lee and thampapillai_2016_external debt in macroeconomics_a review

30
469C Bukit Timah Road Oei Tiong Ham Building Singapore 259772 Tel: (65) 6516 6134 Fax: (65) 6778 1020 Website: www.lkyspp.nus.edu.sg Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy Working Paper Series External Debt in Macroeconomics: A Review Kelvin Lee School of Politics and International Relations Australian National University Email: [email protected] Dodo J Thampapillai Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy National University of Singapore Email: [email protected] February 25, 2016 Working Paper No.: LKYSPP 16-05

Upload: kelvin-lee

Post on 12-Apr-2017

134 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

469C Bukit Timah Road

Oei Tiong Ham Building

Singapore 259772

Tel: (65) 6516 6134 Fax: (65) 6778 1020

Website: www.lkyspp.nus.edu.sg

Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy

Working Paper Series

External Debt in Macroeconomics: A Review

Kelvin Lee

School of Politics and International Relations

Australian National University

Email: [email protected]

Dodo J Thampapillai

Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy

National University of Singapore

Email: [email protected]

February 25, 2016

Working Paper No.: LKYSPP 16-05

Page 2: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

2

Abstract: The paper provides a concise review of the treatment of external debt in

macroeconomic analyses. In this regard, the paper considers: the development of

indicators to quantify external debt alongside theoretical and empirical developments

in which the indicators are utilized. Following the inherent limitations, the theoretical

and empirical studies tend to employ more than one indicator. Both theoretical and

empirical frameworks are distinguished in terms of whether they are static or dynamic

in nature. The theoretical studies were also distinguished in terms of the utilization of

discrete and continuous frameworks. The empirical models were distinguished with

reference to linearity and nonlinearity of the underlying premises. The review enables

the reader to appreciate the relative advantages and disadvantages of the various

frameworks and their contextual relevance. A key theme that runs through the studies

reviewed is the impact of external debt on economic performance. The results, which

are context specific, are mixed.

Keywords: External Debt, Debt-to-GDP Ratio, Debt Service, Difference and

Differential Equations; Static and Dynamic Models

Biographical notes: Kelvin Lee is a PhD candidate at the School of Politics and

International Relations, Australian National University. He graduated with a Master in

Public Policy in 2012 from the Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy, National

University of Singapore. Prior to commencing his PhD research, he worked as

researcher at the Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy and the Policy Unit of the

Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) office at Singapore.

Dodo J Thampapillai is a professor at the Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy

where he teaches economics. His areas of research interest are macroeconomics and

environmental economics. He has a teaching experience in excess of 30 years

Page 3: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

3

1. INTRODUCTION

This paper reviews the ways external debt has been incorporated into national income

determination to demonstrate the impact of external indebtedness on growth. At

present, it is not apparent in academic practice that external debt has been a common

explicit feature in national income accounting. Recent literature tends to equate

external debt to current account deficit. For instance, Villanueva and Mariano (2007)

identify net external debt as “external current account deficit (CAD)”, or savings by

non-residents; CAD is derived from the deduction of gross disposable national

income from the sum of domestic aggregate consumption and gross domestic

investment1. Others like Hallwood and MacDonald (2000) and Hess and Ross (1997)

compute external debt based on the identity equation that demonstrates that the sum

of net domestic savings and net government (tax) revenue equates to the subtraction

of net interest paid abroad from net exports2. Nevertheless, several studies including

those by Musa (2004) have attempted to link current account deficits and growth in

nominal national income3, with such histories going back to Park (1986)4.

Contemporaneously, the euro zone debt crisis witnessed a proliferation of

investigations on external debt-GDP linkages among sovereign and private debt, such

as Stein (2012) who interpreted national external debt through the lens of current

account deficit-to-GDP ratio to explain the financial upheaval in Greece5. In short,

external debt appears to feature as addendum to national income accounting through

myriad methods as sampled above.

1 Delano P. Villanueva and Roberto S. Mariano, “External Debt, Adjustment, and Growth”, in Fiscal

Policy and Management in East Asia, eds. Takatoshi Ito and Andrew K. Rose (United States of

America: The University of Chicago Press, 2007), pp. 203-204. 2 That is, (X – M) – (R – F) = (S – I) + (T – G), where (X – M) stands for net exports, (R – F) as net

interest paid abroad, (S – I) as net domestic savings and (T - G) as net government (tax) revenue. See

C. Paul Hallwood and Ronald MacDonald, International Money and Finance, 3rd edition (United

Kingdom: Blackwell Publishing, 2000), p. 459; Peter Hess and Clark Ross, Economic Development:

Theories, Evidence, and Policies (United States of America: The Dryden Press, Harcourt Brace &

Company, 1997), p. 477. 3 Michael Musa, “Exchange Rate Adjustments Needed to Reduce Global Payments Imbalances”, in

Dollar Adjustment: How Far? Against What?, eds. C. Fred Bergsten and John Williamson,

(Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 2004), pp. 113-138, in Barry Eichengreen,

Global Imbalances and the Lessons of Bretton Woods (United States of America: The MIT Press,

2007), p. 140. 4 Yung Chul Park, “Foreign Debt, Balance of Payments, and Growth Prospects: The Case of the

Republic of Korea, 1965-88”, World Development, Vol. 14, No. 8 (1986), p. 1048. 5 J.L. Stein, Stochastic Optimal Control and the U.S. Financial Debt Crisis (New York: Springer

Science+Business Media New York, 2012), pp. 137-138, 140, 141, 145.

Page 4: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

4

In this paper, we examine how external debt is dealt with in the economics literature.

Despite overlaps, there appears to be three distinct categories:

(i) Development of indicators to quantify the extent of indebtedness;

(ii) Theoretical analyses where external debt is an explicit variable; and

(iii) Empirical analyses where external debt is an explicit variable.

Notwithstanding the differences among the contexts above which will be elaborated

on later, this paper assumes a common understanding of external debt as a concept.

That is, external debt is defined as the “long-term and short-term debt that is owed by

a country to non-residents”, according to Daud and Podivinsky (2011)6. However, that

studies can differ in their foci of particular aspects of external debt necessitates a

decomposition of external debt as detailed by Clark (2002) below7:

1. Long term external debt: “debt that has an original or extended maturity of

more than one year and that is owed to non-residents and repayable in foreign

currency, goods, or services”; which can be further sub-divided into:

a. Public debt: “an external obligation of a public debtor, including the national

government, a political subdivision or agency of either, and autonomous

public bodies”;

b. Publicly guaranteed debt: “an external obligation of a private debtor that is

guaranteed for repayment by a public entity”, and;

c. Private non-guaranteed external debt: “an external obligation of a private

debtor that is not guaranteed by a public entity”.

2. Short term external debt: “debt that has a maturity of one year or less and

includes no distinctions between public and private non-guaranteed short-term

debt”, and;

3. Use of International Monetary Fund (IMF) credit: “repurchase obligations to

the IMF with respect to all uses of IMF resources, excluding those resulting

from drawings in the reserve or first credit tranche.”

The paper is structured as follows. Each of the next three sections considers each

category of debt treatment. This then leads to a concluding review of main lessons.

6 Siti Nurazira Mohd Daud and Jan M. Podivinsky, “Debt-Growth Nexus: A Spatial Econometrics

Approach for Developing Countries”, Transition Studies Review, Vol. 18, No. 1 (September 2011), pp.

1-2. 7 Ephraim Clark, International Finance, 2nd edition (United Kingdom: Thomson, 2002), pp. 261-262.

Page 5: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

5

2. INDICATORS OF FOREIGN DEBT

A straightforward application of external debt on growth assumes the form of

expressing the principal external debt quantum and/or debt servicing (i.e. interest on

external debt) as a ratio to or proportion of gross domestic product (GDP) or gross

national product (GNP). This singular expression measures the severity of foreign

indebtedness on economic development. Nallari and Griffith (2011) explain that this

proportion serves to indicate the ability of a country to service its debt8. This

perspective finds support in Tilak (1990), Tahir (1998), and Reinhart and Rogoff

(2010). Tilak (1990) compares the total public external debt situation of 1970 against

that of 1984 among Sub-Saharan African countries through two indicators: total debt

as a percentage of GNP and debt service as a percentage of GNP. He diagnosed the

external public debt situation as “critical” through the imposition of a severe drag on

the development of African countries between 1970 and 1984 resulting in more

sovereign borrowing9. In an apparent refinement, Tahir (1998) in his clarification of

Pakistan’s external debt in the 1990s introduced the concept of present value of debt

service to GNP and that to foreign exchange earnings; he considers a country as

“severely indebted” if debt/GNP ratio exceeded 80%10, following the World Bank’s

threshold of more than 60% for debt/GNP ratio to be considered moderately

indebted11. Nallari and Griffith (2011) note that such discounted present values factor

in additionally the future value of money, and thus a sovereign’s servicing capacity12.

Perhaps, however, such indicators commanded greatest attention recently through

Reinhart and Rogoff’s (2010) study of the impact of total gross external debt (public

8 Raj Nallari and Breda Griffith, Understanding Growth and Poverty: Theory, Policy and Empirics

(Washington, D.C.: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank,

2011), p. 170. 9 Jandhyala B. G. Tilak, “External Debt and Public Investment in Education in Sub-Saharan Africa”,

Journal of Education Finance, Vol. 15, No. 4, The Oxford Round Table (Spring 1990), pp. 470-471. 10 Pervez Tahir and Eatzaz Ahmad, “The Debt of the Nation [with Comments]”, The Pakistan

Development Review, Vol. 37, No. 4, Papers and Proceedings PART II Fourteenth Annual General

Meeting and Conference of the Pakistan Society of Development Economists Islamabad, January 28-

31, 1999 (Winter 1998), p. 339. 11 The World Bank, World Debt Tables 1992-1993 (Washington D.C.: The International Bank for

Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank, 1993) in Pervez Tahir and Eatzaz Ahmad, “The

Debt of the Nation [with Comments]”, The Pakistan Development Review, Vol. 37, No. 4, Papers and

Proceedings PART II Fourteenth Annual General Meeting and Conference of the Pakistan Society of

Development Economists Islamabad, January 28-31, 1999 (Winter 1998), p. 339. 12 Raj Nallari and Breda Griffith, Understanding Growth and Poverty: Theory, Policy and Empirics

(Washington, D.C.: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank,

2011), p. 170.

Page 6: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

6

and private) on economic growth of developed and developing economies. Average

growth of emerging markets “deteriorates markedly” when external debt is 60% of

GDP, and “further still” at 90% based on 1946-2009 data 13.

Opinions vary on the choice of appropriate indicator. Subtle differences among the

indicators themselves are evident in the snapshot above. Debate appears to centre on

the accurate depiction of the burden external debt imposes on an economy. In his

study of India’s external debt 1992 through 2002, Gupta (1994) argues that the debt

service ratio should be “of real concern” than the external debt-to-GNP ratio as the

former measures a country’s “repayment abilities”14. On the other hand, Mahmood,

Rauf and Ahmad (2009) aver the ‘importance’ of expressing external debt—along

with debt servicing—with relation to foreign exchange earnings and also that to

exports of goods and services. While they acknowledge the external debt-to-GDP

ratio as a fixture in their assessment of Pakistan’s public and external debt

sustainability for the 1970s-2000s duration, they argued that the ratio of external

debt/debt servicing to foreign exchange earnings and that to exports of goods and

services “mirror” a country’s capacity to manage its external imbalances and its

reforms on external debt which impact on foreign exchange earnings and exports15.

Avramovic (1964) justifies the longevity of the external debt-to-current account ratio

due to four reasons: simplicity of comprehension, ease of computation requiring only

data on external debt and current account earnings, absence of alternative indicators

that apply to short term or long term view, and its flexibility as a short and long term

measurement heuristic when computed against proportion of scarce foreign exchange

earnings like capital inflows16; these may very well apply to the external debt-national

income ratio.

13 Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff, “Growth in a Time of Debt”, The American Economic

Review, Vol. 100, No. 2, PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS OF THE One Hundred Twenty Second

Annual Meeting OF THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION (May 2010), pp. 574, 576-577. 14 S. P. Gupta, “Debt Crisis and Economic Reforms”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 29, No. 23

(Jun. 4, 1994), p. 1411. 15 Tahir Mahmood, Shahnaz A. Rauf and Hafiz Khalil Ahmad, “Public and External Debt

Sustainability in Pakistan”, Pakistan Economic and Social Review, Vol. 47, No. 2 (Winter 2009), pp.

246, 256. 16 Dragoslav Avramovic, “Debt Service Ratio”, in Dragoslav Avramovic et. al., Economic Growth and

External Debt (Baltimore, Maryland: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1964), pp. 38, 42.

Page 7: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

7

That the external debt-as-indicator approach finds much support as in the studies

above does not detract from its shortcomings. A central tussle concerns whether such

indicators illustrate national debt burden. In his critique on applying external debt as a

percentage of GDP, Pilbeam (1998) faulted it for “saying nothing on the annual

burden imposed on the country, the amount of repayments falling due, or which

section of the community the burden will fall upon”17; this ventures beyond the

preceding debate over which indicators ought to be selected. Another similar point of

contention involves the alternate measures mentioned previously. Pilbeam (1998)

criticized the external debt as a percentage of goods and services indicator on grounds

of yearly varying exports, and this indicator’s underlying assumption that increasing

export revenue is the sole debt servicing avenue18. A similar indicator, the total debt

service as a percentage of exports of goods and services, also suffers from problems

such as fluctuations in export earnings and the point estimation of debt burden of a

single point, i.e. year, in time19; these as well as biased measurements for long run

analysis caused by exceptional circumstances like bumpers of maturities.20 Doubts

over “critical” ratio thresholds that signify unsustainable debt levels and stock-versus-

flow conceptual confusion over external debt are further problems with external debt-

current account measure,21 but their application extends to external debt-national

income indicator when external debt as a stock concept does not reconcile with

national income which is a flow concept. Point data illustrations are an added concern.

As Ahmad (1998) observes in commenting on Tahir (1998) aforementioned, the static

depictions of the phenomenon presented by indicator data are useful as snapshots, but

are unable on their own to present a more dynamic analysis that formal modelling

would have provided22.

Nevertheless, the indicators continue to be featured hitherto, in spite of serious pitfalls

mentioned above. As can be observed below, several authors actually select more than

17 Keith Pilbeam, International Finance, 2nd edition (Great Britain: Macmillan Press Ltd, 1998), p. 405. 18 Keith Pilbeam, International Finance, 2nd edition (Great Britain: Macmillan Press Ltd, 1998), p. 405. 19 Keith Pilbeam, International Finance, 2nd edition (Great Britain: Macmillan Press Ltd, 1998), p. 405. 20 Dragoslav Avramovic, “Debt Service Ratio”, in Dragoslav Avramovic et. al., Economic Growth and

External Debt (Baltimore, Maryland: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1964), p. 42. 21 Dragoslav Avramovic, “Debt Service Ratio”, in Dragoslav Avramovic et. al., Economic Growth and

External Debt (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1964), pp. 39-41, 42. 22 Pervez Tahir and Eatzaz Ahmad, “The Debt of the Nation [with Comments]”, The Pakistan

Development Review, Vol. 37, No. 4, Papers and Proceedings PART II Fourteenth Annual General

Meeting and Conference of the Pakistan Society of Development Economists Islamabad, January 28-

31, 1999 (Winter 1998), p. 353.

Page 8: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

8

one indicator to compensate for the weaknesses of the external debt/debt service-to-

national income indicator. It appears that the variant of indicators pitting foreign

indebtedness against foreign exchange earnings/export revenue serve a more

particular purpose by testing an economy’s foreign cash flow resilience23; and hence

such indicators ought to be viewed as more specialized. Thus, it should not be

construed that some indicators could be superior to the rest, as their functions differ

and their respective weaknesses previously discussed cannot be made commensurate

when indicators are compared together.

3. THEORETICAL MODELLING

A more contextual study of foreign indebtedness in national income accounting is

obtained through theoretical modelling. External debt is assumed to be an endogenous

variable embedded within a series of mathematical models systematically expounded

in relation to other endogenous and exogenous variables and coefficients (i.e.

parameters) theorized. Such models allow the user to predict results through solving

for variables of interest, or to measure movements among variables by varying one or

more of the variables or coefficients pre-specified; numerical values need not be

inputed to these variables, unlike empirical models which rely on data24. As an

example, in his argument for the superiority of the domestic consumer price index

over export, import and world price indices as deflator of external debt, Dornbusch

(1982) integrated external debt into “conventional treatment of the income effects of

price change”. Through a series of formulae integrating pre-specified exogenous

variables, he then demonstrated their application to the case of Brazil’s external debt

from 1973 to 198025.

Generally, two types of theoretical models can be observed incorporating external

debt and national income: comparative statics models and dynamic models. The key

23 Dragoslav Avramovic, “Debt Service Ratio”, in Dragoslav Avramovic et. al., Economic Growth and

External Debt (Baltimore, Maryland: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1964), pp. 34-36. 24 Gary Evans, “Chapter 1: Economic Models”, Homepage for Prof. Gary R. Evans [cited 15 August

2003], available from: www2. hmc.edu/~evans/, p. 3. 25 Rudiger Dornbusch, “Consumption Opportunities and the Real Value of the External Debt”, Journal

of Development Economics, Vol. 10, No. 1 (February 1982), pp. 93, 94 and 99; Dornbusch’s equation

is given by c = (Y - i*ED – ED(ė – ṗ)) / P, where P = home consumer price index, Y = domestic

nominal value of output, D = external debt in dollars, E = exchange rate, cruzeiros/$, i* = world

nominal rate of interest, ė and ṗ = rates of depreciation and domestic inflation respectively.

Page 9: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

9

difference between comparative statics models and dynamic models centres on time

dependency: dynamic models employ time dependent variables while non-time

dependent variables are inputed into comparative statics models26. An example of the

comparative statics models is taken from Walther (1997) in his study of sustainable

debt. Where the external debt-to-gross national income ratio was a standalone

indicator in the earlier approach, it is now made the subject in an equation to

demonstrate the relationship between the rate of growth of the debt-to-income ratio

and other exogenous variables such as output, absorption, real interest rate on external

debt and the growth rate of real income27. Other applications of comparative statics

models include Dornbusch (1982) introduced earlier.

Dynamic models can be further classified into models employing difference equations

(i.e. mathematical systems of difference) and models relying on differential

equations28. Kohsaka (1991) is a classic example of difference equation models

whereby he defines GNP of current year as a function of GDP of current year and

external debt of previous year, among other variables, in his study of growth

achievement among middle income countries via external debt as capital inflows29. In

measuring the macroeconomic impact external debt exerts on the growth of Barbados,

Boamah (1988) is another example where differences in the quantum of GDP and

external debt for adjacent years go towards determining an investment function in

current year30. Difference equations can also be applied to the indicator approach,

such as in the assessment of Bangladesh’s public debt sustainability by Islam and

Biswas (2005) who modelled the change in the debt-to-GDP ratio at current year as a

function of the stock of debt-to-GDP ratio in the previous year31.

26 Gary Evans, “Chapter 1: Economic Models”, Homepage for Prof. Gary R. Evans [cited 15 August

2003], available from: www2. hmc.edu/~evans/, pp. 6-7. 27 Ted Walther, The World Economy (United States of America: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1997), pp.

375-378; Walther ‘s formula is given as ḋ = - (1 – a) + d(r – ẏ), where ḋ = rate of growth of the

external debt/income ratio, a = absorption/output ratio, d = external debt/income ratio, r = real interest

rate on external debt and ẏ = rate of growth of real income. 28 Gary Evans, “Chapter 1: Economic Models”, Homepage for Prof. Gary R. Evans [cited 15 August

2003], available from: www2. hmc.edu/~evans/, p. 7. 29 Akira Kohsaka, “Macroeconomic Management with External Debt – East Asian Experiences in the

1980s”, Asian Economic Journal, Vol. V, No. 3 (November 1991), pp. 262-263. 30 Daniel Boamah, “Some Macroeconomic Implications of External Debt for Barbados”, Social and

Economic Studies, Vol. 37, No. 4, Regional Programme of Monetary Studies (December 1988), pp.

189-191. 31 Md. Ezazul Islam and Bishnu Pada Biswas, “Public Debt Management and Debt Sustainability in

Bangladesh”, The Bangladesh Development Studies, Vol. 31, No. 1/2 (March-June 2005), p. 93.

Page 10: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

10

Dynamic differential equations models are identified based on the differential

equations employed, although in reality they are not immediately apparent. For

example, in his study of comparative external and internal public debt burdens,

Carlberg (1985) resorted to an apparent comparative statics equation with factor

income made a function of output and along with some parameters; however, a few of

these parameters are themselves derived from time dependent external debt32. Another

instance involves a simple macroeconomic aggregate model by Otani and Villanueva

(1989) on their study of growth oriented policies involving external debt and human

capital linkages. Along with visual (graphical) models, the central model ostensibly

employs a comparative statics model where real GNP is a function of output,

exchange rate, stock of net external liabilities and average cost of net foreign credits

(which is weighted by the stock of net external liabilities), but variables like capital

can vary with time33. It appears that dynamic models featuring both difference and

differential equations also exist. For example, Dellas and Galor’s (1992) “designing

of Pareto welfare improving policies for economic growth” via external public debt

and controls on private capital outflows saw capital of proceeding year made a

function of production, capital and consumption of current year even as capital stock

is subjected to differentiation34. Another is found in Stein’s (2005) exploration of

optimal debt and endogenous growth in models of international finance where short

term external debt of the next year is a function of GDP in the previous year, but long

term external debt is subjected to differentiation based on time35.

Some comments can be made on the utility of these diverse models. Firstly, that

dynamic models offer certain advantages over comparative statics models does not

obviate the other. Evans (1997) contented that dynamic models can “remarkably

32 Michael Carlberg, “External versus Internal Public Debt – A Theoretical Analysis of the Long-Run

Burden”, Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie/Journal of Economics, Vol. 45, No. 2 (1985), p. 143. 33 To be more precise, the model is Y = Q - reDf*/P where “real national income or real GNP (Y) is

equal to output (Q) less real value of interest payments on external debt (reDf*/P)”, where “r is the

average cost of foreign borrowing (or foreign debt), e is exchange rate expressed in local currency per

unit of foreign currency; and Df* is the stock of net external liabilities (external debt minus claims on

foreigners, including official international reserves), expressed in foreign currency”. This is to show as

“excessive” external debt necessitates the development of human capital. See Ichiro Otani and Delano

Villanueva, “Theoretical Aspects of Growth in Developing Countries: External Debt Dynamics and the

Role of Human Capital”, Staff Papers – International Monetary Fund, Vol. 36, No. 2 (Jun. 1989), p.

319. 34 Harris Dellas and Oded Galor, “Growth via External Public Debt and Capital Controls”,

International Economic Review, Vol. 33, No. 2 (May 1992), pp. 269, 271 and 272. 35 Jerome L. Stein, “Optimal Debt and Endogenous Growth in Models of International Finance”,

Australian Economic Papers, Vol. 44, No. 4 (December 2005), pp. 392, 399.

Page 11: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

11

capture subtle feedback effects” like time lags that are overlooked in the static-like

depictions of comparative statics models; such feedback effects until recently can be

better executed through increasingly powerful and affordable computers allowing

near limitless experimentation with combinations of values and assumptions.

However, comparative statics models are preferred because of their ease of

mathematical resolution, at least in business cycle theory36. Secondly, some

theoretical models appear more capable to demonstrate external debt burden, which

has been a contention as seen in the prior indicator approach. Consider Milbourne

(1997) and Dore (1998). Both are dynamic models that employ difference equations.

However, these studies differ from above models by further exploring the impact of

external debt per capita: on the accumulation of net foreign assets per capita in

Milbourne’s (1997) investigation of the relationship between growth, population

growth, capital accumulation and foreign debt37, and; on income growth per person in

Dore’s (1998) focus on the growth potential of Sub Saharan African countries

incorporating government consumption and external debt servicing38. The factoring in

of populations arguably allows a more accurate portrayal of external debt burden on

each individual beyond just a simple proportion of national income.

Theoretical modelling offers several important advantages, but these do not diminish

their limitations. A first advantage of theoretical models is their ability to show the

important variables that determine the variable in question, which finds support in

Walther (1997)39. Sensitivity analysis among variables can thus be carried out by

calibrating the numerical values plugged into the variables, resulting in meaningful

relationships among variables obtained. Secondly, theoretical models compel the

clarification of assumptions. The need to express assumptions “explicit at every stage

of reasoning”40 in mathematical terms lend to their “high integrity” due to “rigorous

36 Gary Evans, “Chapter 1: Economic Models”, Homepage for Prof. Gary R. Evans [cited 15 August

2003], available from: www2. hmc.edu/~evans/, p. 8. 37 Ross Milbourne, “Growth, Capital Accumulation and Foreign Debt”, Economica, New Series, Vol.

64, No. 253 (Feb. 1997), pp. 1, 3. 38 M. H. I. Dore, “Income growth, debt and deficits: lessons from subSaharan Africa”, International

Review of Applied Economics, Vol. 2, No. 1 (1988), pp. 23, 27-28. 39 Ted Walther, The World Economy (United States of America: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1997), p.

378. 40 Alpha C. Chiang, Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics, 3rd edition (United States of

America: McGraw-Hill, Inc., c1984), p.4.

Page 12: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

12

standards of logic inherent in mathematics”41. This would facilitate falsification of

theories. However, the demanding requirements of such models also contribute to

their weaknesses. Evans (1997) in his broad survey of literature listed three. Firstly,

improper assumptions can undermine a model’s usefulness. Simply put, wrong

assumptions can lead to erroneous calculations even if the model is still “logically

consistent internally”. This pitfall is compounded by the irresolution of contradictory

assumptions even as they appear logical42. For example, Dore (1997) in his study

cautioned the assumption of steady state for the 1970-1983 period which had seen

“not only major price upheavals but also very important institutional and technical

changes”43. Secondly, theoretical modelling has been accused of oversimplification of

reality. The linearity and even non-linearity of models do not suffice in aping reality

due to unpredictability and imperfect information; which has led Dore (1997) to

declare his assumption that the variables employed are linear, such as “simple

averages” instead of “steady state values” for the parameters for budget deficits and

external debt44. Evans (1997) argues that simplicity of models has to be made “not

only expedient but necessary” in order to “make sense of this recondite chaos”45.

However, Chiang (1984) disputes this on grounds that the very nature of theory as

“abstract” renders this criticism as “truism”46. Thirdly, mathematical intractability can

render theoretical models useless. Their value lies in their ability to generate results or

show relationships clearly. Evans (1997) explains the need for linear equations in

order for them to be tractable (solvable) in view of “a large number of equations and

variables” found in macroeconomics47. This explains Dore’s (1997) need for applying

linear values, which relates this criticism to the one just mentioned about the

complexity of reality confounding calculation.

41 Gary Evans, “Chapter 1: Economic Models”, Homepage for Prof. Gary R. Evans [cited 15 August

2003], available from: www2. hmc.edu/~evans/, p. 11. 42 Gary Evans, “Chapter 1: Economic Models”, Homepage for Prof. Gary R. Evans [cited 15 August

2003], available from: www2. hmc.edu/~evans/, p. 11. 43 M. H. I. Dore, “Income growth, debt and deficits: lessons from subSaharan Africa”, International

Review of Applied Economics, Vol. 2, No. 1 (1988), p. 36. 44 M. H. I. Dore, “Income growth, debt and deficits: lessons from subSaharan Africa”, International

Review of Applied Economics, Vol. 2, No. 1 (1988), pp. 35-36. 45 Gary Evans, “Chapter 1: Economic Models”, Homepage for Prof. Gary R. Evans [cited 15 August

2003], available from: www2. hmc.edu/~evans/, p. 12. 46 Alpha C. Chiang, Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics, 3rd edition (United States of

America: McGraw-Hill, Inc., c1984), pp.4-5. 47 Gary Evans, “Chapter 1: Economic Models”, Homepage for Prof. Gary R. Evans [cited 15 August

2003], available from: www2. hmc.edu/~evans/, p. 12.

Page 13: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

13

Although a representative sample of the genre cannot be claimed, some

commonalities can be drawn amidst the apparent differences exhibited by the studies

reviewed above. Firstly, many theoretical models operate on qualified findings, which

corroborate the above assessment. That is, their utility is effective to the extent that

underlying assumptions are met. Walther (1997), Boamah (1988), Milbourne (1997),

and Dore (1998) fit this observation. Secondly, the dynamism of these models is stark,

compared to the indicator approach. All dynamic equations models considered

account for lagged variables that are applied to cases over long periods of time.

Thirdly, as illustrated above, application of models to actual cases is not always

present. Milbourne (1997), Carlberg (1985), Otani and Villanueva (1989) and Dellas

and Galor (1992) are notable examples. These authors demonstrate that economic

inferences can still be drawn even in the absence of case studies by recourse to a

reflection of the theoretical outcomes.

4. EMPIRICAL MODELLING

Empirical models focus on the determinable strength of relationships between

variables through their correlations. This approach presents an even more nuanced

examination of the external debt-national income relationship compared to the

indicator and theoretical modelling approaches. Data gathered from multiple units of

observation are processed via statistical techniques; thus, empirical models are

developed from theoretical models but go beyond48. In an empirical model typically

laid out as a system of interconnecting equations, external debt and national income

are portrayed as independent variables (i.e. regressors); dependent variables (that is,

regressands), or; both. Metwally and Tamaschke (1994a) serves as an instructive case

through their use of ordinary least squares in econometric techniques to model the

interaction between the rate of growth of GNP as regressand and external debt

servicing as regressor among other explanatory variables vis-à-vis three heavily

indebted North African countries 1975-199249. In their study of external debt on

economic growth for 31 developing countries spanning four geographical regions,

Daud and Podivinsky (2011) employ spatial econometrics designating output as the

48 Gary Evans, “Chapter 1: Economic Models”, Homepage for Prof. Gary R. Evans [cited 15 August

2003], available from: www2. hmc.edu/~evans/, pp. 5-6. 49 M. M. Metwally and Rick Tamaschke, “The Interaction Among Foreign Debt, Capital Flows, and

Growth: Case Studies”, Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 16, No. 6 (1994a), pp. 597, 599.

Page 14: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

14

regressand, and debt service ratio as among the regressors.50. Where external debt is

made the regressand and national income the regressor, Gani (1999) typifies the

econometric model applied to exploring the external debt burden on small island

developing countries in the South Pacific using a variant of the generalized least

squares method51. Looney (1987) is another example applying a simple regression

model with total external public debt made a function of GDP among other regressors

which include military expenditures to investigate the “main causes of Third World

external public debt”52.

Aside from commonly observed techniques as above, another application involves the

necessary assignment of both external debt and national income as regressor and

regressand within an empirical model. Several studies focus on exploring the degree

of cointegration between these two variables in a time series sense. One common test

of cointegration is Granger’s causality test which “examines the causal relationship

between a set of variables by testing for their predictability based on past and present

values”53. Exploring Granger’s causality between short term external debt and GDP is

seen in Butts (2009) for 27 Latin American and Caribbean countries over 1970-

200354. Other studies, however, explored the tri-causality between national income

and another variable with reference to external debt as a third variable. Such a

relationship between national income and exports have been explored by Ahmed, Butt

and Alam (2000) with reference to four South Asian and four Southeast Asian

countries from 1990 to 199755, and Amoateng and Amoako-Adu (1996) with respect

50 Siti Nurazira Mohd Daud and Jan M. Podivinsky, “Debt-Growth Nexus: A Spatial Econometrics

Approach for Developing Countries”, Transition Studies Review, Vol. 18, No. 1 (September 2011), pp.

5-9. 51 Azmat Gani, “The Burden of External Debt in the South Pacific Island Countries”, Savings and

Development, Vol. 23, No. 1 (1999), pp. 33, 36. 52 Robert E. Looney, “Impact of Military Expenditures on Third World Debt”, Canadian Journal of

Development Studies/Revue canadienne d’études du development, Vol. 8, No. 1 (1987), p. 11. 53 Qazi Masood Ahmed, Mohammad Sabihuddin Butt, Shaista Alam and Aqdas Ali Kazmi,

“Economic Growth, Export, and External Debt Causality: The Case of Asian Countries [with

Comments]”, The Pakistan Development Review, Vol. 39, No. 4, Papers and Proceedings PART II

Sixteenth Annual General Meeting and Conference of the Pakistan Society of Development

Economists Islamabad, January 22-24, 2001 (Winter 2000), p. 597. 54 Hector C. Butts, “Short Term External Debt and Economic Growth—Granger Causality: Evidence

from Latin America and the Caribbean”, The Review of Black Political Economy, Vol. 36, No. 2 (June

2009), pp. 93, 95-96, 110. 55 Qazi Masood Ahmed, Mohammad Sabihuddin Butt, Shaista Alam and Aqdas Ali Kazmi, “Economic

Growth, Export, and External Debt Causality: The Case of Asian Countries [with Comments]”, The

Pakistan Development Review, Vol. 39, No. 4, Papers and Proceedings PART II Sixteenth Annual

Page 15: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

15

to 35 African countries for the period 1971-199056. Investigations of different

combinations of multi-variate causality variables—though not necessarily involving

Granger’s causality test—include Karagol (2006) involving GNP, defence

expenditures, external debt and total investment for Turkey for 1960-200257.

Differences have been observed among the depiction of changes in national income

with respect to external debt and vice-versa. Magnitudes of changes in variables are

depicted either in linear or logarithmic measurements. With external debt assigned as

among regressors, linear changes like growth rates in national income as regressand

are seen in multivariate linear regression models. Such models include Fosu (1999)

exploring the effect of external debt burden on the economic growth of 35 sub-

Saharan African countries from 1980 to 199058, and Metwally and Tamaschke

(1994b) also measuring external debt burden’s impact on economic growth in Algeria,

Egypt and Morocco from 1975 to 198959. Linear changes in national income per

capita have also been observed in several papers, a sample of which include

Checherita-Westphal and Rother (2012) investigating the linkage between public

external debt and growth rate of GDP per capita in 12 euro area countries for a 40

year duration since 197060; Vamvakidis (2008) investigating the propensity to adopt

economic reform by factoring in private external debt for developing and emerging

economies sampled from 1970 to 2000,61 and; for Granger causality test related,

Ahmed (2012) in his sample of 25 sub-Saharan African countries from 1988 to 2007

exploring multi-variate causality between real domestic income and real external debt

General Meeting and Conference of the Pakistan Society of Development Economists Islamabad,

January 22-24, 2001 (Winter 2000), pp. 598-603. 56 Kofi Amoateng and Ben Amoako-Adu, “Economic growth, export and external debt causality: the

case of African countries”, Applied Economics, Vol. 28, No. 1 (1996), pp. 23, 24-26. 57 Erdal Karagol, “The Relationship Between External Debt, Defence Expenditures and GNP Revisited:

The Case of Turkey”, Defence and Peace Economics, Vol. 17, No. 1 (2006), pp. 49-50, 55. 58 Augustin Kwasi Fosu, “The External Debt Burden and Economic Growth in the 1980s: Evidence

from sub-Saharan Africa”, Canadian Journal of Development Studies/Revue canadienne d’études du

development, Vol. 20, No. 2 (1999), pp. 310-313. 59 M. M. Metwally and Rick Tamaschke, “The Foreign Debt Problem of North African Countries”,

African Review of Money Finance and Banking, No. 1/2 (1994b), pp. 109, 115-116. 60 Cristina Checherita-Westphal and Philipp Rother, “The impact of high government debt on economic

growth and its channels: An empirical investigation for the euro area”, European Economic Review,

Vol. 56, No. 7 (2012), pp. 1395, 1398, 1403. 61 Athanasios Vamvakidis, “External debt and economic reform: does a pain reliever delay the

necessary treatment?”, Journal of Economic Policy Reform, Vol. 11, No. 3 (2008), p. 197.

Page 16: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

16

together with other explanatory variables62. Where external debt is the regressand,

Craigwell, Rock and Sealy (1988) have reported changes in public external debt as

shortfall in real output varies for observations of Barbados from 1959 to 198663. On

the other hand, several other studies have chosen to report changes in national income

in percentages derived from logarithmic expressions instead. An example is Pattillo,

Poirson and Ricci (2003) who explored the channels through which external debt

impacted growth via panel regression for 61 developing countries during the period

1969-199864. Logarithmic changes in national income per capita have been observed

in papers by Daud and Podivinsky (2012) on external debt-economic growth linkages

using “dynamic panel data of Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) framework”

for 31 countries 1970-200565, and Shahbaz, Shabbir and Butt (2013) applying a multi-

variate Granger causality test to not only to the log of real GDP per capita, but also to

the log of external debt per capita for Pakistan’s case for the 1973-2009 duration66.

The uncommon study where change in external debt service as regressand has been

reported in logarithm derived percentages from logarithmic change in income is

demonstrated by Hunte (2002) in his study of saving behaviour and external debt

servicing from data of 36 sub-Saharan African countries obtained in the Human

Development Report for year 200067.

Similar to theoretical models, empirical models can also be segregated into static and

dynamic models. Such models are differentiated on usage of time lagged explanatory

variables: absence of such variables would render the model static, and dynamic for

the obverse. Multivariate linear regression models can exhibit both static and dynamic

62 Abdullahi D. Ahmed, “Debt Burden, Military Spending And Growth In Sub-Saharan Africa: A

Dynamic Panel Data Analysis”, Defence and Peace Economics, Vol. 23, No. 5 (2012), pp. 485, 493,

494. 63 Roland Craigwell, Llewyn Rock and Ronald Sealy, “On the Determination of the External Public

Debt: The Case of Barbados”, Social and Economic Studies, Vol. 37, No. 4, Regional Programme of

Monetary Studies (December 1988), pp. 137, 142-143. 64 Catherine A. Pattillo, Helene Poirson and Luca Antonio Ricci, “Through What Channels Does

External Debt Affect Growth?”, Brookings Trade Forum 2003, eds. Susan M. Collins and Dani Rodrik

(March 2, 2004), pp. 238, 245, 250. 65 Siti Nurazira Mohd Daud and Jan M. Podivinsky, “Revisiting the role of external debt in economic

growth of developing countries”, Journal of Business Economics and Management, Vol. 13, No. 5

(2012), pp. 968, 972-973. 66 Muhammad Shahbaz, Muhammad Shahbaz Shabbir and Muhammad Sabihuddin Butt, “Does

Military Spending Explode External Debt in Pakistan?”, Defence and Peace Economics (2013),

http:/ / dx.doi.org/ 10.1080/ 10242694.2012.724878 , pp. 1, 5, 8. 67 C. Kenrick Hunte, “Saving Behaviour and External Debt-Service: Evidence from Sub-Saharan

Africa”, African Review of Money Finance and Banking (2002), pp. 70-72.

Page 17: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

17

models. Such models of the static variety include previously mentioned studies such

as Metwally and Tamaschke (1994a), Metwally and Tamaschke (1994b) and Fosu

(1999). The input of year specific data, as they appear for Metwally and Tamaschke

(1994a)68 and Metwally and Tamaschke (1994b)69, do not automatically preclude

their models as static so long as lagged variables have not been inputed, while Fosu

(1999)70 relies on country specific data. Dynamic multivariate linear regression

models include studies such as Tchereni, Sekahmpu and Ndovi’s (2013) examination

of the growth rate of Malawi’s GDP tied to stock of external debt among other

variables which justified the adoption of lags to present “a robust explanation of

macroeconomic factors that affect economic growth in Malawi”71; Aizenman, Jinjarak

and Park (2013) whose study of change of GDP per capita subject to lagged short

term debt and the interaction variable between state fragility and short-term debt

among other variables employed lagged dependent and independent variables72, and;

Hallak (2013) where growth of GDP per capita and growth of constant GDP are

assigned as dependent variables commensurate with private sector share of external

debt with control variables featuring lagged GDP per capita growth, inter alia73.

Logarithmic-linear multivariate regression models also exhibit these twin types. Static

ones include Lin and Sosin (2001) measuring the logarithmic growth of GDP per

capita subject to foreign debt-to-GDP ratio among other variables who note that

exploring “time-related issues” is “not the purpose of the cross-section model

presented here”74. Examples of dynamic multivariate logarithmic-linear models

include Pattillo, Poirson and Ricci (2003), Daud and Podivinsky (2012) and

Craigwell, Rock and Sealy (1988) all afore-mentioned. The Pattillo, Poirson and Ricci

68 M. M. Metwally and Rick Tamaschke, “The Interaction Among Foreign Debt, Capital Flows, and

Growth: Case Studies”, Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 16, No. 6 (1994a), p. 599. 69 M. M. Metwally and Rick Tamaschke, “The Foreign Debt Problem of North African Countries”,

African Review of Money Finance and Banking, No. 1/2 (1994b), pp. 115-116. 70 Augustin Kwasi Fosu, “The External Debt Burden and Economic Growth in the 1980s: Evidence

from sub-Saharan Africa”, Canadian Journal of Development Studies/Revue canadienne d’études du

development, Vol. 20, No. 2 (1999), pp. 310-311. 71 B. H. M. Tchereni, T. J. Sekhampu and R. F. Ndovi, “The Impact of Foreign Debt on Economic

Growth in Malawi”, African Development Review, Vol. 25, No. 1 (March 2013), p. 88. 72 Joshua Aizenman, Yothin Jinjarak and Donghyun Park, “Capital Flows and Economic Growth in the

Era of Financial Integration and Crisis, 1990-2010”, Open Economies Review, Vol. 24, No. 3 (July

2013), p. 17. 73 Issam Hallak, “Private sector share of external debt and financial stability: Evidence from bank

loans”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 32 (2013), p. 34. 74 Shuanglin Lin and Kim Sosin, “Foreign debt and economic growth”, Economics of Transition, Vol.

9, No. 3 (2001), pp. 639, 641, 642.

Page 18: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

18

(2003) study includes lagged GDP per capita among the control variables75. Daud and

Podivinsky (2012) base their analysis on a “general dynamic model”76. Where change

in public external debt is the regressand, “cost of foreign credit variable” is designated

as a lagged regressor which renders Craigwell, Rock and Sealy’s (1988) model

dynamic77. Virtually all cointegration models mentioned up to this point are dynamic

models. Further examples include Butts, Mitchell and Berkoh (2012) and Chowdhury

(1994). Butts, Mitchell and Berkoh (2012) utilized the “autoregressive distributed lag

model approach” to examine the “short- and long-run relationships between external

debt and economic growth in Thailand” from 19702 to 2003 with exchange rate and

international reserves as “auxiliary variables”78. Chowdhury (1994) applied “lagged

dependent variables” in his causality test on total external debt and GNP to a total of

seven countries spanning South, Southeast and East Asia for the period 1970-8879.

The usefulness of the empirical model approach merits discussion. While the diversity

of models introduced above prevents any specific meaningful critique, some common

advantages and disadvantages can be discerned from across the spectrum. The

empirical model approach seems to boast three advantages. Firstly, the strength of the

relationship among target variables can be measured. Causal effects can be precisely

computed mathematically. These have been borne out in expressions in linear and

logarithmic terms as mentioned. Even the direction of the magnitude change, i.e. in

increments or decrements, can be shown. Secondly, like theoretical models,

hypotheses can be tested. Regression requires subjecting some hypothesis to

verification. Such verification is processed through an algorithm of equations that

enables conclusions to be drawn from the data inputs through the variables pre-

specified. Inclusion of time dynamism, cointegration tests and analysis on different

75 Catherine A. Pattillo, Helene Poirson and Luca Antonio Ricci, “Through What Channels Does

External Debt Affect Growth?”, Brookings Trade Forum 2003, eds. Susan M. Collins and Dani Rodrik

(March 2, 2004), p. 245. 76 Siti Nurazira Mohd Daud and Jan M. Podivinsky, “Revisiting the role of external debt in economic

growth of developing countries”, Journal of Business Economics and Management, Vol. 13, No. 5

(2012), p. 974. 77 Roland Craigwell, Llewyn Rock and Ronald Sealy, “On the Determination of the External Public

Debt: The Case of Barbados”, Social and Economic Studies, Vol. 37, No. 4, Regional Programme of

Monetary Studies (December 1988), pp. 142-143. 78 Hector C. Butts, Ivor Mitchell and Albert Berkoh, “Economic Growth Dynamics and Short-term

External Debt in Thailand”, The Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 46, No. 1 (Spring 2012), pp. 101,

107. 79 Khorshed Chowdhury, “A structural analysis of external debt and economic growth: some evidence

from selected countries in Asia and the Pacific”, Applied Economics, Vol. 26, No. 12 (1994), p. 1123.

Page 19: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

19

dependent variables—external debt and national income—can thus be made possible.

Thirdly, empirical models arguably address the ‘lack of realism’ claim that theoretical

models suffer from. Data collected from fieldwork observations can ground

hypotheses through inductive inquiry. However, qualifications belie these pluses.

Firstly, some evidence of potential simultaneous causality bias exists. This occurs

when some empirical models do not adjust for reverse causality between variables.

Butts (2009) reports “bi-directional causality relationships” between economic growth

and short-term external debt in his study on 27 Latin American and Caribbean

countries80. Secondly, data gaps can compromise the integrity of empirical models.

For example, insufficient data on external debt compelled Checherita-Westphal and

Rother (2012) to resort to gross government debt instead of external (public) debt as

one of the independent variables in a regression function with growth rate of GDP per

capita as dependent variable in their examination of 12 European countries81. Thirdly,

apparent contradictory conclusions can be reached when relying on empirical

modelling. Such conflict weakens the consensus between Aizenman, Jinjarak and

Park (2013) and Tchereni, Sekhampu and Ndovi (2013) on the negative effects

external debt imposes on GDP82, to the extent of the former’s conclusion that

“...short-term debt had a sizable negative impact on growth in the crisis period but no

impact in the noncrisis period”83. Fourthly, conceptual confusion undermines an

empirical construct’s integrity. An instructive case is Kazmi’s criticism of the earlier

study by Ahmed, Butt and Alam (2000) for apparently liberally interpreting

interchangeably debt as a stock variable and debt-servicing as a flow variable, creating

“a diffused and blurred theoretical framework” giving rise to “contradictory results”84.

80 Hector C. Butts, “Short Term External Debt and Economic Growth—Granger Causality: Evidence

from Latin America and the Caribbean”, The Review of Black Political Economy, Vol. 36, No. 2 (June

2009), p. 93. 81 Cristina Checherita-Westphal and Philipp Rother, “The impact of high government debt on economic

growth and its channels: An empirical investigation for the euro area”, European Economic Review,

Vol. 56, No. 7 (2012), pp. 1395, 1398. 82 Joshua Aizenman, Yothin Jinjarak and Donghyun Park, “Capital Flows and Economic Growth in the

Era of Financial Integration and Crisis, 1990-2010”, Open Economies Review, Vol. 24, No. 3 (July

2013), p. 386; B. H. M. Tchereni, T. J. Sekhampu and R. F. Ndovi, “The Impact of Foreign Debt on

Economic Growth in Malawi”, African Development Review, Vol. 25, No. 1 (March 2013), pp. 85, 88. 83 Joshua Aizenman, Yothin Jinjarak and Donghyun Park, “Capital Flows and Economic Growth in the

Era of Financial Integration and Crisis, 1990-2010”, Open Economies Review, Vol. 24, No. 3 (July

2013), p. 386. 84 Qazi Masood Ahmed, Mohammad Sabihuddin Butt, Shaista Alam and Aqdas Ali Kazmi, “Economic

Growth, Export, and External Debt Causality: The Case of Asian Countries [with Comments]”, The

Pakistan Development Review, Vol. 39, No. 4, Papers and Proceedings PART II Sixteenth Annual

General Meeting and Conference of the Pakistan Society of Development Economists Islamabad,

January 22-24, 2001 (Winter 2000), pp. 607-608.

Page 20: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

20

Although perhaps unrepresentative of overall literature, four observations can

nevertheless be discerned. Firstly and obviously, empirical models appear to be

popular with studies centring on external debt’s impact on national income

accounting. The following papers bear testimony to this: Fosu (1999), Metwally and

Tamaschke (1994b), Lin and Sosin (2001), Aizenman, Jinjarak and Park (2013), Daud

and Podivinsky (2011), Daud and Podivinsky (2012), Vamvakidis (2008), Tchereni,

Sekahmpu and Ndovi (2013), Checherita-Westphal and Rother (2012), and Pattillo,

Poirson and Ricci (2003). Research on the impact on external debt seem confined to a

select few, such as Gani (1999), and Craigwell, Rock and Sealy (1988). That majority

of these studies are of contemporary vintage can be accounted for by modern

advances in statistical techniques as previously noted. Worth considering is the

evident scarcity of certain research topics which can serve to illuminate possible

literature gaps that future empirical studies can more intensively explore. Secondly,

most empirical models are efficacious as they present logical results that support the

hypotheses proposed. Only a few produce counter-intuitive ones: Tchereni, Sekahmpu

and Ndovi (2013), Chowdhury (1994) and Ahmed, Butt and Alam (2000). Excepting

the latter as critiqued by Kazmi, that their hypotheses are debunked do not

automatically dismiss their research, barring evidence of technical misapplication. In

a sense, healthy debate would benefit from more contrarian viewpoints and their

publication ought to be encouraged. Thirdly, the use of qualifiers has been prevalent,

as with theoretical models. These are observed in Fosu (1999), Metwally and

Tamaschke (1994b), Lin and Sosin (2001), Vamvakidis (2008), Checherita-Westphal

and Rother (2012), Pattillo, Poirson and Ricci (2003), Daud and Podivinsky (2012),

Gani (1999), Craigwell, Rock and Sealy (1988), Butts, Mitchell and Berkoh (2012),

and Karagol (2006). The use of assumptions warns that empirical models are relevant

only to the extent that they are valid and reliable for the assumptions fulfilled; and

thus should serve to indicate the veracity of a study which only those empirically

trained can capably identify. Fourthly and relatedly, studies conducted with empirical

models seem capable of providing only tentative conclusions. The use of assumptions

supports this view, exacerbated by assumptions’ dubious reflection of reality.

Moreover, the coefficients derived from empirical models are merely postulations

based on past examples; which can serve as useful guide for prediction but doubtful as

to their predictive powers for future cases.

Page 21: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

21

5. CONCLUSIONS

Some recapitulation is in order. The indicator approach has been presented as a

relatively simple ratio or proportion that external debt occupies in national income.

The theoretical modelling approach situates external debt and national income as

endogenous variables that do not necessarily require numerical values for resolution

and demonstration of mutual impact. Empirical models build on theoretical models to

present measurable impacts that external debt exerts on national income and vice-

versa. Indicators perhaps find use in initial calculations, with more demanding studies

employing theoretical models and find demonstration through empirical techniques.

Barring their respective limitations, a possible—and possibly ideal—combination

works to express indicators as variables embedded in a series of theoretical models to

find expression through empirical (statistical) techniques. However, as said, each

approach comes with it certain limitations that remain to be seen whether they can be

addressed when applied in tandem.

A second inference results from the sense obtained that a hierarchical ranking of

approaches can be discerned in terms of their relative superiority. Empirical models, it

seems, are choice methods as observed from the plethora of studies churned out. That

empirical models are not only tractable but calculable probably explain their

popularity. However, it is also observed that greater demands are imposed

commensurate with the sophistication of approach adopted. A certain proficiency with

complex mathematical manipulations is presumed as prerequisite when considering

theoretical models—and even more so with empirical models85, as compared to the

indicator approach.

The choice of approach for each study should be determined from the conditions

imposed by the phenomenon of interest. Limiting factors of a paper should go beyond

temporal, terrestrial and financial considerations to include technical restrictions as

manifested by the working assumptions under which each approach operates

effectively. That the use of qualifications abounds throughout the discussion of

various papers above should justify sounding out this cautionary word. Empirical

85 Gary Evans, “Chapter 1: Economic Models”, Homepage for Prof. Gary R. Evans [cited 15 August

2003], available from: www2. hmc.edu/~evans/, p. 5.

Page 22: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

22

modelling appears to be the favoured choice from above as gleaned from the

multitude of papers derived from it, but that should not be read as discrimination

against the indicator and theoretical modelling approaches. Insofar that the external

debt-national income relationship ought to be fleshed out in as great detail and depth,

employment of empirical models poses its own serious risks that it must make sense

at times to fall back on indicators or theoretical models. Such a sober recognition of

realities is necessary, which goes towards informing the summarized description of

each approach in Table 1.

Page 23: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

23

Table 1: Characteristics of 3 approaches.

Approach Purpose Variants Pros Cons

Indicator To measure the

severity of foreign

indebtedness on

national income

Choice of

denominators:

national income or

exports of goods and

services

1) Easy to calculate

and understand

2) Not data

intensive

3) Absent

alternative choices

of indicators

4) Flexible long

term and short term

convenient

measurement

1) As measure of

national debt

burden debatable

2) Fluctuating

data

3) Static, not

dynamic,

displays

4) Questions of

critical debt

thresholds

5) Stock-versus-

flow conceptual

confusion

Choice of

numerators: external

debt principal or

external debt service

Theoretical

models

To solve for

unknown variables

or measure

movements among

variables; need not

require numerical

values

Choice of static or

dynamic models

1) Show variables

that affect target

variable

2) Compel

clarification of

assumptions

1) Use of

improper

assumptions

2) Reductionist

by over-

simplifying

reality

3) Risk of

mathematical

intractability

Use of difference

equations,

differential

equations, or both

Empirical

models

To determine

strength of

relationships

between variables

through correlation

Choice of dependent

variable: external

debt or national

income, or both (for

cointegration

testing)

1) Strength of

relationship

between target

variables

measurable

2) Allows testing

of different

hypotheses

3) Models more

grounded in reality

with empirical data

1) Potential

simultaneous

causality bias

2) Data gaps can

compromise

integrity of

model

3) Risk of

drawing

contradictory

conclusions

4) Conceptual

confusion can

undermine

model’s integrity

Linear or

logarithmic

expressions of

dependent variable

Choice of static or

dynamic models

Page 24: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

24

References

Ahmed, Abdullahi D. “Debt Burden, Military Spending And Growth In Sub-Saharan

Africa: A Dynamic Panel Data Analysis”. Defence and Peace Economics, Vol. 23,

No. 5 (2012), pp. 485-506.

Ahmed, Qazi Masood, Mohammad Sabihuddin Butt, Shaista Alam and Aqdas Ali

Kazmi. “Economic Growth, Export, and External Debt Causality: The Case of Asian

Countries [with Comments]”. The Pakistan Development Review, Vol. 39, No. 4,

Papers and Proceedings PART II Sixteenth Annual General Meeting and Conference

of the Pakistan Society of Development Economists Islamabad, January 22-24, 2001

(Winter 2000), pp. 591-608.

Aizenman, Joshua, Yothin Jinjarak and Donghyun Park. “Capital Flows and

Economic Growth in the Era of Financial Integration and Crisis, 1990-2010”. Open

Economies Review, Vol. 24, No. 3 (July 2013), pp. 371-396.

Amoateng, Kofi, and Ben Amoako-Adu. “Economic growth, export and external debt

causality: the case of African countries”. Applied Economics, Vol. 28, No. 1 (1996),

pp. 21-27.

Avramovic, Dragoslav, S. Shahid Husain, Jan de Weille, Johan Froland, and J. P.

Hayes; assisted by Hans Wyss and S. Shahid Husain. Economic Growth and External

Debt. Baltimore, Maryland: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1964.

Boamah, Daniel. “Some Macroeconomic Implications of External Debt for

Barbados”. Social and Economic Studies, Vol. 37, No. 4, Regional Programme of

Monetary Studies (December 1988), pp. 171-191.

Butts, Hector C. “Short Term External Debt and Economic Growth—Granger

Causality: Evidence from Latin America and the Caribbean”. The Review of Black

Political Economy, Vol. 36, No. 2 (June 2009), pp. 93-111.

Page 25: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

25

Butts, Hector C., Ivor Mitchell and Albert Berkoh. “Economic Growth Dynamics and

Short-term External Debt in Thailand”. The Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 46,

No. 1 (Spring 2012), pp. 91-111.

Carlberg, Michael. “External versus Internal Public Debt – A Theoretical Analysis of

the Long-Run Burden”. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie/Journal of Economics, Vol.

45, No. 2 (1985), pp. 141-154.

Checherita-Westphal, Cristina, and Philipp Rother. “The impact of high government

debt on economic growth and its channels: An empirical investigation for the euro

area”. European Economic Review, Vol. 56, No. 7 (2012), pp. 1392-1405.

Chiang, Alpha C. Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics. 3rd edition.

United States of America: McGraw-Hill, Inc., c1984.

Chowdhury, Khorshed. “A structural analysis of external debt and economic growth:

some evidence from selected countries in Asia and the Pacific”. Applied Economics,

Vol. 26, No. 12 (1994), pp. 1121-1131.

Clark, Ephraim. International Finance. 2nd edition. United Kingdom: Thomson, 2002.

Craigwell, Roland, Llewyn Rock and Ronald Sealy. “On the Determination of the

External Public Debt: The Case of Barbados”. Social and Economic Studies, Vol. 37,

No. 4, Regional Programme of Monetary Studies (December 1988), pp. 137-150.

Daud, Siti Nurazira Mohd, and Jan M. Podivinsky. “Debt-Growth Nexus: A Spatial

Econometrics Approach for Developing Countries”. Transition Studies Review, Vol.

18, No. 1 (September 2011), pp. 1-15.

———. “Revisiting the role of external debt in economic growth of developing

countries”. Journal of Business Economics and Management, Vol. 13, No. 5 (2012),

pp. 968-993.

Page 26: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

26

Dellas, Harris, and Oded Galor. “Growth via External Public Debt and Capital

Controls”. International Economic Review, Vol. 33, No. 2 (May 1992), pp. 269-281.

Dore, M. H. I. “Income growth, debt and deficits: lessons from subSaharan Africa”.

International Review of Applied Economics, Vol. 2, No. 1 (1988), pp. 23-41.

Dornbusch, Rudiger. “Consumption Opportunities and the Real Value of the External

Debt”. Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 10, No. 1 (February 1982), pp. 93-

101.

Fosu, Augustin Kwasi. “The External Debt Burden and Economic Growth in the

1980s: Evidence from sub-Saharan Africa”. Canadian Journal of Development

Studies/Revue canadienne d’études du development, Vol. 20, No. 2 (1999), pp. 307-

318.

Gani, Azmat. “The Burden of External Debt in the South Pacific Island Countries”.

Savings and Development, Vol. 23, No. 1 (1999), pp. 29-45.

Gupta, S. P. “Debt Crisis and Economic Reforms”. Economic and Political Weekly,

Vol. 29, No. 23 (Jun. 4, 1994), pp. 1411-1418.

Hallak, Issam. “Private sector share of external debt and financial stability: Evidence

from bank loans”. Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 32 (2013), pp.

17-41.

Hallwood, C. Paul, and Ronald MacDonald. International Money and Finance. 3rd

edition. United Kingdom: Blackwell Publishing, 2000.

Hunte, C. Kenrick. “Saving Behaviour and External Debt-Service: Evidence from

Sub-Saharan Africa”. African Review of Money Finance and Banking (2002), pp. 63-

74.

Page 27: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

27

Islam, Md. Ezazul, and Bishnu Pada Biswas. “Public Debt Management and Debt

Sustainability in Bangladesh”. The Bangladesh Development Studies, Vol. 31, No. 1/2

(March-June 2005), pp. 79-102.

Karagol, Erdal. “The Relationship Between External Debt, Defence Expenditures and

GNP Revisited: The Case of Turkey”. Defence and Peace Economics, Vol. 17, No. 1

(2006), pp. 47-57.

Kohsaka, Akira. “Macroeconomic Management with External Debt – East Asian

Experiences in the 1980s”. Asian Economic Journal, Vol. V, No. 3 (November 1991),

pp. 261-283.

Lin, Shuanglin, and Kim Sosin. “Foreign debt and economic growth”. Economics of

Transition, Vol. 9, No. 3 (2001), pp. 635-655.

Looney, Robert E. “Impact of Military Expenditures on Third World Debt”. Canadian

Journal of Development Studies/Revue canadienne d’études du development, Vol. 8,

No. 1 (1987), pp. 7-26.

Mahmood, Tahir, Shahnaz A. Rauf and Hafiz Khalil Ahmad. “Public and External

Debt Sustainability in Pakistan”. Pakistan Economic and Social Review, Vol. 47, No.

2 (Winter 2009), pp. 243-267.

Metwally, M. M., and Rick Tamaschke. “The Interaction Among Foreign Debt,

Capital Flows, and Growth: Case Studies”. Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 16, No.

6 (1994a), pp. 597-608.

———. “The Foreign Debt Problem of North African Countries”. African Review of

Money Finance and Banking, No. 1/2 (1994b), pp. 109-122.

Milbourne, Ross. “Growth, Capital Accumulation and Foreign Debt”. Economica,

New Series, Vol. 64, No. 253 (Feb. 1997), pp. 1-13.

Page 28: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

28

Musa, Michael. “Exchange Rate Adjustments Needed to Reduce Global Payments

Imbalances”, in Dollar Adjustment: How Far? Against What?, eds. C. Fred Bergsten

and John Williamson. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 2004,

pp. 113-138. In Barry Eichengreen, Global Imbalances and the Lessons of Bretton

Woods. United States of America: The MIT Press, 2007.

Nallari, Raj, and Breda Griffith. Understanding Growth and Poverty: Theory, Policy

and Empirics. Washington, D.C.: The International Bank for Reconstruction and

Development/The World Bank, 2011.

Hess, Peter, and Clark Ross. Economic Development: Theories, Evidence, and

Policies. United States of America: The Dryden Press, Harcourt Brace & Company,

1997.

Otani, Ichiro, and Delano Villanueva. “Theoretical Aspects of Growth in Developing

Countries: External Debt Dynamics and the Role of Human Capital”. Staff Papers –

International Monetary Fund, Vol. 36, No. 2 (Jun. 1989), pp. 307-342.

Park, Yung Chul. “Foreign Debt, Balance of Payments, and Growth Prospects: The

Case of the Republic of Korea, 1965-88”. World Development, Vol. 14, No. 8 (1986),

pp. 1019-1058.

Pattillo, Catherine A., Helene Poirson and Luca Antonio Ricci. “Through What

Channels Does External Debt Affect Growth?”. Brookings Trade Forum 2003, eds.

Susan M. Collins and Dani Rodrik (March 2, 2004), pp. 229-258.

Pilbeam, Keith. International Finance. 2nd edition. Great Britain: Macmillan Press

Ltd, 1998.

Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff. “Growth in a Time of Debt”. The

American Economic Review, Vol. 100, No. 2, PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS OF

THE One Hundred Twenty Second Annual Meeting OF THE AMERICAN

ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION (May 2010), pp. 573-578.

Page 29: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

29

Shahbaz, Muhammad, Muhammad Shahbaz Shabbir and Muhammad Sabihuddin

Butt. “Does Military Spending Explode External Debt in Pakistan?”. Defence and

Peace Economics (2013), http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10242694.2012.724878, pp. 1-24.

Stein, Jerome L. “Optimal Debt and Endogenous Growth in Models of International

Finance”. Australian Economic Papers, Vol. 44, No. 4 (December 2005), pp. 389-

413.

Stein, J.L. Stochastic Optimal Control and the U.S. Financial Debt Crisis. New York:

Springer Science+Business Media New York, 2012.

Tahir, Pervez, and Eatzaz Ahmad. “The Debt of the Nation [with Comments]”. The

Pakistan Development Review, Vol. 37, No. 4, Papers and Proceedings PART II

Fourteenth Annual General Meeting and Conference of the Pakistan Society of

Development Economists Islamabad, January 28-31, 1999 (Winter 1998), pp. 331-

353.

Tchereni, B. H. M., T. J. Sekhampu and R. F. Ndovi. “The Impact of Foreign Debt on

Economic Growth in Malawi”. African Development Review, Vol. 25, No. 1 (March

2013), pp. 85-90.

Tilak, Jandhyala B. G. “External Debt and Public Investment in Education in Sub-

Saharan Africa”. Journal of Education Finance, Vol. 15, No. 4, The Oxford Round

Table (Spring 1990), pp. 470-486.

Vamvakidis, Athanasios. “External debt and economic reform: does a pain reliever

delay the necessary treatment?”. Journal of Economic Policy Reform, Vol. 11, No. 3

(2008), pp. 187-199.

Walther, Ted. The World Economy. United States of America: John Wiley & Sons,

Inc., 1997.

Villanueva, Delano P., and Roberto S. Mariano. “External Debt, Adjustment, and

Growth”. In Fiscal Policy and Management in East Asia, eds. Takatoshi Ito and

Page 30: Lee and Thampapillai_2016_External Debt in Macroeconomics_A Review

30

Andrew K. Rose. United States of America: The University of Chicago Press, 2007,

pp. 199-221.

World Bank, The. World Debt Tables 1992-1993. Washington D.C.: The International

Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank, 1993. In Pervez Tahir

and Eatzaz Ahmad. “The Debt of the Nation [with Comments]”. The Pakistan

Development Review, Vol. 37, No. 4, Papers and Proceedings PART II Fourteenth

Annual General Meeting and Conference of the Pakistan Society of Development

Economists Islamabad, January 28-31, 1999 (Winter 1998), pp. 331-353.

Internet Sources

Evans, Gary. “Chapter 1: Economic Models”. Homepage for Prof. Gary R. Evans

[cited 15 August 2003]. Available from: www2. hmc.edu/~evans/.