introduction to briefing papers on usaid’s economic growth objective · 2010. 12. 10. ·...

23
INTRODUCTION TO BRIEFING PAPERS ON USAID’S ECONOMIC GROWTH OBJECTIVE Arnold C. Harberger May 2010 These briefing papers were written in order to bring to a wide readership a better understanding of how promoting economic growth in recipient countries serves the broader aims of the U.S. foreign aid program, and how USAID’s activities contribute to the achievement of this goal. The papers are not intended as executive summaries, condensing masses of material into a paragraph or a page. Instead, they try to give readers an insider’s view. They try to communicate many of the subtleties and complications that are encountered in the actual implementation of foreign aid programs. They try to share with readers the complex linkages that connect foreign aid programs at one end of the chain to host government policies and actions, and ultimately to the end result of greater economic growth and the many benefits it brings to the affected population. And finally they try to give readers a fuller understanding of the growth process itself. Briefing Note #1, entitled “Economic Growth Challenge” sets out the reasons why economic growth has been and should continue to be a pillar of our foreign aid programs. Economic growth has been the most important catalyst helping millions of people, all over the world, to escape from poverty. It has enhanced the role of women and fostered individual initiative and energy. In general it has been accompanied by sounder economic policies that

Upload: others

Post on 03-Feb-2021

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • INTRODUCTION TO BRIEFING PAPERS ON

    USAID’S ECONOMIC GROWTH OBJECTIVE

    Arnold C. Harberger

    May 2010

    These briefing papers were written in order to bring to a wide readership a better

    understanding of how promoting economic growth in recipient countries serves the broader aims

    of the U.S. foreign aid program, and how USAID’s activities contribute to the achievement of

    this goal. The papers are not intended as executive summaries, condensing masses of material

    into a paragraph or a page. Instead, they try to give readers an insider’s view. They try to

    communicate many of the subtleties and complications that are encountered in the actual

    implementation of foreign aid programs. They try to share with readers the complex linkages

    that connect foreign aid programs at one end of the chain to host government policies and

    actions, and ultimately to the end result of greater economic growth and the many benefits it

    brings to the affected population. And finally they try to give readers a fuller understanding of

    the growth process itself.

    Briefing Note #1, entitled “Economic Growth Challenge” sets out the reasons why

    economic growth has been and should continue to be a pillar of our foreign aid programs.

    Economic growth has been the most important catalyst helping millions of people, all over the

    world, to escape from poverty. It has enhanced the role of women and fostered individual

    initiative and energy. In general it has been accompanied by sounder economic policies that

  • have supported advances in education and health, and have furthered competition, innovation

    and enhanced productivity in the private sector.

    Note #1 also points out very early that USAID’s activities supporting economic growth

    have yielded “high returns on the aid dollar”. This brings up a point which I have repeatedly

    emphasized in other contexts. Business people characterize their projects in terms of the rate of

    return that they generate, and individuals assess their portfolios in this way. These also are the

    terms in which we should think when we try to evaluate government spending of many types,

    including foreign aid projects aimed at promoting growth. This last assertion may be obvious to

    most people, but many still remain who seem to be thinking in other terms when they are

    assessing the worth of foreign aid. Thus one all too frequently finds intimations that aid has

    failed if the recipient country’s growth rate has not bounced to the 5-7 percent range. Clearly

    such thoughts are not even remotely based on a “rate of return” framework. An aid project or

    program amounting to 1% of the recipient country’s real income should be judged successful if it

    raises that level by a tenth of a percent. This would mean a 10% real rate of return on that aid

    investment. And such a rate of return would meet the rigorous criterion for successful public

    investment that the World Bank has imposed over the past 50-odd years. To put the matter

    bluntly, if we invest 1% of (say $1000) of our income, we should be happy if as a consequence

    our income increases by $100 per year (a tenth of a percent). It would be almost a miracle for an

    investment of $1000 to end up yielding an annual return of $1000 (100% per year). So when

    thinking about aid’s impact on growth we have to measure the results in relation to the amount

    invested (by USAID alone, or by USAID plus other contributors).

    In assessing the results of foreign aid programs, particularly those aimed at promoting

    growth, it is only very rarely that a program’s individual contribution to growth can be isolated.

    2

  • This might work for a project introducing a new crop in a certain region of the country, where

    the specific costs and returns of the operation can be separately identified and quantified. But

    much of the time a given project will represent only one of many different forces working to

    improve economic performance, so that we have to resort to indirect measures in order to

    estimate the project’s specific contribution. And even here we often encounter deficiencies in

    the statistical data we have to work with, limitations of the available statistical techniques, and

    the very common problem of isolating “our” project’s specific contribution. Special problems

    also arise in the cases of projects of policy reform and institutional capacity building. Here it is

    quite easy to assess the specific results of the project -- the actual change in policy, the actual

    institutional change -- but hard to go from these to the project’s ultimate impact on the future

    course of GDP or some other measure of public benefit.

    Briefing Note #2 deals with the concept of economic growth. This is not as simple a

    matter as it may at first appear, because our standard measure of growth -- the increase in real

    gross domestic project (GDP) -- does not capture all the facets of growth that might be

    considered relevant. The mere discovery of a mineral deposit may add greatly to the perceived

    wealth of a nation, but it does not add to its GDP until its reserves are actually extracted.

    Reductions in infant mortality and increases in the expected lifespan of men and women are

    other manifestations of increased welfare that are not directly reflected in GDP. And various

    other types of perceived improvement in welfare -- such as reducing the incidence of poverty or

    expanding the reach of education -- can in principle take place even in the absence of an

    improvement in per capita GDP.

    Yet when all is said and done, GDP remains as our most reliable single indicator of

    economic performance. The newly discovered mineral deposit may not add to GDP right now,

    3

  • but it certainly is likely to do so over its productive lifetime. And if it does not do so (as would

    be the case of the value of the ore that was extracted ended up being less than the economic costs

    of extracting it), the operation is clearly not worthwhile.

    Many studies have also shown that most of the other measures of welfare (reductions in

    poverty and infant mortality, increased longevity, improved education, nutrition, housing and

    medical care) are all strongly linked to GDP per capita. Note #2 compares the experiences of

    Haiti and Chile. It reveals vast differences in welfare over the last half century, mostly generated

    by the different growth rates of the two countries in the period since World War II. Korea is also

    cited as an outstanding example of the fruits of economic growth. Many people are not aware of

    the fact that living standards in Korea were not much different from those of Haiti and Ghana in

    1960. Five decades of spectacular growth in GDP per capita have been the main force that

    transformed Korea into a modern economy.

    It is difficult to expound on the merits of GDP as a measure of growth without seeming to

    anoint it with an aura of perfection. One should always bear in mind that no single measure will

    ever capture all the richness of a complex phenomenon or process. So when we measure and

    observe GDP growth we should also pause to reflect on the whole process of growth and on the

    way societies tend to evolve as growth takes place. Economic growth tends to free people from

    drudgery. It provides greater opportunity for cultural and educational pursuits. It generates

    greater possibilities for people to become involved in the political process, and broadly speaking

    is associated with more open and democratic political arrangements. In addition, women tend to

    become more centrally involved in both the productive and the political process in economies

    enjoying good economic growth.

    4

  • Institutions are another important element in the story of growth. Schools and

    universities expand both in number and in quality as economic growth proceeds. The institutions

    of the financial sector tend to grow more than in proportion to GDP. Almost as a necessity, the

    quality of a country’s police and judicial institutions has to keep pace with its economic

    development (the economy cannot function well enough to grow rapidly if these institutions

    cannot provide adequate support). Similarly, the press and other communications media almost

    necessarily play a larger role as an economy develops.

    But the linkages between economic growth and all these associated benefits are not

    perfect. Authoritarian governments have survived long periods of growth. Indeed, a few of

    them (e.g., Singapore) have been remarkably successful in fostering it, but where this is true they

    have not stood in the way of good economic policies and of institutional arrangements (other

    than some basically political ones) that are supportive of growth.

    But one thing should be clear -- the engines of growth are not likely to make everybody

    happier. By its nature economic growth has losers as well as winners. The biggest driving

    forces behind the growth process -- innovation and real cost reduction -- work through newer and

    cheaper methods displacing older and more expensive ones. Those who are tied to the old way

    of doing things by habit or tradition or even mere location (as with certain agricultural crops and

    methods) will tend to suffer as their methods of production or even their way of life is rendered

    obsolete. This can happen even in the most well-ordered and well-functioning growth scenario.

    But growth can also work to the detriment of people when its fruits are plundered by a rapacious

    elite. When this occurs it is usually connected to major mineral discoveries whose profits are

    then captured by a ruling (often military) elite and used for its own private benefit. But please

    5

  • note that it makes no sense to put the blame for this on anybody but the culprits -- it certainly

    isn’t the growth process that is at fault.

    Briefing Note #3 focuses on how economic growth typically works to reduce the

    incidence of poverty and to enhance society’s welfare in important dimensions. The worldwide

    record clearly shows how high levels of poverty are mainly observed in low-income countries,

    and how these levels tend to fall sharply as such countries advance, even if only to lower-middle-

    income status. But it is also true that the incidence of poverty is subject to many other influences

    in addition to per capita income. Yet growth is still the strongest and most pervasive force

    working to promote the escape from poverty. One often encounters in the public media the idea

    that with economic growth “the rich get richer and the poor get poorer”. There is no plausible

    evidence to support such a thought. Extensive studies (particularly by David Dollar and Art

    Kraay) have shown that there is no tendency whatever for the incomes of the poor (the bottom

    fifth of the population) to fall as overall GDP per capita surges. On average the share in total

    GDP of this bottom quintile actually tends to increase somewhat in the process of growth,

    indicating that their incomes typically improve by a greater-than-average percentage as growth

    proceeds.

    In other dimensions of welfare and human development the correlation with income per

    capita is also extremely strong. Infant mortality falls, people become better educated and live

    longer and healthier lives. Women shed many traditional burdens and take on positive new

    responsibilities. Many of these welfare dividends of economic growth also serve, in a sort of

    virtuous circle, as promoters of still further growth.

    Efforts by countries to deal with their poverty problems should in general be applauded,

    but care should be taken in the choice of policies aimed at this objective. I would call attention

    6

  • to two potential traps -- that of “handout” regimes that develop a passive dependency on the part

    of the recipients, and that of policies focusing too heavily on incentives to capital. On the first

    we recall the old proverb that “it is better to teach a man how to fish rather then to give him a

    fish to eat every day”. This proverb carries a strong lesson, but one must recognize that cases do

    appear in which the immediate alternative to a handout is starvation. Such cases give strong

    backing to the idea of strictly humanitarian aid. Yet one must always be mindful of the fact that

    such aid, by sitting in the sidelines with respect to growth promotion, has no natural termination

    date.

    On the second trap I can do no better than recall Brazil’s program of investment

    incentives for the poverty-stricken northeast and Amazon regions of the country. This program

    was initially aimed at dealing with the chronic problems of low wages, of unemployment and of

    underemployment in these regions. It mainly operated through the forgiveness of corporation

    income taxes arising out of private investments approved for execution under the program. The

    problem was that this incentive was concentrated on the capital factor, and was therefore

    stronger, the more capital-intensive was the covered investment. It is said that one of the first

    investments approved under the program was a petrochemical plant in Recife, in which the

    greater part of the wages bill went to pay chemists, engineers and other technicians brought in

    from the prosperous Sao Paulo area. After the entire program had been functioning for some 15

    years, the sum total of new jobs authorized under its aegis was less than one year’s natural

    increase in the labor force of the affected regions!! This case calls attention to perhaps the

    greatest maxim of all concerning public policy. Policies are only good when their benefits

    exceed their costs; hence major (expensive) policies deserve careful analysis and planning in

    order to ensure this result.

    7

  • Even though GDP growth is far from being the only force operating to reduce poverty

    and advance human welfare in a country, the force with which it works in these directions is

    truly impressive. Note #3 cites the cases of Zambia and Indonesia. Zambia’s level of GDP per

    capita far exceeded Indonesia’s in 1970, and Zambia was ahead on the other main welfare

    indicators as well. But by 2005 Indonesia’s GDP per capita had quadrupled while Zambia’s had

    actually fallen, and Indonesia’s poverty rate had been brought down to only a quarter of

    Zambia’s. The key difference was the conduct of economic policy in the two countries.

    Indonesia’s was managed by a notable team of technocrats (the “Berkeley Mafia”), well founded

    in economic fundamentals and strongly supported by USAID and others. In contrast, Zambia’s

    policy departed from the messages of good economic policy in almost every direction, falling

    prey to a local variant of populist interventionism known as African Humanism. The study notes

    that this comparison is by no means a one-off event. One could pick any of a number of

    successful growth performances (China, Botswana, Mauritius, Korea, Chile) and juxtapose it to

    any one of a number of laggard economies (Haiti, Moldova, Cameroon, Madagascar, South

    Africa) and come to exactly the same conclusion.

    The conclusion of Note #3 is that sound economic policy should be an important pillar of

    any effort to promote economic and human development. Good policy should pay attention to

    spreading the reach of education, medical care, and public health measures. These aims can be

    justified in their own right, but it should be noted that they also contribute positively to a

    country’s economic performance. They therefore are useful complements to more strictly

    efficiency-oriented objectives such as fiscal reform, improved public investment appraisal, trade

    liberalization and financial deepening.

    8

  • Note #4 deals with policy actions that can be taken to promote growth. Here I believe the

    most important lesson is that policy only rarely affects growth directly. Its influence is indirect

    and can work through many different channels. I came to this realization by studying the

    technical details of the growth process. When economists study economic growth they typically

    (since around 1950) decompose the rate of growth into three main components -- a labor

    contribution, a capital contribution, and a third one due to what I call “real cost reduction” but

    which in the literature bears a number of different names -- “technical advance,” “improvement

    in total factor productivity”, “the fruits of innovation”, etc.

    The labor component of the growth rate can in turn be broken down into two main pieces

    -- additions to the labor force and improvements in its quality. The capital contribution likewise

    can be split into a part due to the amount of net investment and a second part due to the

    productivity (rate of return) to be expected from that investment. Real cost reduction explains

    the remainder of growth -- that is not accounted for by the labor and capital components.

    Just by thinking about this decomposition of the growth rate, one can see that it can be

    applied not only to the growth in a country’s overall GDP but also to that of its major sectors

    (agriculture, manufacturing, services, etc.), to individual industrial classifications whether big

    (like automobiles or textiles) or small (like ladies’ dresses or men’s shoes), and even down to the

    individual enterprise or even the individual product lines of a given firm.

    Thinking about the growth decomposition in this way, one quickly recognizes that the

    place where growth takes place is in the individual enterprise and that: 1) adding to the quantity

    of labor used by an enterprise, 2) hiring skilled rather than unskilled workers, 3) making

    decisions to invest so as to increase the capital stock, 4) finding investments of higher

    productivity, and 5) discovering ways to save costs -- all these things are what the owners of

    9

  • small enterprises and the management teams of large ones are constantly engaged in. Once this

    is recognized, one’s next natural reaction is the realization that there is little direct connection

    between the policy decisions that are taken in the halls of government and those millions upon

    millions of separate decisions of hiring, firing, investment and real cost reduction that are taking

    place in thousands upon thousands of productive entities throughout the economy.

    Seeing this, one quickly recognizes that the role of economic policy is indirect -- policy

    does not make growth, but certainly may and without doubt can influence it in both the negative

    and the positive direction. Some governments have created a policy environment conducive to a

    flowering of the forces of growth, while others have produced policies that have led these forces

    to wither. Note #4 lists (in exhibit 2) a number of policy categories and objectives that usually

    work to build an environment favorable to growth. Among them are 1) improving and

    expanding infrastructure, 2) maintaining macroeconomic stability, 3) investing in education

    and health services, 4) disseminating information on market opportunities and relevant

    technologies, 5) implementing financial market reforms, 6) reducing barriers to trade, 7)

    simplifying regulations and bureaucratic procedures, 8) making the tax system and its

    administration more efficient, 9) creating a legal and institutional setting that keeps corruption

    under control, 10) maintaining a sustainable budget profile, a competitive exchange rate and a

    sound banking system, 11) strengthening institutions to protect property rights, enforce

    contracts and control crime, 12) providing a clear framework of rules and procedures (as

    against administrative discretion) covering investments and other business operations, 13)

    respecting human rights, 14) establishing accountable governance and 15) developing

    effective processes for dispute resolution.

    10

  • Commenting on this list, I would say first of all that it would be hard to find a serious

    development economist who would raise objections to it. Yet some would probably want to add

    emphasis to some points or add a few others. This merely reflects the facts that each item in

    such a list is really a huge umbrella, covering a wide range of potential policies and government

    actions. Such a list calls attention to how enormous is the task, and how the job is probably

    never going to be really completed.

    Moreover, a careful scrutiny of the list makes it clear that serious mistakes can be made

    even as one appears to be following one or another of its maxims. One can build infrastructure

    projects that are ill-designed and too expensive, so that their benefits are not large enough to

    justify their costs. And so it goes with other rubrics -- education initiatives, health programs,

    deregulation moves, etc. can turn out to have very positive results, but they can also turn out to

    have benefits that are too small to warrant their costs.

    What does this tell us? It tells us that the task of providing a good policy framework goes

    far beyond a list of sensible maxims. Note #4 goes on to emphasize the need for investments to

    be efficient and competitive, the desirability of a tax system that treats alternative investments

    even-handedly, and the usefulness of a policy environment which does not discriminate against

    foreign investment. One could go on almost indefinitely, bringing in more and more detail and

    concreteness. But the real message is that the maxims are perfectly good and sensible, but they

    do not themselves provide justification for any specific set of policies or actions. Such actions

    must be studied individually and carefully before reaching the conclusion that they will

    contribute to an environment that is supportive of economic growth.

    When all the complexities and possibilities of error in economic policymaking are taken

    into account, it is small wonder that many countries have faltered or stumbled along the way.

    11

  • This can stem partly simply from a lack of adequate knowledge and expertise or from the

    absence of a reliable and competent cadre of civil servants. But failure can also stem from the

    heavy hand of social traditions and norms that resist rationalization and modernization, and from

    entrenched elites whose power and status is threatened by the openness, transparency, and social

    mobility that are key elements in a favorable growth environment.

    Problems of the types just mentioned create a very useful role for external assistance to

    developing countries. These problems help to highlight why developing countries do not usually

    respond well to “one size fits all” recipes for economic policy reform -- even when the

    standardized policy package is well designed from a technical point of view. The trouble is that

    such packages usually run afoul of deeply entrenched traditions or fail to enlist the support of

    key stakeholder groups. The bottom line here is that a good program of foreign aid usually

    requires a good deal of tailoring-to-measure in order to suit the specific needs and overcome the

    specific obstacles in a given country. As Note #4 says “taking into account each country’s

    unique history, culture, economic structure and resources, donors need to study the constraints

    and opportunities particular to each situation.” Decisions on identification, design, sequencing

    and measures of reform have to be “country specific”. This is where USAID has special

    advantages due to its presence on the ground, usually over a long prior history, its direct

    involvement with the individuals and groups like to be affected by a program of reform, and its

    relative agility in responding to new challenges and opportunities.

    Briefing Note #6 deals with the economic impact of projects, programs or policies. In

    many cases this boils down to applying the standard procedures of economic cost-benefit

    analysis, which will be described in more detail below. But the lack of adequate data, the

    imprecision of our estimates and forecasts, or what is often the near impossibility of attributing a

    12

  • specific flow of benefits to a particular project or program, can make it necessary to resort to less

    technical, more descriptive language in assessing its worth.

    The idea behind economic impact studies, and behind cost-benefit analysis in general, is

    to try to prevent public funds from being badly allocated or at worst, even just wasted. It is hard

    to quarrel with this laudable objective, but its execution is far harder than just stating the

    principle. But before embarking on a survey of the methodology and its challenges, I want to

    emphasize that, no matter how great are the difficulties of identifying and measuring them, it is a

    big step forward simply to spend some time and energy trying to think sensibly and rationally

    about the costs and benefits of a project or program. Technical challenges and difficulties are no

    excuse for simply routinely approving projects ex ante or for just bypassing the possibility of an

    evaluation ex post!!

    Standard cost-benefit analysis is a branch of applied welfare economics whose roots go

    back at least to the 18th century. Its underlying principles lie behind the economic arguments

    favoring competition, free trade and free entry. They also underlie much of what the economics

    profession has to say about how best to organize a country’s tax system. The application of these

    principles to the evaluation of investment projects has its roots around the 1920s but reached its

    fuller development starting in the 1950s and 1960s. By now the analytical framework of cost-

    benefit analysis is well developed, and is regularly applied in the evaluation of public investment

    projects in an increasing number of countries.

    The framework of cost-benefit analysis builds on the construction of two histories -- what

    the relevant “world” would look like, one “with” the program or project under review, and the

    other “without” it. Looking forward in an ex ante analysis thus requires a quantification of the

    stream of costs and benefits, with and without the project, going from the date of the earliest

    13

  • outlays on the project up to the expected termination of its economic life. This is relatively easy

    to do for a highway improvement or an addition to an electricity grid (where the expected results

    of our project are compared to meeting the same energy demands at the expected normal

    alternative cost per kilowatt hour). It is far more difficult to do for a program of trade

    liberalization or for an agricultural research station. In an ex post review of an existing project,

    one needs to look backward and try to specify what the relevant piece of the world would have

    looked like if the project had never been undertaken. Yet more complicated are programs like

    judicial reform or village social services.

    Standard cost-benefit analysis does not even attempt to break down the costs and benefits

    of a project by source of funds. It rarely makes sense to split up a project’s benefits into a part

    due to USAID’s contribution, a part due to funds from other donors, and a part due to the

    recipient country’s own funds used to finance it. It usually makes more sense to assess the

    overall benefit of the project, and then to arbitrarily distribute this amount in proportion to the

    contributions coming from the various sources.

    Sometimes a project or program will result in a significant increase or reduction in

    government revenues. In such cases, modern cost-benefit analysis places a percentage premium

    (on added inflows of cash) and an equivalent percentage penalty (on added outflows). The

    rationale behind this treatment is based on the fact that getting an extra rupee or peso of tax

    revenue entails two kinds of costs -- first, the administrative costs of collection and second, the

    efficiency costs due to the distortions that added taxes typically introduce into the economic

    system. Such a premium/penalty rate is hard to estimate even for advanced countries, and even

    more difficult in developing economies. But it is clearly a mistake to proceed on the assumption

    that these costs do not exist. The immediate “solution” to this problem is to adopt an estimate of

    14

  • “extra economic cost per peso/rupee of extra tax revenue” which is clearly conservative. Most

    economists who have worked in this area would probably agree that a premium/penalty rate of

    10-20 percent would fall in the conservative range. This provides a mechanism for recognizing

    an economic benefit from projects that by themselves bring an added inflow of cash to the

    national treasury, and to recognize an economic cost when the project produces an added cash

    outflow.

    It should be clear from what has been said up to now that it would be illusory to think of

    maintaining a full-blown, state-of-the-art cost-benefit analysis for each and every program or

    project that USAID finances. Indeed, the cost of such an evaluation could easily exceed total

    project outlays in the cases of low-budget projects. So full-blown cost-benefit analysis should be

    done selectively, on projects whose size and characteristics make them suitable for such studies.

    The remaining projects should not be forgotten, however. They deserve analysis ex ante and

    scrutiny ex post, applying tests of plausibility and reasonableness such as may be justified by the

    size and nature of the project.

    Briefing Paper #5 is intentionally placed here (after rather than before briefing paper #6)

    because it examines specific ways in which USAID and selected other organizations have

    actually applied cost-benefit analysis and other evaluation techniques. The Millennium

    Challenge Corporation, which is a sort of sister organization to USAID, finances programs

    designed by the recipient countries themselves. Its motto could well be “helping those who are

    ready to work hard to help themselves.” The programs that MCC helps to finance typically

    consist of several components, each of which is subjected to an ex ante cost-benefit analysis by

    MCC. This cost-benefit analysis then forms the basis for follow-up monitoring at various stages

    of the construction and execution of each program component. The MCC imposes a criterion

    15

  • real rate of return in the neighborhood of 10%, and requires an independent ex post evaluation of

    each project. In many respects the MCC’s procedures come close to fulfilling the dreams of

    cost-benefit analysts, a result that is bolstered by the fact that most MCC projects are of the types

    (infrastructure, etc.) that are readily amenable to cost-benefit analysis.

    The World Bank regularly conducts both ex ante and ex post economic analysis of

    projects, but many of them are of types that do not lend themselves to full-blown cost-benefit

    studies. In such projects the Bank uses a 6-point grading scale, rather than developing detailed

    quantitative project profiles and calculating a real rate of economic return. The World Bank’s

    Independent Evaluation Group, which conducts the ex post analyses, finds that something like

    80% of its cases end up being judged satisfactory. This should be good news for supporters of

    foreign aid programs generally -- note that a project with a 5% real return (not bad by most

    investors’ standards) would be judged unsatisfactory under the World Bank’s traditional 10%

    standard.

    Note #5 is frank in recognizing that USAID’s monitoring and evaluation program is less

    well-developed than those of the MCC and the World Bank. It can surely benefit from more

    extensive and more rigorous use of economic analysis, both ex ante and ex post. Equally

    important is the cultivation within USAID of a mindset of continuous hard-headed focus on the

    likely costs and benefits of new projects and on actual outcomes of older ones.

    Briefing Note #7 is titled “Intermediate Results” (IRs). It focuses on how one can use

    available indicators to get information on the development effectiveness of a project while it is

    still underway, or when a full-blown cost-benefit analysis is precluded because of its cost or by

    the nature of the project. Such indicators can provide IRs, which can be thought of as measuring

    16

  • different intermediate steps in the causal chain which connects a project’s actions to the ultimate

    benefits that it is expected to bring about.

    Some of the cases mentioned in Note #7 are:

    PROJECT RESULTS INDICATORS

    • Financial Reform Increase in World Bank’s “Getting Credit” Score

    • Dairy Sector Technical Support Percentage of Productivity IncreaseIncreased Supply of Milk

    • Agricultural Inputs Market Development # of Dealers and Agents TrainedSize of Increase in Crop Output

    • Streamlining Business Registration Increased Number, Cost and Speed of Registrations

    • Strengthening Competition in Introduction of Voice Over Internet SourceTelecommunications Drastic Cuts in Prices of Calls

    • Securities and Stock Exchange Reform Increase in TradingNumber of New ListingsAmount of New Investment Funds Raised Through the Stock Market

    • Financial Sector Reforms Increased # of Bank LocationsIncrease in Volume of Loans

    • Fiscal Sector Reforms Improved ComplianceReduced EvasionSavings of Administrative CostsIncreased Revenue With Same Tax Rate

    These example demonstrate that even though intermediate results do not tell the whole

    story, they can be powerful indicators of how worthwhile a given project is likely to be.

    Briefing Note #8 deals with the long-term benefits that USAID programs often generate.

    The note covers cases illustrating five categories of goals: building policy analysis capacity,

    17

  • promoting trade and investment, modernizing the financial sector, improving revenue

    mobilization and supporting enterprise development.

    Korea is an outstanding example of successful economic growth, for which USAID

    (together with its predecessor ICA) can claim a non-negligible share of the credit. Even if that

    share were as little as 1 or 2 percent the benefit stream would often be gigantic in relation to U.S.

    aid disbursements. Korea’s GDP today is, in real terms, more than 25 times what it was in 1964.

    USAID’s contribution probably added up to around 1 year’s worth of Korea’s GDP at that time,

    including the financing of the bulk of its imports of the period, the provision of technical advice

    (especially in the early years) and the training of a cadre of policy and technical experts. Long-

    term effects similar to those in Korea can be found in Indonesia and Thailand and, to a more

    modest but nonetheless impressive extent, in El Salvador.

    In the case of Vietnam, the work of USAID was particularly notable in promoting trade

    and investment. It set in motion a series of initiatives and reforms that led to Vietnam’s

    accession to the WTO in 2007. In the process the country’s investment and exports soared, and

    brought it into the ranks of “growth champions.”

    In Kazakhstan, USAID concentrated on a Financial Sector Initiative, which helped build

    a burgeoning capital market, create a mortgage finance system, and stimulate the development of

    funded pension plans in both the public and private sectors.

    Fiscal Reform has been a major focus of USAID’s work in many countries, of which

    Note #8 selects Jamaica for closer treatment. After a fall of 22% in that country’s per capita

    income over a decade (1973-83), a major effort at policy reform was mounted. USAID provided

    expert advisors who, working with a local Tax Reform Commission, designed a modernized tax

    system that scored well in terms both of economic efficiency and of political acceptability. Tax

    18

  • rates were lowered, and the tax base was broadened and greatly simplified. The result was an

    increase in revenues and a restoration of vigorous economic growth.

    A good example of USAID’s support for enterprise development is its work with the Ica

    Farmers Association in Peru, supporting the introduction and expansion of a new crop -- green

    asparagus. Starting from zero, Peru became the world’s leading exporter of this product, beating

    out even such giant countries as the United States and China. Subsequently USAID has played a

    major role in spreading the cultivation of other products which ended up opening further new

    export markets. While one may expect that green asparagus and the other new crops would

    probably ultimately have reached Peru’s farmers even without USAID’s help, the evidence is

    overwhelming that this would have taken a long time and would probably have followed a rocky

    path. USAID surely played a critical role in bringing about quick acceptance and rapid

    development of these new lines.

    In many parts of the developing world small and medium enterprises have been important

    wellsprings of economic growth. Note #8 reports on USAID’s support of a single Sri Lankan

    poultry enterprise. Technical assistance given by USAID helped this firm to expand output and

    its labor force more than fivefold, and to provide a corresponding stimulation to over 2000

    surrounding farms which supplied the enterprise with chickens.

    Briefing Note #9 deals with programs of support for food and agriculture. It is hard to

    exaggerate the importance of food availability in first permitting and then sustaining the huge

    expansion of the world’s population and the concomitant rise in human welfare that have

    occurred in the last two to three centuries. Before that period most Europeans were living on

    only about 1500 calories per day, and poor health and lack of energy were important

    impediments to greater production of food and other items. Today there are still parts of the

    19

  • world where conditions are not much better, and some of the world’s overall supply of food

    products has been diverted to nonfood uses (e.g., biofuels). As a result we have witnessed

    substantial rises in the world prices of the major foodgrains, which have cut into the diets of

    many of the world’s poorest people. International donors have responded by reversing a strong

    downward trend in food and agriculture assistance.

    USAID has long been active in promoting the modernization and diversification of

    agriculture in developing countries. Some of the biggest hurdles to be overcome consisted (and

    in a number of places still consist) of ill-designed government interventions in market processes,

    of artificially low prices (below world markets) for food products and agricultural inputs, and of

    government monopolies in the storage, export, and sometimes even the distribution of key

    agricultural crops. In some places farmers have been required to plant basic pulses and grains on

    land that could have been planted to fruits and vegetables of much higher value.

    Note #9 recounts some of USAID’s achievements in programs of modernization and

    rationalization of agricultural production, marketing and trade. Particularly notable success was

    achieved in Bangladesh. There, largely through programs arranged by the International Food

    Policy Reserve Institute (IFPRI), USAID supported the abolition of food rationing programs and

    the development of modern markets, resulting in both increased production efficiency and in

    large savings for the country’s Treasury. In another very successful program, food supplements

    to households were made contingent on school attendance by the children, thus simultaneously

    promoting the twin government goals of improved nutrition and enhanced educational attainment

    within poor families.

    In Indonesia USAID played a key role in supporting the advanced training of agricultural

    specialists, plus the development and strengthening of food policy institutions. In Egypt USAID

    20

  • played a major role in liberalizing feed and rice production and in opening the country’s credit,

    distribution, and agricultural procurement operations. This was followed by reforms in water

    resource management, in the markets for agricultural inputs, and in institutional development, all

    of which strengthened the role of the private sector in Egyptian agriculture.

    In Guatemala USAID helped to stimulate the adoption of new, labor-intensive

    horticultural crops, raising farm incomes and greatly expanding non-traditional agricultural

    exports. Other programs were directed at improving the productivity and incomes of farm

    families in the poorest regions of the country.

    USAID continues to work to promote agricultural productivity, diversification and

    modernization, aiming at the goals of improved nutrition, agricultural income growth and food

    security for the recipient country’s people.

    Briefing Note #10 deals with promoting economic growth in post-conflict situations.

    Growth helps such countries surmount the low and stagnant income levels and the heavy

    dependence on extractive industries which tend to fuel new outbreaks of violence. But beyond a

    possible initial bounce as pre-conflict activities are resumed, most post-conflict economies face

    many obstacles in creating an economic, legal and institutional environment in which the

    fundamental forces of growth -- investment, innovation and real cost reductions -- can flourish.

    Often a certain tension arises in the choice of policies. If major regeneration of employment is to

    occur right after the end of a conflict, it pretty much has to be done by government. Yet the

    long-run aim is for the private sector to be the principle generator of new employment and

    economic growth. It becomes a major challenge to find ways of accomplishing the first

    objective without imperiling the transition to the second. USAID has helped countries respond

    21

  • to this challenge by supporting first-stage programs that are quite clearly transitory in nature and

    in aiding the post-conflict recovery of farms and small businesses.

    In the macroeconomic area it is important that post-conflict governments get quickly onto

    a sound policy track. Good budgetary management is a key factor here, which the U.S. has

    helped to provide with notable success in Bosnia (in modernizing Treasury operations) and

    Liberia (hands-on tutelage in budgetary practices). Major reforms in tax policy and

    administration are also often called for. On the expenditure side USAID has been instrumental

    in introducing a totally new pension system in Iraq (which paid a big dividend by significantly

    increasing the national rate of saving). It also helped to greatly improve the management of

    resource earnings in East Timor and Sierra Leone.

    Monetary management, exchange rate policy, and financial sector development obviously

    pose critical challenges for governments generally, but especially so in post-conflict situations

    where countries can all too easily fall into the trap of trying to keep the public sector working

    and striving to stimulate the economy, simply by running huge budget deficits financed by

    printing money. The tasks of giving outside assistance here tends to be shared by many entities,

    of which the IMF, the World Bank, the U.S. Treasury and USAID, are among the leaders.

    Among USAID’s important contributions have been helping to establish a new national currency

    and strengthening the technical capacity of the central bank in Afghanistan, assisting in creating

    the central bank in Kosovo and supplying training for its staff, and collaborating in the

    establishment of a nationwide credit system in Bosnia.

    Efforts to promote private development face special problems in post-conflict situations,

    but USAID has often found ways to overcome them. In Iraq a web of small business

    development centers was created, in Afghanistan a series of financial services outlets processed

    22

  • nearly a quarter of a million loans; in East Timor a coffee cooperative supported by USAID has

    grown to become the country’s larges coffee exporter.

    * * * * *

    I hope this introduction gives readers a sense of the richness of the menu presented in the

    ten briefing papers. Promoting economic development is an enormously complex task, full of

    obstacles and pitfalls, yet presenting great challenges for all who are involved. To make

    progress toward this goal one cannot rely on romantic shibboleths; instead one must put one’s

    mind and hands to work on one obdurate real-world problem after another, seeking always to

    find paths whose benefits outweigh their costs. This is the world that faces all who are dedicated

    to promoting growth and fighting poverty in developing countries. And obviously this is the

    world in which USAID lives and works. Readers will enrich their understanding of this world

    and deepen their appreciation of USAID’s role within it, as they absorb the messages contained

    in these briefing notes.

    23