health. Distressed banks

were found to cut lending (Ivashina and Scharfstein, 2008), increase interest rates (Hubbard et al.,

2002; Santos, 2011; Chodorow-Reich, 2014) and affect their customers’ stock prices (Slovin et al.

1993; Ongena et al. 2003; Carvalho et al., 2015). Others study transmissions of liquidity shocks

from banks to firms (Schnabl 2012; Chava and Purnanandam 2011; Khwaja and Mian 2008).

In line with Santos (2011), we find that a financially distressed bank charged its good customers a

premium on their loans. We contribute by demonstrating that the premium disappeared and the

good customers could borrow cheaper elsewhere when the bank was shut down. Besides providing

practical knowledge relevant to firms, banks, and regulators, this finding also contributes to the

relationship lending literature as an identification of both hold-up costs and the lower bound of

switching costs. While the distressed bank was functioning, it held up its customers and charged a

premium – i.e. hold-up costs. Since firms chose to pay these costs instead of switching, total

switching costs must have been even higher. When the bank closed, all good and bad firms had to

switch, thus, by switching, good firms no longer signaled their inferiority and borrowed cheaper.

7 The discount found by Ioannidou and Ongena (2010) is 87 bps, and by Bonfim et al. (2018) – 59 bps.

Page 11: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

11

This explanation suggests that switching costs stem primarily from interbank information

asymmetries but, in theory, shoe-leather switching costs may also be responsible. For example,

perhaps customers of “Distressed bank” could have always borrowed cheaper but chose not to due

to costs of traveling between banks. In this case, bad firms would have also borne such costs, and,

thus, could have also been exploited, but we do not find such evidence (see section 4.2.4). Also,

we find that obscure younger firms were exploited more (see section 4.2.1). Thus, we add validity

to the recent findings of Bonfim et al. (2018), who tested Von Thadden’s (2004) model and found

that switching costs stem from information asymmetries as opposed to shoe-leather costs. We also

repeat their test, find similar results but contribute with a cleaner identification of forced switches8.

Finally, we contribute to a large body of literature investigating how interest rates vary with length

of lending relationships (Petersen and Rajan, 1994; Berger and Udell, 1995; Lopez-Espinosa et

al., 2017). By measuring complete lengths of firm-bank relationships and controlling for

unprecedented level of fixed effects, we uncover a concave link between relationship age and

interest rates, which is in line with reputational concerns (Sharpe, 1990). To our knowledge, only

Lopez-Espinosa et al. (2017) measured entire lengths of relationships and found a similar pattern.

We add much-needed external validity to their findings, as they analyzed only one Spanish bank.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the data and the institutional

setting. Section 3 describes the closures of the banks. Section 4 uses both a graphical analysis and

a difference-in-difference analysis to study how the closures of the banks affected the borrowing

costs of their customers. Section 5 conducts a loan matching analysis to test whether forced-

switchers at new banks indeed received similar rates to those received by old customers. Section

6 directly tests the link between loan rates and lengths of relationships. Section 7 concludes.

2. Data and Institutional Setting

We use quarterly data on corporate loans outstanding between 2011 q4 and 2018 q1, provided by

the Bank of Lithuania, and observe the following variables: year, quarter, loan id, loan type, firm

id, bank id, loan issue date, loan maturity date, loan outstanding amount, loan interest rate, loan

8 Bonfim et al. (2018) studied firms’ switches of banks succeeding closures of banks' branches. However, closures of

banks’ branches did not completely eliminate the possibility of continuing to borrow from the same banks, while, in

our case, a closure of the whole bank did.

Page 12: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

12

currency, loan collateral value, indicator if a firm had late repayments within a given quarter, firm’s

industry and firm’s total loan amount. The database includes all debt contracts issued to all firms

by all credit institutions registered in Lithuania. In addition, we observe firm id, bank id, loan

initiation date and loan termination date of all loans between 1995 and 2011, which allows us to

measure the complete lengths of all firm-bank relationships.

We disregard credit unions and other small lenders and consider the 12 largest banks, which

account for 95% of all observations and 98% of banks’ total assets. Five of the 12 banks are funded

primarily by Lithuanian capital and have had none or limited cross-border activities. The other

seven banks are branches or subsidiaries of foreign – mostly Scandinavian – parent banks. The

banking sector is rather concentrated as, at the beginning of our sample period (2011 Q4), the five

Scandinavian-owned banks held 82% of the outstanding credit issued to firms. The three largest

banks accounted for 65% of this credit. The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) for outstanding

loans throughout our sample period varied between 1,632 and 1,992.

In our sample period, the 12 banks had 190,728 outstanding debt contracts issued to 35,905 firms,

which constitutes 1,635,779 quarterly observations. These include 117,557 new contracts that were

issued to 25,436 firms within our sample period. All these contracts were issued in the local

currency and only between one firm and one bank.9 Table 1a provides loans’ summary statistics

(aggregate and split by loan type). In our analyses, we use the three most popular loan types in

terms of the number of contracts and the loan amount issued. They jointly constitute 86% of the

total number of contracts: leasing – 69%, term loans – 13% and credit lines – 4%. The total amount

issued sums up to 48 billion EUR. Of this amount, 54% is attributable to term loans, 14% to leasing

contracts, 11% to credit lines and the rest to overdrafts, mortgages and other types of contracts.

The average (median) loan size across all loans is EUR 0.25 million (EUR 0.026 million), the

average (median) interest rate is 3.8% (3.2%), and the average (median) time to maturity of debt

contracts at the time of issuance is 2.7 years (2.8 years). In our regression analyses, we winsorize

the top and bottom 0.5% of observations of each of these variables, but this has trivial effects on

9 We have dropped 2,886 loans (2%) issued in foreign currencies and 1,005 (1%) collective loans taken jointly by

more than one firm. Our database does not include syndicated loans but their outstanding amount is relatively small,

e.g. according to the ECB’s Statistical Data Warehouse, at the end of 2011, syndicated loans to Lithuanian non-

financial corporations amounted to EUR 0.7 bn, which is 4% of the loans outstanding in our dataset at the same time.

Page 13: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

13

the results. Only 20% of contracts are collateralized but, for term loans and credit lines, this number

reaches above 80%.

Firms in Lithuania are relatively small and reliant on banks’ funding. As shown in Table 1b, at the

beginning of the sample (2011 Q4), the average (median) outstanding debt across the 17,266 firms

was almost EUR 1 million (EUR 0.06 million) and the aggregate firms’ debt to banks was EUR

16.8 billion. This illustrates the firms’ reliance on banks, since, according to Nasdaq Baltic

monthly statistics, at the same time the stock market capitalization was EUR 3.1 billion and the

market value of all publicly traded corporate bonds was EUR 1.3 billion. At the end of 2011, 77%

of firms had relationships with only one bank and 68% of firms had relationships shorter than 6

years on average.10 In our sample, the three largest sectors in terms of the number of firms were

wholesale and retail (26%), transportation (12%), and manufacturing (10%). Throughout the

whole sample period, 17% of all firms delayed at least one repayment.

Lithuania has been a member of the European Union since 2004 and the eurozone since 2015. The

supervision of Lithuanian credit institutions follows the Basel III regulations (OECD, 2017). Since

2003, a credit bureau has been collecting information on firms' liabilities in Lithuania, which

makes the Lithuanian credit market more transparent than credit markets in many other countries.

Banks can access a detailed ten-year-history of their applicants' current and expired debt contracts.

Information includes loan types, starting and maturity dates, repayment schedules, loan amounts,

interest rates, number of payments delayed, number of days delayed, total amounts delayed, etc.

Nevertheless, important interbank information asymmetries remain. For example, firms are likely

to keep borrowed funds in an account with the same bank, which, in turn, can observe firms’

spending patterns. Furthermore, due to the possibility of loans evergreening, other banks may treat

firms’ credit histories with caution.

The economic environment in our sample period was marked by a sharp recovery after the 2007-

2009 financial crisis. In 2011, Lithuania’s GDP grew by 6%, the financial system was stable and

total profits in the banking sector almost reached a record-high pre-crisis level (Bank of Lithuania,

2011). Throughout our sample period, average interest rates were gradually declining, following

the expansionary monetary policies of the European Central Bank.

10 In line with Ioannidou and Ongena (2010) and Bonfim et al. (2018), a firm is said to have a relationship with a bank

if it had an outstanding debt with that bank at any time within the previous 12 months.

Page 14: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

14

Our institutional setting is comparable to those of some other related papers. For instance, Bonfim

et al. (2018) study another relatively small market in the eurozone – Portugal, where firms also

largely rely on banks’ funding, and where a few of the largest banks dominate the market. For

example, in the sample period of 2012-2015, six banks held 85% of the market (Bonfim et al.,

2018). Some related papers examine even smaller markets; for example, Schäfer (2016) studies

6,649 firms in Armenia in 2009-2013 while Ioannidou and Ongena (2010) study 2,805 firms in

Bolivia in 1999-2003. Our setting particularly differs from theirs in terms of the credit markets’

transparency, as in Portugal (Bonfim et al., 2018) and Bolivia (Ioannidou and Ongena, 2010) banks

could access only 2 months of their applicants’ credit history while in Armenia, a private credit

bureau provided a history of 5 years. This strengthens the external validity of our results: if

interbank information asymmetries matter in Lithuania, where banks can access 10 years of firms’

credit histories, they are likely to matter even more in less transparent markets. However, it is not

clear if our results would be replicated in larger and less concentrated (more competitive) markets.

On the one hand, more interbank competition makes relationship lending more important to banks

(Boot and Thakor, 2000). On the other hand, interbank competition generally makes it difficult for

banks to internalize benefits from lending relationships, i.e. to exploit borrowers (Petersen and

Rajan, 1995; Boot and Thakor, 2000; Degryse and Ongena, 2005).

3. Closures of Banks

In order to identify how losses of lending relationships affect firms’ borrowing costs, we use two

almost simultaneous closures of banks. In this section, we describe the two cases. Since our setting

may pose some endogeneity concerns, we address them in section 4.3. – the robustness check.

First, in 2013 q1 (January 30), “Healthy bank” 11 – a branch of a large international bank –

announced its strategic decision to leave the Lithuanian and Estonian markets and to concentrate

its business in Latvia, where it had the oldest and largest headquarters in the Baltic region.

According to the bank’s press release, this decision was part of the parent bank’s strategic plan to

save operational costs globally and to increase internal efficiency of activities in Central and

Eastern Europe. After the announcement, the bank stopped issuing new loans and effectively

abandoned its borrowers, who were forced to switch to other banks. Borrowing from the Latvian

11 Borrowers of “Healthy bank” had lower borrowing costs and less frequent defaults (Figures 1.1 and 1.2) than

borrowers of most other banks in Lithuania.

Page 15: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

15

branch was not a feasible option since at that time Latvia and Lithuania had different currencies.

Just before the announcement, at the end of 2012 Q4, the bank lent to 219 firms and was 8th in

terms of corporate loans’ portfolio size.

Second, “Distressed bank” 12 was a publicly traded Lithuanian bank (i.e. owned and controlled by

a Lithuanian businessman) with EUR 0.3 billion lent to 1230 firms as of 2012 Q4 – the 6th largest

corporate loans’ portfolio. The bank’s activities were stopped in 2013 q1 (February 12), due to

risk mismanagement and over-reporting of its asset values, as uncovered by the Bank of Lithuania.

The majority of the bank’s misrepresented assets consisted of loans extended to firms closely

related to the bank’s major shareholder (OECD, 2017). Although the bank was commonly known

to be relatively risky due to rumors and negative coverage in the media, the closure was largely

unexpected not only by markets, but also by governmental institutions, which lost large uninsured

deposits amounting to EUR 80 million (Kuodis, 2013). Yet, the closure did not have systemic

repercussions (OECD, 2017). Financial markets reacted modestly while the total amount of

deposits in the banking system even increased in the days following the shutdown (Kuodis, 2013).

During the three weeks after the shutdown, KPMG Baltics manually reviewed all the bank’s assets

and split them into a “good bank”, which included loans that were likely to perform normally and

a “bad bank”, which included loans that had their values misrepresented and/or were likely to

default. The “bad bank” was liquidated and the “good bank” was acquired by another bank. The

total value of the “good bank” was EUR 0.52 billion, which included EUR 189 million of loans,

EUR 126 million of fixed-income securities, EUR 106 million of cash and EUR 100 million of

other assets. The acquiring bank took over all insured deposits of the failed bank, amounting to

EUR 0.79 billion, and received a compensation of EUR 0.27 billion from the state in order to

balance out the assumed assets and liabilities (Ciulada, 2013).

In some ways, the acquiring bank was comparable to “Distressed bank”; for example, it was a

publicly traded bank with the 5th largest corporate loans’ portfolio as of 2012 Q4. The largest

shareholders were the European Bank for Reconstruction & Development (EBRD) and five

Lithuanian companies and individuals. In 2012, there were rumors that the two banks, that is, the

acquiring bank and the "Distressed bank", might merge in order to exploit synergies stemming

12 Borrowers of “Distressed bank” had higher borrowing costs and more frequent defaults (Figures 1.1 and 1.2) than

borrowers of most other banks in Lithuania.

Page 16: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

16

from similar clienteles. Both banks were known for lending to SMEs and having well-established

networks of offices across the country (BNS and lrytas.lt, 2012).

In order to verify the health of “Healthy bank” and “Distressed bank”, we compare the credit

quality of their customers with the credit quality of customers of other banks in the following way.

We define banks’ customers in line with Ioannidou and Ongena (2010): if a firm had any amount

of debt outstanding with a particular bank at any point of time within one prior year, the firm is

called a customer of that bank. We identify customers of all banks at the end of 2012 q4 – just

before the quarter in which both “Distressed bank” and “Healthy bank” stopped issuing loans. We

exclude customers of “Distressed bank” that were assigned to the “bad bank” during the bank’s

resolution process. For each bank, we calculate a proportion of customers that delayed at least one

repayment on any debt contract within one year before January 1, 2013 (Figure 1.1). Similarly, for

the same groups of customers, we calculate an amount-weighted average interest rate across all

contracts (term loans, leasing and credit lines) outstanding within one year before January 1, 2013

(Figure 1.2).13 The two charts include customers of 11 banks since one bank was closed at the

beginning of our sample period.5

Figure 1.1 indicates that before the two banks’ closures, customers of “Distressed bank” had the

most frequent repayment delays, even when firms assigned to the “bad bank” were excluded. In

contrast, customers of “Healthy bank” had the least frequent repayment troubles. These patterns

are also reflected by the weighted average interest rates of each customer group prior to January

1, 2013 in Figure 1.2: borrowers of “Distressed bank” paid the most, while borrowers of “Healthy

bank” were among those paying the least.

Out of the 1,230 customers of “Distressed bank”, 206 were assigned to the “bad bank”. Out of the

remaining 1,024 firms, 554 took new loans after the shock and thus reappeared in the credit

register, which suggests that the other 470 were either not able borrow again or did not need new

loans after the failure of “Distress bank”. After the shock, out of the 554 firms, 268 firms took new

loans from the acquiring bank, while 286 firms borrowed from somewhere else – not the acquirer.

13 We ignore 15 loans (term loans, leasing or credit lines) issued between January 1, 2013 and February 11, 2013 by

“Distressed bank” as information about these loans is observed after the shock - at the end of 2013 Q1. The observed

values may be affected by the shock and thus might not accurately represent the situation in the pre-shock period.

“Healthy bank” issued no loans (term loans, leasing or credit lines) within these dates.

Page 17: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

17

In this research, we aim to identify and examine only the best borrowers of “Distressed bank”, as

according to Sharpe (1990), they are the most subject to hold-up. Thus, we are primarily interested

in those firms which managed to survive and borrow again after the “Distressed bank’s” closure.

In addition, we consider only those borrowers of “Distressed bank” that were assigned to the “good

bank” by KPMG and only those that did not delay any repayment throughout the whole sample

period from 2011 to 2018. Furthermore, we disregard those “Distressed bank’s” customers which

took new loans from the acquiring bank after the shock and consider only those which chose to

borrow somewhere else. Most of the latter firms switched to Scandinavian-owned banks, which

were known to select higher credit quality firms and, thus, to lend at lower prices than Lithuanian-

owned banks on average. As a result, the latter condition helps us to: (1) identify the highest-

quality customers of “Distressed bank” with even more certainty and, (2) ensure that our main

results are not affected by the pricing strategy of the single acquiring bank.

4. How does a bank's closure affect the borrowing costs of its customers?

4.1. Empirical strategy

In this section, we apply in parallel a graphical analysis and a difference-in-difference regression

to study how the borrowing costs of customers of the “Distressed bank” changed when the bank

failed and the firms were forced to switch to other banks. We then repeat the analysis with

customers of “Healthy bank”.

In line with Ioannidou and Ongena (2010) and Bonfim et al. (2018), a bank’s customer in each

quarter is defined as a firm which had some amount of debt outstanding with that bank within one

prior year.14 We identify banks’ customers on February 12, 2013 – the day of “Distressed bank’s”

closure.15 We call a customer “exclusive” if it had no debts with any other bank within the same

prior year. For each firm in 2013 q1, we measure in quarters the lengths of existing lending

relationships with each bank and calculate an average length across all existing firm’s

relationships. For exclusive customers, this average corresponds to the length of their single

relationship. In our setting, firms with average relationships longer than 6 years are called “long-

14 In line with Ioannidou and Ongena (2010), we conservatively assume that relationship ties are broken if there is a

gap without outstanding loans longer than 1 year. 15 For “Healthy bank’s” analysis, we use the day the bank announced its plans to leave the market – January 30, 2013.

After this date, the bank issued only two debt contracts, which we exclude from our analysis.

Page 18: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

18

term customers” and other firms are called “short-term customers”. The cut-off of 6 years was

chosen due to an interest rate pattern uncovered in Figure 5, which indicates that after 6 years of

relationships, average interest rates start to decrease. In section 6, this pattern is tested controlling

for time varying firm (e.g. age, riskiness etc.), time varying bank and time invariant firm-bank-

specific characteristics.

The data sample is split into two periods: “before” takes into account debt contracts issued up to

December 31, 2012, while “after” takes into account contracts issued after February 12, 201315 –

the day when activities of “Distressed bank” were suspended.13 For each firm, at the end of every

quarter, we calculate an average interest rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts, which is used

as a proxy for firms’ borrowing costs. Borrowing costs of 2013 q1 and later quarters are based

only on contracts issued after February 12, 2013.15

In the default setting, we consider jointly the three most popular loan types (i.e. term-loans, leasing

and credit lines) in terms of both the total amount issued (79% of the sample) and the number of

contracts (86% of the sample). Later, we show that our results are qualitatively similar for these

loan types separately. In order to identify the best credit quality firms, which in theory are the most

subject to hold-up (Sharpe 1990), we consider those “Distressed bank’s” customers which satisfy

all the following quality conditions: (1) survived the shock and thus reappeared in the credit

register after it, (2) were assigned to the “good bank” by KPMG, (3) did not delay any repayment

throughout our sample period 2011 q4 – 2018 q1, and (4) switched to banks other than the one

which acquired the “good bank” (i.e. did not borrow from the acquiring bank at any time after

losing relationships with “Distressed bank”). We also show that our results are qualitatively similar

if we relax all these conditions and graphically demonstrate the development of borrowing costs

for firms which do not satisfy either one of these quality conditions.

Using this default setting, we end up with 232,819 quarterly firm-level observations of 18,900

firms, 209 of which were customers of “Distressed bank” – our default treatment group.16 The

default control group consist of the rest of firms (18,691) which were customers of all other banks

except for “Distressed bank” at the moment of the shock. These firms also reappeared in the credit

16 These numbers would increase to 310,027 observations, 31,146 firms and 1,173 customers of “Distressed bank”

without applying the four firms’ quality constraints.

Page 19: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

19

register after the shock and did not delay any repayment within our sample period 2011 q4 – 2018

q1. We show that our results are similar when using an alternative control group – customers of

the most similar bank to “Distressed bank” in terms of size, customer’s quality (measured as a

proportion of firms with delayed repayments) and customers’ average loan rates.

We hypothesize that if “Distressed bank” exploited hold-up and extracted rents from its best

customers, we would see their borrowing costs decreasing more than for other firms after the

bank’s failure. This effect should be particularly strong for more dependent “exclusive” customers,

and, if long-term relationships are beneficial, as suggested by Figure 5, even stronger for

“exclusive” “short-term” customers. In order to formally test these hypotheses, we run the

following regression specifications. Specifications numbered with “a” exclude fixed effects, those

with “b” include firm-fixed effects and those with “c” include both firm-fixed effects and time-

fixed effects. In order to account for the possibility of standard errors being correlated within firms

and quarters, we cluster errors multiway within these both dimensions. Our results are robust if we

leave errors unclustered or if we cluster only within either one of the two dimensions.

Specification (1a):

𝑏𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑖𝑛𝑔_𝑐𝑜𝑠𝑡𝑠𝑓,𝑞 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝛽2 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 + 𝛽3 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝜀𝑓,𝑞

Specification (1b):

𝑏𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑖𝑛𝑔_𝑐𝑜𝑠𝑡𝑠𝑓,𝑞 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝛽2 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 + 𝛽3 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝐹𝐹𝐸 + 𝜀𝑓,𝑞

Specification (1c):

𝑏𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑖𝑛𝑔_𝑐𝑜𝑠𝑡𝑠𝑓,𝑞 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝛽2 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 + 𝛽3 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝐹𝐹𝐸 + 𝑇𝐹𝐸 + 𝜀𝑓,𝑞

Where

• 𝑏𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑖𝑛𝑔_𝑐𝑜𝑠𝑡𝑠𝑓,𝑞 is an average interest rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts in

quarter q for firm f.

• 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the quarter q is equal to or larger than 2013 q1,

and zero otherwise.

Page 20: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

20

• 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 is a dummy variable equal to 1 if firm f was in a treatment group, i.e. a customer

of the closed bank “Distressed bank”, and zero if firm f was in a control group.

• 𝐹𝐹𝐸 - firm-fixed effects.

• 𝑇𝐹𝐸 - time-fixed effects, also referred to as “quarter-fixed effects”, as the data is quarterly.

Due to a common trend of decreasing interest rates throughout the whole sample period, we expect

the coefficient 𝛽1 to be negative. Our coefficient of interest is 𝛽3, which we also expect to be

negative and statistically significant. This would indicate that after the bank’s failure, borrowing

costs of “Distressed bank” customers decreased by more than could be explained by the common

trend.

Specification (2a):

𝑏𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑖𝑛𝑔_𝑐𝑜𝑠𝑡𝑠𝑓,𝑞 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝛽2 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 + 𝛽3 ∗ 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 + 𝛽4 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 +

𝛽5 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 + 𝛽6 ∗ 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝛽7 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝜀𝑓,𝑞

Where 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 is a dummy variable equal to 1 if firm f is a customer of only one bank, and zero

otherwise. Specifications (2b) and (2c) extend specification (2a) by including fixed effects in line

with specifications (1b) and (1c).

If our coefficient of interest on the triple interaction 𝛽7 is negative and statistically significant, it

means that the negative effect measured by the coefficient 𝛽3 in regression specifications (1a),

(1b) and (1c) is particularly strong for exclusive customers as compared to non-exclusive ones, i.e.

borrowing costs of exclusive “Distressed bank” customers dropped the most.

Specification (3a):

𝑏𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑖𝑛𝑔_𝑐𝑜𝑠𝑡𝑠𝑓,𝑞 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝛽2 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 + 𝛽3 ∗ 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 + 𝛽4 ∗ 𝑠ℎ𝑜𝑟𝑡_𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑓 + 𝛽5 ∗

𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝛽6 ∗ 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝛽7 ∗ 𝑠ℎ𝑜𝑟𝑡_𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑓 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 + 𝛽8 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗

𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 + 𝛽9 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑠ℎ𝑜𝑟𝑡_𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑓 + 𝛽10 ∗ 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 ∗ 𝑠ℎ𝑜𝑟𝑡_𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑞 + 𝛽11 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 ∗

𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 + 𝛽12 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑠ℎ𝑜𝑟𝑡_𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑓 + 𝛽13 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 ∗ 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 ∗

𝑠ℎ𝑜𝑟𝑡_𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑓 + 𝛽14 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 ∗ 𝑠ℎ𝑜𝑟𝑡_𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑓 + 𝛽15 ∗ 𝑎𝑓𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑞 ∗ 𝑐𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑒𝑑𝑓 ∗ 𝑒𝑥𝑐𝑙𝑢𝑠𝑖𝑣𝑒𝑓 ∗

𝑠ℎ𝑜𝑟𝑡_𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑓 + 𝜀𝑓,𝑞

Page 21: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

21

Where 𝑠ℎ𝑜𝑟𝑡_𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑓 is a dummy variable equal to 1 if firm’s f average length of existing lending

relationships before the bank’s failure was shorter than 6 years, and zero otherwise. Specifications

(3b) and (3c) extend specification (3a) by including fixed effects in line with specifications (1b)

and (1c).

If our coefficient of interest on the quadruple interaction 𝛽15 is negative and statistically

significant, it means that the negative effect measured by the coefficient 𝛽7 in regression

specifications (2a), (2b) and (2c) is stronger for “short-term” customers than for “long-term”

customers i.e. borrowing costs of “exclusive” “short-term” “Distressed bank’s” customers dropped

the most.

4.2. Results

First, we estimate the difference-in-difference regression specifications (1a), (1b), (1c), (2a), (2b),

(2c), (3a), (3b) and (3c) using our default setting defined in section “4.1. Empirical strategy”. Then

we modify this setting by considering: (1) only term loans, (2) only leasing contracts, (3) only

customers of the most similar bank to “Distressed bank” as a control group, (4) including firms

that were dropped out due to credit quality restrictions, and (5) using customers of “Healthy bank”

as a treatment group.

4.2.1. Default setting

Table 2 presents the results of the default setting. The coefficient of interest 𝛽3 in regression

specification (1a) is equal to -1.420 and is statistically significant at the 1% level. This means that

after the closure of “Distressed bank”, loan rates of its customers (i.e. the treatment group)

decreased by 1.42 percentage point (pp) more than for all other firms on average. This result is

displayed in Figure 2.1: before the “Distressed bank’s” failure, the average interest rate of the

treatment group was declining in parallel to the rate of the control group but was significantly

higher. Immediately after the bank’s closure the average interest rate of its customers dropped

sharply and converged to the market’s average. When controlling for fixed effects in specifications

(1b) and (1c), the estimated coefficient of interest remains negative (-1.1) and statistically

significant at the 1% level.

Page 22: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

22

As shown in Table 2, column (2a), the coefficient of interest 𝛽7 is equal to -2.536 and statistically

significant at the 1% level, while the coefficient 𝛽3 remains negative (-0.955) and statistically

significant at the 1% level. This indicates that relative to the rest of the market, average interest

rates for “non-exclusive” borrowers dropped by 1 pp, while “exclusive” customers enjoyed a

massive drop of 3.5 pp (𝛽3 + 𝛽7) on average. This differential effect can be seen in Figure 2.2: the

gap between “exclusive” and “non-exclusive” borrowers was large before the bank’s failure, but

it vanished after it. Interestingly, despite the downward common trend of average interest rates,

loan rates for “exclusive” customers were increasing before the bank’s closure, which suggests

that these customers were increasingly more exploited. While this violates the common trends

assumption, the upward direction suggests that in the absence of the shock, the borrowing costs of

exclusive “Distressed bank’s” customers would have grown even larger. Therefore, we might be

underestimating the negative impact of the relationship break-up on borrowing costs. When

controlling for fixed effects in specifications (2b) and (2c), in both cases the coefficients 𝛽3 and

𝛽7 are statistically significant at the 1% level and are approximately equal to -0.5 and -3,

respectively.

Table 2, column (3a) shows that the coefficient of interest on the quadruple interaction 𝛽15 is

negative (-2.8) and statistically significant at the 5% level. It becomes even more negative (-3.7)

and significant at the 1% level in specifications with fixed effects (3b) and (3c). This means that

the “exclusive” “short-term” customers experienced the biggest drop of all “Distressed bank’s”

customers, which is reflected in Figure 2.3. The figure displays average borrowing costs only of

customers of “Distressed bank” split into 4 groups. Before the bank’s closure, “exclusive” “short-

term” customers on average borrowed the most expensively, followed by “exclusive” “long-term”

borrowers, followed by “non-exclusive” “short-term” customers and, finally, followed by “non-

exclusive” “long-term” borrowers. After the closure, the gaps between these groups shrank and

the average borrowing costs intertwined over time. Despite an arguably stronger dependence on

“Distressed bank”, the “long-term” customers were treated better by the failing bank than the

“short-term” ones, which suggests that long-term relationships may be beneficial. Alternatively,

this result may be explained by a positive correlation between relationships’ length and firms’ age:

younger firms are more obscure to an outside bank, and thus, might be more vulnerable to hold-

up. In fact, when we redefine the 𝑠ℎ𝑜𝑟𝑡_𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑚𝑓 variable equal to 1 if firm’s f first appearance on

Page 23: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

23

the credit register was less than six years ago as of 2013 Q1, and zero otherwise, the coefficient of

interest 𝛽15 becomes smaller in absolute magnitude and less significant but remains qualitatively

similar: 𝛽15 = -1.9 and p-value = 0.116 in column (3a); 𝛽15 = -2.9 and p-value = 0.014 in column

(3b); 𝛽15 = -3.0 and p-value = 0.013 in column (3c) (see Appendix 9.1.). In order to test if long-

term relationships indeed may be beneficial, in section 6, we examine the link between the

relationship length and interest rates controlling for all observed and unobserved firm-specific

time-varying characteristics, including firm’s age.

4.2.2. Only term loans and only leasing contracts

The results are similar when using separately both term loans and leasing contracts. Appendix 1.1.

displays the figure comparable to Figure 2.1., and Appendix 1.2. contains a table similar to Table

2, with the difference that only term loans are considered. Appendices 2.1. and 2.2. shows the same

for leasing contracts. In both cases, after the shock, loan rates dropped significantly more to the

“Distressed bank’s” customers (and particularly for exclusive and short-term customers) than for

the rest of the market.

4.2.3. Alternative control group: customers of the most similar bank

The results are very similar to the default setting, when we use an alternative control group. Instead

of customers of all banks other than “Distressed bank”, we use customers of the bank which is the

most similar to “Distressed bank” in terms of size, customer quality (measured as a proportion of

firms with delayed repayments) and customers’ average loan rates. The figure in Appendix 3.1.

displays the evolution of average borrowing costs of the treatment group and the control group.

The table in Appendix 3.2. shows coefficient estimates from the difference-in-difference analysis.

4.2.4. The Only Firm-Quality Restriction – Shock Survivors

Since the best-quality firms are the most subject to hold-up (Sharpe, 1990), we attempt to identify

these firms with as much certainty as possible and focus our main analysis on them. However, as

shown by the figure in Appendix 4.1. and the table in Appendix 4.2., our results are qualitatively

similar to the default setting if we jointly relax three of the four restrictions and include: (1) all

firms which delayed repayments within our sample period, (2) “Distressed bank’s” customers

assigned to the “bad bank”, and (3) “Distressed bank’s” customers that switched to the bank which

Page 24: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

24

acquired the “good bank”. The only restriction we keep is that we consider only those firms which

survived the shock, i.e. reappeared in the credit register after the shock. This is necessary to ensure

that we compare the same firms before and after the shock. After including the worst-quality firms,

we end up with 607 firms in the treatment group and still see a statistically significant (at the 1%

level) post-shock drop in average borrowing costs for “Distressed bank’s” customers relative to

the rest of the market.

Figures 3.1., 3.2. and 3.3. clarify how effective the three firm-quality criteria are in identifying

good-quality firms. They show the evolution of borrowing costs when the full treatment group of

607 firms is split into two: good and bad customers of “Distressed bank”, based on one of the

aforementioned three criteria. Figure 3.1. reveals that those “Distressed bank’s” customers that

had no repayment delays within our sample period experienced a post-shock drop in average

borrowing costs but those customers that had at least one repayment delay did not. Similarly,

according to Figure 3.2., “Distressed bank’s” customers that were assigned to the “good bank” by

KPMG experienced a drop in loan rates after the bank’s closure, but customers that were assigned

to the “bad bank” experienced a loan rate hike. Interestingly, customers assigned to the “bad bank”

borrowed cheaper than those assigned to the “good bank” while the bank was still open, but this

reversed after the bank’s closure.17 Similarly to Figure 3.1., Figure 3.3. shows that those

“Distressed bank’s” customers that stayed with the acquiring bank (i.e. the bank which acquired

the “good bank” and before the shock was considered to be similar to “Distressed bank” in many

respects) did not experience any drop in borrowing costs after the bank’s closure. However, the

majority of firms were able to switch to other banks (mostly Scandinavian-owned banks, which

were known to attract better-quality firms) and enjoyed much lower interest rates.

All in all, the three firm-quality criteria help to identify the best-quality firms and to make them

more comparable between the treatment and control groups in the default setting. However, the

criteria are not necessary to expose a statistically significant negative effect of the lending

relationship break-up on borrowing costs.

17 As mentioned in section “3. Closures of banks”, the majority of the bank’s misrepresented assets, which were

assigned to the “bad bank” by KPMG, consisted of loans extended to firms closely related to the bank’s major

shareholder (OECD, 2017). This explains why they could borrow cheaper than genuinely high-quality firms.

Page 25: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

25

4.2.5. “Healthy bank’s” customers as a treatment group

Finally, we repeat the analysis using the default setting but with customers of “Healthy bank” as a

treatment group. Table 3 shows that none of the coefficients of interest are significant, while Figure

4.1. reveals that average borrowing costs of “Healthy bank’s” customers followed the common

trend without major shifts before and after the bank’s closure. This suggests that, on average,

relationships with “Healthy bank” neither reduced nor inflated borrowing costs for firms.

Overall, our results suggest that while “Distressed bank” was functioning, interbank information

asymmetries were causing severe switching costs for its best customers and provided hold-up

opportunities for the bank. “Distressed bank” exploited these hold-up opportunities and extracted

rents from its best customers. Exclusive, and, in particular, exclusive short-term customers appear

to have been exploited the most. Once the bank failed, information asymmetries between

“Distressed bank” and other banks disappeared together with “Distressed bank”, all firms – good

and bad – were forced to switch, and, thus, by switching, good firms no longer signaled their

inferiority (e.g. inability to borrow from their current bank). As a result, these firms were free to

choose other lenders and borrow at much lower average market rates. Such behavior of “Distressed

bank” is not surprising, considering that financially distressed banks have fewer resources and

incentives to care about their reputation and are more concerned about surviving (Boot et al.,

1993). This reasoning is confirmed by the absence of evidence of similar behavior by “Healthy

bank”, which may have been highly concerned about its reputation.

The large estimated hold-up costs imposed by “Distressed bank” are somewhat surprising

considering the credit market’s transparency in Lithuania. Banks can access a ten-year-history of

their applicants' current and expired debt contracts. Nevertheless, important information

asymmetries across banks appear to remain. For example, firms may keep borrowed funds in an

account with the same bank, who, in turn, can observe firms’ spending patterns. Also, due to the

possibility of the loan evergreening by distressed banks, other banks may treat firms’ credit

histories with caution. If interbank information asymmetries matter in Lithuania, they are likely to

matter even more in markets where banks cannot access such a long and detailed history of firms’

debts.

4.3. Robustness tests

Page 26: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

26

One of the main findings of this study is that borrowing costs of the best “Distressed bank’s”

customers drop sharply after the bank is closed, and we explain this primarily by a break-up of

lending relationships. However, there are other potential explanations why the closure of a bank

could cause or coincide with changes in borrowing costs of its customers. Firstly, a continuous

deterioration of firms’ credit quality could have caused both the bank’s closure and the change in

loan rates of its customers. Secondly, the bank’s closure could have cast doubt for other lenders

on the true quality of even the best customers of the failed bank. However, both of these scenarios

would push borrowing costs of the “Distressed bank’s” customers upwards after the bank’s

closure, while we find the opposite. Thus, we might underestimate the downward impact of

relationship break-up on borrowing costs.

Thirdly, the almost simultaneous closures of “Healthy bank” and “Distressed bank” are likely to

have affected the interbank market concentration, as indicated by the jump of HHI from 1,796 in

2012 Q4 to 1,959 in 2013 Q2. This would not influence the results of our difference-in-difference

analysis if the concentration of banks had equal effects on firms in both the treatment group (i.e.

customers of a closed bank) and the control group (i.e. all other firms). However, according to

Klemperer (1987), in markets with switching costs, “the monopoly power that firms gain over their

respective market segment leads to vigorous competition for market share before consumers have

attached themselves to suppliers”. Thus, firms that have lost and are lacking lending relationships

(i.e. our treatment group) may be affected by the interbank competition more than firms which are

already locked-in by banks. A weakening competition should drive interest rates of the former

“Distressed bank’s” borrowers upwards, while our difference-in-difference analysis shows a steep

drop. Thus again, due to changes in competition, we may underestimate the negative impact of the

loss of lending relationships on firms’ borrowing costs. Nevertheless, we run a robustness test in

which we make our treatment and control groups as similar as possible with respect to the

sensitivity to competition. We disregard forced switching loans of “Distressed bank’s” customers

after the shock, i.e. the first loans taken by “Distressed bank’s” borrowers after they lost their sole

lending relationships, and consider only subsequent loans taken after these customers already

started new relationships. As shown in Figure 11 and Table 15 in Appendices 5.1. and 5.2.,

respectively, our results remain robust.

Page 27: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

27

Fourthly, the estimated drop in borrowing costs from the difference-in-difference analysis could

have been affected by the auditors’ conclusions. For instance, banks could acknowledge the

superior quality stamp provided by the KPMG’s valuation and, therefore, charge firms assigned to

the “good bank” lower interest rates. However, our results are qualitatively similar if we consider

only those post-shock loans (leasing, term loans and credit lines) which were issued within the

three weeks after the bank’s failure, i.e. before “Distressed bank” was split by the auditor

(Appendices 6.1. and 6.2.).

Fifthly, it seems possible that the high pre-shock borrowing costs of “Distressed bank’s” customers

were driven by some very old loans and the observed drop is explained simply by resetting loan

inventories of every firm to zero at the date of the shock. We show that the results are qualitatively

similar to the main ones in two robustness checks: (1) if we consider narrower time windows

around the shock, i.e. only loans (leasing, term loans and credit lines) issued during the two years

before the shock and the two years after the shock (Appendices 7.1. and 7.2.), and (2) if we consider

only newly issued loans (leasing, term loans and credit lines) in each quarter (Appendices 8.1. and

8.2.). There are two reasons why we treat these results as a robustness check and not as the main

results. Firstly, as shown by the figure in Appendix 8.3., “Distressed bank” had a tendency to price

its loans cheaper initially and slightly increase interest rates on the same loans in the following

months, while, on average, the rest of banks show the opposite loan-pricing policy. Therefore, by

considering only the newly issued loans, we would underestimate the actual borrowing costs of

the “Distressed bank’s” customers and overestimate borrowing costs of all other firms. Secondly,

by using only newly issued loans, we would drop a significant number of useful observations and

reduce the power of our tests.

5. Do interest rates really converge after the failure of “Distressed bank”?

In this section, we use the fact that after losing a sole lender due to its closure, firms were forced

to switch to other banks. We follow a loan matching analysis in order to compare interest rates on

forced-switching loans and similar non-switching loans issued at the same time by the same bank

to two similar firms – a forced-switcher, i.e. a former customer of “Distressed bank”, and an old

customer (non-switcher). This analysis allows us to examine the following findings from section

4 in more detail: (1) whether borrowing costs of “Distressed bank’s” customers converged to a

Page 28: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

28

market’s average after the bank’s failure, (2) whether relationships with healthy banks on average

neither reduce nor inflate borrowing costs for firms18, and (3) whether information asymmetries

are the primary cause of switching costs, as argued by Bonfim et al. (2018) in a similar setting19.

In this analysis, we examine former “exclusive” customers of “Distressed bank” assigned to the

“good bank” after the bank’s failure. Again, we jointly consider the three most popular loan types:

leasing, term loans and credit lines.

5.1. Empirical strategy

Table 4 provides switching-related definitions used in our setting. We follow the loan matching

technique applied by Ioannidou and Ongena (2010), who studied endogenous firms’ decisions to

switch banks and matched regular switching loans (i.e. loans from a bank with which a firm had

no debts outstanding within one prior year) with similar non-switching loans (i.e. loans from a

bank with which a firm had some debt outstanding within one prior year). In order to ensure

comparability between their results and ours, we first replicate their setting comparing regular-

switching loans with non-switching loans and then compare forced-switching loans (i.e. a subset

of switching loans taken by firms that were forced to switch after losing their sole lending

relationship with “Distressed bank”) to non-switching loans.

All loans are considered only once – in a quarter in which they were issued. Table 5 provides

average characteristics of each group of loans. In total, our dataset contains 1,302 forced-switching

loans, which include customers of “Distressed bank”, “Healthy bank” and the bank which closed

in the first quarter of our sample5, 13,133 regular-switching loans, and 81,731 non-switching loans.

As compared to non-switching loans, forced-switching loans on average carry a higher interest

rate. Also, the latter loan type appears to be more likely to have a fixed interest rate, larger

collateral, slightly shorter time to maturity and a larger loan amount. Borrowers of forced

switching loans seem to be much smaller as measured by the total amount of debt, slightly riskier

as measured by the probability of delayed repayments one year before and one year after taking a

loan, and to have fewer and shorter lending relationships on average. Regular-switching loans

18 If relationships with healthy banks were beneficial (costly), we would expect an old customer of a bank to pay a

lower (higher) interest rate than a similar new customer, which was forced to switch. 19 Bonfim et al. (2018) study closures of banks’ branches. We argue that our identification of forced switching is

cleaner since a closure of the whole bank completely eliminates the possibility of borrowing from that bank.

Page 29: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

29

appear to be the largest, and their borrowers the riskiest and with the most lending relationships.

In terms of all other considered characteristics, regular-switching loans appear in between forced-

switching loans and non-switching loans. In order to control for these differences when comparing

interest rates, we match loans on these loan and firm characteristics. All matching variables are

explained in Table 6.

We apply the following procedure. First, we identify all newly issued regular-switching, forced-

switching and non-switching loans based on definitions in Table 4. Consistently with section 4,

we consider the three most popular loan types together: leasing, term loans, and credit lines.

Second, every regular-switching loan is matched with as many non-switching loans as possible,

based on the set of matching variables described in Table 6. For each pair, we calculate an interest

rate spread between a switching and a non-switching loan. The spreads are regressed on a constant,

and standard errors are clustered at a switching-loan level. Third, we repeat the procedure

considering forced-switching loans instead of regular-switching loans.

5.2. Results

5.2.1. Regular-switching loans

Table 7 presents the results. As seen in column I, when matching on all the loan and firm

characteristics defined in Table 6, regular-switching loans obtain a discount of 26.3 bps (significant

at the 1% level) as compared to non-switching loans. This result is not surprising since firms are

expected to switch only when they receive an offer which is better than one from their inside bank.

Using similar sets of matching variables, Ioannidou and Ongena (2010) found a discount between

82.2 bps and 97.2 bps in Bolivia in 1999-2003. The smaller discount obtained in Lithuania could

be explained by a more concentrated loan market (Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) for

outstanding loans throughout our sample period varied from 1,632 to 1,992, while in Bolivia in

1999-2003, HHI varied between 1,335 and 1,587).

As shown in Table 7, column (model) II, the result is virtually the same if matching restrictions

are somewhat relaxed. By increasing the matching window for all continuous variables from ±30%

to ±70% and dropping a few variables, we increase the number of observations from 112 to

285,453 without biasing the result. The estimated discount in column/model II is 25.9 bps and

Page 30: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

30

significant at the 1% level. Under model II, two loans are matched if they were issued in the same

quarter by the same bank to two firms of similar size (proxied by total debt) and riskiness (proxied

by a dummy equal to 1 if a firm delayed at least one repayment in one prior year, and zero

otherwise), and if the two loans were of the same type, similar amount, similar proportion of loan

amount collateralized, and similar maturity. Under model II, we have enough observations to

estimate switching discounts for the three types of loan types separately (columns III to V): 26.1

bps discount (significant at 1% level) for leasing, 7.0 bps (significant at 5% level) discount for

term loans and 28.1 bps (significant at the 1% level) discount for credit lines. We use model II as

a benchmark model in the rest of our analysis.

5.2.2. Forced-switching loans

In order to compare forced-switching loans to non-switching loans, we apply the set of matching

variables used in Table 7 column (model) II and add one more – “Prior relationship length”, which

matches firms with comparable lengths of previous relationships and controls for firms’ age. Table

8 presents the results. The first three columns consider forced-switchers from “Distressed bank”.

As a robustness check, columns IV to VI include forced-switchers from “Healthy bank” and the

bank which closed in the first quarter of the sample period5. The estimated switching discount in

column I is equal to 3.1 bps and is not statistically significant. This implies that after losing their

lending relationships with “Distressed bank” and switching to new lenders, firms on average were

offered interest rates similar to ones received by old customers of the same lenders. This also

suggests that, on average, relationships with healthy banks neither reduce nor inflate borrowing

costs. Bonfim et al., (2018) interprets this finding as evidence that information asymmetries are

the primary source of switching costs. This interpretation follows from the theoretical model of

Von Thadden (2004), which explains regular-switching discounts as successful randomized

attempts of uninformed outside banks to outcompete offers of informed inside banks. Thus, if the

inside bank does not exist, there is no reason to offer a discount. If, instead, shoe-leather switching

costs and the competition for the market share were causing the discounts (Klemperer 1987), a

firm should receive such a discount regardless of whether it has an inside bank or not.

In columns II and III of Table 8, we split the matched loan pairs into two groups and re-estimate

the discounts. Column II considers loan pairs, in which old customers (non-switchers) had long

Page 31: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

31

prior lending relationships (on average longer than 6 years), while column III considers non-

switchers with prior relationships shorter than 6 years20 on average. When compared to non-

switchers engaged in long-term relationships, forced-switchers from “Distressed bank” received

more expensive loans by 19.7 bps on average (significant at 5% level). In contrast, forced-

switchers from “Distressed bank” received an average discount of 23.5 bps (significant at the 5%

level) when compared to non-switchers with shorter-term relationships. As shown in columns IV

to VI, these results remain robust and become even slightly stronger after including forced-

switchers from the other two banks that closed in our sample period.

Overall, we find that after switching to new banks, former customers of “Distressed bank” and old

customers of those banks received similar interest rates, even when controlling for lengths of firms’

previous relationships. This strengthens the validity of evidence from section 4, showing that

firms’ borrowing costs converge to a market’s average after the failure of their distressed bank.

Moreover, consistently with the diff-in-diff analysis for “Healthy bank”, this suggests no benefits

or costs on average from relationships with healthy banks. Also, as argued by Bonfim et al. (2018),

this also suggests that switching costs mainly stem from information asymmetries. Yet, we find a

differential effect that varies with relationship length. In line with findings of the difference-in-

difference analysis for “Distressed bank”, this suggests that long-term relationships with banks are

generally beneficial, and shorter-term relationships are costly.

6. How do interest rates depend on lending relationship length?

This question has been heavily studied in the relationship lending literature (e.g. Petersen and

Rajan, 1994; Berger and Udell, 1995). Few studies, however, have analyzed the benefits and costs

of very long-term relationships. To the best of our knowledge, only Lopez-Espinosa et al. (2017)

tracked the complete lengths of lending relationships. They found a concave link between

relationship length and interest rates, which is in line with our findings in sections 4 and 5. In this

section, we study this link not only in order to explain our findings in sections 4 and 5, but also to

add much-needed external validity to the findings of Lopez-Espinosa et al. (2017), who studied

the behavior of only one Spanish bank.

20 The cut-off of 6 years was chosen on the basis of an interest rate pattern uncovered in Figure 5, which indicates that

after 6 years of relationships, average interest rates start to decrease. This pattern is tested in detail in section 6.

Page 32: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

32

6.1. Empirical strategy

Figure 5 displays average interest rates of all newly issued debt contracts in the first year of our

sample period (2011 q4 – 2012 q3), grouped by the length of relationships between borrowers and

lenders. We restrict the sample period to one year in order to avoid influence from the downward

trend of interest rates over time. The graph suggests that interest rates increase in the first years of

relationships, stay elevated until the 6th year, and then start decreasing. This pattern could be driven

by changes in other loan characteristics or by the survivorship of the best-quality firms. In order

to account for these possibilities, we employ two different techniques: (1) loan matching and (2)

panel regression.

6.1.1. Loan matching

Arguably, interest rates on loans are decided jointly with other loan characteristics, i.e. loan size,

maturity, and collateral. Therefore, regressing an interest rate on a relationship length and

including endogenous loan characteristics as controls could bias the results. Different studies

tackle the endogeneity by using the distance between a firm and a bank as an instrumental variable

(Bolton et al., 2016; Beck et al., 2017), applying propensity score matching (Li et al., 2017), using

simultaneous equations (Bharath et al., 2011), omitting endogenous controls (Schäfer, 2016) or

assuming that interest rates are set after deciding other loan characteristics (Bharath et al., 2011).

We follow Ioannidou and Ongena (2010), who use a non-parametric approach – matching similar

loans on other loan characteristics. In this way, we do not need to assume anything about the

sequence of loan pricing.

We follow a procedure similar to the one described in section 5.1. Firstly, we identify all newly

issued switching and non-switching loans based on definitions in Table 4. Consistently with

sections 4 and 5, we consider the three most popular loan types: leasing, term loans, and credit

lines. Secondly, every regular-switching loan is matched with as many subsequent non-switching

loans taken by the same firm from the same bank as possible. The loans are matched if they are of

the same loan type and similar maturity, loan amount and collateral size. In order to control for

changes in firms’ quality over time, we run our analysis twice: (1) first, matching two loans if the

borrower either delayed at least one repayment within one year before taking each of these loans,

Page 33: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

33

or did not delay any repayments before taking each of these loans, and (2) second, keeping only

those firms which never delayed any repayment within our sample period.

Thirdly, for each matched pair, we calculate an interest rate spread between a non-switching loan

and a switching loan and a time spread between the two loans. Based on the time spread, each pair

gets assigned one out of six yearly time-gap dummies equal to 1. The six time-gaps are: up to 1

year, between 1 and 2, between 2 and 3, between 3 and 4, between 4 and 5 and more than 5 years.

Estimated interest rate spreads are regressed on a set of time-gap dummies. We control for time

trends by subtracting a 3-month Euribor rate from every interest rate reported at the end of the

quarter and by including switching loans’ time fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered at a

switching loan level.

6.1.1. Panel regression

In order to control better for firms’ quality, age and other unobservable time-varying firm

characteristics, we run a panel regression similar to Lopez-Espinosa et al. (2017) but controlling

for observable and unobservable firm-specific-time-varying characteristics. The identification

stems from firms that in the same quarter borrowed from at least two different banks with which

they had different relationship lengths. In addition, we control for firm-bank-specific-time-

invariant21, bank-specific-time-varying22 and loan type-specific characteristics.

We estimate the following regression model using newly issued leasing contracts, term loans and

credit lines between 2011 q4 and 2018 q1.

𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑒𝑠𝑡_𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑙,𝑓,𝑏,𝑞 = 𝛼 + 𝛽1 × 𝑙𝑛 (𝑟𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝_𝑙𝑒𝑛𝑔𝑡ℎ𝑓,𝑏,𝑞) + 𝛽2 ×

𝑙𝑛2(𝑟𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝_𝑙𝑒𝑛𝑔𝑡ℎ𝑓,𝑏,𝑞) + 𝛽3 × 𝑡𝑖𝑚𝑒_𝑡𝑜_𝑚𝑎𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑙,𝑓,𝑏,𝑞 + 𝛽4 × 𝑝𝑒𝑟𝑐_𝑐𝑜𝑙𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑙𝑙,𝑓,𝑏,𝑞 + 𝛽5 ×

𝑙𝑜𝑎𝑛_𝑠𝑖𝑧𝑒𝑙,𝑓,𝑏,𝑞 + 𝑓𝑖𝑟𝑚 × 𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑟𝑡𝑒𝑟 𝐹𝐸 + 𝑓𝑖𝑟𝑚 × 𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐹𝐸 + 𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑘 × 𝑞𝑢𝑎𝑟𝑡𝑒𝑟 𝐹𝐸 + 𝑙𝑜𝑎𝑛𝑡𝑦𝑝𝑒 𝐹𝐸 +

𝜖𝑙,𝑓,𝑏,𝑞 (4)

where,

21 For instance, if the manager of a firm personally knows the manager of a bank, this could lead to both longer lending

relationships and lower interest rates. Firm x Bank – fixed effects control for this and similar possibilities. 22 For instance, if a bank occasionally engages in promotion campaigns, this could affect its relationships and interest

rates at the same time. Bank x Time – fixed effects control for this and similar possibilities.

Page 34: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

34

• 𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑒𝑠𝑡_𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑙,𝑓,𝑏,𝑞 is the interest rate charged for the newly issued loan 𝑙, taken by firm

𝑓, from bank 𝑏, in quarter 𝑞.

• 𝑟𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝_𝑙𝑒𝑛𝑔𝑡ℎ𝑓,𝑏,𝑞 is the length of the relationship between firm 𝑓 and bank 𝑏 in

quarter 𝑞 measured in quarters. Relationship lengths are measured from 1995 to 2018.

• 𝑡𝑖𝑚𝑒_𝑡𝑜_𝑚𝑎𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑙,𝑓,𝑏,𝑞 is time to maturity of the issued loan.

• 𝑝𝑒𝑟𝑐_𝑐𝑜𝑙𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑙𝑙,𝑓,𝑏,𝑞 is the amount of the collateral relative to the size of the loan:

collateral/loan_size.

• 𝑙𝑜𝑎𝑛_𝑠𝑖𝑧𝑒𝑙,𝑓,𝑏,𝑞 is the outstanding amount of the loan.

• FE stands for “fixed effects”.

In line with Lopez-Espinosa et al. (2017), we use the logarithm of relationship length and its

square. The logarithm ensures that an extra year in a long-lasting relationship has less impact on

the interest rate than an extra year in a short relationship. Including a squared logarithm allows us

to capture non-linear dynamics, which could resemble the shape of dynamics between the lending

relationship length and the interest rate depicted in Figure 5. We expect to obtain a positive and

significant coefficient on the logarithm of relationship length and a negative and significant

coefficient on its square.

6.2. Results

6.2.1. Loan matching

Results are presented in Table 9. All six estimated dummy coefficients on time-gap dummies are

significant at the 1 % level and are equal to 49.3 for a time gap smaller than 1 year, 55.2 for a gap

between 1 and 2 years, 46.1 for a gap between 2 and 3 years, 37.6 for a gap between 3 and 4 years,

31.3 for a gap between 4 and 5 years and -41.6 for a gap larger than 5 years. This implies that after

switching to a new bank and receiving a discount of 25.9 bps (estimated in Table 7, column II) the

following loans taken in the next 5 years from the same bank are on average more expensive,

which is broadly in line with Ioannidou and Ongena (2010). Loans taken within the first year of

the new relationship are on average more expensive by 49.3 bps than the switching loan. Loans

taken within the second year of the relationship are on average more expensive by 55.2 bps than

the switching loan etc.

Page 35: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

35

However, after two years the interest rate starts to decrease, and after five years it drops below the

average rate received on the switching loan. The loan rate dynamics are depicted in Figure 6.1.

The results are robust if we take into account only those firms which never delayed any repayment

throughout our sample period (time-gap dummies are reported in the last row of Table 9).

6.2.1. Panel regression

The results of the panel regression are consistent with the results of the loan matching analysis.

Table 10, columns 4 presents the results of our benchmark regression specification (4) described

in section 6.1.1. As expected, the coefficient on the logarithm of relationship length is positive

(significant at the 1% level) while the coefficient on its square is negative (significant at the 10%

level). The results are even more significant in column 5 (both coefficients significant at the 1%

level) where we additionally control for fixed effects of loan-type interacted with time, firm and

bank. Column 6 shows that the results are virtually the same if we drop possibly endogenous

controls for loan characteristics (maturity, loan size and collateralized proportion of the loan size).

Table 10 also reveals that it is important to control for firm x time fixed effects (column 3) in order

to capture the nonlinear dynamics, although they are partially captured by using non-interactive

firm, bank, time and loan-type fixed effects (column 2). Without absorbing any fixed effects, the

results are insignificant (column 1).

Predicted values of regression specification 4 and 5 are displayed in Figure 6.2. They indicate that,

on average, interest rates rise sharply by roughly 0.5% in the first year of a new lending relationship

and then start decreasing until, after 6 years, rates fall below the initial levels. These results are in

line with the interest rate dynamics estimated using the loan matching analysis (Table 9 and Figure

6.1).

Overall, our results suggest that very long-term relationships (on average, above 6 years) help

firms to reduce borrowing costs, while short-term relationships are costly. This pattern is consistent

with the following explanation. Banks attract new customers by offering discounts. After starting

the new lending relationships, banks may exploit their informational advantages and extract rents

from their customers in the next 6 years on average. However, banks seem to provide their

Page 36: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

36

customers with incentives to stay loyal by slowly lowering lending prices and promising even

lower rates in the long run.

7. Conclusion

In this paper, we studied how lending relationships with banks affected firms’ borrowing costs.

For identification, we used closures of banks – a novel setting that allowed us to ask the following

research questions for the first time. How do banks’ closures affect loan rates of their customers?

Does this effect depend on the closed bank’s health and the lost relationships’ length? We used

graphical and the difference-in-difference analyses and found that the closure of the healthy bank

had no effect on its customers’ borrowing costs. Meanwhile, when the financially distressed bank

closed, its customers’ borrowing costs dropped sharply and immediately converged to the market’s

average. The drop was even more pronounced for “exclusive” borrowers (i.e. those lacking other

lending relationships) and especially for “short-term” (<6 years) borrowers.

The loan matching analysis supported our evidence that, after the closure of “Distressed bank”, its

customers borrowed at average market interest rates. We found that banks offered the same rates

to their old customers and to forced-switchers (firms that lost their sole inside bank), which

suggests that relationships with healthy banks on average neither benefited nor hurt firms. In line

with Bonfim et al. (2018), this also provides evidence that information asymmetries are the

primary source of switching costs. Nevertheless, we found a differential effect: long-term

customers (>6 years) borrowed cheaper and shorter-term (<6 years) customers borrowed more

expensively than forced-switchers. The panel regression and loan matching analyses confirmed

that short-term relationships are generally costly, but long-term relationships are beneficial.

Overall, existing theory and our findings suggest that, normally, banks offer discounts to attract

firms and in the next few years exploit their switching costs stemming from interbank information

asymmetries. Yet, possibly due to reputational concerns, banks treat their loyal customers well and

signal to other firms that in the long run relationships pay off. Meanwhile, if a bank is in financial

distress, it has fewer resources and incentives to treat its borrowers nicely. As a result, borrowing

costs of such customers stay inflated until the bank’s closure eliminates information asymmetries

between the failed bank and other banks, and allows firms to switch banks without signaling

inferiority.

Page 37: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

37

Our results have some policy implications. Firstly, liquidating a distressed failing bank, as opposed

to bailing it out, may help its high credit quality customers to quickly access much cheaper and

more fairly priced financing. This consideration is particularly relevant if the bank’s failure is

isolated and does not cause a systemic event. Secondly, the case of “Distressed bank” revealed

that even in a relatively transparent market, where banks can access a detailed ten-year-history of

firms’ credit, interbank information asymmetries matter and might hinder efficient credit

allocation (Dell’Ariccia and Marquez, 2004). Policy-makers may well consider ways to further

reduce these asymmetries.

Page 38: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

38

References

Angelini, P., Salvo, R. D., & Ferri, G. (1998). Availability and cost of credit for small businesses:

Customer relationships and credit cooperatives. Journal of Banking & Finance,22(6-8), 925-954.

doi:10.1016/s0378-4266(98)00008-9

Ashcraft, A. B. (2005). Are banks really special? New evidence from the FDIC-induced failure of

healthy banks. The American Economic Review, 95(5), 1712-1730.

Bank of Lithuania. (2011). Informacija apie kredito ir mokėjimo įstaigų veiklą bei jų priežiūrą 2011

m. Retrieved from

https://www.lb.lt/uploads/documents/files/news/informacija_apie_kredito_ir_mokejimo_istaigu_

veikla_bei_ju_prieziura_2011_m.pdf.

Beck, T., Degryse, H., Haas, R. D., & van Horen, N. (2017). When Arms Length is Too Far.

Relationship Banking Over the Business Cycle. Journal of Financial Economics,Forthcoming.

doi:10.2139/ssrn.2461601

Berger, A. N., & Udell, G. F. (1995). Relationship Lending and Lines of Credit in Small Firm

Finance. The Journal of Business,68(3).

Berlin, M., & Mester, L. J. (1999). Deposits and Relationship Lending. The Review of Financial

Studies,12(3), 579.

Bernanke, B. S. (1983). Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great

Depression. The American Economic Review, 73, 257-276.

Bharath, S. T., Dahiya, S., Saunders, A., & Srinivasan, A. (2011). Lending Relationships and Loan

Contract Terms. The Review of Financial Studies,24(4), 1141-1203. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhp064

BNS and lrytas.lt. (2012, December 19). Ūkio ir Šiaulių bankai gali būti sujungti? Lrytas.lt. Retrieved

May 19, 2019, from https://verslas.lrytas.lt/mano-pinigai/2019/05/17/news/lrytas-lt-skaitytojai-

apie-devetu-rubu-parduotuves-ir-geda-ir-megztini-uz-30-ct-nusiperki-10390319/

Bolton, P., Freixas, X., Gambacorta, L., & Mistrulli, P. E. (2016). Relationship and Transaction

Lending in a Crisis. Review of Financial Studies,29(10), 2643-2676. doi:10.3386/w19467

Bonfim, D., Nogueira, G., & Ongena, S. (2017). Sorry, Were Closed: Loan Conditions When Bank

Branches Close and Firms Transfer to Another Bank. Working Paper. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2749155

Boot, A. W., Greenbaum, S. I., & Thakor, A. (1993). Reputation and Discretion in Financial

Contracting. American Economic Review,83(5), 1165-1183.

Boot, A. W., & Thakor, A. V. (2000). Can Relationship Banking Survive Competition? The Journal

of Finance, 55(2), 679-713. doi:10.1111/0022-1082.00223

Botsch, M., & Vanasco, V. (2019). Learning by lending. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 37, 1-

14. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2018.03.002

Carvalho, D. R., Ferreira, M. A., & Matos, P. P. (2015). Lending Relationships and the Effect of Bank

Distress: Evidence from the 2007-2008 Financial Crisis. Journal of Financial and Quantitative

Analysis,50(6), 1165-1197.

Page 39: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

39

Chava, S., & Purnanandam, A. K. (2011). The Effect of Banking Crisis on Bank-Dependent

Borrowers. Journal of Financial Economics,99(1), 116-135.

doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.08.006

Chodorow-Reich, G. (2014). The Employment Effects of Credit Market Disruptions: Firm-level

Evidence from the 2008–9 Financial Crisis *. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,129(1), 1-59.

doi:10.1093/qje/qjt031

Ciulada, P. (2013, October 11). Gerosios Ūkio banko dalies gelbėjimo operacija valstybei kainuos

128 mln. Lt brangiau. Verslo Zinios. Retrieved May 17, 2019, from

https://www.vz.lt/archive/article/2013/10/11/gerosios-ukio-banko-dalies-gelbejimo-operacija-

valstybei-kainuos-128-mln-lt-brangiau

Cooper, N. (2012, February 1). Bankroto administratorius: "Snoras" žlugo greičiausiai ne dėl krizės.

Retrieved from https://www.vz.lt/archive/article/2012/2/1/bankroto-administratorius-snoras-

zlugo-greiciausiai-ne-del-krizes

Dahiya, S., Saunders, A., & Srinivasan, A. (2003). Financial Distress and Bank Lending

Relationships. The Journal of Finance,50(1), 375-399.

Degryse, H. A., & Ongena, S. R. (2005). Distance, Lending Relationships and Competition. The

Journal of Finance, 60(1), 231-266. doi:https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00729.x

Dell’Ariccia, G., & Marquez, R. (2004). Information and bank credit allocation. Journal of Financial

Economics,72(1), 185-214. doi:10.1016/s0304-405x(03)00210-1

Diamond, D. W. (1984). Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring. The Review of

Economic Studies,51(3), 393. doi:10.2307/2297430

Gobbi, G. & Sette E. (2015), “Relationship Lending During a Financial Crisis”, Journal of the

European Economic Association, 13(3), 453-481.

Hubbard, R. G., Kuttner, K. N., & Palia, D. (2002). Are There Bank Effects in Borrowers Costs of

Funds? Evidence from a Matched Sample of Borrowers and Banks. The Journal of Business,75(4),

559-581.

Ioannidou, V., & Ongena, S. R. (2010). Time for a Change: Loan Conditions and Bank Behavior when

Firms Switch Banks. The Journal of Finance,65(5).

Jiménez, G., Ongena, S., Peydró, J.-L., and Saurina, J. 2017. Macroprudential policy, countercyclical

bank capital buffers, and credit supply: Evidence from the Spanish dynamic provisioning

experiments. Journal of Political Economy 125, 2126–77.

Klemperer, P. (1987). Markets with Consumer Switching Costs. The Quarterly Journal of

Economics,102(2), 375-394.

Korte, J. (2015). Catharsis - Tracing the Real Effects of Bank Insolvency and Resolution. Journal of

Financial Stability, 16, 213-231

Kuodis, R. (2013, February 13). R.Kuodis: Valstybės įstaigų vadovai turėjo suprasti, kad dėti pinigus

į Ūkio banką yra rizikinga. Retrieved from https://www.delfi.lt/verslas/archive/rkuodis-valstybes-

istaigu-vadovai-turejo-suprasti-kad-deti-pinigus-i-ukio-banka-yra-rizikinga.d?id=60663867

Page 40: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

40

Kysucky, V., & Norden, L. (2015). The Benefits of Relationship Lending in a Cross-Country Context:

A Meta-Analysis. Management Science,62(1).

Li, Y., Srinivasan, A., & Lu, R. (2017). Relationship Bank Behavior During Borrower

Distress. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis (JFQA), Forthcoming.

doi:10.2139/ssrn.1773069

Lopez-Espinosa, G., Mayordomo, S., & Moreno, A. (2017). When Does Relationship Lending Start

to Pay? Journal of Financial Intermediation,31, 16-29.

Mian, A., & Khwaja, A. I. (2008). Tracing the Impact of Bank Liquidity Shocks: Evidence from an

Emerging Market. American Economic Review,98(4), 1413-1442. doi:10.1257/aer.98.4.1413

Minamihashi, N. (2011). Credit Crunch Caused by Bank Failures and Self-Selection Behavior in

Lending Markets. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 43(1), 133-161. doi:10.1111/j.1538-

4616.2010.00368.x

OECD (2017). Lithuania: Review of the Financial System (Report). OECD

Ongena, S., Smith, D. C., & Michalsen, D. (2003). Firms and their distressed banks: Lessons from the

Norwegian banking crisis. Journal of Financial Economics,67(1), 81-112. doi:10.1016/s0304-

405x(02)00232-5

Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. G. (1994). The Benefits of Lending Relationships: Evidence from Small

Business Data. The Journal of Finance,49(1), 3. doi:10.2307/2329133

Petersen, M., & Rajan, R. (1995). The Effect of Credit Market Competition on Lending Relationships.

The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(2), 407-443. doi:https://doi.org/10.2307/2118445

Rajan, R. G. (1992). Insiders and Outsiders: The Choice between Informed and Arms-Length

Debt. The Journal of Finance,47(4), 1367-1400. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1992.tb04662.x

Santos, J. A. (2011). Bank Corporate Loan Pricing Following the Subprime Crisis. The Review of

Financial Studies,24(6), 1916-1943. doi:https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhq115

Scharfstein, D. S., & Ivashina, V. (2010). Bank Lending During the Financial Crisis of 2008. Journal

of Financial Economics,97(3), 319-338.

Schenone, C. (2009). Lending Relationships and Information Rents: Do Banks Exploit Their

Information Advantages? Review of Financial Studies,23(3), 1149-1199. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhp080

Schäfer, L. (2018). “Forgive but Not Forget”: The Behavior of Relationship Banks When Firms Are

in Distress. Review of Finance. doi:10.1093/rof/rfy031

Schnabl, P. (2012). The International Transmission of Bank Liquidity Shocks: Evidence from an

Emerging Market. The Journal of Finance, 67(3), 897-932. doi:10.1111/j.1540-

6261.2012.01737.x

Sharpe, S. A. (1990). Asymmetric Information, Bank Lending and Implicit Contracts: A Stylized

Model of Customer Relationships. The Journal of Finance,45(4), 1069. doi:10.2307/2328715

Page 41: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

41

Slovin, M. B., Sushka, M. E., & Polonchek, J. A. (1993). The Value of Bank Durability: Borrowers

as Bank Stakeholders. The Journal of Finance,48(1), 247-266. doi:10.1111/j.1540-

6261.1993.tb04708.x

Thadden, E. V. (2004). Asymmetric information, bank lending and implicit contracts: The winners

curse. Finance Research Letters,1(1), 11-23. doi:10.1016/s1544-6123(03)00006-0

Page 42: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

42

FIGURE 1.1

Proportion of each bank’s customers with delayed repayments prior to January 1, 2013 Figure 1.1 shows the proportion of each bank’s customers that delayed at least one repayment on any debt contract within one

year prior to January 1, 2013. A bank’s customer is defined as a firm which had any amount of debt outstanding with that bank

for any period of time within one year prior to January 1, 2013. The figure displays the proportion and the 95% confidence

interval.

FIGURE 1.2

Loan rates of each bank’s customer group prior to January 1, 2013 Figure 1.2 shows a weighted average interest rate (weighted by outstanding loan amount) calculated for each bank’s customer

group across all contracts (term loans, leasing and credit lines) outstanding and across all quarters within one year prior to

January 1, 2013. A bank’s customer is defined as a firm which had any amount of debt outstanding with that bank for any period

of time within one year prior to January 1, 2013. The figure displays the average interest rate and the 95% confidence interval.

Page 43: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

43

FIGURE 2.1

Borrowing Costs of Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. All Other Firms. Considering Three Loan

Types and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Figure 2.1 complements the results of Table 2, regression specification (1a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

two groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” and customers of all other banks, evolve over time. A firm is considered a

customer of a bank if it had any debt with that bank within one year prior to 2013 February 12 (failure of “Distressed bank”).

This shock is marked by the vertical line. Borrowing costs for each firm equal an average interest rate weighted by loan

outstanding amounts at each quarter. Leasing, term loans and credit lines are considered. After the shock, contracts issued before

the shock are not considered. The chart considers only those firms that reappeared in the credit register (survived) after the shock

and never delayed any repayment within the whole sample period. In addition, the chart considers only those customers of

“Distressed bank” that were assigned to the “good bank” and did not switch to the acquiring bank.

FIGURE 2.2

Borrowing Costs of Exclusive Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. All Other Firms. Considering Three

Loan Types and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Figure 2.2 complements the results of Table 2, regression specification (2a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

four groups of firms: exclusive and non-exclusive customers of “Distressed bank” and exclusive and non-exclusive customers

of all other banks, evolve over time. A firm is considered a customer of a bank if it had any debt with that bank within one year

prior to 2013 February 12 (failure of “Distressed bank”). This shock is marked by the vertical line. If a firm had debts only with

that one bank, it is an exclusive customer. Borrowing costs for each firm equal an average interest rate weighted by loan

outstanding amounts at each quarter. Leasing, term loans and credit lines are considered. After the shock, contracts issued before

the shock are not considered. The chart considers only those firms that reappeared in the credit register (survived) after the shock

and never delayed any repayment within the whole sample period. In addition, the chart considers only those customers of

“Distressed bank” that were assigned to the “good bank” and did not switch to the acquiring bank.

Page 44: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

44

FIGURE 2.3

Borrowing Costs of Exclusive and Short(Long)-Term Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. All Other

Firms. Considering Three Loan Types and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Figure 2.3 complements the results of Table 2, regression specification (3a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

four groups of firms: exclusive and non-exclusive, long-term and short-term customers of “Distressed bank” evolve over time.

A firm is considered a customer of a bank if it had any debt with that bank within one year prior to 2013 February 12 (failure of

“Distressed bank”). This shock is marked by the vertical line. If a firm had debts only with that one bank, it is an exclusive

customer. If a firm’s average relationship length with its banks in 2013 q1 was shorter than 6 years, it is a “short-term” customer.

Borrowing costs for each firm equal an average interest rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts at each quarter. Leasing,

term loans and credit lines are considered. After the shock, contracts issued before the shock are not considered. The chart

considers only those firms that reappeared in the credit register (survived) after the shock and never delayed any repayment

within the whole sample period. In addition, the chart considers only those customers of “Distressed bank” that were assigned

to the “good bank” and did not switch to the acquiring bank.

FIGURE 3.1

Borrowing Costs of “Distressed bank’s” Customers With Repayment Delays vs. Without. Considering

Three Loan Types and the Only Firm-Quality Restriction – Shock Survivors Figure 3.1 shows how average borrowing costs of three groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” with repayment delays,

customers of “Distressed bank” without repayment delays and customers of all other banks, evolve over time. A firm is

considered a customer of a bank if it had any debt with that bank within one year prior to 2013 February 12 (failure of “Distressed

bank”). This shock is marked by the vertical line. Borrowing costs for each firm equal an average interest rate weighted by loan

outstanding amounts at each quarter. Leasing, term loans and credit lines are considered. After the shock, contracts issued before

the shock are not considered. The chart considers only those firms that reappeared in the credit register (survived) after the

shock.

Page 45: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

45

FIGURE 3.2

Borrowing Costs of “Distressed bank’s” Customers Assigned to “Good Bank” vs. “Bad Bank”.

Considering Three Loan Types and the Only Firm-Quality Restriction – Shock Survivors Figure 3.2 shows how average borrowing costs of three groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” assigned to the “good

bank” by KMPG, customers of “Distressed bank” assigned to the “bad bank” by KMPG and customers of all other banks, evolve

over time. A firm is considered a customer of a bank if it had any debt with that bank within one year prior to 2013 February 12

(failure of “Distressed bank”). This shock is marked by the vertical line. Borrowing costs for each firm equal an average interest

rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts at each quarter. Leasing, term loans and credit lines are considered. After the shock,

contracts issued before the shock are not considered. The chart considers only those firms that reappeared in the credit register

(survived) after the shock.

FIGURE 3.3

Borrowing Costs of “Distressed bank’s” Customers that Switched to Acquirer vs. Switched to Other

Banks. Considering Three Loan Types and the Only Firm-Quality Restriction – Shock Survivors Figure 3.3 shows how average borrowing costs of three groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” that stayed with the

acquiring bank, customers of “Distressed bank” that switched to other banks and did not borrow from the acquirer and customers

of all other banks, evolve over time. A firm is considered a customer of a bank if it had any debt with that bank within one year

prior to 2013 February 12 (failure of “Distressed bank”). This shock is marked by the vertical line. Borrowing costs for each

firm equal an average interest rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts at each quarter. Leasing, term loans and credit lines

are considered. After the shock, contracts issued before the shock are not considered. The chart considers only those firms that

reappeared in the credit register (survived) after the shock.

Page 46: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

46

FIGURE 4.1

Borrowing Costs of Customers of “Healthy bank” vs. All Other Firms. Considering Three Loan Types

and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Figure 4.1 complements the results of Table 3, regression specification (1a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

two groups of firms: customers of “Healthy bank” and customers of all other banks, evolve over time. A firm is considered a

customer of a bank if it had any debt with that bank within one year prior to 2013 January 30 (the day of “Healthy bank’s”

decision to stop business). This shock is marked by the vertical line. Borrowing costs for each firm equal an average interest

rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts at each quarter. Leasing, term loans and credit lines are considered. After the shock,

contracts issued before the shock are not considered. The chart considers only those firms that reappeared in the credit register

(survived) after the shock and never delayed any repayment within the whole sample period.

FIGURE 5

(Uncontrolled) relationship between interest rate and firm-bank relationship length Figure 5 shows the relationship between firm-bank relationship length and the interest rates charged. All new debt contracts

issued in the first year of the sample, i.e. 2011 q4 – 2012 q3, were grouped by years of relationship between a lender and a

borrower. The sample period in this graph is limited to one year in order to avoid the influence of the downward interest rate

trend over time. Average interest rate and a 95% confidence interval is plotted for each group.

Page 47: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

47

FIGURE 6.1

Results of the Loan Matching Analysis: The Development of Interest Rates After Switching Figure 6.1 complements the results of Table 7 and Table 9. The figure shows the development of average interest rates

throughout the relationship time. The first observation (taken from Table 7, column II) indicates the average discount firms

receive when they voluntarily switch to other banks and start new lending relationships. The rest of observations (taken from

Table 9) show how on average the rate at a new bank develops throughout years after switching.

FIGURE 6.2

Panel Regressions: Relationship between interest rate and firm-bank relationship length Figure 6.2 complements the results of Table 10. It plots predicted values of the panel regressions estimated in Table 10 columns

4 and 5. The regressions estimated a non-linear link between interest rate charged on newly issued loans (leasing contracts, term

loans and credit lines issued between 2011 q4 and 2018 q1) and the relationship length between a bank and a firm.

Page 48: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

48

TABLE 1a

Summary statistics of loan characteristics Table 1a reports summary statistics of all the loans in the data sample. Statistics are split by loan type (the three most popular

ones – leasing, term loans and credit lines – and other).

TABLE 1b

Summary statistics of firm characteristics The top part of Table 1b reports summary statistics of all the firms in the data sample. Statistics are split by firms’ industry (the

three most popular ones – Manufacturing, Retail/wholesale and Transportation – and other). The middle and bottom parts report

firms’ statistics at a fixed point of time – the beginning of the sample period – 2011 Q4.

Loantype Leasing Term loans Credit lines Other Total

Number of loans 131,238 24,507 7,847 27,136 190,728

Number of loans collateralized 2,170 20,045 6,700 9,850 38,765

Percentage of loans collateralized 2% 82% 85% 36% 20%

Loan size (EUR) average 49,443 1,039,184 696,573 374,643 249,509

25th percentile 12,729 34,754 30,000 1,014 12,164

median 23,364 113,143 94,127 10,000 25,809

75th percentile 54,747 463,392 300,000 60,000 71,330

Loan maturity (years) average 2.9 3.4 1.0 1.3 2.7

25th percentile 1.8 1.3 0.5 0.5 1.0

median 2.8 2.8 0.8 0.8 2.8

75th percentile 4.3 4.8 1.5 1.8 4.0

Loan interest rate (%) average 3.2 4.4 4.1 6.0 3.8

25th percentile 1.9 2.9 2.8 1.4 2.0

median 3.0 4.0 4.1 4.1 3.2

75th percentile 4.2 5.5 5.4 8.8 4.8

Firms' industry Manufacturing Retail/Wholesale Transportation Other Total

Number of firms 3,730 9,207 4,209 18,759 35,905

Number of firms without delayed repayments between 2011-2018 2,977 7,758 3,356 15,855 29,946

Number of firms with delayed repayments between 2011-2018 753 1,449 853 2,904 5,959

Percentage of firms with delayed repayments between 2011-2018 20% 16% 20% 15% 17%

Firm size (proxied as total debt to banks), average 1,633,159 818,025 912,740 1,605,811 1,325,397

25th percentile 25,162 19,720 26,341 12,200 16,492

median 97,476 57,924 86,440 40,000 52,896

75th percentile 437,597 228,600 303,427 200,417 246,129

Number of firms at the beginning of the sample - 2011Q4 2,073 4,684 2,161 8,348 17,266

Firm size (proxied as total debt to banks) at 2011Q4, average 1,143,963 609,510 643,322 1,215,557 970,929

25th percentile 27,239 20,273 33,819 14,771 19,028

median 101,348 57,784 101,367 44,779 59,923

75th percentile 434,430 225,705 322,799 257,414 275,412

Number of firms with a single relationship at 2011Q4* 1,446 3,514 1,512 6,858 13,330

Number of firms with multiple relationships at 2011Q4* 627 1,170 649 1,490 3,936

Number of firms with short (average<6y) relationships at 2011Q4* 1,267 3,054 1,499 5,933 11,753

Number of firms with long (average>6y) relationships at 2011Q4* 806 1,630 662 2,415 5,513

*a firm is said to have a relationship with a bank if it had some outstanding debt with that bank within the previous 12 months

Page 49: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

49

TABLE 2

Difference-in-difference Analysis Default Setting: Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. All Other Firms.

Three Loan Types and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Table 2 reports coefficient estimates from difference-in-difference panel regressions without fixed effects (specifications 1a, 2a

and 3a) with firm-fixed effects (specifications 1b, 2b and 3b) and with firm-fixed effects and quarter(time)-fixed effects

(specifications 1c, 2c and 3c). The data used in the analysis is at the quarter-firm level. The dependent variable

“borrowing_costs” is a firm’s average interest rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts at each quarter. In quarters 2011q4 -

2012q4, we consider only leasing contracts, term loans and credit lines issued up to 2012 December 31. In quarters 2013q1 -

2018q1, we consider only leasing contracts, term loans and credit lines issued from 2013 February 12 (the day of “Distressed

bank’s” closure). The explanatory variables are four dummies: “after” - equal to 1 if an observation is from quarters 2013q1 -

2018q1, and 0 otherwise; “closed” – equal to 1 if a firm belongs to the treatment group, i.e. had any debt outstanding with the

closed “Distressed bank” within one year prior to 2013 February 12, and 0 otherwise; “exclusive” – equal to 1 if a firm had

debts only with one bank within the same prior year, and 0 otherwise; “short_term” equal to 1 if a firm’s average relationship

length with its banks in 2013 q1 was shorter than 6 years, and 0 otherwise. Other explanatory variables are interactions between

these four variables. Robust standard errors are clustered multiway at the firm and quarter levels. P-values are reported in

parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed, respectively.

(1a) (1b) (1c) (2a) (2b) (2c) (3a) (3b) (3c)

after -0.989*** -1.234*** -0.787*** -1.181*** -0.429** -1.075***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.013) (0.000)

closed 1.174*** 0.481*** 0.510***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.002)

exclusive 0.158*** 0.242***

(0.000) (0.000)

short_term 0.853***

(0.000)

closed x after -1.420*** -1.108*** -1.096*** -0.955*** -0.507*** -0.498*** -1.209*** -0.608*** -0.606***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

exclusive x after -0.454*** -0.080* -0.050 -0.713*** -0.071 -0.024

(0.000) (0.053) (0.202) (0.000) (0.151) (0.606)

short_term x after -0.892*** -0.258*** -0.266***

(0.000) (0.001) (0.001)

closed x exclusive 3.318*** 1.850

(0.000) (0.133)

closed x short_term -0.240

(0.304)

exclusive x short_term -0.351***

(0.000)

after x closed x exclusive -2.536*** -3.054*** -2.978*** -0.722 -0.338 -0.312

(0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.511) (0.661) (0.688)

after x closed x short_term 0.726*** 0.247 0.263

(0.002) (0.279) (0.244)

after x exclusive x short_term 0.693*** 0.043 0.015

(0.000) (0.608) (0.860)

closed x exclusive x short_term 2.035

(0.141)

after x closed x exclusive x short_term -2.758** -3.758*** -3.685***

(0.038) (0.002) (0.002)

Constant 4.431*** 4.659*** 3.584*** 4.325*** 4.639*** 3.601*** 3.971*** 4.595*** 3.652***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Firm-fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES

Quarter-fixed effects YES YES YES

Number of observations 232,819 232,819 232,819 232,819 232,819 232,819 232,819 232,819 232,819

Adjusted R-squared 0.043 0.792 0.808 0.052 0.793 0.809 0.059 0.794 0.811

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: borrowing_costs

Page 50: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

50

TABLE 3

Difference-in-difference Analysis: Customers of “Healthy bank” vs. All Other Firms. Three Loan

Types and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Table 2 reports coefficient estimates from difference-in-difference panel regressions without fixed effects (specifications 1a, 2a

and 3a) with firm-fixed effects (specifications 1b, 2b and 3b) and with firm-fixed effects and quarter(time)-fixed effects

(specifications 1c, 2c and 3c). The data used in the analysis is at the quarter-firm level. The dependent variable

“borrowing_costs” is a firm’s average interest rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts at each quarter. In quarters 2011q4 -

2012q4, we consider only leasing contracts, term loans and credit lines issued up to 2012 December 31. In quarters 2013q1 -

2018q1, we consider only leasing contracts, term loans and credit lines issued from 2013 January 30 (the day of “Healthy

bank’s” decision to stop business). The explanatory variables are four dummies: “after” - equal to 1 if an observation is from

quarters 2013q1 - 2018q1, and 0 otherwise; “closed” – equal to 1 if a firm belongs to the treatment group, i.e. had any debt

outstanding with the closed “Healthy bank” within one year prior to 2013 January 30, and 0 otherwise; “exclusive” – equal to 1

if a firm had debts only with one bank within the same prior year, and 0 otherwise; “short_term” equal to 1 if a firm’s average

relationship length with its banks in 2013 q1 was shorter than 6 years, and 0 otherwise. Other explanatory variables are

interactions between these four variables. Robust standard errors are clustered multiway at the firm and quarter levels. P-values

are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed, respectively.

(1a) (1b) (1c) (2a) (2b) (2c) (3a) (3b) (3c)

after -1.026*** -1.263*** -0.849*** -1.217*** -0.490*** -1.104***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.005) (0.000)

closed -0.918*** -0.950*** -1.082***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

exclusive 0.123*** 0.175***

(0.004) (0.000)

short_term 0.840***

(0.000)

closed x after 0.018 0.147 0.106 -0.129 0.174 0.152 -0.392*** 0.150 0.130

(0.899) (0.310) (0.466) (0.445) (0.301) (0.370) (0.005) (0.284) (0.371)

exclusive x after -0.417*** -0.070* -0.040 -0.661*** -0.044 0.000

(0.000) (0.095) (0.314) (0.000) (0.364) (0.994)

short_term x after -0.881*** -0.271*** -0.279***

(0.000) (0.001) (0.001)

closed x exclusive 0.419 1.046*

(0.149) (0.070)

closed x short_term 0.231

(0.407)

exclusive x short_term -0.280***

(0.002)

after x closed x exclusive 0.139 -0.273 -0.304 0.089 -0.565 -0.540

(0.634) (0.342) (0.292) (0.858) (0.153) (0.200)

after x closed x short_term 0.629* 0.069 0.068

(0.082) (0.846) (0.849)

after x exclusive x short_term 0.651*** 0.013 -0.013

(0.000) (0.879) (0.879)

closed x exclusive x short_term -1.088

(0.101)

after x closed x exclusive x short_term -0.093 0.458 0.378

(0.886) (0.428) (0.524)

Constant 4.476*** 4.673*** 3.572*** 4.394*** 4.653*** 3.584*** 4.040*** 4.607*** 3.639***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Firm-fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES

Quarter-fixed effects YES YES YES

Number of observations 234,219 234,219 234,219 234,219 234,219 234,219 234,219 234,219 234,219

Adjusted R-squared 0.043 0.790 0.807 0.049 0.790 0.807 0.057 0.791 0.808

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: borrowing_costs

Page 51: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

51

TABLE 4

Definitions of switching Table 4 provides switching-related definitions used in section 5.

Term Definition

Inside bank A bank with which a firm had any amount of debt outstanding at any

point of time within 1 prior year. In line with Ioannidou and Ongena

(2010), we conservatively assume that relationship ties are broken if

there is a gap without outstanding loans of 1 year or longer. The authors

show that results are robust using time periods other than 1 year.

Outside bank A bank with which a firm had no debt outstanding at any point of time

within 1 prior year.

Switcher A firm which is taking a loan from an outside bank. Consistently with

Ioannidou and Ongena (2010) and Bonfim et al. (2018), we exclude

firms that had no debts with any bank within the last 12 months.

Switching loan (or regular-switching loan) A loan taken by a switcher from an outside bank.

Non-switching loan A loan taken by a firm from its inside bank.

Forced-switching loan A switching loan which is taken by a firm after it lost its sole lending

relationship with “Distressed bank”.

TABLE 5

Summary statistics of loan characteristics Table 5 provides average characteristics of all newly issued debt contracts between 2011 q4 and 2018 q1

Non-switching

loans

Regular-

switching loans

Forced-

switching loans

Loans to firms

that had no

loans in 1 prior

year

Total

Number of all newly issued debt contracts 81,731 13,133 1,302 21,391 117,557

Interest rate (%) 3.34 4.49 4.95 4.92 3.77

Probability of a floating rate (%) 75% 66% 58% 62% 71%

Probability of using collateral (%) 17% 32% 51% 27% 21%

Proportion of collateralized loan amount (%) 27% 54% 69% 39% 33%

Time to maturity (quarters) 12 12 11 12 12

Loan amount (euros) 223,510 347,619 259,267 208,172 234,980

Amount of total borrowers's debt (euros) 21,126,904 4,594,471 1,612,482 612,518 15,330,980

Probability of borrower's delayed repayment within last year (%) 6% 10% 7% - 6%

Probability of borrower's delayed repayment within next year (%) 7% 11% 8% 5% 7%

Number of borrower's prior inside banks 1.9 2.3 1.5 - 1.8

Length of borrower's prior relationships (quarters) 21 17 10 - 21

Page 52: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

52

TABLE 6

Matching Variables Table 5 provides the descriptions of matching variables

Category Matching variables A switching loan and a non-switching loan were matched:

Macro Year & quarter if both loans were issued in the same quarter (in total 26 quarters:

2011 q4 – 2018 q1)

Bank Outside bank if the bank that issued both loans was the switcher’s new

(outside) bank (in total 12 banks)

Firm Firm if both loans were issued to the same firm (in total 25,436 firms)

Firm Repayment troubles last year if either both firms delayed at least one repayment or both firms

did not delay any repayments in the previous 4 quarters

Firm Economic activity (sector) if both firms operated in the same sector (in total 20 sectors)

Firm Total bank debt (+-30%) if a non-switcher’s total amount of debt in the given quarter was

similar to a switcher’s total amount of debt (using a (-30%,

+30%) window around switcher’s debt)

Loan Loan type if both loans were of the same type (e.g. leasing, term loans,

credit lines)

Loan Proportion of loan collateralized (+-30%) if both loans had a similar proportion of the face value

collateralized (using a (-30%, +30%) window around the

switching loan’s collateralized proportion)

Loan Loan maturity (+-30%) if both loans had a similar maturity (using a (-30%, +30%)

window around the switching loan’s maturity)

Loan Loan amount (+-30%) if both loans had a similar amount (using a (-30%, +30%)

window around the switching loan’s amount)

Loan Floating loan rate if both loans had either floating or fixed interest rates (a rate is

defined as floating if it varies more than 50% of the time)

Firm Loan rate on prior inside loans (+-30%) if both firms had similar interest rates (maximum across all

outstanding loans) in the previous period (using a (-30%, +30%)

window around the switcher’s rate)

Firm Prior relationship length (+-30%) if both firms had similar lengths of lending relationships (average

across all inside banks) in the previous period (using a (-30%,

+30%) window around the switcher’s length)

Firm Prior multiple bank relationships if both firms either had or did not have multiple bank

relationships in the previous period

Firm Prior primary lender if both firms either had or did not have a primary lender (a bank

which provided more than 50% of a firm’s debt) in the previous

period

Firm Prior scope of the bank relationship if both firms either had or did not have different loan types

Page 53: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

53

TABLE 7

Results of the Loan Matching Analysis: Spreads Between Regular-Switching and Non-Switching

Loans We estimate a spread between an interest rate on a switching loan and an interest rate on a similar non-switching loan taken by

a similar firm in the same quarter from the same bank. Definitions of switching and non-switching loans and inside and outside

banks are provided in Table 4. We pair every switching loan with as many non-switching loans as possible, based on matching

variables described in Table 5. Columns I and II consider leasing contracts, term loans and credit lines, while column III

considers only leasing, column IV – only term loans, and column V – only credit lines. The windows used for matching

continuous variables are relaxed in columns II to V from +-30% to +-70%. Estimated interest rate spreads are regressed on a

constant. The estimated coefficients on the constant are reported in the bottom row. Robust standard errors are clustered at the

switching loan level and reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed,

respectively.

I II III IV V

Loan types considered All three All three Leasing Term loans Credit lines

Window used for matching +-30% +-70% +-70% +-70% +-70%

Year & quarter Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Outside bank Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Repayment troubles last year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Economic activity (sector) Yes

Total bank debt (+-30% or 70%) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Loan type Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Proportion of loan collateralized (+-30%

or 70%)

Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Loan maturity (+-30% or 70%) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Loan amount (+-30% or 70%) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Floating loan rate Yes

Loan rate on prior inside loans (+-30%

or 70%)

Yes

Prior relationship length (+-30% or

70%)

Yes

Prior multiple bank relationships Yes

Prior primary lender Yes

Prior scope of the bank relationship Yes

Number of switching loans 86 7,951 6,450 1,139 362

Number of non-switching loans 66 33,690 31,165 2,022 503

Number of observations (matched pairs) 112 285,453 281,309 3,431 713

Spread in basis points -26.3*** -25.9*** -26.1*** -7.0** -28.1***

(7.5) (1.0) (1.0) (3.5) (4.7)

Page 54: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

54

TABLE 8

Results of the Loan Matching Analysis: Spreads Between Forced-Switching and Non-Switching Loans. We estimate a spread between an interest rate on a forced-switching loan and an interest rate on a similar non-switching loan

taken by a similar firm in the same quarter from the same bank. Definitions of forced-switching and non-switching loans and

inside and outside banks are provided in Table 4. We pair every forced-switching loan with as many non-switching loans as

possible, based on matching variables described in Table 5. Columns I and IV consider all firms, columns II and V consider

only those non-switching firms that on average had relationships with banks longer than 6 years, and columns III and VI – only

those non-switching firms that on average had relationships with banks shorter than 6 years. Estimated interest rate spreads are

regressed on a constant. The estimated coefficients on the constant are reported in the bottom row. Robust standard errors are

clustered at the switching loan level and reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1%

levels, two-tailed, respectively.

I II III IV V VI

Forced-switchers from

which banks?

“Distressed” “Distressed” “Distressed” 3 closed

ones

3 closed

ones

3 closed

ones

Loan types considered All three All three All three All three All three All three

Window used for

matching

+-70% +-70% +-70% +-70% +-70% +-70%

Subsample All firms Nonswitcher

with long

relationships

(>6 years)

Nonswitcher

with short

relationships

(<6 years)

All firms Nonswitcher

with long

relationships

(>6 years)

Nonswitcher

with short

relationships

(<6 years)

Year & quarter Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Outside bank Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Repayment troubles last

year

Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Total bank debt (+-70%) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Loan type Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Proportion of loan

collateralized (+-70%)

Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Loan maturity (+-70%) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Loan amount (+-70%) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Prior relationship length

(+-70%)

Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Number of switching

loans

40 19 19 68 22 46

Number of non-switching

loans

199 118 75 328 137 191

Number of observations

(matched pairs)

248 139 99 383 158 225

Spread in basis points 3.1 19.7** -23.5** -5.4 19.9** -24.7***

(8.2) (8.5) (10.0) (8.0) (7.5) (8.6)

Page 55: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

55

TABLE 9

Results of the Loan Matching Analysis: The Development of Interest Rates Over Time We estimate a spread between an interest rate on a non-switching loan and an interest rate on a similar switching loan taken by

the same firm from the same bank, when they started the lending relationship. Definitions of switching and non-switching loans

and inside and outside banks are provided in Table 4. We pair every switching loan with as many non-switching loans as

possible, based on matching variables used in Table 7, column II, except that instead of matching on firms’ size we match on

the firm’s identity. Estimated interest rate spreads are regressed on a set of dummy variables which indicate yearly time gaps

between the switching and the non-switching loans. We control for time trends by subtracting 3-month Euribor rate from every

interest rate and by including switching loans’ time fixed effects. The estimated coefficients on the time-gap dummies are

reported in the bottom row. Robust standard errors are clustered at the switching loan level and reported in parentheses. *, **,

and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed, respectively.

Time gaps between a non-switching

loan and a switching loan

Up to

1 year

From 1 to

2 years

From 2 to

3 years

From 3 to

4 years

From 4 to

5 years

More than

5 years

Loan types considered All three All three All three All three All three All three

Window used for matching +-70% +-70% +-70% +-70% +-70% +-70%

Outside bank Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Repayment troubles last year Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Firm Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Loan type Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Proportion of loan collateralized (+-

70%)

Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Loan maturity (+-70%) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Loan amount (+-70%) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Number of switching loans 2,495 1,563 1,011 797 340 136

Number of non-switching loans 2,877 2,116 1,922 1,209 523 323

Number of observations (matched

pairs)

33,168 60,495 145,640 106,740 5,790 922

Coefficient on the time-gap dummy 49.3*** 55.2*** 46.1*** 37.6*** 31.3*** -41.6***

(7.8) (8.0) (8.0) (8.0) (8.1) (10.8)

Considering only those firms which never had any repayment delays:

Number of switching loans 2,184 1,467 941 776 327 116

Number of non-switching loans 2,540 1,915 1,840 1,168 512 211

Number of observations (matched

pairs)

32,250 60,132 145,430 106,688 5,775 432

Coefficient on the time-gap dummy 53.4*** 59.8*** 50.2*** 41.6*** 35.7*** -40.9*

(7.1) (7.3) (7.3) (7.3) (7.4) (22.9)

Page 56: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

56

TABLE 10

Panel Regression: Relationship between interest rate and firm-bank relationship length Table 10 reports coefficient estimates from the panel regressions where the dependent variable “loan rate” is an interest rate

charged on a new loan l issued by bank b to firm f in quarter q, and the explanatory variable is the logarithm of the length of the

relationship between firm f and bank b in quarter q measured in quarters. In order to capture the non-linear dynamics, we also

add the square of the explanatory variable. We use newly issued leasing contracts, term loans and credit lines between 2011 q4

and 2018 q1. Relationship lengths are measured from 1995 to 2018. Each column presents coefficients obtained using different

level of controls. We control for loan characteristics, i.e. time to maturity, loan amount and collateralized proportion of loan

amount, firm fixed effects, quarter fixed effects, bank fixed effects, loan type fixed effects and interactions between these fixed

effects. Robust standard errors are clustered at the firm level. P-values are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate

significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed, respectively.

1 2 3 4 5 6

Log(relationship length) -0.147 0.144*** 0.305** 0.598*** 0.717*** 0.710***

(0.504) (0.000) (0.010) -0.009 (0.000) (0.000)

Log(relationship length)^2 -0.036 -0.035*** -0.078*** -0.179* -0.216*** -0.213***

(0.492) (0.000) (0.005) (0.098) (0.007) (0.008)

Constant 4.078***

(0.000)

Controls for loan characteristics YES YES YES YES YES

Firm - FE YES

Quarter - FE YES

Bank - FE YES

Loan type - FE YES YES

Firm x Quarter - FE YES YES YES YES

Firm x Bank - FE YES YES YES

Bank x Quarter - FE YES YES YES

Loan type x Quarter - FE YES YES

Loan type x Firm - FE YES YES

Loan type x Bank - FE YES YES

Number of observations 95,400 86,045 58,679 57,769 56,123 56,130

Adjusted R-squared 0.106 0.803 0.936 0.950 0.955 0.955

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: loan rate

Page 57: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

57

Appendix

Appendix 1.1.

FIGURE 7

Borrowing Costs of Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. All Other Firms. Considering Term Loans and

Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Figure 7 complements the results of Table 11, regression specification (1a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

two groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” and customers of all other banks, evolve over time. A firm is considered a

customer of a bank if it had any debt with that bank within one year prior to 2013 February 12 (failure of “Distressed bank”).

This shock is marked by the vertical line. Borrowing costs for each firm equal an average interest rate weighted by loan

outstanding amounts at each quarter. Only term loans are considered. After the shock, contracts issued before the shock are not

considered. The chart considers only those firms that reappeared in the credit register (survived) after the shock and never

delayed any repayment within the whole sample period. In addition, the chart considers only those customers of “Distressed

bank” that were assigned to the “good bank” and did not switch to the acquiring bank.

Page 58: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

58

Appendix 1.2.

TABLE 11

Difference-in-difference Analysis: Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. All Other Firms. Term Loans

and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Table 11 reports coefficient estimates from difference-in-difference panel regressions without fixed effects (specifications 1a,

2a and 3a) with firm-fixed effects (specifications 1b, 2b and 3b) and with firm-fixed effects and quarter(time)-fixed effects

(specifications 1c, 2c and 3c). The data used in the analysis is at the quarter-firm level. The dependent variable

“borrowing_costs” is a firm’s average interest rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts at each quarter. In quarters 2011q4 -

2012q4, we consider only term loans issued up to 2012 December 31. In quarters 2013q1 - 2018q1, we consider only term loans

issued from 2013 February 12 (the day of “Distressed bank’s” closure). The explanatory variables are four dummies: “after” -

equal to 1 if an observation is from quarters 2013q1 - 2018q1, and 0 otherwise; “closed” – equal to 1 if a firm belongs to the

treatment group, i.e. had any debt outstanding with the closed “Distressed bank” within one year prior to 2013 February 12, and

0 otherwise; “exclusive” – equal to 1 if a firm had debts only with one bank within the same prior year, and 0 otherwise;

“short_term” equal to 1 if a firm’s average relationship length with its banks in 2013 q1 was shorter than 6 years, and 0 otherwise.

Other explanatory variables are interactions between these four variables. Robust standard errors are clustered multiway at the

firm and quarter levels. P-values are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels,

two-tailed, respectively.

(1a) (1b) (1c) (2a) (2b) (2c) (3a) (3b) (3c)

after -0.025 -0.728*** 0.054 -0.841*** 0.574*** -0.866***

(0.804) (0.000) (0.608) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000)

closed 1.506*** 0.659* 1.481**

(0.000) (0.052) (0.023)

exclusive -0.227*** 0.001

(0.006) (0.995)

short_term 1.229***

(0.000)

closed x after -1.897*** -1.551*** -1.573*** -1.612*** -0.791** -0.806** -2.817*** -1.443** -1.459**

(0.000) (0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.045) (0.041) (0.000) (0.027) (0.026)

exclusive x after -0.458*** 0.199** 0.218** -0.991*** 0.236** 0.263**

(0.000) (0.035) (0.021) (0.000) (0.047) (0.028)

short_term x after -1.390*** 0.063 0.030

(0.000) (0.670) (0.837)

closed x exclusive 3.706*** -0.163

(0.002) (0.804)

closed x short_term -1.853***

(0.009)

exclusive x short_term -0.634***

(0.000)

after x closed x exclusive -1.289 -3.838*** -3.839*** 5.933* 2.904 3.123

(0.367) (0.008) (0.008) (0.053) (0.397) (0.372)

after x closed x short_term 2.762*** 1.318* 1.327*

(0.000) (0.080) (0.077)

after x exclusive x short_term 1.340*** -0.088 -0.100

(0.000) (0.661) (0.620)

closed x exclusive x short_term 4.941***

(0.001)

after x closed x exclusive x short_term -9.291*** -8.091** -8.322**

(0.008) (0.039) (0.036)

Constant 4.285*** 4.931*** 4.286*** 4.415*** 4.978*** 4.228*** 3.915*** 4.989*** 4.224***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Firm-fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES

Quarter-fixed effects YES YES YES

Number of observations 62,808 62,808 62,808 62,808 62,808 62,808 62,808 62,808 62,808

Adjusted R-squared 0.002 0.891 0.896 0.022 0.892 0.897 0.031 0.893 0.898

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: borrowing_costs

Page 59: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

59

Appendix 2.1.

FIGURE 8

Borrowing Costs of Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. All Other Firms. Considering Leasing

Contracts and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Figure 8 complements the results of Table 12, regression specification (1a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

two groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” and customers of all other banks, evolve over time. A firm is considered a

customer of a bank if it had any debt with that bank within one year prior to 2013 February 12 (failure of “Distressed bank”).

This shock is marked by the vertical line. Borrowing costs for each firm equal an average interest rate weighted by loan

outstanding amounts at each quarter. Only leasing contracts are considered. After the shock, contracts issued before the shock

are not considered. The chart considers only those firms that reappeared in the credit register (survived) after the shock and

never delayed any repayment within the whole sample period. In addition, the chart considers only those customers of

“Distressed bank” that were assigned to the “good bank” and did not switch to the acquiring bank.

Page 60: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

60

Appendix 2.2.

TABLE 12

Difference-in-difference Analysis: Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. All Other Firms. Leasing

Contracts and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Table 12 reports coefficient estimates from difference-in-difference panel regressions without fixed effects (specifications 1a,

2a and 3a) with firm-fixed effects (specifications 1b, 2b and 3b) and with firm-fixed effects and quarter(time)-fixed effects

(specifications 1c, 2c and 3c). The data used in the analysis is at the quarter-firm level. The dependent variable

“borrowing_costs” is a firm’s average interest rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts at each quarter. In quarters 2011q4 -

2012q4, we consider only leasing contracts issued up to 2012 December 31. In quarters 2013q1 - 2018q1, we consider only

leasing contracts issued from 2013 February 12 (the day of “Distressed bank’s” closure). The explanatory variables are four

dummies: “after” - equal to 1 if an observation is from quarters 2013q1 - 2018q1, and 0 otherwise; “closed” – equal to 1 if a

firm belongs to the treatment group, i.e. had any debt outstanding with the closed “Distressed bank” within one year prior to

2013 February 12, and 0 otherwise; “exclusive” – equal to 1 if a firm had debts only with one bank within the same prior year,

and 0 otherwise; “short_term” equal to 1 if a firm’s average relationship length with its banks in 2013 q1 was shorter than 6

years, and 0 otherwise. Other explanatory variables are interactions between these four variables. Robust standard errors are

clustered multiway at the firm and quarter levels. P-values are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at

the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed, respectively.

(1a) (1b) (1c) (2a) (2b) (2c) (3a) (3b) (3c)

after -1.301*** -1.465*** -1.057*** -1.328*** -0.822*** -1.220***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

closed 0.385** 0.450*** 0.581***

(0.011) (0.002) (0.004)

exclusive 0.303*** 0.210***

(0.000) (0.000)

short_term 0.578***

(0.000)

closed x after -0.633*** -0.577*** -0.578*** -0.841*** -0.637*** -0.636*** -1.171*** -0.768*** -0.764***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

exclusive x after -0.450*** -0.215*** -0.195*** -0.537*** -0.168*** -0.120**

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.007) (0.037)

short_term x after -0.645*** -0.277*** -0.279***

(0.000) (0.001) (0.001)

closed x exclusive 2.654*** -1.966***

(0.001) (0.000)

closed x short_term -0.367

(0.185)

exclusive x short_term -0.006

(0.937)

after x closed x exclusive -2.161*** -1.857** -1.595* 2.858*** 1.766*** 2.150***

(0.003) (0.038) (0.078) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

after x closed x short_term 0.828*** 0.327 0.321

(0.005) (0.246) (0.260)

after x exclusive x short_term 0.375*** -0.002 -0.051

(0.000) (0.986) (0.570)

closed x exclusive x short_term 5.110***

(0.000)

after x closed x exclusive x short_term -5.912*** -4.272*** -4.387***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Constant 4.392*** 4.544*** 3.240*** 4.197*** 4.494*** 3.305*** 3.970*** 4.449*** 3.357***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Firm-fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES

Quarter-fixed effects YES YES YES

Number of observations 175,327 175,327 175,327 175,327 175,327 175,327 175,327 175,327 175,327

Adjusted R-squared 0.092 0.805 0.831 0.096 0.806 0.832 0.105 0.807 0.833

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: borrowing_costs

Page 61: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

61

Appendix 3.1.

FIGURE 9

Borrowing Costs of Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. a Similar Bank. Considering Three Loan

Types and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Figure 9 complements the results of Table 13, regression specification (1a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

two groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” and customers of a similar bank, evolve over time. A firm is considered a

customer of a bank if it had any debt with that bank within one year prior to 2013 February 12 (failure of “Distressed bank”).

This shock is marked by the vertical line. Borrowing costs for each firm equal an average interest rate weighted by loan

outstanding amounts at each quarter. Leasing, term loans and credit lines are considered. After the shock, contracts issued before

the shock are not considered. The chart considers only those firms that reappeared in the credit register (survived) after the shock

and never delayed any repayment within the whole sample period. In addition, the chart considers only those customers of

“Distressed bank” that were assigned to the “good bank” and did not switch to the acquiring bank.

Page 62: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

62

Appendix 3.2.

TABLE 13

Difference-in-difference Analysis: Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. a Similar Bank. Three Loan

Types and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions Table 13 reports coefficient estimates from difference-in-difference panel regressions without fixed effects (specifications 1a,

2a and 3a) with firm-fixed effects (specifications 1b, 2b and 3b) and with firm-fixed effects and quarter(time)-fixed effects

(specifications 1c, 2c and 3c). The data used in the analysis is at the quarter-firm level. The dependent variable

“borrowing_costs” is a firm’s average interest rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts at each quarter. In quarters 2011q4 -

2012q4, we consider only leasing contracts, term loans and credit lines issued up to 2012 December 31. In quarters 2013q1 -

2018q1, we consider only leasing contracts, term loans and credit lines issued from 2013 February 12 (the day of “Distressed

bank’s” closure). The explanatory variables are four dummies: “after” - equal to 1 if an observation is from quarters 2013q1 -

2018q1, and 0 otherwise; “closed” – equal to 1 if a firm belongs to the treatment group, i.e. had any debt outstanding with the

closed “Distressed bank” within one year prior to 2013 February 12, and 0 otherwise; “exclusive” – equal to 1 if a firm had

debts only with one bank within the same prior year, and 0 otherwise; “short_term” equal to 1 if a firm’s average relationship

length with its banks in 2013 q1 was shorter than 6 years, and 0 otherwise. Other explanatory variables are interactions between

these four variables. Robust standard errors are clustered multiway at the firm and quarter levels. P-values are reported in

parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed, respectively.

(1a) (1b) (1c) (2a) (2b) (2c) (3a) (3b) (3c)

after -0.821*** -0.842*** -1.027*** -1.027*** -1.008*** -1.037***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

closed 0.595*** 0.067 -0.050

(0.009) (0.614) (0.778)

exclusive 0.540*** 0.275

(0.001) (0.139)

short_term 0.490***

(0.000)

closed x after -1.588*** -1.500*** -1.495*** -0.715*** -0.661*** -0.648*** -0.629*** -0.646*** -0.637***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

exclusive x after 0.430** 0.377* 0.437** 0.983*** 0.901*** 0.951***

(0.023) (0.057) (0.028) (0.001) (0.004) (0.003)

short_term x after -0.044 0.022 0.038

(0.796) (0.901) (0.826)

closed x exclusive 2.936*** 1.817

(0.000) (0.134)

closed x short_term 0.123

(0.635)

exclusive x short_term 0.196

(0.329)

after x closed x exclusive -3.419*** -3.511*** -3.471*** -2.418** -1.310 -1.314

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.035) (0.106) (0.107)

after x closed x short_term -0.123 -0.033 -0.029

(0.651) (0.909) (0.918)

after x exclusive x short_term -0.783** -0.756** -0.749**

(0.015) (0.031) (0.031)

closed x exclusive x short_term 1.489

(0.285)

after x closed x exclusive x short_term -1.283 -2.958** -2.898**

(0.334) (0.016) (0.018)

Constant 5.010*** 5.141*** 4.499*** 4.739*** 5.174*** 4.367*** 4.531*** 5.180*** 4.361***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Firm-fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES

Quarter-fixed effects YES YES YES

Number of observations 16,970 16,970 16,970 16,970 16,970 16,970 16,970 16,970 16,970

Adjusted R-squared 0.108 0.613 0.636 0.181 0.631 0.654 0.195 0.639 0.661

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: borrowing_costs

Page 63: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

63

Appendix 4.1.

FIGURE 10

Borrowing Costs of Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. All Other Firms. Considering Three Loan

Types and the Only Firm-Quality Restriction – Shock Survivors Figure 10 complements the results of Table 14, regression specification (1a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

two groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” and customers of all other banks, evolve over time. A firm is considered a

customer of a bank if it had any debt with that bank within one year prior to 2013 February 12 (failure of “Distressed bank”).

This shock is marked by the vertical line. Borrowing costs for each firm equal an average interest rate weighted by loan

outstanding amounts at each quarter. Leasing, term loans and credit lines are considered. After the shock, contracts issued before

the shock are not considered. The chart considers only those firms that reappeared in the credit register (survived) after the

shock. It includes all firms independently on whether they delayed any repayment within our sample period or not. Also, it

includes all customers of “Distressed bank” independent of whether they were assigned to the “good bank” or “bad bank” and

whether they switched to the acquiring bank or not.

Page 64: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

64

Appendix 4.2.

TABLE 14

Difference-in-difference Analysis Default Setting: Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. All Other Firms.

Three Loan Types and the Only Firm-Quality Restriction – Shock Survivors Table 14 reports coefficient estimates from difference-in-difference panel regressions without fixed effects (specifications 1a,

2a and 3a) with firm-fixed effects (specifications 1b, 2b and 3b) and with firm-fixed effects and quarter(time)-fixed effects

(specifications 1c, 2c and 3c). The data used in the analysis is at the quarter-firm level. The dependent variable

“borrowing_costs” is a firm’s average interest rate weighted by loan outstanding amounts at each quarter. In quarters 2011q4 -

2012q4, we consider only leasing contracts, term loans and credit lines issued up to 2012 December 31. In quarters 2013q1 -

2018q1, we consider only leasing contracts, term loans and credit lines issued from 2013 February 12 (the day of “Distressed

bank’s” closure). The explanatory variables are four dummies: “after” - equal to 1 if an observation is from quarters 2013q1 -

2018q1, and 0 otherwise; “closed” – equal to 1 if a firm belongs to the treatment group, i.e. had any debt outstanding with the

closed “Distressed bank” within one year prior to 2013 February 12, and 0 otherwise; “exclusive” – equal to 1 if a firm had

debts only with one bank within the same prior year, and 0 otherwise; “short_term” equal to 1 if a firm’s average relationship

length with its banks in 2013 q1 was shorter than 6 years, and 0 otherwise. Other explanatory variables are interactions between

these four variables. Robust standard errors are clustered multiway at the firm and quarter levels. P-values are reported in

parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed, respectively.

(1a) (1b) (1c) (2a) (2b) (2c) (3a) (3b) (3c)

after -0.918*** -1.162*** -0.757*** -1.099*** -0.359** -0.986***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.030) (0.000)

closed 1.289*** 0.994*** 1.047***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

exclusive 0.078** 0.218***

(0.050) (0.000)

short_term 0.947***

(0.000)

closed x after -0.707*** -0.401*** -0.421*** -0.747*** -0.299** -0.302*** -0.967*** -0.252** -0.251**

(0.000) (0.003) (0.001) (0.000) (0.010) (0.009) (0.000) (0.049) (0.046)

exclusive x after -0.425*** -0.099** -0.068* -0.737*** -0.101** -0.057

(0.000) (0.015) (0.075) (0.000) (0.034) (0.210)

short_term x after -0.914*** -0.267*** -0.281***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

closed x exclusive 1.104*** 0.874**

(0.000) (0.017)

closed x short_term -0.297*

(0.079)

exclusive x short_term -0.456***

(0.000)

after x closed x exclusive -0.045 -0.493* -0.516* 0.525 0.076 0.020

(0.867) (0.084) (0.068) (0.130) (0.816) (0.950)

after x closed x short_term 0.590*** -0.034 -0.038

(0.001) (0.847) (0.830)

after x exclusive x short_term 0.734*** 0.061 0.039

(0.000) (0.439) (0.612)

closed x exclusive x short_term 0.477

(0.317)

after x closed x exclusive x short_term -1.076** -0.877* -0.822

(0.041) (0.095) (0.113)

Constant 4.490*** 4.744*** 3.739*** 4.440*** 4.718*** 3.759*** 4.038*** 4.675*** 3.816***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Firm-fixed effects YES YES YES YES YES YES

Quarter-fixed effects YES YES YES

Number of observations 271,938 271,938 271,938 271,938 271,938 271,938 271,938 271,938 271,938

Adjusted R-squared 0.042 0.791 0.805 0.050 0.791 0.805 0.057 0.792 0.806

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: borrowing_costs

Page 65: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

65

Appendix 5.1.

FIGURE 11

Borrowing Costs: Default Setting but No First Switching Loans (Robustness Test) Figure 11 complements the results of Table 15, regression specification (1a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

two groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” and customers of all other banks, evolve over time. The definitions and

data used are the same as in the default setting (e.g. see Figure 2.1.), with one modification: we disregard first forced switching

loans of “Distressed bank’s” customers after the shock – i.e. loans taken when these firms had no inside bank, and consider only

subsequent loans taken after these customers already started new relationships.

Appendix 5.2.

TABLE 15

Difference-in-difference Analysis: Default Setting but No First Switching Loans (Robustness Test) Table 15 reports coefficient estimates from difference-in-difference panel regressions without fixed effects (1a) with firm-fixed

effects (1b) and with firm-fixed effects and quarter(time)-fixed effects (1c). The variables and data used are the same as in the

default setting (see Table 2), with one modification: we disregard first forced switching loans of “Distressed bank’s” customers

after the shock – i.e. loans taken when these firms had no inside bank, and consider only subsequent loans taken after these

customers already started new relationships. Robust standard errors are clustered multiway at the firm and quarter levels. P-

values are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed, respectively.

(1a) (1b) (1c)

after -0.989*** -1.234***

(0.000) (0.000)

closed 0.879***

(0.000)

closed x after -1.129*** -0.714*** -0.703***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Constant 4.431*** 4.652*** 3.577***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Firm-fixed effects YES YES

Quarter-fixed effects YES

Number of observations 232,283 232,283 232,283

Adjusted R-squared 0.041 0.794 0.810

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: borrowing_costs

Page 66: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

66

Appendix 6.1.

FIGURE 12

Borrowing Costs: Default Setting but Only Loans Before KPMG’s Conclusions (Robustness Test) Figure 12 complements the results of Table 16, regression specification (1a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

two groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” and customers of all other banks, evolve over time. The definitions and

data used are the same as in the default setting (e.g. see Figure 2.1.), with one modification: we consider only those post-shock

loans (leasing, term loans and credit lines) which were issued within the three weeks after the bank’s closure (i.e. before KPMG’s

conclusions).

Appendix 6.2.

TABLE 16

Difference-in-difference Analysis: Default Setting but Only Loans Before KPMG’s Conclusions

(Robustness Test) Table 16 reports coefficient estimates from difference-in-difference panel regressions without fixed effects (1a) with firm-fixed

effects (1b) and with firm-fixed effects and quarter(time)-fixed effects (1c). The variables and data used are the same as in the

default setting (see Table 2), with one modification: we consider only those post-shock loans (leasing, term loans and credit

lines) which were issued within the three weeks after the bank’s closure (i.e. before KPMG’s conclusions). Robust standard

errors are clustered multiway at the firm and quarter levels. P-values are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate

significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed, respectively.

(1a) (1b) (1c)

after -0.692*** -0.875***

(0.000) (0.000)

closed 0.922***

(0.001)

closed x after -1.348*** -1.034*** -1.024***

(0.001) (0.009) (0.008)

Constant 4.221*** 4.387*** 3.678***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Firm-fixed effects YES YES

Quarter-fixed effects YES

Number of observations 7,615 7,615 7,615

Adjusted R-squared 0.033 0.849 0.864

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: borrowing_costs

Page 67: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

67

Appendix 7.1.

FIGURE 13

Borrowing Costs: Default Setting but +-2 years around the shock (Robustness Test) Figure 13 complements the results of Table 17, regression specification (1a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

two groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” and customers of all other banks, evolve over time. The definitions and

data used are the same as in the default setting (e.g. see Figure 2.1.), with one modification: we consider only those debt contracts

which were issued within two years before and two years after the “Distressed bank’s” closure.

Appendix 7.2.

TABLE 17

Difference-in-difference Analysis: Default Setting but +-2 years around the shock (Robustness Test) Table 17 reports coefficient estimates from difference-in-difference panel regressions without fixed effects (1a) with firm-fixed

effects (1b) and with firm-fixed effects and quarter(time)-fixed effects (1c). The variables and data used are the same as in the

default setting (see Table 2), with one modification: we consider only those debt contracts which were issued within two years

before and two years after the “Distressed bank’s” closure. Robust standard errors are clustered multiway at the firm and quarter

levels. P-values are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed,

respectively.

(1a) (1b) (1c)

after -0.630*** -0.855***

(0.001) (0.000)

closed 0.558**

(0.028)

closed x after -0.866*** -0.686*** -0.658**

(0.002) (0.008) (0.010)

Constant 4.471*** 4.650*** 4.011***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Firm-fixed effects YES YES

Quarter-fixed effects YES

Number of observations 52,016 52,016 52,016

Adjusted R-squared 0.032 0.839 0.852

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: borrowing_costs

Page 68: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

68

Appendix 8.1.

FIGURE 14

Borrowing Costs: Default Setting but Only Newly Issued Loans (Robustness Test) Figure 14 complements the results of Table 18, regression specification (1a). The figure shows how average borrowing costs of

two groups of firms: customers of “Distressed bank” and customers of all other banks, evolve over time. The definitions and

data used are the same as in the default setting (e.g. see Figure 2.1.), with one modification: we consider only newly issued loans

in each quarter.

Appendix 8.2.

TABLE 18

Difference-in-difference Analysis: Default Setting but Only Newly Issued Loans (Robustness Test) Table 18 reports coefficient estimates from difference-in-difference panel regressions without fixed effects (1a) with firm-fixed

effects (1b) and with firm-fixed effects and quarter(time)-fixed effects (1c). The variables and data used are the same as in the

default setting (see Table 2), with one modification: we consider only newly issued loans in each quarter. Robust standard errors

are clustered multiway at the firm and quarter levels. P-values are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance

at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed, respectively.

(1a) (1b) (1c)

after -1.056*** -1.193***

(0.000) (0.000)

closed 0.558

(0.147)

closed x after -0.864** -0.532* -0.505*

(0.026) (0.070) (0.070)

Constant 4.359*** 4.483*** 3.456***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Firm-fixed effects YES YES

Quarter-fixed effects YES

Number of observations 38,809 38,809 38,809

Adjusted R-squared 0.045 0.542 0.579

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: borrowing_costs

Page 69: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

69

Appendix 8.3.

FIGURE 15

Average interest rates on loans (term loans, leasing contracts and credit lines) issued in 2011Q4 Figure 15 shows the quarterly development of average interest rates on loans (term loans, leasing contracts and credit lines)

issued in 2011 Q4 by two groups of banks: (1) “Distressed bank”, and (2) all other banks. Only loans maturing in 2013 Q1 or

later are considered.

Page 70: Loss of a lending relationship: shock or relief? · 2019. 7. 10. · 4: Banks that are known for exploiting their customers might struggle to attract new borrowers. 8: GDP grew by

70

Appendix 9.1.

TABLE 19

Difference-in-difference Analysis: Customers of “Distressed bank” vs. All Other Firms. Three Loan

Types and Four Firm-Quality Restrictions. Firm Age Instead of Relationship Length Table 19 reports coefficient estimates from difference-in-difference panel regressions without fixed effects (specification 3a)

with firm-fixed effects (specification 3b) and with firm-fixed effects and quarter(time)-fixed effects (specification 3c). The data

used in the analysis is at the quarter-firm level. The dependent variable “borrowing_costs” is a firm’s average interest rate

weighted by loan outstanding amounts at each quarter. In quarters 2011q4 - 2012q4, we consider only leasing contracts, term

loans and credit lines issued up to 2012 December 31. In quarters 2013q1 - 2018q1, we consider only leasing contracts, term

loans and credit lines issued from 2013 February 12 (the day of “Distressed bank’s” closure). The explanatory variables are four

dummies: “after” - equal to 1 if an observation is from quarters 2013q1 - 2018q1, and 0 otherwise; “closed” – equal to 1 if a

firm belongs to the treatment group, i.e. had any debt outstanding with the closed “Distressed bank” within one year prior to

2013 February 12, and 0 otherwise; “exclusive” – equal to 1 if a firm had debts only with one bank within the same prior year,

and 0 otherwise; “short_term” equal to 1 if a firm’s first appearance in the credit register was less than six years ago counting

from the quarter in which “Distressed bank” was closed – 2013 q1, and 0 otherwise. Other explanatory variables are interactions

between these four variables. Robust standard errors are clustered multiway at the firm and quarter levels. P-values are reported

in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed, respectively.

(3a) (3b) (3c)

after -1.037*** -1.095***

(0.000) (0.000)

closed 0.456***

(0.002)

exclusive 0.198***

(0.000)

short_term 0.939***

(0.000)

closed x after -0.516*** -0.435*** -0.435***

(0.000) (0.003) (0.003)

exclusive x after -0.142*** -0.087* -0.051

(0.003) (0.063) (0.257)

short_term x after -0.245*** -0.289*** -0.302***

(0.008) (0.001) (0.000)

closed x exclusive 1.844**

(0.043)

closed x short_term -0.080

(0.757)

exclusive x short_term -0.425***

(0.000)

after x closed x exclusive -1.590* -1.142** -1.056*

(0.058) (0.049) (0.064)

after x closed x short_term -0.274 -0.165 -0.136

(0.294) (0.518) (0.589)

after x exclusive x short_term 0.091 0.119 0.111

(0.309) (0.177) (0.204)

closed x exclusive x short_term 2.358*

(0.050)

after x closed x exclusive x short_term -1.871 -2.945** -2.967**

(0.116) (0.014) (0.013)

Constant 4.044*** 4.718*** 3.762***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Firm-fixed effects YES YES

Quarter-fixed effects YES

Number of observations 232,819 232,819 232,819

Adjusted R-squared 0.078 0.794 0.810

P-values in parentheses. Standard errors are clustered multiway within firms and quarters

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Dependent variable: borrowing_costs