labor markets and unemployment. the labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the...

105
Labor Markets and Unemployment

Upload: veronica-oneal

Post on 06-Jan-2018

227 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Labor Markets and Unemployment

Page 2: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor by employers and the supply of labor by individuals like ourselves who are in the labor market.

• The equilibrium wage is determined in the labor market and changes in either the demand or supply of labor will influence the wage rate.

Page 3: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Page 4: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Unemployment is one of the most visible indicators of economic activity. – The rate of unemployment typically rises

considerably during recessions then falls as the economic recovers.

Page 5: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Defining Unemployment• In any population survey, every adult is placed into one of

three categories: employed, unemployed, or not in the labor force. – Anyone who worked for pay at all during the reference week is

considered to be employed, including parttime workers. – Among those not employed, those who were both actively

seeking work and immediately available for work, plus those who were awaiting recall from a temporary layoff from their previous job, are classified as unemployed.

– Anyone else, i.e., those who did not work, were not on layoff, and either were not actively seeking work or were not available for work, are considered to be out of the labor force.

Page 6: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• the extent of unemployment is commonly expressed as the unemployment rate, which is the number unemployed divided by the total labor force, which consists of the sum of employment and unemployment.– In Europe, the “headline number” is more likely to

be the number of unemployed rather than the rate.

Page 7: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Theories of Unemployment

• In an ideal labor market, wages would adjust to balance the supply and demand for labor.– This ensures that all workers are always fully employed

• But reality does not resemble this ideal.– There are always some workers without job, even when

the overall economy is doing well. (unemployment will never falls to zero)

• So, why unemployment? Why Are There Always Some People Unemployed?– There is no single unified model of unemployment.

Page 8: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Classical’s View:– excessively high wages depress labor demand. – The policy implication: institutions maintaining

higher wage levels, such as unions or minimum wage laws, harm employment in the aggregate. • Economists dismissed the possibility that aggregate

demand might not be sufficient to absorb aggregate supply, citing Say’s Law that “supply creates its own demand.”

Page 9: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Keynesians’s View:– wage-cutting simply aggravates the shortfall of demand

since it leaves workers with less money to spend on consumer goods.

• Policy Implication: governments should use monetary policy (cutting interest rates) and especially fiscal policy (reducing taxes or expanding spending) to “prime the pump” of private consumer expenditure and to assure full employment.

• Governments, including that of the United States, implemented this theory through social welfare spending and public works programs.

Page 10: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Note that the Walrasian paradigm based on the market for a homogeneous good predicts that there should be no unemployment, so this workhorse benchmark model of neoclassical economics is not informative.

Page 11: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Since there are many ways in which actual labor markets differ from a Walrasian market, there are many possible approaches that can be followed.

• While employment and unemployment are clearly connected in important ways, a theory of employment alone is not sufficient to explain the behavior of unemployment.– One fallacy that is often committed by uninformed members

of the public and the media is to assume that a decline in employment of, say, 1000 workers necessarily means that unemployment will rise by 1000.

Page 12: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Rather than simply viewing unemployment as the counter-state to employment, we model it as a process of search.

• The success that individuals seeking new jobs will have in finding them depends on two broad kinds of circumstances: 1. the general balance of demand and supply in the labor market,

and 2. the match between the searchers’ characteristics and those of

the available jobs. • There are two broad categories of approaches to explaining

movements in unemployment that correspond to these two kinds of circumstances.

Page 13: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• One approach emphasizes the heterogeneity of workers and jobs. – Because every worker and every job has unique characteristics,

matching them up through a search process is time consuming. • Search models examine the propensity of employers and job searchers to

achieve matches and how that propensity varies over time. This approach models the flows of workers and jobs between states: a job match that results in a hire transforms an unemployed worker into an employed worker and a vacant job into an occupied one.

• To complete the model, one must examine the other labormarket flows: job creation and destruction, entry to and exit from the labor force, and the flow of separations of existing workers from their jobs.

Page 14: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

– In the search approach, natural unemployment fluctuates when there are changes in the efficiency of matching in the economy or in the other flows between labor market states.

• For example, if structural shifts in the economy make it more difficult to match the characteristics of unemployed workers with those of vacant jobs, then matching will be less efficient and the natural rate of unemployment will increase.

– It should be emphasized that the kind of unemployment described by the search theories does not require a general excess supply of labor.

• It stresses the fact that even when the number of unemployed is equal to the number of job vacancies, neither number is likely to be zero.

Page 15: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The other major approach emphasizes microeconomic imperfections that lead to imbalance between demand and supply in the aggregate labor market, especially to excess labor supply.– These imperfections can be associated with government

interference such as minimum wages and unemployment benefits, or with deviations in the behavior of firms or workers from the assumptions of price-taking competitive markets such as the presence of unions or noncompetitive behavior by employers. This approach often tends to maintain the assumption that labor is a homogeneous good and emphasizes the possibility of a lasting imbalance between demand and supply in the unified labor market.

Page 16: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• One popular model that takes that approach is the efficiency-wage model. – This model is based on the notion that firms pay higher

wages than would normally be necessary in order to attract workers.

– While each firm in an efficiency-wage model wants to pay more than other firms, that obviously cannot happen.

• If all firms offer an efficiency wage, then aggregate wages in the economy are bid up above the market-clearing level and a general excess supply of labor results.

Page 17: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Contract models are based on the observation that labor contracts often forbid firms from changing wages in the short run, but allow them to respond to variations in their need for labor through layoffs and overtime. – A rich literature exists that examines the rationale

for such contracts and their optimal structure.

Page 18: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Another model that follows this approach is the insider-outsider model, where a sharp distinction is drawn between the bargaining status of individuals who are currently working (insiders) and those who are unemployed or out of the labor force (outsiders). This model has been advanced as a promising explanation for the poor performance of labor markets in continental Europe in recent decades.

Page 19: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Minimum Wages and Unemployment

• simple minimum-wage model• The most basic analysis of the minimum wage

proceeds in the way that we would analyze any price floor.

• Assumptions:– labor is assumed to be homogeneous; – all workers participate in the same market and

earn the same wage.

Page 20: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• If the market is Walrasian, then the wage will be w* and the economy will operate with full employment at the level L*.

Page 21: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• If a minimum wage is imposed at a level higher than the equilibrium wage, say at w1, then the market cannot reach equilibrium. Only L workers are hired at w1 and L″ − L ′ ′workers are unemployed.

• What is the effect of MW on employment and unemployment? Is that the same?

• No, they are not of the same magnitude. – Employment falls from L* to L , while unemployment ′ rises (by

more) from zero to L″ − L . ′– This is because the higher wage draws additional workers into

the labor market if the labor-supply curve slopes upward.

Page 22: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The magnitude of unemployment arising out of the minimum wage in this model depends on the elasticity of the labor-supply and labor-demand curves.– If these curves are highly inelastic (steep), then the

unemployment gap is small and the main impact of the minimum wage is to transfer income from consumers (through higher prices of products) or producers (through lower profits, if the product market is not competitive) to workers.

– If labor demand and supply are highly elastic (flat) then there will be a large reduction in employment and a large increase in unemployment.

Page 23: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Beyond its simplistic representation of the labor market, the analysis depicted in Figure 1 is flawed in one important respect: minimum wages are almost always set well below the average wage in the economy, not above it.

• Thus, the minimum wage has no effect on the market at all. – Most workers, including virtually all skilled workers, earn more

than the minimum wage and are not directly impacted by its presence. Some workers, mostly young and unskilled workers, may be affected, however.

• To capture this kind of interaction, we need a segmented model of the labor market that separates skilled from unskilled labor.

Page 24: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• To summarize, effective minimum-wage laws appear to benefit the fraction of unskilled workers that are able to find jobs. They reduce the welfare of those unskilled workers who cannot find employment.

Page 25: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• What does the empirical findings say about the impact of minimum wage?– A lengthy empirical literature has examined the

impact of minimum-wage laws on both employment and unemployment.

– Although there is a considerable range of results, the consensus seems to be that minimum wages have relatively minor employment/ unemployment effects

Page 26: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Unions and Unemployment

• The presence of a labor union that engages in collective bargaining on behalf of workers can alter the nature of the labor market in many ways. Several theories of unemployment incorporate the behavior of unions.– Romer analyzes the insider-outsider model, which

is often thought to represent union behavior

Page 27: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• What do unions do?– While union activities and styles of organization differ

substantially from country to country and over time, unions almost universally raise their members’ wages through the process of collective bargaining.

– But unless unions also raise the marginal product of labor, this will result in a lower level of employment of union labor than would occur in a competitive market.

Page 28: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The structure of labor unions varies considerably across economies.– In some countries, unions are often defined by

industry or by craft.• Ex. United States, Canada, Japan, and UK

– In such cases, wage bargaining is at the enterprise or plant level

– In others, unions are much more centralized. • Ex. Finland, Norway, Australia, and Belgium

– In this case, a single centralized wage bargain affects most of the entire economy.

Page 29: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Case 1: An economy wide union– In this case, wage bargaining is completely centralized – If the union bargains for a real wage higher than the equilibrium

level, employment will fall along the labor-demand curve.– Unemployment will arise as workers seek to obtain union jobs

but are unable to find employers willing to hire them at the union wage.

– Although the model with an economy-wide union seems to be prone to high unemployment, that is not always the case.

• A union that represents the entire work force may recognize that a higher wage demand will reduce employment and that there is nowhere else for those workers to find work.

Page 30: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Case-2: A two-sector model of unions and unemployment– Most countries have a substantial sector of the

economy that is not covered by collective bargaining– In such cases, it seems more realistic to model the

labor market as having two sectors: a union sector and a nonunion sector

• In the union sector, wages are above the equilibrium level due to effective bargaining.

• The nonunion sector functions competitively.

Page 31: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• For simplicity, the demand for labor in the two sectors is assumed to be similar, i.e., the marginal product of labor is the same in the union and nonunion sectors.– When the union increases the wage through bargaining, firms will reduce

employment of union labor. Thus, there may be some initial unemployment in the union sector and a differential between union and nonunion wages.

– Can this situation be sustained in equilibrium, or will demand and supply adjust further? As in the case of the minimum wage, there are possible spillovers between markets that may influence the ultimate equilibrium.

• Supply spillover- wait unemployment• Demand spillover-dd for good for union products decline

• Under this scenario, union power will be eroded over time, perhaps reducing the union wage differential and the share of the work force that is unionized.– There will be little effect of unions on unemployment in the long run if demand

spillovers are important.

Page 32: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Thus, a powerful but not universal union sector can cause wage differentials among industries and a decline in employment in covered industries.

• However, it is unlikely that very much of this decline in employment will result in unemployment.– Only if workers queue for union jobs rather than spilling

over into the nonunion sector will the existence of a union raise the equilibrium unemployment rate.

– Even this effect may diminish over time if substitution on the demand side reduces union power in the long run.

Page 33: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Efficiency-Wage models

• Neoclassical factor demand theory treats the firm as a price taker in labor markets.– No control over wage structure (has no market power).

• It must pay the going wage in order to attract any workers; paying more than that amount is costly and pointless.

– Given the mkt wage, it determines employment level based on the marginal-revenue-product curve .

• the productivity of each worker is determined strictly by the technological factors that underlie the production function.

• Like robots, workers are plugged into the production process and are assumed to do their job regardless of wages, working conditions, or other factors.

Page 34: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The theory of efficiency wages is based on the premise that firms may voluntarily choose to pay more than the market-equilibrium wage for at least some categories of labor.

• Why would a firm choose to do this? – There are four of the most important reasons for

higher wages:

Page 35: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

– First, and most simply, a higher wage can increase worker’s food consumption, and thereby cause them to be better nourished and more productive.

• Obviously this possibility is not important in developed economies. Nonetheless, it provides a concrete example of an advantage of paying a higher wage. For that reason, it is often used as reference point.

Page 36: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

– Second, a higher wage can increase workers’ effort in situations where the firm cannot monitor them perfectly.

• In Walrasian labor market, workers are indifferent about losing their jobs, since identical jobs are immediately available.

– Thus if the only way that firms can punish workers who exert low effort is by firing them, workers in such a labor market have no incentive to exert effort.

• But if the firm pays more than the market clearing wages, its jobs are valuable. Thus its workers may choose to exert effort even if there is some chance they will not be caught if they do not.

Page 37: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

– Third, paying higher wage can improve workers’ ability along dimensions the firm cannot observe.

• Specifically, if higher-ability workers have higher reservation wages, offering a higher wage raises the average quality of the application pool, and thus raises the average ability of workers the firm higher.

– When ability is observable, the can pay higher wages to more able workers; thus observable ability difference do not lead to any departures from the Walrasian case.

Page 38: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

– Finally, a high wage can build loyalty among workers, and hence induce high effort;

• conversely, a low wage can cause anger and desire for revenge, and there by lead to shirking or sabotage.

• Akerlof and Yellen (1990) present extensive evidence that workers’ effort is affected by such forces as anger, jealously, and gratitude.

– For example, they describe studies showing that workers who believe they are underpaid sometimes perform their work in ways that are harder for them in order to reduce their employers’ profits.

Page 39: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

– Other potential advantages of higher wages are:• It can reduce turnover (and recruitment and training

costs, if they are born by the firm); • It can lower the likelihood that workers will unionize; • It may attract a more qualified pool of applicants. • It can raise the utility of managers who have some

ability to pursue objectives other than maximizing profits.

Page 40: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Other compensation schemes

Page 41: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Model of Efficiency Wages

• Assumptions:– There is a large number, N, of identical competitive

firms. – We can think of the number of firms as being determined by the

amount of capital in the economy, which is fixed in the short run.

• The representative firm seeks to maximize its real profits, π which are given by:

---------------------1– Where Y is the firm’s output, w is the real wage that

it pays, and L is the amount of labour it hires.

Page 42: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• A firm’s output depends both on the number of workers it employs and on their effort. – For simplicity we neglect other inputs and assume

that labor and effort enter the production function multiplicatively.

– Thus the representative firm’s output is -----------2

• Where e denotes workers’ effort.

Page 43: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The crucial assumption of efficiency-wage models is that effort depends positively on the wage the firm pays. – In this section we consider the simple case (due to

Solow, 1979) where the wage is the only determinant of effort. Thus,

----------------- 3• Finally, there are L identical workers, each of

whom supplies one unit of labour in elastically.

Page 44: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Note that there are many assumptions that could be used to justify this effort-wage or efficiency-wage relationship. – For example, higher wages may make workers more

content, healthier (if equilibrium wages in the economy are very low), more hard-working, less likely to cause problems for other workers, and less likely to quit.

– Any of these effects raises the worker’s productivity, so the efficiency-wage framework encompasses a fairly broad set of underlying assumptions.

Page 45: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Analyzing the model

• To keep the model as simple as possible, we ignore capital.

• The firm’s real profits (measured in units of the output good) are:

π = Y − wL = F[e(w)L] − wL.• The firm wishes to maximize this profit

function.

Page 46: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• But what are its choice variables? • We are used to firms that take w as given and choose

the profit-maximizing level of L. However, in an efficiency-wage situation, firms are assumed to choose both the wage and the level of employment.

– Thus, the problem facing the representative firm is ------------ 4

Page 47: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Are there any constraints on these choices? • Surely if the firm offers too low a wage it will be unable to

attract as many workers as it wants.

Page 48: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Romer examines two cases. – In the first case, there is unemployment in the

economy and unemployed workers are assumed to be willing to work at any wage that the firm offers. (They have a zero “reservation wage,”)

– In the second, there are no unemployed workers and the firm must offer a wage at least as high as that of other firms.

Page 49: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Case 1: when there is unemployment– In this case, to maximize profit, the firm chooses the values of L and w

that maximize the profit expression.– In this case the firm can choose the wage freely.

• If unemployment is zero, on the other hand, the firm must pay at least the wage paid by other firms.

– When the firm is unconstrained, the first-order conditions for L and w are

----------------- 5

----------------- 6

– and we assume that the second order conditions are satisfied.

Page 50: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• We can rewrite equation 5 as: ……………. 7

• Substitution (7) into (6) and dividing by L yields ……….. 8

– This condition can be interpreted as implying that the elasticity of effort with respect to the wage must equal one when the firm is at the optimal wage and employment level.

Page 51: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• To understand this condition, note that output is a function of the quantity of effective labor, eL. – The firm therefore wants to hire effective labor as cheaply as

possible. When the firm hires a worker, it obtains e(w)units of effective labor at a cost of w; thus the cost per unit of effective labor is w/e(w)

– When the elasticity of e with respect to w is 1, a marginal change in w has no effect on this ration; thus this is the first-order condition for the problem of choosing w to minimize the cost of effective labor.

• The wage satisfying (1.8) is known as the efficiency wage.

Page 52: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The following figure depicts the choice of graphically in (w.e)space. – The rays coming out form the origin are lines where the ration

of e to w is constant; the ratio is larger on the higher rays. Thus the firm wants to choose w to attain as high a ray as possible. This occurs where the e(w) function is just tangent to one of the rays-that is, where the elasticity of w with respect to e is 1.

– Panel (a) shows a case where effort is sufficiently responsive to the wage that over some range the firm prefers a higher wage. Panel (b) shows a case where the firm always prefers a lower wage.

Page 53: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor
Page 54: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Finally, equation (7) states that the firm hires workers until the marginal product of effective labor equals its cost. – This is analogous to the condition in a standard

labor-demand problem that the firm hires labor up to the point where the marginal product equals the wage.

Page 55: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Equations (7) and (8) describe the behavior of a single firm. Describing the economy-wide equilibrium is straightforward. – Let w* and L* denote the values of w and l that satisfy (7) and

(8). – Since firms are identical, each firm chooses these same values of

w and L. – Total labor demand is therefore NL*

• If labor supply, exceeds this amount, firms are unconstrained in their choice of w. In this case the wage is w*. Employment is NL*. And there is unemployment of amount L-NL*. If NL*exceeds L, on the other hand, firms are constrained. In this case, the wage is bid up to the point where demand and supply are in balance, and there is no unemployment.

Page 56: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• i.e., • the economy-wide equilibrium in this model can feature either zero

unemployment (if aggregate labor demand at the efficiency wage is greater than or equal to supply) or positive unemployment (if labor demand is less than supply). Suppose that we are in a positive-unemployment equilibrium. What prevents firms from lowering the wage when unemployed workers come knocking at their doors offering to work for less than what the firm is currently paying? The answer is that they recognize that lowering wages will reduce employee productivity enough to raise labor costs by more than the saving in lower wages. Thus, the usual Walrasian mechanism that would tend to eliminate excess supply in the labor market is disabled in an efficiency-wage model and unemployment can remain indefinitely.

Page 57: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Implications – This model shows how efficiency wages can give rise to

unemployment. – In addition, the model implies that the real wage is unresponsive to

demand shifts. • Suppose the demand for labor increases. Since the efficiency wage, w*is

determined entirely by the properties of the effort function, e(.), there is no reason for firms to adjust their wages. Thus the model provides a candidate explanation of why shifts in labor demand lead to large movements in employment and small changes in the real wage.

– In addition, the fact that the real wage and effort do not change implies that firms’ labor costs do not change.

• As a result, in a model with price-setting firms, the incentive to adjust prices is small.

Page 58: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Unfortunately, these results are less promising than they may appear. – The difficulty is they apply not just to the short run but

to the long run: the model implies that as economic growth shifts out the demand for labor, the real wage remains unchanged an unemployment trends downward. Eventually, unemployment reaches zero at which point further increases in demand lead to increases in the real wage. In practice, however, we observe no clear trend in unemployment over extended periods.

Page 59: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• In other words, the basic fact about the labor market that we need to understand is not just that shifts in labor demand appear to have little impact on the real wage and fall almost entirely on employment in the short run; it is also that they fall almost entirely on the real wage in the long run. The model does not explain this pattern.

Page 60: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

A more General Version• While the simple wage/efficiency link may be appropriate for a

developing country in which higher wages enhance worker efficiency through better health and nutrition, the story is more complicated when the rationale behind the efficiency boost is effort, contentment, or retention. – Even a firm that pays high wages may suffer from low morale if its

wages are low relative to those of other firms in the market. • A worker’s contentment and level of effort probably depends more on her

perception of her wage relative to other firms rather than on the actual level of the wage.

– Similarly, a higher rate of unemployment in the market is likely to cause workers to feel fortunate to have their current jobs and encourage them to work hard in order to retain them.

Page 61: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Thus, with so many potential sources of efficiency wages, the wage is unlike to be the only determinant of effort.

• So, lets adds realism to the model by enriching the effort function to take account of factors other than the firm’s wage that influence worker productivity.

Page 62: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Thus a natural generalization of the effort function,(3), is

…………. 9where wa is the wage paid by other firms in the market and u is the unemployment rate• Effort is increasing in the firm’s own wage but decreasing in the

wage of other firms. • An increase in unemployment, other things being equal, raises

effort.

Page 63: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Each firm is small relative to the economy, and therefore takes and as given.

• The representative firm’s problem is the same as before, except that and u now affect the effort function. – The first-order conditions can therefore be rearranged to

obtain …………….. 10

…………… 11

-

Page 64: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• These conditions are analogous to (1.7) and (1.8) in the simpler version of the model.

– Since wa and u are exogenous to the individual firm, the first-order conditions for setting the wage and employment level will not change, except that they will now depend explicitly on the alternative wage and unemployment rate.

• Assume that the e(.) function is sufficiently well behaved that there is a unique optimal w for a given wa and u. – Given this assumption, equilibrium requires; w=wa; if not, each firm

wants to pay a wage different from the prevailing wage. Let w* and L* denote the values of w and L satisfying (10) – (11) with w=wa.

– As before, if NL* is less than L, the equilibrium wage is w* and there is unemployment of amount L-NL*.

– And if NL* exceeds L, the wage is bid up and the labor market clears.

Page 65: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

– This extended version of the model has promise for accounting for both the absence of any trend in unemployment over the long run and the fact that shifts in labor demand appear to have large effects on unemployment in the short run. This is most easily seen by means of an example, based on Summers

– Numerical example is available on Romer (pp:447-

Page 66: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The efficiency model (or the model given in the example) will generally result in positive unemployment. – The intuition behind this result is straightforward.

• Each firm would like to pay an efficiency wage higher than its peers in order to elicit greater effort from its workers.

• In equilibrium, all firms pay the same wage, so no individual firm can encourage effort by paying more than others. However, as all firms bid up wages, the quantity of labor demanded falls below the quantity supplied, leaving some workers unemployed.

• The existence of this unemployment serves as a motivation to workers to work hard, since it increases the cost of losing their jobs. Thus, although each firm attempts to pay an efficiency wage in order to motivate workers to greater effort, it is the higher unemployment that results from these wage hikes that eventually serves that role.

Page 67: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Apart from the existence of equilibrium unemployment, the efficiency-wage model can explain one other observed anomaly. – In a competitive labor market, given parameters values that are

reasonable, we should see large fluctuations in real wages and only minor variations in employment when business cycles occur.

– In a market with efficiency wages, changes in the general level of product demand that cause fluctuations in labor demand may result in large changes in employment with relatively stable real wages. This seems more consistent with observed business cycles than the implications of the competitive, Walrasian model.

Page 68: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

The Shapiro-Stiglitz model• Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984) entitled their paper “Equilibrium

unemployment as a worker discipline device.” – This idea clearly fits in well with the model of the previous section: high

unemployment encourages greater effort. • The Shapiro-Stiglitz model is a specific application of efficiency

wages in which workers have an incentive to shirk (not work hard). Firms, obviously, would like to assure that workers instead exert high effort and thus achieve high productivity. – If the firm can monitor worker performance at no cost, then it can

simply insist on its desired level of effort as a condition of employment and fire workers who shirk. The level of performance required and the wage would be set jointly at levels that would assure that the firm could attract workers.

Page 69: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• However, the more interesting and realistic case is one in which firms cannot directly observe individual workers’ effort. Instead, there is a given probability (less than one) that a shirking worker will be caught and fired.

• Thus, workers must decide whether to shirk or to work hard by balancing the increased utility of shirking against the probability of being caught and fired. – However, the worker’s incentives depend in an important way on what happens to

fired workers. If they can simply move immediately to another firm and shirk, then there is no real cost to being caught and no incentive to work hard. In order to motivate hard work, the fired shirker must lose something by being fired. In the spirit of the previous model, the fired worker either loses a wage premium (efficiency wage) offered by the employer or faces the prospect of an unemployment spell.

– Since all firms offer the same wage in equilibrium, it must be the existence of unemployment that gives workers an incentive to work hard. Hence the title “equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device.”

Page 70: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Assumptions– The economy consists of a large number of

workers, L, and a large number of firms, N. The workers maximize their expected discounted utilities, and firms maximize their expected discounted profits. The model is set in continuous time. For simplicity, the analysis focuses on steady states.

Page 71: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Consider workers first. • The representative worker’s lifetime utility is • …………… 22

where u(t) is instantaneous utility at time t, ρ and is the discount rate.

………23 Where w is the wage and e is the worker’s effort. There are

only two possible effort levels, e=0 and e=e

Page 72: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Thus at any moment a worker must be in one of three states: – employed and working hard (state E),

• in which case they have instantaneous utility equal to w(t) − e .

– employed but shirking (state S),• i.e., they are exerting zero effort, and hence their utility

is w(t).– unemployed (state U)

• Unemployed workers get utility of zero

Page 73: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The highest utility comes from being employed but shirking, but workers can remain in that state only until their shirking behavior is discovered, at which point they are fired and become unemployed.

Page 74: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The formal analysis of the Shapiro-Stiglitz model introduces us to the concept of hazard rates, which have become a popular tool for analysis of economic situations in which agents must predict when or if a particular event will occur. – Hazard-rate models first evolved from the actuarial literature of

the insurance industry (hence the name “hazard” that is attached). These models represent the probability that a particular event will occur during a period of time of given length by a hazard function.

– The hazard rate b is the instantaneous probability of changing from one state to another.

Page 75: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• A key ingredient of the model is its assumptions concerning workers’ transitions among the three states.– The model has three hazard rates;

• b is the probability that the job of an employed worker who is not shirking will end,

• q is the probability that a shirking worker will be caught and fired, and

• a is the probability that an unemployed worker will find a job

Page 76: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• These probabilities govern the transition of workers between states. The only decision that workers make in the model is whether to work or to shirk when they are employed. As in other efficiency-wage models, firms maximize profit by setting a wage level and employment level to maximize profit.

• The key difference between this model and the simpler efficiency-wage models is that the e(w, wa, u) function is endogenously determined: – workers decide whether to work hard or shirk as a function of their

wage and the unemployment rate. – Similarly, the hiring rate a is determined endogenously by the

balance of demand and supply in the aggregate labor market.

Page 77: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Let’s specify the hazard rates:– there is an exogenous rate at which jobs end

– firms detection of workers who are shirking is also a Poisson process

• q is exogenous, and detection is independent of job breakups.

– Thus if a worker is employed and not shirking, the probability that he or she is still employed time τ later is e-qτ (the probability that the worker has not been caught and fired) times e-bτ (the probability that the job has not ended exogenously).

Page 78: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

– unemployed workers find employment at rate a per unit time. Each worker takes a as given.

– In the economy as a whole, however, a is determined endogenously.

– When firms want to hire workers, they choose workers at random out of the pool of unemployed workers. Thus a is determined by the rate at which firms are hiring (which is determined by the number of employed workers and the rate at which jobs end) and the number of unemployed workers.

– Because workers are identical, the probability of finding a job does not depend on how workers become unemployed of on how long they are unemployed.

Page 79: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Firms’ behavior is straightforward. A firm’s profits at are

…….. 25Where L is the number o employees who are exerting effort and S is the numbers who are shirking.

• The problem facing the firm is to set w sufficiently high that its workers do not shirk, and to choose L .

Page 80: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Because the firm’s decisions at any date affect profits only at that date, there is no need to analyze the present value of profits: the firm chooses w and L at each moment to maximize the instantaneous flow of profits.

Page 81: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The Values of E , U , and S • …………………………………………..

Page 82: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Implicit-contract models

• This is the second departure from Walrasian assumption– This model recognizes the existence of long term

relationship between firms and workers– Firms do not hire workers afresh each period,

instead many jobs involve long-term attachement and considerable firm specific skills on the part of workers

• How long did the current pay rate remain constant?

Page 83: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The possibility of long term relationship implies that the wage does not have to adjust to clear the labor market each period. – Workers are content to stay in their current jobs as

long as the income streams they expect to obtain are preferable to their outside opportunities; because of their long term relationships with their employers, the current wage may be relatively unimportant to the comparison.

Page 84: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The essence of the model is that workers are risk averse while the firm is assumed to be risk neutral. – In this situation, it is mutually beneficial for the firm to offer

implicit insurance to workers in the form of contracts that reduce the sensitivity of workers’ incomes in response to fluctuations in labor demand.

– In exchange for this insurance, workers accept lower wages than they would otherwise demand.

– There is a mutual gain since the firm (which does not care about risk) raises its expected profit but incurs more risk, and the workers reduce risk enough to more than offset the utility lost from lower expected incomes.

Page 85: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

The model

• Consider a firm with dealing with a group of workers.

• The firm’s profit are

Page 86: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Consider a single period and assume that A is random– Thus, when workers decide whether to work for

the firm, they consider the expected utility they obtain the single period given the randomness in A, rather than the average utility they obtain over many periods as their income and hours vary in response to fluctuations in A

Page 87: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Page 88: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• With a discrete probability distribution over finite set of alternative states of the world Ai, the expected value of profit and the expected value of utility are just summations across outcomes of the probability of each outcome times the profit or utility under that outcome.

Page 89: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The above last equation implies that the representative worker’s expected utility is

Page 90: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Wage contracts: simple but common forms of contract– Let’s consider the case where the contract specified the

wage and the firm choose employment once A is determined.

– In such contracts unemployment and real wage rigidity arise immediately

– Example: A fall in labor DD cause the firm to reduce employment at the fixed real wage while labor SS does not shift, which creates unemployment.

• Here the cost of labor does not respond because, by assumption, the real wage is fixed

Page 91: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• But this is not a satisfactory explanations and real wage rigidity. The difficulty is that this type of contract is inefficient.– Firms choose employment taking wage as given– The MPL is independent of A– Employment varies with A, the marginal disutility of

working depends on A– Thus, the marginal product of labor is generally not

equal to the marginal disutility of work.• So it is possible to make both parties to contract better-off.

Page 92: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Ex: – if labor SS is not very elastic, the inefficiency is large– When labor demand is low, the marginal disutility of work

is low, and so the firm and the workers could both be made better off if the workers worked slightly more

• Thus, we can appeal to fixed-wage contracts with unemployment determination at the firm’s discretion as a potential explanation of unemployment and real wage rigidity only if we can explain why a firm and its workers would agree to such an arrangement

Page 93: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

Insider-Outsider Models

• The insider-outsider model is a variation on the contract model that recognizes that the firm and a certain group of senior workers (continuing workers, perhaps) may conspire to improve their conditions jointly at the expense of less senior workers (new hires).

Page 94: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The Model:– There are two group of workers:

• The Insiders-are workers who have some connection with the firm at the time of the bargaining, and whose interest are taken in to account in the contract.

• The Outsiders-are workers who have no initial connection with the firm but who may be hired after the contract is set

– The firm and the insider bargains over wage and employment

– Hours are fixed, so labor input can vary only through change in the number of workers

Page 95: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The firm’s profit are:

– Because of normal employment growth and turnover, most of the time the insiders are fully employed and the only hiring decision concerns how many outsiders to hire.

Page 96: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Assume that LI always equal LI

• Since the insiders are always employed, their utility depends only on their wage:

• Second:– The wages paid to the two types of workers cannot be set

independently• The higher WI, the higher Wo will be

• Assume that Wo rises one-for one with WI

Page 97: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Assume that outsiders have sufficient bargaining power and that the gap between insider and outsider wages (c) is sufficiently small that the firm always able to hire as many new workers at WI-C as it wants.– Like the one facing strong union

• Now, the firm’s choice variables can be WI and Lo in each state. This is because:– Wo is detrmined by WI and equation (x) above.– LI is fixed at LI

Page 98: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The firm must provide the insider with expected utility of at least U0. the Lagrangian for the firm’s problem is thus:

• The FOC for Loi is

Or

Page 99: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The last equation is just as the conventional labor demand problem: employment is chosen to equate the MP of labor with wage

• Note that the implication of this equation is in sharp contrast to what happens with implicit contracts:– This is because outsiders, who are the workers relevant to the

marginal employment decision, are not involved in the original bargaining.

– The insiders and the firm act to maximize their joint surplus. They, therefore agree to hire outsiders upto the point where their marginal product equals the wage they must be paid; the outsiders preferences are irrelevant to this calculation.

Page 100: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The FOC for WIi is

• This implies that

• Since Loi is higher in good states (during good economic times, more workers will be employed), this last equation implies that:– U’(WIi) is higher→WIi is lower

• i.e., the wage is counter cyclical

Page 101: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The critical assumption of the model is that the outsiders’ and insiders’ wage are linked. Without this link, the firm can hire outsiders at the prevailing economy-wide wage.– Thus, insider and outsider considerations have potentially

important implications only if a link between outsiders’ and insiders’ wage can be established.

Page 102: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The conclusion in this model is that– insiders and the firm arrange employment conditions so that

outsiders are hired according to the usual marginal product condition, with no effective insurance via contract.

– When productivity is low, outsiders will lose their jobs.• It is worth noting in passing that the labor-market structures

of many European countries encourage this insider-outsider distinction. – For example, to combat terribly high unemployment (over 20%)

and low hiring rates, Spain passed laws allowing new workers to be hired under temporary arrangements, while existing workers could not be fired without incurring high separation costs.

Page 103: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• The Blanchard and Summers model extends the idea of insiders and outsiders by allowing the number of insiders to change with shocks to productivity. – In this situation, there will be no tendency for

employment and unemployment to revert to “natural” levels.

– Employment in the economy will tend to follow a random walk, with the currently employed (insiders) protecting their employment status but reluctant to lower wages to bring in any outsiders.

Page 104: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

• Unemployment:– If the entire labor market is characterized by

insider power, greater insider power reduces employment by raising the wage and causing firms to move up their labor demand curve.

• Thus in this case the insider-outsider distinction provides a candidate explanation of unemployment.

– The more realistic case, however, is for there to be insider power only in part of the labor market, with the rest relatively competitive

Page 105: Labor Markets and Unemployment. The labor market determines the equilibrium price of labor - the wage rate, by bringing together the demand for labor

– In the latter case:• Insider power even increases average unemployment

– This is because, workers try to obtain jobs in high paying sectors.

– Workers laid-off from high paying sectors are reluctant to return to their old jobs and accept longer spells of unemployment

– New entrants to the labor force are reluctant to accept jobs in the competitive sector