layna mosley unc-ch 20121026

38
Debt Management, Country Categorizations and Government-Financial Market Relations Layna Mosley, UNC October 26, 2012

Upload: unceurope

Post on 23-Jun-2015

146 views

Category:

Education


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Debt Management, Country Categorizations and Government-Financial Market Relations: Presentation for UNC Center for European Studies Fall Lecture Series 2012, Beyond the Euro Crisis

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Debt Management, Country Categorizations and Government-Financial Market Relations

Layna Mosley, UNCOctober 26, 2012

Page 2: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Sovereign Debt in the EU• Early 2000s: interest rate convergence among euro-zone

nations.• Virtuous circle for sovereign borrowers.

• Default risk assumed to be non-existent, even among highly-indebted EU nations.• “No bailout” clause of Maastricht Treaty lacked

credibility.• Little market response to violations of the Stability

and Growth Pact.• Governments were able to suggest rules for investors.• E.g. 3 percent fiscal deficit rule.

Page 3: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

0

5

10

15

20

25

Interest Rates on Benchmark Government Bonds

AustraliaAustriaBelgium CanadaCzech RepublicDenmarkFinlandFranceGermanyGreece HungaryIcelandIrelandItalyJapanKoreaNetherlandsNew ZealandNorwayPortugalSlovak RepublicSpainSwedenUnited KingdomUnited States

Page 4: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 20110

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

Government Bond Rates, 2005-2011

AustriaBelgium FranceGermanyGreece IrelandItalyNetherlandsPortugalSpainUnited KingdomUnited States

Page 5: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

• With the crisis, a renewed attention to default risk, and to differences across countries.

• Reward for EMU disappears, or at least is reduced.

• Chart: variance in government bond rates among OECD nations.

19951996

19971998

19992000

20012002

20032004

20052006

20072008

20092010

20110

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

Page 6: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

What should we learn from the EU’s debt crisis? (1) The return of default risk among developed

nations?

(2) All government debt is not created equal, or managed equally.

• Affects sensitivity of governments to financial market pressures.

Page 7: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Debt Management

• When debt matures• Tradeoff between cost and rollover risk• 2010: Ireland 5.9 years vs. UK 14.1 years

Page 8: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Australia

Austria

Canada

Denm

ark

Estonia

Finland

France

Germ

any

Hungary

Ireland

Italy

Netherlands

New

Zealand

Spain

United Kingdom

United States

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

Average Time to Maturity of Government Debt, 2010

Page 9: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

1980198119821983198419851986198719881989199019911992199319941995199619971998199920002001200220032004200520062007200820092010

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

Average Time to Maturity of Marketable Government Debt, OECD Countries

25th pctile50th pctile75th pctile

Page 10: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

OECD governments will need to refinance about 30% of their long term debt in the next 3 years.

Source: OECD Sovereign Borrowing Outlook, No. 4, 2012

Page 11: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Source: OECD Sovereign Borrowing Outlook, 2012

Page 12: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Debt Management

• When debt matures• Tradeoff between cost and rollover risk• 2010: Ireland 5.9 years vs. UK 14.1 years

• Who holds debt• Private vs. official creditors (e.g. central banks)• Resident vs. non-resident investors• 2010: 94% non-resident Greece vs. 56% Italy

Page 13: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Country

Austria

Canada

Czech Republic

Denm

ark

Estonia

Finland

Hungary

Italy

Mexico

New

Zealand

Slovak Republic

Slovenia

Spain

Sweden

Turkey

United Kingdom

United States

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

Percentage of Marketable Debt Held by Non-Residents, 2009

Page 14: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

19851986198719881989199019911992199319941995199619971998199920002001200220032004200520062007200820092010

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

Non-Resident Investment as % of Total Marketable Debt, OECD Countries

25th pctile50th pctile75th pctile

Page 15: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Debt Management

• When debt matures• Tradeoff between cost and rollover risk• 2010: Ireland 5.9 years vs. UK 14.1 years

• Who holds debt• Private vs. official creditors (e.g. central banks)• Resident vs. non-resident investors• 2010: 94% non-resident Greece vs. 56% Italy

• In which currencies debt is denominated• “Original sin” (Eichengreen and Hausman)• Risk to investors vs. risk to governments• Domestic vs. foreign currency debt

Page 16: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Debt Management Outcomes

• To what extent do these outcomes reflect strategic choices by governments, versus willingness of investors to lend?

• Debt management outcomes as dependent variable

• What are the implications of debt management outcomes for responses to crises and, more broadly, for government policymaking autonomy?

• Debt management outcomes as independent variable.

Page 17: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Governing Debt• Establishment of separate DMOs in many OECD nations in

the 1980s and early 1990s.• Variation in location (MoF, CB)• Variation in autonomy and mandates

• In emerging markets, greater attention in 2000s.• Concerns about short term debt and foreign currency

denominated debt.• Efforts to move from floating to fixed rate debt, and from

foreign- to domestic-issued debt.• Facilitated by global market liquidity in mid-2000s.• Attempts by IGOs to diffuse “best practices” for DMOs

• Main tradeoff: costs vs. risks• Shorter maturity & foreign currency• Longer maturity & domestic currency

Page 18: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Dependent Variable:Time to Maturity of Public Debt• Cross-sectional time series analyses• Independent variables: moving average over last three years

(alternative: five years).• Lagged dependent variable• 1980-2009, OECD nations• n=~300 (13 to 19 countries)

• Significant predictors of average time to maturity:• Inflation (-)• Government budget balance (-), or government debt (-)• Effective number of political parties (-)• Central bank independence (+; less robust)

• Not significantly associated with time to maturity:• Left government• Coalition (vs. single party) government• EMU participation• Location of debt management office (separate or not)

Page 19: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

What should we learn from the EU’s debt crisis? (1) The return of default risk among developed nations?

(2) All government debt is not created equal, or managed equally.

(3) Investors’ assessments of sovereign borrowers vary over time and across countries – and not only because of changes in country-specific economic or political fundamentals.

Page 20: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Assessing Sovereign Risk?• When setting risk premiums for sovereign debt, at what do

investors look?• If governments are attentive to market pressures, how do these

pressures operate?

• Investors’ primary concerns are currency, inflation and default risk.• 1990s and 2000s: investors treated developed and emerging

market countries differently.• Assumed no default risk among developed nations, so consider

only macro-indicators (deficits, inflation)• Worried more about default among developing nations, so

looked also at supply side policies, government ideology, elections.

Page 21: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Assessing Sovereign Risk• Developing nations are therefore more constrained by

market pressures than developed ones.

• Also have greater need to attract foreign capital.• And are more exposed to externally-induced volatility:• Importance of push vs. pull factors to risk premiums.• Commodity exporters• The borrowing strategies pursued by emerging market

governments can exacerbate “ability to pay” concerns.

• After accounting for policy outcomes, emerging and frontier market countries pay higher risk premiums than developed nation borrowers.

Page 22: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Variation in Market Constraints• The prices governments pay to borrow on international

markets vary markedly:• Across countries (sovereign credit ratings, macroeconomic

fundamentals)• Over time (liquidity, risk appetite, elections)(Archer et al 2007; Bernhard and Leblang 2006; Cantor and Packer 1996; Hardie 2006; Jensen and Schmith 2005; Mosley 2003; Tomz 2007)

• In addition, different types of governments are differently constrained by global capital markets:developed vs. developingcommodity vs. manufacturing exportersborrowers from commercial banks vs. bond markets(Campello 2012, Mosley 2003, Kaplan 2012, Wibbels 2006)

Page 23: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Are market constraints interdependent?• Does the sovereign risk premium paid by one country

systematically shape the way that investors assess sovereign risk in other nations?

• If so, how, and through which channels do sovereign risk assessments diffuse?

• One principal mechanism: country classifications• Professional investors sort countries into “peer” groups

Page 24: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Are market constraints interdependent?• Optimal portfolio diversification dictates that professional

investors often manage highly dissimilar assets• sovereign debt, corporate debt, equities, derivatives and cash • and they often invest in a diverse range of locations

• They rely on information shortcuts to assess risk (heuristics)• Summary indicators of fiscal and monetary outcomes.

• Budget deficit• Debt ratios• Inflation

• Also: categories• “developed” vs. “developing” (Mosley 2003)• peripheral Europe: “emerging Europe” in the 1990s “eurozone” in

the 2000s “PIIGS” in the 2010s

Page 25: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Sovereign Peer Groupings• Investors may over- or under-estimate sovereign risk based on

the category into which the country is grouped:

• When investors are more optimistic about a given group of countries, each country in that group will experience an improvement in market access.

• When investors are more pessimistic about a category of countries, a borrower within that category may suffer – even if the country’s fundamentals do not warrant such pessimism.

• This implies that investors’ responses to domestic policy are neither fixed, nor fully objective.

Page 26: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Interdependent Sovereign Risk• Over the long term, sovereign risk assessments should vary

with domestic fundamentals.

• In the short term, sovereign risk may correlate across nations due to contagion from crises or changes in global liquidity.

• But, even after controlling for these short- and long-term effects, we expect an additional effect of “country category”• Country risk premium will be significantly correlated with the risk

premiums paid by other borrowers in the same category.(Hypothesis 1)

Page 27: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Comparing Countries• We also expect that, when investors evaluate individual

sovereign borrowers, they do so in relative terms: • The risk premium associated with a given fiscal deficit, for

instance, depends on what other countries are doing.• Governments are evaluated relative to what they are expected to

do.• Tomz 2007: stalwarts vs. lemons

• Here, peer categorizations matter because they define the relevant comparison group.• Sovereign risk premiums are associated, all else equal, with what

other borrowers in the same category are doing, in terms of government budgets, and deficits. (Hypothesis 2)

Page 28: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Which Peer Groups Matter?• We examine 3 types of investment categorizations:

1. Region: • Asia, Western Europe, post-Communist Europe, Latin America,

Non-Latin Caribbean, Middle East and North Africa, North America, South Asia, and Africa [World Bank categories]

2. Market and Economic Development:a. MSCI: Emerging Markets; Frontier; Developedb. FTSE: Emerging Markets; Frontier; Developed; Advanced Emerging; Secondary Emerging

3. Risk Rating: • Fitch Long-Term Sovereign Credit Ratings

• (Coded as a 1-12 sovereign risk score)

Page 29: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Data and Method• Dependent variables:• Sovereign spreads (EMBI): monthly and annual data for 26

emerging market economies, 2001-2010.• Credit default swap (CDS) prices, monthly data for 26 developed

and developing countries, 2000-2010.

• Independent variables:• Domestic economic: government debt, government consumption,

budget balance, inflation, capital account openness.• Domestic political: democracy, government ideology, opposition

party ideology, electoral cycle, presidential/parliamentary• Global: US interest rate, US treasury bond yields, US stock market

returns.• Peer group: average risk premium of those in the same category

Page 30: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Data and Method• We estimate cross-sectional time series models, using an Error

Correction Model (ECM).• This allows us to consider both the short-term and long-term

effects of the regressors.• Generalized least squares estimator, country fixed effects, linear

time trend.

• Full results of the estimations are available in the paper (Tables 1 through 5)

Page 31: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Main Findings

Blank cells indicate that the effect of peer category risk premium is not statistically significant, controlling for all other independent variables.

Page 32: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Main Findings

• In terms of relative assessments (Hypothesis 2):• The level of government debt in (regional) peer countries is

negatively and significantly associated with spreads.• A country’s own debt level is, as we would expect, positively

and significantly associated with spreads.• Categorization may provide governments with an opportunity

to outperform their peers, for which they are rewarded.

• If we take sovereign ratings as the dependent variable,• When one’s rating category peers have better fiscal outcomes,

one’s rating is higher, all else equal.• Again, a country’s own fiscal balance also is positively and

significantly associated with one’s sovereign rating.

Page 33: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

Caveats and Conclusion• Annual data obscures what are often shorter-term movements in

sovereign debt markets.• Models suggest that almost all of the disturbances to equilibrium

in risk premiums are corrected within one year.• Most of the political variables included in our models, however,

are measured on an annual basis.• Sample: a limited set of countries (e.g. those for which there is a

CDS market or which are included in EMBI+)

• More generally, aggregate-level observational data may not be the best way to assess our proposed causal mechanisms.• Future work: survey experiment design.

• Our findings suggest, however, that the ways in which countries are grouped – and changes in those groupings – may be important determinants of governments’ capacity to access bond markets.

Page 34: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026
Page 35: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026
Page 36: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026
Page 37: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026
Page 38: Layna Mosley UNC-CH 20121026

DV: Annual Δ_Spread Table 1. Explaining Annual Changes in Sovereign Debt Spreads

Peer Category: Region Risk Rating MSCI FTSE

    1     2     3     4  

  Coef.   Std. Err. Coef.   Std. Err. Coef.   Std. Err. Coef.   Std. Err.

Spread t-1 -1.08 *** 0.07 -1.12 *** 0.06 -0.94 *** 0.07 -1.11 *** 0.07

Peer Diffusion                        

Peer Spread          

t-1 0.21 ** 0.10 -0.20 * 0.11 0.22 * 0.13 -0.26 *** 0.09

Δ 0.37 *** 0.07 0.09 0.07 0.45 *** 0.10 -0.13 0.09

Domestic Politics and Economy                        

Gov Consumption          

t-1 1.02 24.23 4.59 27.13 3.72 24.43 19.76 25.89

Δ -23.86 19.78 -4.07 21.34 -15.16 20.08 -36.84 * 22.33

Debt          

t-1 4.37 ** 2.18 4.15 ** 1.88 2.77 2.24 5.51 *** 2.10

Δ 6.40 *** 2.26 5.78 *** 1.76 7.04 *** 2.13 7.88 *** 2.15

Maturity          

t-1 1.15 5.10 -3.85 5.46 -7.16 5.38 -2.40 4.82

Δ -1.79 3.56 -6.35 * 3.62 -8.14 ** 3.66 -2.77 3.51

Inflation          

t-1 0.33 0.46 0.07 0.48 0.68 0.46 0.63 0.52

Δ 0.02 0.33 -0.11 0.34 0.10 0.34 0.02 0.39

Budget Balance          

t-1 -20.89 ** 10.57 -26.37 ** 10.98 -16.42 11.20 -20.98 * 11.21

Δ -31.89 *** 8.30 -25.73 *** 8.47 -25.46 *** 8.64 -23.93 *** 8.79

Democracy          

t-1 11.86 14.17 20.07 14.42 12.47 13.52 15.10 12.90

Δ 22.40 22.37 25.12 21.99 5.68 23.53 32.87 22.03

KA Open          

t-1 -80.68 ** 33.55 -65.33 * 35.37 -54.40 33.85 -59.09 * 33.26

Δ -59.39 * 36.41 -56.40 40.39 -58.81 40.33 -31.58 35.59

Years to Election          

t-1 -32.76 ** 14.63 -29.64 * 15.49 -25.99 * 14.44 -25.52 ** 13.04

Δ -9.47 9.92 -12.17 9.98 -10.52 9.90 -7.66 8.88

Left          

t-1 128.18 267.97 26.77 385.25 -30.57 440.41 28.30 337.53

Right          

t-1 36.95 400.40 -673.79 * 399.72 -642.29 * 377.14 -650.50 * 346.34

Opposition Right          

t-1 85.90 61.58 40.49 61.68 56.35 57.26 50.99 45.05

Opposition Left          

t-1 116.75 * 70.25 104.07 68.31 93.53 67.58 54.50 55.99

System          

t-1 -52.33 39.09 -7.75 39.86 1.05 39.45 -29.78 39.05

Common Shocks                        

US Prime Rate          

t-1 29.75 ** 12.28 30.99 *** 12.44 34.93 *** 13.21 33.09 *** 13.00

Δ -25.89 * 14.80 -68.22 *** 14.88 -10.85 17.29 -70.54 *** 15.19

Time          

t-1 -12.85 8.95 -22.22 *** 8.47 -9.43 9.64 -19.05 ** 8.42

Const. 25956   17988 44910 *** 16975 19192   19351 38372 ** 16896

N. obs 171   171 171 171

Wald chi2 454.59   1353.14 479.67 444.68

Prob > chi2 0   0 0 0

FGLS error correction model of annual change in Sovereign Stripped Spreads *** p<.01; ** p<.05; * p<.1