international sanctions on iran

Upload: karl-henrik-smith

Post on 02-Mar-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    1/42

    Karl-Henrik Smith

    Outside of the many sarafi, foreign exchange bureaus, peoplegathered on the street to watch flat-screen televisions displaying

    the almost minute-by-minute slide in the rial; and men and

    women gathered at the kiosks to buy dollars as a hedge againstcrippling inflation or just because they thought the government

    might soon run out of them due to new international sanctionsagainst Iranian banks. - Majd (2014: 246-7)

    International Sanctions on Iran

    An Explanatory Critique

    Copenhagen Business School

    2016

    International Business &

    Politics (IBP)

    Bachelor Thesis

    STU-Count: 91,000

    Number of pages: 40

    Advisor: Hubert Buch-Hansen,

    [email protected]

    Date: 23/05/2016

    Name: Karl-Henrik Smith

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    2/42

    1

    Table of Contents

    1. Introduction 3

    1.1. Analytical focus: Targeted sanctions and the federal government 4

    2. Methodology 5

    2.1. Critical realism 5

    2.1.1. Ontology 5

    2.1.2. Epistemology 6

    2.1.3. Methods and empirical material 6

    2.2. Choice of theory 7

    2.2.1. Neorealism vs. liberal institutionalism 8

    2.2.2. Critical realism and the neo-neo debate 8

    2.3. Methodological application 9

    2.3.1. Economic sanctions and institutions 92.3.2. Explanatory critique 9

    3. Theory 10

    3.1. Liberal institutionalist theory of mutual dependence 10

    3.2. Neorealist theory of international regimes 12

    3.3. Conclusion: Theoretical overlaps and application 14

    4. Case: International sanctions on Iran 15

    4.1. Empirical data and case setting 15

    4.1.1. Five-year development plans (FYPDs) 15

    4.1.2. Interventionism 16

    4.1.2.1. Political intervention 16

    4.1.2.2. Economic intervention 17

    4.1.3. Theocracy 19

    4.1.3.1. The political spectrum in Iran 19

    4.1.3.2. The economic impact of theocracy 19

    4.1.4. Reformism 21

    4.1.4.1. The Khatami reforms (1997-2005) 21

    4.1.4.2. Ahmadinejads subsidy reform plan (2005-2013) 22

    4.1.4.3. Rouhani and the Iranian nuclear deal (2013-) 24

    4.2. Analysis of interaction between institutional mechanisms 25

    4.2.1. Interventionism and theocracy: Neorealist applications 25

    4.2.1.1. Economic sanctions and foreign intervention 25

    4.2.1.2. Economic sanctions and Iranian theocracy 26

    4.2.2. Reformism and the FYPDs: Liberal institutionalist applications 29

    4.2.2.1. Incremental change: The Khatami reforms (1997-2005) 29

    4.2.2.2. Mitigating sanctions: The Ahmadinejad administration (2005-2013) 30

    4.2.2.3. Lifting sanctions: The second-wave reformists (2013-) 31

    4.3. Conclusion 32

    5. Discussion 33

    5.1. The role of institutions and interaction between mechanisms 33

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    3/42

    2

    5.2. Assessing the post-sanctions era 34

    5.2.1. Have economic sanctions achieved their desired aim in Iran? 34

    5.2.2. Recommendations for further action 35

    6. Conclusion 357. References 37

    Abstract

    The efficacy of international sanctions is a topic of increasingly widespread public debate. Though

    existing research primarily investigates the motivations for imposing sanctions, this report seeks to

    determine the ability of sanctions to deter or alter the behavior of a target country. I aim to explain

    how Iran, a country that has undergone profound systematic changes since the 1979 revolution, has

    fared under such constraints. I draw on the liberal institutionalist theory of mutual dependence and

    neorealist regime theory to determine whether sanctions have been effective, and the prospects of

    cooperation in the future. This report argues that the desired behavior from imposing the economic

    embargo has not been achieved, and that it has instead contributed to a multitude of unwarranted

    dynamics (e.g. poverty, corruption), structural factors that contribute to Tehrans policy-making and

    isolationism. This report focuses on three institutional mechanisms that have created the conditions

    for the proliferation or appeasement of sanctions in Iran: interventionism, theocracy and reformism.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    4/42

    3

    1. Introduction

    Economic sanctions have become increasingly significant over the past century, as states attempt to

    obtain concessions from target countries. Yet, the theoretical basis underpinning the efficiency of

    sanctions is limited. Academic focus surrounding economic sanctions primarily concerns moral or

    political implications of their imposition, rather than discussing how states adapt their domestic and

    foreign policies under economic coercion. The strict purpose of sanctions is not to punish states, but

    rather engender a behavioural shift ranging anywhere from altering policies to regime change. Two

    of the largest theories in international relations, realism and liberalism, address issues such as state

    agency and the role of institutions in encouraging compromise over conflict. Both theories apply to

    the case of Iran, which has suffered under unilateral (US-imposed) sanctions since the 1979 Iranian

    Revolution, and multilateral (UN-imposed) sanctions since 2006 due to international concern over

    Irans nuclear energy program. While foreign countries and institutions have consistently promoted

    tightening the embargo, they have failed to generate a significant shift in the Iranian governments

    regional and domestic behaviour - namely, the pursuit of nuclear energy technology, the financing

    of terrorist groups, and the abuse of human rights. As such, this report aims to answer the following

    research question:

    What are the main institutional mechanisms that account for the spread of sanctions in Iran, and to

    what extent has the impact of the embargo perpetuated Tehrans response to foreign policies?

    I strive to determine the institutional mechanisms that give rise to economic sanctions, and attempt

    to show that their ability to shape state behaviour is questionable. The mechanisms I consider in this

    report are both internal and external, since there are a number of emergent properties (domestically

    and abroad) responsible for this tool of foreign policy. The study takes an actor-oriented approach,

    focusing specifically on policies within Iran in response to the embargo, but also investigates the

    role played by other states, institutions, organisations and firms. Findings are directed at sender

    states, namely the US federal government, but also international organisations (IOs) and other

    actors that have pursued multilateral sanctions against the Iranian regime. First, I introduce critical

    realism and discuss how the choice of methodology informs my choice of theory. Second, I discuss

    liberal institutionalism and neorealism, explaining their relevance to the case and research question.

    Third, I bring forth empirical evidence, and analyse the interaction between respective institutional

    mechanisms provided. Fourth, the case study is discussed. Finally, the report will conclude.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    5/42

    4

    1.1. Analytical focus: Targeted sanctions and the federal government

    This reports analytical focus will be on targeted instead of comprehensive sanctions. Ever since the

    revolution, a full embargo has been in place in Iran: this measure refers to the prohibition of all

    commercial activity or the imposition of tariffs and protectionary measures. Targeted sanctions, on

    the other hand, refer to blocking transactions with particular groups, individuals and multinational

    corporations (Masters 2015). These can take many forms, including travel bans, asset freezes, arms

    embargoes, capital restraints, and trade restrictions (ibid). I contend that targeting individual actors

    can mitigate otherwise detrimental effects of embargoes on civilians, as comprehensive sanctions

    may cement structural problems like poverty or corruption (ibid). The analytical focus on targeted

    sanctions allows analysing sanctions more broadly, helping determine which elements in particular

    caused the most harm to Irans economy. As the embargo failed to bring significant concessions

    from the federal government, states and IOs began using targeted sanctions to effectively generate

    changes in behaviour, but this strategy faces many difficulties. While sanctions have traditionally

    been imposed to harm the elite (those with agenda-setting power and the ability to influence policy),

    their impact is mostly felt on poorer, working-class individuals (Marcus 2010). These policies have

    reinforced nationalist sentiment through political mobilisation and suspicion of foreign states (ibid).

    The federal government is a significant actor as well, as the Iranian Parliament (Majlis) advances

    economic initiatives every five years in medium-term strategic plans. These five-year development

    plans (FYPDs) are important because they lay out the foundation for state-led policies, but also vary

    based on which elected coalition hold a parliamentary majority (e.g. conservatives, reformists). This

    report will assess policy enactment and impact, due to the role of the federal government - rather

    than individual provinces - in agenda-setting (Ghasimi 2012). These FYPDs provide a framework to

    promote the private sector and embark on public sector reforms aimed at a more equitable and just

    society (ibid). Each administration since the Iranian Revolution has prioritised different issuesthrough these FYPDs, which allows a greater focus on certain issues in the medium run. The federal

    government may thus be a necessary condition in mitigating the effectiveness of sanctions since it

    provides objectives or targets for individual provinces, but is also insufficient because the state

    alone cannot overturn the problems caused by decades of economic coercion. Notwithstanding, the

    focus on the federal government is an important part of understanding how domestic and foreign

    policies adapt when a state is confronted with the prospect of sanctions.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    6/42

    5

    2. Methodology

    2.1. Critical realism

    While there is much empirical evidence to investigate the consequences of imposing sanctions, thisreport attempts to make scientific explanations as objective as possible while recognising that

    truth is fallible and incomplete. I plan to analyse the underlying agents and structures responsible

    for the spread of sanctions as a tool of foreign policy. As such, the critical realist approach is

    necessary since it can help extricate the aforementioned institutional mechanisms, allowing for the

    investigation and identification of the relationships and non-relationships, respectively, between

    what we experience, what actually happens, and the underlying mechanisms that produce [events].

    (Danermark et al. 2002: 21) The objective a critical realist framework within the scope of this report

    is to uncover the mechanisms responsible for the phenomena of interest (economic sanctions), and

    determine whether they have been entrenched over time.

    2.1.1. Ontology

    The founder of critical realism, Roy Bhaskar, originally coined the term as a blend of a philosophy

    of science (transcendental realism) and of human sciences (critical naturalism). Developments since

    the 1970s have encompassed an increasingly broad range in economics and social sciences (Jackson

    2010). This report considers the merits of critical realist thought within international relations, and

    aims to illustrate which generative causal tendencies give rise to the use of sanctions in the global

    sphere. A vital component of this study is the concept of transfactualism, which allows for an

    explanation of occurrences beyond the empirical domain, as it uncovers the underlying mechanisms

    responsible for the rise of phenomena (ibid). According to critical realism, a phenomenon arises not

    solely from human experiences, discourses or actual events, but also underlying structures, powers,

    and tendencies that exist, whether or not detected or known through experience and/or discourse

    (Patomki and Wight 2000: 223). The primary criticisms of positivism within international relations

    concern its tendency to associate events between each other, rather than identifying the mechanisms

    that have led to those events in the first place (ibid). Patomki and Wight expound on the virtues of

    critical realist thinking in international relations, stating that there is a reductionist problem-field

    which cannot be addressed through positivist, constructivist or post-structuralist thought (ibid). The

    analysis of phenomena can instead only be complete with an understanding of the fundamental

    powers or causal tendencies that give rise to actual, observable events.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    7/42

    6

    2.1.2. Epistemology

    In scientific practice, critical realism follows the notion of methodological pluralism, according to

    which the method must suit the object of investigation as well as the purpose of it (Danermark et

    al. 2002: 27). Therefore, it is the nature of the phenomenon under investigation, and of the research

    question, that should determine the methods being used (ibid). The understanding of reality as open

    and differentiated admits that causal powers are triggered by the interaction between objects, giving

    reality a relational character. Therefore, the purpose of scientific enquiry is to uncover relationships

    between the different factors involved. The process for this is twofold. The first is abduction, which

    contextualises phenomena and facts to render them intelligible in a specific framework by analysing

    their interaction with underlying mechanisms or causal tendencies. In other words, abduction gives

    meaning to phenomena since they are interpreted within a particular conceptual framework (ibid:

    91). The second part, retroduction, finds that knowledge of the conditions that are not observable in

    the empirical domain can be generates. Retroductive reasoning is thus an analysis of the substantial

    relations through thought experiments or counterfactual thinking, which can help to determine how

    a specific phenomenon is generated (ibid). The methods critical realists use to engage in abduction

    and retroduction are equally important, since they underpin the entire analysis.

    2.1.3. Methods and empirical materialThis report employs a heuristic case study, which we use to explicate a single case, Iran, to uncover

    the underlying structures responsible for economic sanctions and Tehrans policy-orientation. This

    type of case study allows us to explore the phenomenon to bring about new knowledge, which is in

    line with the critical realist belief that it is always possible to produce knowledge due to its fallible

    character (Moses & Knutsen 2012: 140). This will be supplemented with an additional investigation

    of the institutional structures that allow for sanctions more broadly: the set of interactions between

    institutional mechanisms accounting for the spread of sanctions in Iran and abroad. The choice of

    empirical material in the case will include primary sources, such as speeches and firsthand accounts

    of historical events, but the majority of the analysis relies on secondary sources, including academic

    documents, journals, and newspaper articles. The choice of both primary and secondary sources is

    paramount, since having extensive empirical material can counteract limited reliability of primary

    sources (ibid). The data provided is important since it allows the report to analyse how institutional

    mechanisms interact with the phenomenon.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    8/42

    7

    The purpose of our heuristic case study is to recognise and understand the implications of economic

    sanctions in Iran. Defining the effect of sanctions is an abstraction from a particular set of structural

    and institutional mechanisms, which is necessary since the domain of the actual - the events that

    occur - provides no insight into institutional and state-related features (Danermark et al. 2002: 42). I

    denote institutional mechanisms, rather than mechanisms in the broad sense of the term, to mean the

    structures that arise from institutions and institutional arrangements, and which can be formal as

    well as informal (ibid). Since concrete evidence pertaining to the domain of the actual is lacking, it

    becomes impossible to offer advice on mitigating the impact of sanctions. This report begins with

    an outline of concrete events and circumstances in Iran, to determine the mechanisms characterising

    the relationship between coercion and institutions in the domain of the real, which includes all that

    which produces events (ibid). This relationship is determined through an analysis of the empirical

    evidence and an explanation of how the data relates to the institutional mechanisms. I will then use

    abduction to contextualise these mechanisms and determine their influence over sanctions, and use

    retroduction to investigate the substantial relations in Iran that gave rise to this phenomenon.

    2.2. Choice of theory

    The field of international relations is a vital part of studies in international political economy (IPE),

    mainly because political and economic shifts are dependent on interstate activity. Two of the main

    schools of thought in international relations are realism and liberalism, and both have been evolving

    significantly since their inception. Early realism is seen as a reactionary ideology against interstate

    conflict and war, though contemporary realism is increasingly state-centric, focusing on issues like

    survival and self-reliance (Dunne and Schmidt 2008). Critics of realist assumptions were called

    idealists, and believed that states domestic philosophies and ideologies should more broadly be

    applied as a doctrine of foreign policy. Idealism is the precursor for modern liberalism, as writers

    like Kant popularised notions of perpetual peace or democratic peace within international regimes,

    goals that would be encouraged by political and economic interdependence (Gartzke 1998). There

    have been numerous improvements to both realism and liberalism; contemporary incarnations of

    realism and liberalism, neorealism and liberal institutionalism, have sharpened their focus to 1) how

    cooperation is brought about within international regimes, and 2) the role of institutions, states and

    other actors in doing so. The neo-neo debate is central to this reports aim of determining how

    sanctions have proliferated in Iran.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    9/42

    8

    2.2.1. Neorealism vs. liberal institutionalism

    The liberal institutionalist school (L-I) under Keohane and Nye postulates that states benefit from

    mutual dependence since it can help resolve conflicts of interest or existing tensions (laissez-faire

    economic views, unrestricted free trade, etc.). This, they claim, can promote cooperation through

    existing linkages and negotiations, as IOs and other institutions have a central role in ensuring that

    cooperation occurs. Institutionalists have an actor-oriented view of international regimes, claiming

    that states have agency and can resolve disputes while achieving absolute gains. Neorealists, on the

    other hand, have a more pessimistic outlook of geopolitics, claiming that conflicts of interest are

    actually disempowering states and institutions from resolving disputes, since a number of actors

    also want to achieve relative gains. Therefore, existing linkages can be destabilised by a number of

    external issues (volatility in oil prices, hegemonic influence, etc.). To that extent, neorealist regime

    theory, developed by Joseph Grieco, claims that states are not atomistic (absolutist) but positional

    (relativist), concerned not just about achieving absolute but also relative gains.

    2.2.2. Critical realism and the neo-neo debate

    This theoretical debate, or neo-neo debate, will guide the choice of theory and empirical material. It

    allows the report to focus on behavioural factors of the trade-related aspects of foreign and domestic

    policy, especially in terms of how rational actors make decisions with asymmetric information. The

    research aims to show that targeted economic sanctions are affected by the following institutional

    mechanisms: interventionism, theocracy and reformism. This framework will be supplemented by

    an examination of institutional tipping points that have occurred during the sanctions timeline, and

    attempts to reverse course on certain entrenched structures by encouraging democratic and tolerant

    values in society. Once the report uncovers the causal powers that characterise economic sanctions,

    the neo-neo framework will contextualise the phenomenon to determine which substantial relations

    exist between the aforementioned institutional mechanisms. In view of this, I then offer suggestions

    for further action and assess the relevance of the post-sanctions era through a neoliberal-neorealist

    lens. The report will finally conclude whether or not the case of sanctions on Iran feeds into either

    approach more than the other.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    10/42

    9

    2.3. Methodological application

    2.3.1. Economic sanctions and institutions

    Due to the interdisciplinary nature of sanctions, this report will be both qualitative and quantitative,

    delving into the mechanisms causing the spread of sanctions as well as techniques used to measure

    their effectiveness in the case of Iran. The analysis will contain intuitive and econometric elements;

    since qualitative methods are traditionally more concerned with interactions between mechanisms,

    this paper benefits from mixed-method research, which is a common approach in critical realism.

    This approach thus provides the ability to analyse the causal tendencies of economic coercion from

    a multidisciplinary approach, and ultimately delivers a more complete picture of the socio-

    economic impact sanctions can have (Patomki and Wight 2000). The objective of causality is todemonstrate how the conditions that constitute the explanans, or that which does explaining,

    generate the event or phenomenon that is being explained, the explanandum (ibid). As such, this

    report intends to illustrate how the phenomenon of economic sanctions is the logical conclusion of

    the interaction between the set of institutional mechanisms that characterise it.

    2.3.2. Explanatory critique

    An important concept in critical realism is explanatory critique, which is used for this reports actor-

    oriented approach. It refers to the process where having knowledge of undesirable structures allows

    actors to transform them into more desirable structures (Danermark et al. 2002: 195). Explanatory

    critique discards the idea that beliefs are open to casual interpretation, since rejecting a belief would

    imply rejecting the conditions or structures necessary for their existence. This theory opens up the

    exciting possibility that we may be able to discovervalues, whose beliefs prove to be incompatible

    with their own true explanation (Archer et al. 1998: xviii). This demonstrates that agency is a form

    of emancipation, since it can remove the influence of certain oppressive or constraining structures

    (ibid). Explanatory critique disproves beliefs previously held to be true by criticising the underlying

    causes or generative mechanisms sustaining that belief (Witt 2012). A central theme in this theory is

    the interplay between factual and value-laden judgments, as values can be extricated not only from

    certain institutional mechanisms, but also by the interaction between such mechanisms. Explanatory

    critique thus positively evaluates (all things being equal) action aimed at removing the underlying

    causes (ibid: 9). This theory will be used further when investigating how causal powers have been

    counteracted by state agency.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    11/42

    10

    3. Theory

    The liberal institutionalist framework posits that states cooperate given common interests, and that

    institutions can alleviate collective action problems. An important notion in liberal institutionalism

    is that of interdependence, which neorealists argue is counterproductive since conflicts of interest

    strengthen the likelihood of tension (Waltz 1988: 48), and liberal institutionalists believe leads to

    higher chances of collaboration and dispute resolution (Keohane and Nye 1987). This section draws

    on neorealism and liberal institutionalism to identify and investigate the institutional mechanisms

    responsible for the spread of sanctions, with Keohane and Nyes theory of mutual dependence, and

    Joseph Griecos regime theory. In this neo-neo debate, there are two fundamental disagreements:

    the origins of cooperation, and the role of IOs and institutions in ensuring states cooperate with each

    other. Each theory will be studied in turn.

    3.1. Liberal institutionalist theory of mutual dependence

    Inthe work of Robert Keohane (1941-) and Joseph Nye (1937-), Power and interdependence, the

    interests of state and non-state actors are examined in terms of power politics and interdependence.

    That is, they claim that behaviour of the state is governed by military and security concerns, where

    individual governments aspire to benefit from international exchange while maintaining as much

    autonomy as possible (Keohane and Nye 1987: 730). Interdependence, which they broadly define

    as situations of reciprocity between countries or actors within countries (ibid), would then constitute

    a vital role in international relations. However, recent academic research in international relations

    postulates that economic interdependence alone cannot stem political conflict. Mansfield and

    Pollins note the contingencies in the relationship between interdependence and conflict, as they

    claim that trade contains cooperative and coercive dimensions (Mansfield and Pollins 2003: 8). The

    positive or negative effects of trade are thus conditional from a liberal institutionalist perspective.

    This builds on previous studies, which conclude that expanding trade networks in a mercantilist

    framework are responsible for commercial rivalries and even military conflict (ibid). The

    conditional nature of interdependence can thus be accredited to the impact of contextually relevant

    factors, which include differences in integration in the world market, regulatory frameworks, and

    regimes (Evaghorou and Mertzanidis 2012). In order to achieve gains from interdependence, these

    factors would need to be counteracted within a complex geography made up of states,

    international and non-governmental organizations, and transnational corporate networks (ibid).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    12/42

    11

    According to the theory of mutual dependence developed by Keohane and Nye, relations of power

    influence state decision-making and behaviour. This represents a situation where various channels

    of contact bridge societies, there is no issue hierarchy, and governments refrain from using military

    force (Keohane and Nye 1987: 731). Mutual dependence adopts an actor-oriented approach with a

    focus on transnational and interstate relations, whose objective is to study how certain patterns of

    political processes affect actor behaviour rather than to employ a structural explanation to account

    for action (ibid). These political processes can be intertwined with conditional factors (e.g. reform

    policies, political system) that affect the positive or negative effects of interdependence. Keohane

    and Nye identify three political processes that lead to mutual dependence: issue-linkages, agenda

    formation, and IOs (ibid). The idea of issue-linkages is equally a liberal institutionalist phenomenon

    as a neorealist one, although Keohane and Nye argue that the linkages increase under conditions of

    mutual dependence, while neorealists like Waltz do not believe economic interdependence mitigates

    conflicts of interest (ibid). Agenda formation is an important liberal institutionalist contribution, in

    that changes in domestic policy are usually representative of a poor operation of a regime in a

    coherent and functionally linked issue-area (ibid: 738).

    Later developments of mutual dependence integrate perspectives on issues like democracy (Drezner

    2003), security (Gartzke 2010), and bargaining (Rana 2015). If states cooperate, according to liberal

    institutionalists, then socio-economic, political, and military issues are mitigated. However, because

    there is asymmetric information, rational actors are unable to determine whether other states will

    comply. This assumption is at the foundation of realist regime theory, which points out that there

    are difficulties in forming international regimes if there is a disruption in the balance of power. The

    relationship between economic interdependence and sanctions is thus triggered by the interaction

    between two mechanisms: a) political and economic foreign interventionism, which directly results

    in b) Iranian theocracy. I determine through retroduction the substantial relations that underpin theinteraction between these two mechanisms, and find that a necessary condition for economic growth

    is the creation of democratic institutions willing to implement reforms. The substantial relations are

    twofold. First, a theocratic government presupposes the existence of embeddedness of certain social

    values and norms. Second, foreign interventionism is conditional, assuming that intervention occurs

    in order to preserve foreign interests in an uncooperative domestic environment (Majd 2014).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    13/42

    12

    3.2. Neorealist theory of international regimes

    International regimes constitute the set of principles, norms, rules, and decision-making procedures

    around which actor expectations converge in a given issue area (Krasner 1982: 185). Investigating

    regimes is thus necessary to analyse the relationships between institutional mechanisms and actors,

    particularly when studying issues of behavioural trade. The concept of regime theory refers to these

    interactions and relationships, as well as the role of institutions in shaping the behaviour of rational

    actors (ibid). An important notion for proponents of this theory is hegemony, since neorealists claim

    that cooperation is more likely to ensue from an unequal balance of power between states. Sjolander

    and Cox clarify this:

    A hegemonic framework thus stresses the need for the dominant actors to make compromises in theirinterests and policies in order to confer benefits on their subordinates to maintain their active consent.

    We can view this as the need for the dominant actors to provide a material basis of consent via a political

    and ideological bargaining process (Sjolander and Cox 1994: 83-84).

    Hegemony is important for regime theory because it delineates the parameters in which cooperation

    takes place. Economic and political hegemons hold influence over other states as a result of material

    power and ideological leadership (ibid). As such, subordinated states are subject to the interests of a

    ruling class in hegemonic states, where dominant actors rely on coercion rather than consent (firms,

    IOs, states). Of course, this begs the question of whether such a scenario is cooperation if hegemons

    are imposing their will on subordinated states; this is one of the liberal institutionalist criticisms of

    neorealisms reliance on hegemonic stability theory (HST). Another key element of such regimes is

    the ability and willingness to keep governments satisfied enough to leave control in private hands

    (ibid: 84). Therefore, for neorealists, hegemons can only form stable international regimes if they

    have significant bargaining power over other states to override the interests of subordinated actors.

    The importance of hegemonic stability in international regime theory will be further explored in theanalysis in section 4.2.

    Despite the fact that regime theory has traditionally been studied from a liberal institutionalist view,

    neorealists like Joseph Grieco (1953-) expanded on this theory to uncover the limits of cooperation

    for a number of issues, such as bilateral trade, human rights or military security (Grieco 1988). This

    variant of regime theory criticises liberal institutionalist views on security and mutual dependence,

    stating instead that the understanding of defensive state positionality and the relative gains

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    14/42

    13

    problem for collaboration is a better guide for states seeking self-reliance within an international

    regime (ibid: 507). In other words, those states subordinate to the interests of ruling elite in other

    countries should cooperate with dominant states only if they satisfy their interests in the process.

    Neorealist regime theory sees states as the only major players in world politics, claiming that they

    are unitary-rational actors in global governance (ibid). Grieco further developed regime theory with

    the concept of international anarchy, or the set of geopolitical tensions and conflicts states face; he

    claims anarchy is opposed to the institutionalist belief that IOs and other institutions encourage

    cooperation on a state level (ibid). Neorealists perceive states as positional as they are concerned

    about achieving relative and absolute gains: a state that is satisfied with a partners compliance in a

    joint arrangement might nevertheless exit from it because the partner is achieving relatively greater

    gains (ibid: 487). This view of states sees institutions as discouraging cooperation, because of

    external issues that undercut the potential for interstate negotiation (e.g. sanctions, oil price

    volatility). Diverging interests, rather than leading to mutual dependence between states, would

    instead generate increased conflicts and challenges for international regimes (ibid).

    A number of earlier studies of state behaviour have inspired neorealist regime theory. For example,

    governmentality theory purports states institutionalise many organised practices (values and norms)

    to produce a collective mentality within the population (Foucault 1978). This finds relevance within

    regime theory as it lends credence to the belief that states entrench a set of principles on a number

    of issues. Another, the notion of regimes as intervening variables, posits that the causal tendencies

    that account for regime creation should be held responsible for the final outcome or behaviour of an

    actor (Krasner 1982). Such causal tendencies include power and interest, for example, and may be

    manifest through the behaviour of individuals, particular bureaucracies, and IOs (ibid: 205). Third,

    the notion of nonterritorial imperialism developed by Susan Strange critiqued liberal institutionalist

    views of international regimes, instead stating that the American hegemon spreads its values acrossstates, firms, IOs and various other institutions (Strange 1982). This is achieved by a combination

    of military alliances and a world economy opened up to trade, investment and information (ibid:

    482). These views all recognise that exogenous factors are necessary in the formation of regimes,

    rejecting liberal institutionalist views that the mechanisms that produce regimes are endogenous to

    them (Krasner 1982).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    15/42

    14

    3.3. Conclusion: Theoretical overlaps and application

    Though neorealist and liberal institutionalist perspectives of international relations differ, they share

    some basic assumptions. The first concerns anarchy and actor behaviour, in the sense that conflicts

    and tensions are conditional, arising from a very specific set of circumstances (Powell 1994). For

    this case study on Iran, liberal institutionalists and neorealists would agree that events preceding the

    revolution, and the sanctions themselves, are responsible for the political and economic situation in

    Iran today. Despite disparities in the schools of thought concerning the role of institutions and other

    actors in bringing about these circumstances, there is consensus on conditionality and its importance

    in shaping current events (ibid). The second assumption is when it comes to the role of cooperation

    in forming international regimes: both liberal institutionalism and neorealism have an actor-oriented

    approach to international relations, because they see cooperation as conducive to an improvement in

    state relations and economic growth (ibid). While both theories differ on what the generative causes

    of cooperation are, they recognise that cooperation can contribute in the establishment of a stable

    political and economic relationship between states. These overlaps are necessary to consider during

    the application of theory to the case, which takes place in the analysis and discussion.

    In focusing on how the federal government has responded to economic sanctions, this report draws

    both on liberal institutionalist and neorealist perspectives. The pre-existing dichotomy between both

    points of view allows this report to analyse economic sanctions from a shared perspective of formal

    and informal institutional mechanisms that mitigate or strengthen the effects of economic sanctions.

    Institutions are formal when they are characterised by rule of law (e.g. constitutions, regulations) or

    bodies to carry out a set of enforced rules (e.g. legislatures, courts); however, they are informal if

    comprising societal or unenforceable rules, like tradition, religion or family (Helmke and Levitsky

    2003: 8). The disparity between institutions is important for the methodological application to the

    theoretical framework, since informal rules will so often govern the behaviour of formal stateactors, influencing both strategy and policy (ibid). I ultimately use different theoretical explanations

    to explain why the effectiveness of economic sanctions is circumvented by institutional mechanisms

    of interventionism, theocracy, and reformism. This framework will have further applicability as the

    report explains how recent initiatives to circumvent the Iranian embargo engage with the identified

    institutional mechanisms, and whether they effectively confirm the validity of either theory.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    16/42

    15

    4. Case: International sanctions on Iran

    4.1. Empirical data and case setting

    To uncover the mechanisms behind the Iranian embargo, this report will present empirical materialand highlight how it relates to economic sanctions. The empirical material has been chosen on the

    basis of Irans five-year development plans (FYPDs), leading up to the Iranian Revolution of 1979

    to present day. Empirical material will show that despite Iran having been a relatively prosperous

    economy in the 1960s and early 1970s, economic sanctions have contributed to its relative isolation

    in recent decades. As the Iranian government has been forced to adapt to economic sanctions, it has

    had to implement policies specifically designed to mitigate their effects. This section makes use of

    the material to draw upon the theories introduced to tease out which mechanisms in Iran have been

    entrenched due to international sanctions. This section will highlight three institutional mechanisms

    in particular: interventionism, theocracy, and reformism. However, before doing so, I delve into the

    importance of Irans five-year development plans (FYPDs), which have been a significant factor of

    agenda formation in the country since 1989.

    4.1.1. Five-year development plans (FYPDs)

    The Iranian Parliament, or Majlis, has been implementing the five-year development plans (FYPDs)

    developed by respective administrations since 1989, following the death of Ayatollah Khomeini and

    changes in the constitution. The purpose of these FYPDs has been to guide domestic policy-making

    towards economic development and reconstruction, as well as set individual targets according to the

    belief system of either party in power (Marschall 2003). FYPDs comprise an important role in this

    reports analytical focus, because they are symbolic of the governments policy goals in response to

    targeted sanctions and the US-imposed embargo. Though the goals of the proposed plans are often

    desirable, they are counteracted by the influence of actors whose interests collide with those of the

    federal government (e.g. states, IOs and firms). As economic sanctions continue to negatively affect

    the economy, Irans FYPDs suggest implementing policies that can guide the state through coercive

    foreign policies (ibid). The two major political parties, reformists and conservatives, are responsible

    for shaping their respective agendas in FYPDs during their term, and the outlined goals and policies

    need to be approved by the Supreme Leader (further discussed in section 4.1.3.). This is challenging

    for Irans long-term development, however, as either party may reverse policies and targets initially

    advanced by the other once elected.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    17/42

    16

    After the election of conservative Akbar Hashemi Rafsanjani, the first five-year development plan

    (1989-1994) was enacted, aiming to solve issues like restructuration of spending following the Iran-

    Iraq War, population migration, liquidity, and increasing inflation rates (Brumberg and Farhi 2016).

    The project of liberalisation in the early 1990s failed due to societal and geopolitical pressure, as the

    trade balance widened due to post-war demand, and the U.S. pressured other states to forestall new

    loans to the Islamic Republic (ibid: 84). Ensuing FYPDs have concentrated on economic openness

    (2ndFYPD), promoting structural reforms and civil liberties (3rdFYPD), a smaller government role

    and enterprise privatisation (4thFYPD), and a greater focus on energy sources and the private sector

    (5thFYPD). Each plan also aimed to reach quantitative targets, such as unemployment, inflation and

    growth; these medium-term economic plans have been crucial in shaping the objectives for future

    administrations as well (Ghasimi 2012). FYPDs have also played an important role in shaping how

    the federal government responds to economic sanctions, since domestic policies are only partially

    effective if the state is prevented from reaching its full potential.

    4.1.2. Interventionism

    4.1.2.1. Political intervention

    The Iranian Revolution of 1979, in which the Shah was overthrown in favour of an Islamic republic

    led by Ayatollah Khomeini, is often seen as a catalyst for contemporary Irans economic situation.

    However, a number of external factors account for the revolution, particularly foreign intervention

    and policies directed at Iran. Mohammad Mossadegh, who was elected as Irans first prime minister

    in 1951, pushed to nationalise assets held by the Anglo-Iranian Oil Company (Kapu!ci"ski 1985), a

    measure the United Kingdom perceived as a breach of contract. In response, a global campaign was

    mounted by the UK to ensure oil technicians and workers from various countries could not travel to

    Iran, persuaded multinational corporations to refuse to buy Iranian oil, and froze Iranian accounts in

    London and overseas (Kinzer 2010). Targeted sanctions motivated MNCs to withdraw from the oil

    refineries in the city of Abadan, effectively preventing the exportation of oil and other commodities

    (ibid). As diplomatic relations with the United States deteriorated, Iran became increasingly isolated

    from other states. Stephen Kinzer, a former New York Times correspondent, claims that: a strong

    democratic consciousness survives, but civic life is stunned (ibid: 127). Thus, while Irans current

    economic situation is often blamed on domestic politics, the revolution itself was partially due to

    Iranian suspicion of outside influence following the Abadan Crisis (ibid).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    18/42

    17

    The Abadan Crisis lasted from 1951-1953, after which Mossadegh was overthrown in a coup dtat

    by a joint CIA-MI6 operation, and replaced by Mohammad Reza Pahlavi, a pro-Western shah who

    portrayed himself as a reformer but whose rule became increasingly autocratic and repressive over

    time (Ansari 2001). To legitimise dynastic rule and institutionalise monarchical values in Iran, the

    shah launched a White Revolution in 1963, a strategy focusing on land reforms, restructuration of

    government spending (e.g. sales of state-owned factories), and the expansion of liberties for women

    (ibid). Though the reforms had far-reaching consequences in the goal towards westernisation, civil

    society in Iran was dismantled. The White Revolution was fundamentally a political programme

    conceived by members of the political elite in order to sustain as much of the established relations

    of domination as realistically possible (ibid: 2). The federal governments policies between 1953-

    1979 may have been largely pro-Western, but Iranians remained under dynastic rule with the shah

    attempting to preserve traditional power relations. Interventionism thus had severe repercussions on

    a political and economic level, as Iranians manifested their desire for self-governance by revolting

    in 1978-1979 and instilling the Ayatollah Khomeini in the shahs place (ibid).

    4.1.2.2. Economic intervention

    After the overthrow of Mohammed Reza Pahlavi in 1979, Irans economy became subject to US-

    imposed sanctions in finance/banking, trade, oil exports, asset freezes and travel bans, and weapons

    development (Laub 2015). Most of these sanctions were targeted, used as a diplomatic measure in

    response to issues deemed serious by the United States, such as funding international terrorism and

    the abuse of human rights (ibid). Travel bans directed at specific individuals, banks, and groups like

    the Iranian Revolutionary Guard Corps (IRGC), and the freezing of over $100 billion in assets held

    by the federal government were both meant to prevent fuelling proxy wars in the Middle East while

    preserving foreign interests (ibid). This was complemented in 2006 by a number of United Nations

    Security Council (UNSC) resolutions in direct response to Irans uranium enrichment program, andwas followed by European Union sanctions shortly thereafter (figure 1). The large number of actors

    involved reflects the many reasons why Iran is being coerced: while the UN and the EU have been

    motivated by concerns pertaining to nuclear weapons proliferation and conflict, US-imposed

    sanctions predate such concerns. These unilateral sanctions have covered a range of issues, such as

    the hostage crisis, human rights abuses, political developments, the nuclear energy program, and

    securing the interests of American allies in the region (ibid).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    19/42

    18

    Figure 1- GDP and oil production in Iran, 2005-2015 (The Economist 2015)

    As figure 1 demonstrates, the imposition of multilateral sanctions (UN-imposed) is correlated with a

    sharp decrease in Irans Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and increase in the price of Brent crude oil,

    which has had severe repercussions: Although Irans economy is less dependent on [oil] than some

    others in the region, it still accounts for 42% of government revenues (The Economist 2015). Two

    rounds of unilateral sanctions also harmed Irans economy. The first was the Iran-Libya Sanctions

    Act (ILSA), signed in 1996 by the Clinton administration in response to the states pursuit of

    nuclear energy and financial support of terrorist organisations like Hezbollah and Hamas (Katzman

    2006). This would deprive Iran of modernising its key petroleum sector, which generates about 20-

    25% of the countrys GDP (ibid). The second round of sanctions was the Comprehensive Iran

    Sanctions, Accountability and Divestment Act (CISADA), passed in 2011, according to which

    foreign-based financial institutions or subsidiaries that deal with sanctioned banks are barred fromconducting deals in the United States or with the U.S. dollar (Laub 2015). This would deter other

    states and corporations from dealing with sanctioned banks, a measure that has been called a death

    penalty for any bank (ibid). Irans oil exports were targeted, inhibiting multinational corporations

    (MNCs) from providing services related to the states energy sector. Exports of oil in Iran have

    fallen from 2.5 million bpd in 2011 to 1.1 million bpd in 2013, as the EU halts imports of oil

    altogether and other states dropping significantly (ibid).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    20/42

    19

    4.1.3. Theocracy

    The Iranian Revolution led to the overthrow of the Pahlavi dynasty and its replacement with a self-

    styled Islamic republic under Ayatollah Ruhollah Khomeini (1979-). Regime change was a crucial

    element in motivating the US to impose sanctions on Iran, but also had important effects on agenda

    formation and domestic policies. This section examines the political and economic implications of

    Irans theocratic government, looking first at the political spectrum in Iran and differences between

    the two major parties, and second at the immediate impact of the revolution and effects of theocratic

    ideology on policy-making and interstate cooperation.

    4.1.3.1. The political spectrum in Iran

    Iranian politics are syncretic, which designates a scale outside the conventional left-right spectrum.

    While reformists and conservatives encompass the two main coalitions, all constitutional authority

    resides with the Vali-e Faqih, or supreme leader (Sadjadpour 2009), a position currently held by Ali

    Khamenei. The Iranian political system is unusual since it combines Islamic law, or Shar!ah, with

    elements of representative democracy. Despite this hybrid system, the state remains authoritarian,

    as many pragmatic candidates are disallowed from running in presidential and legislative elections

    (ibid). The Observatory for Human Rights has claimed that elections in Iran are not democratic for

    the mere reason that the Council of Guardians chooses the nominees (Alexandros 2005). The swayof Irans theocracy over foreign policy in Iran is thus twofold: firstly, religious leaders consistently

    limit policy proposals and legislation of reformist and centrist political leaders, which prevents the

    representation of majority interests (ibid); secondly, international sanctions are being incrementally

    enacted by other states and IOs, which forces the government to continuously adapt its strategies in

    order to mitigate their effect (ibid).

    4.1.3.2. The economic impact of theocracy

    After the Iran hostage crisis, in which over sixty American citizens and diplomats were held captive

    in response to foreign intervention, the United States imposed unilateral economic sanctions against

    Tehran. This included asset freezes of around $12 billion (e.g. bank deposits, gold, etc.), primarily

    as a punitive measure in retaliation to the diplomatic crisis. The impact of these sanctions, alongside

    a military blockade imposed during the Iran-Iraq war, was reflected by stagnating GDP in the early

    1990s. Another pressing concern over this period was decreasing oil prices, as crude oil production

    dropped by 3.9 million barrels per day (bpd) by the end of the revolution due to investor uncertainty

    and international sanctions (Energy Information Administration 2002). This led to a crisis for the

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    21/42

    20

    Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), and was the main impetus for the 1979 oil

    shock (ibid). The combination of economic sanctions, decreasing oil prices and the enduring Iran-

    Iraq war was the primary cause of the sharp decline in Iranian GDP in the late 1980s, after a number

    of neutral countries halted trade due to insurance and military considerations (Farrokh 2011; figure

    2). Oil and non-oil exports fell by 55% during the war, oil revenues dropped from $20bn in 1982 to

    $5 bn in 1988, and the inflation rate reached 50% that same year (ibid).

    Figure 2- GDP in Iran, 1979-2016 (TradingEconomics 2016)

    Iranian morale crumbled as a result of both the embargo and military conflict, with the consequent

    economic stagnation lasting well over a decade. The imposition of the ILSA in 1996 and CISADA

    in 2011 only served to further entrench Irans stagnating economy. Though Iranian GDP increased

    in the early 2000s, this is largely the result of reforms passed by president Mohammad Khatami

    rather than sanctions relief. The Ahmadinejad administration oversaw an economic boom, but

    mounting global concern over Irans role in nuclear non-proliferation contributed to investorsuncertainty as the United States, the European Union and a number of supranational bodies imposed

    targeted sanctions on the federal government and related firms (Davenport 2015). As illustrated in

    figure 1, Irans GDP has experienced a significant decrease since 2010 as the result of multilateral

    sanctions imposed by IOs like the United Nations, the IMF, and the WTO. Power relations between

    conservative clerics and moderates remain, however, and constitute the main roadblock for potential

    economic reconstruction.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    22/42

    21

    4.1.4. Reformism

    As aforementioned, the largest parties in the Iranian political spectrum are the conservatives and the

    reformists. Following the Iranian revolution and the hostage crisis from 1979-1981, radicals under

    president Ali Khamenei dominated the Iranian Parliament (Majlis), and claimed American and EU

    sanctions were constructive instead of harmful as they encouraged self-sufficiency, forcing Iranians

    to adapt and survive with little outside aid (ibid). The federal government began to implement a

    series of policies and reforms in the late 1990s to respond to such economic coercion. The section

    examines three policies in particular: Khatamis structural reforms, Ahmadinejads subsidy reform

    plan, and the Rouhani nuclear deal with the P5+1.

    4.1.4.1. The Khatami reforms (1997-2005)

    The first reform occurred during the presidency of Mohammed Khatami, a moderate whose election

    was representative of Iranians wishes of a more open society. Advocating for greater political and

    social freedoms, the relaxation of cultural norms, and economic rehabilitation, Khatami attempted

    to fundamentally alter Iranian society (Menashri 2010: 61). Khatami, elected in 1997, presided over

    the 3rdFYPD, which focused on structural reforms as a number of improvements were made in the

    rule of law, individual freedoms, social justice, and political tolerance (Siddiqi 2006). Though Iran

    presided over a period of economic growth in the late 1990s and early 2000s, this was not the resultof theocratic ideologies, but rather reformist policies promoted under the 2ndand 3rdFYPDs. On the

    economy, Khatamis goal was to create 750,000 new jobs annually and achieving an average yearly

    real GDP growth of 6%, as well as to reduce subsidies for major commodities (ibid). While most of

    the reforms ultimately failed to pass due to political differences with the Ayatollah and ruling elite,

    Khatami was able to successfully begin a reformist movement that lasted beyond his presidency. I

    argue that this is because the institutional mechanism of reformism can even result from attempts at

    policy change, since failure at enacting policies may instigate actual reform over time:

    Khatami failed to implement his major reforms. But his policies have had some positive effects. The

    economy has started moving forward, even if progress has been slower than expected. Violations by the

    courts have been repeatedly highlighted, though they have not been prevented. A number of stifling

    social restrictions have been lifted, at least unofficially. It is still dangerous to be openly critical of the

    regime, but the level of free speech is unprecedented to the years before Khatami (Siddiqi 2006).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    23/42

    22

    The efforts of reform during Khatamis term were futile due to political differences, and the Majlis

    was ultimately unable to enact open market or humanitarian policies (ibid). International sanctions

    led to opposition by radical factions of the conservative side, legitimising their narrative that foreign

    intervention in domestic affairs, rather than isolationism and the repression of civil liberties, should

    be held accountable for Irans economic situation. Yet, minor successes of first-wave reformists

    under Khatami set the stage for the increased desire for economic openness and structural change.

    The increased focus on civil society acted as a counterbalance to corruption and theocracy, instead

    promoting positive values like transparency and development (Rivetti and Cavatorta 2013). Even a

    number of former Khomeinist revolutionaries became reformist, and denounced the transformation

    of revolutionary ideals into the defence of privileges acquired by certain social groups since the

    revolution (ibid: 648). The reformist rhetoric that emerged from Khatami assuaged foreign powers

    like the United States, who eased sanctions on Iran imposed as part of the ILSA. In the end, trends

    and discourses emerging from the Khatami era culminated in the 2013 election of Hassan Rouhani

    and achievements by second-wave reformists, including the signature of the Iranian nuclear deal

    in 2015 that brought global sanctions relief to Iran.

    4.1.4.2. Ahmadinejads subsidy reform plan (2005-2013)

    The second reform examined here was launched during Mahmoud Ahmadinejads presidency. AfterIrans refusal to interrupt its nuclear program and collaborate with the International Atomic Energy

    Agency (IAEA), the United Nations imposed comprehensive sanctions as a punitive measure and to

    encourage compliance (Haidar 2016). Over the following years, this was complemented by UNSC

    resolutions which included an arms embargo, freezing of assets, global monitoring of Iranian banks,

    targeted travel bans, and cargo inspections (ibid). To mitigate the impact of sanctions, Ahmadinejad

    carried out structural reforms by passing a subsidy reform plan (Nikou and Glenn 2010). The plan,

    passed as part of the 5thFYPD, aimed to phase out all subsidies within five years, as immediate cuts

    affected the price of various products (petroleum, wheat, sugar, etc.), and instead of subsidies, small

    sums of cash would be distributed to individuals (ibid). Despite the sanctions having been imposed

    in response to the risk of nuclear proliferation, they harmed the economy: during the Ahmadinejad

    administration, both Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and per capita income were lower than during

    either of his predecessors terms (figure 3). However, this was more than just the result of sanctions:

    isolationist policies and fervent nationalism both contributed (ibid).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    24/42

    23

    Figure 3- GDP and per capita income by administration (IMF 2012; cited in Habibi 2013)

    The Subsidy Reform Law, a crucial component of Irans 5thFYPD, aimed to remove price subsidies

    over five years, requiring for domestic prices of gasoline and other refined oil products be raised to

    within 90 percent of the international prices for delivery of these items to Persian Gulf destinations

    (Habibi 2013: 3). The ultimate objective of the plan was to increase standards of living for lower-

    income households and working class families, expand production efficiency and export capacity,

    and reduce income inequality (ibid). Though Ahmadinejad ultimately implemented the reform plan,

    economic sanctions lifted inflation and unemployment, and empowered the Islamic Revolutionary

    Guard Corps (IRGC). The IRGC, a militant arm of the republic, tried to curb the effects of sanctions

    by increasing smuggling efforts and using front companies in other countries to produce imports of

    essential goods (ibid: 6). Despite the economic significance of Ahmadinejads subsidy reform plan

    for Iran in the long term, the effects of international sanctions mitigated any optimistic prospects of

    reducing poverty and income inequality in Iran. As the institutional mechanism of reformism occurs

    incrementally, the conservative policies of Ahmadinejad reversed the progress made under Khatami

    (e.g. fractured relations with the US). Yet, this was only temporary: even though Ahmadinejads

    presidency experienced a lower average GDP than either of his predecessors, cooperation was only

    halted until the election of a more moderate, outward-looking candidate (Habibi 2013).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    25/42

    24

    4.1.4.3. Rouhani and the Iranian nuclear deal (2013-)

    The third reform was the signature in 2015 of the Iranian nuclear deal between Iran, the P5+1 (five

    permanent members of the UNSC), and the EU. The treaty, also known as the Joint Comprehensive

    Plan of Action (JCPOA), implied the lifting of all targeted sanctions should the federal government

    agree to reduce the number of centrifuges and enriched uranium (JCPOA 2015). The deal incurred

    the freeing of over $100 billion of foreign-held Iranian assets, allowing Iran to export 300,000 bpd,

    and authorising the modernisation of economic sectors such as transportation or infrastructure (Naji

    2016). The Iranian federal government under Hassan Rouhani provided the IAEA with full agency,

    visibility and accountability over Iranian nuclear reactors in return, and reduced its total stockpile of

    enriched uranium to less than 300 kilograms (Kerry 2016). Making remarks on implementation day,

    the United States Secretary of State, John Kerry, praised the benefits of diplomacy and negotiation

    over conflict and war (ibid). However, reconnecting Iran to the global financial system is a point of

    contention: a number of critics claim Iran is likely to continue weapons development and use newly

    unfrozen assets to fund regional militant groups like the Palestinian Liberation Organization (PLO)

    or Hezbollah, and promote Irans national interests in the region (Naji 2016).

    The JCPOA was significant from a domestic policy perspective as well. The 6thFYPD (2016-2021),

    submitted on the same day as sanctions were lifted, emphasised a larger focus on attracting foreigninvestment and less reliance on oil revenues (Financial Tribune 2016). The federal government set a

    growth target of 8% annually, responding to falling crude oil prices, decades of isolationist policies,

    and a high unemployment rate (ibid). In the 2016 legislative elections, the first after the signing of

    the deal, moderate reformists made gains in the Majlis and the Assembly of Experts, illustrating the

    growing desire for economic openness and rapprochement with the West (Salehi-Isfahani 2016). In

    between 2013 and 2016, the inflation rate has dropped from a high of 34.7% to less than 10% (ibid).

    And yet, economic successes have not translated to higher wages, while the pursuit of monetary and

    fiscal policies to fight inflation has negatively impacted per capita income (ibid). Anxieties remain

    that the United States Congress may impose fresh non-nuclear related sanctions, and that American

    restrictions on dollar-denominated transactions with Iran may deter European investors and MNCs

    (Geranmayeh 2016). Despite economic hardships, ordinary Iranians have received a psychological

    boost from the political opening accompanying the nuclear deal and welcome the distance from the

    shadow of war (ibid). The JCPOA has provided the basis for future progress.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    26/42

    25

    4.2. Analysis of interaction between institutional mechanisms

    The purpose of this section is to analyse the interaction between the mechanisms uncovered in the

    theory and empirical sections. First, I will argue that the mechanism of foreign interventionism

    lends credibility to the neorealist school of thought, since the establishment of democratic

    institutions in Iran and the potential for economic growth have been stymied by international

    sanctions. This has occurred to the benefit of the United States and Iranian theocrats, and to the

    detriment of ordinary Iranians. Second, I will demonstrate how the FYPDs and reformist tendencies

    have buoyed liberal institutionalist beliefs that IOs and other institutions can lead to cooperation and

    economic growth, and diminish relations of power between hegemons and subordinated states. The

    two-part causal analysis illustrates the link between theory and empirical facts, showing a set of

    empirical regularities that show how sanctions have affected the policies of the Iranian federal

    government. The analysis shows how the studied institutional mechanisms can positively or

    negatively impact the tendencies perpetuated by economic sanctions.

    4.2.1. Interventionism and theocracy: Neorealist applications

    4.2.1.1. Economic sanctions and foreign intervention

    Eli Heckscher (1879-1952), an economist, describes sanctions as a form of economic warfare,

    since they weaken the ability of other states to pursue conflict: sever the trading links between the

    enemy and their allies and also with neutral powers and, in so doing, to reduce the level of military

    and civilian goods available to support military ventures (David and Engerman 2006: 348). The

    policies included in sanctions, such as higher tariffs or encouraging production of substitutes, thus

    fit within a neorealist framework as states abandon trade with a specific country to fulfil their own

    interests. Heckscher recognises this, claiming that the aim of sanctions is not economic but political,

    because a state that adopts sanctions hopes to influence third countries behaviour toward a target

    state in the process (ibid: 350). While countries like the United States have long used sanctions as a

    diplomatic tool to coerce foreign governments into changing their behaviour, their effectiveness is

    questionable. Glenn Kessler from the Washington Postclaims that today, the prospect of sanctions

    relief is likely to have more impact than sanctions themselves: the promise of easing sanctions is

    sometimes used as a lure to induce countries to change behaviour (Kessler 2011). This follows

    from Heckschers view of sanctions as a political tool, in that they coerce uncooperative regimes to

    concede to the demands made by dominant states (ibid).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    27/42

    26

    Heckschers assessment is important to this case study, because foreign policies can often shape

    both the political landscape and economic outcomes (figure 1). Neorealists posit that cooperation

    stems from states attempting to satisfy their own interests rather than achieve mutual gains, and as

    such there are limits to cooperating in international regimes (Powell 1994). While the 1953-1979

    period oversaw a pro-Western reformist shah, the state became more autocratic to the detriment of

    Iranian citizens. An important distinction thus needs to be made between coercion and cooperation,

    since the former is institutionally triggered while the latter is the result of interstate activity (ibid).

    For this case, the distinction is made clear by events which occurred after 1979: policies directed at

    the Iranian government aimed to prevent structural issues, like corruption, the spread of theocratic

    ideology, human rights abuses, or the funding of militant groups. However, rather than achieving

    concessions, they instead caused major harm to the Iranian economy by deterring foreign investors

    and entrenching poverty in Iran (OECD 2011). The institutional mechanism of interventionism thus

    contributed to the isolation of Iran from the rest of the world, lending credence to neorealist views

    of the international regime and the limits of cooperation (Powell 1994).

    4.2.1.2. Economic sanctions and Iranian theocracy

    The Iranian Revolution led to a decline in GDP and a drop in oil production from 5m bpd in 1979 to

    1.5m bpd in 1981 (figure 4). After the ideology promoted by the Ayatollah Khomeini took root, a

    hybrid republican theocratic system based on Islamic law was installed. The immediate effect of

    this was an escalation of corruption: Transparency International ranks Iran 136 th in the Corruption

    Perceptions Index (CPI) and the World Bank places Iran 118th in the ease-of-doing-business index

    (The Economist 2016). The hybrid nature of Iranian politics designates a semi-representative state;

    while there is a broad political spectrum covering a range of interests, candidates must be approved

    by both the Supreme Leader Khamenei and high-ranking jurists and theologians from the Guardian

    Council (Brumberg and Farhi 2016). Any change that occurs thus requires working through, ratherthan against, the existing institutions of Irans semi-autocracy (ibid). The elections of moderate

    centrists Mohammad Khatami in 1997 and Hassan Rouhani in 2013 are indications of such change

    (figure 4), since for both years, the Guardian Council approved all radicals and very few moderates.

    The Iranian regime is therefore characterised by a particular set of principles and norms (informal

    institutions) based on theocratic values that have inspired the rule of law, including the process of

    policy-making domestically and abroad (ibid).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    28/42

    27

    Figure 4- GDP and oil production in Iran, 1965-2015 (The Economist 2016)

    At the height of the revolution, the population in Iran numbered 37.47m, and within fifteen years it

    soared to just under 60m. The establishment of a theocratic regime in Iran encouraged the economic

    burden faced by ordinary Iranians: to appease a war-weary society after the conflict, the theocracy

    kept consumer prices for energy, basic foods, medicines and utilities () well below market prices

    (Nikou and Glenn 2010). The Iranian Revolution and the birth of the theocratic system were largely

    fuelled by a suspicion of interventionism in Iran. The last shah of Iran was overthrown as a result of

    resistance to foreign influence in the region, a declining economy, increasing dependence on oil,

    and civil rights violations (Kamel 2015: 45). Such suspicion carried out through the Ali Khamenei

    administration, as economic sanctions were imposed and the United States supported Iraq during

    the Iran-Iraq war from 1980-1988 (ibid). The post-revolutionary Iranian regime therefore fits within

    neorealist ideology in the sense that the American hegemon, which had been dominant in the region

    for much of the 20thcentury, began to lose sway over an increasingly unstable region. Hasenclever

    et al. (2000) defined this as hegemonic afterglow, during which the uncontested superiority of the

    leader has vanished, but factors such as inertia, habit, or fear of instability resulting from change

    work in favour of the regimes the once dominant state had established at the height of its power

    (Hasenclever et al. 2000: 9).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    29/42

    28

    Another dimension of neorealism that applies to theocratic regimes is the game theoretical concept

    of a Prisoners Dilemma. This represents a situation where two rational actors who would gain most

    from cooperation may not do so due to asymmetric information (Powell 1994). This model is useful

    in international relations since it illustrates neorealist assumptions of the international system (ibid).

    Joseph Grieco, who developed neorealist regime theory, claims: player[s] responds to an iterated

    conventional Prisoners Dilemma with conditional cooperation solely out of a desire to maximise its

    individual long-term total payoffs (Grieco 1988: 496). Though all players would stand to gain the

    most from cooperating with each other, they nevertheless aim to optimise their own situation. Thus,

    neorealist understanding of actor rationality claims that any cooperation that results from interstate

    linkages is purely self-motivated, because states will care not only about absolute, but also relative

    gains (ibid). Figure 5, which represents an iterated Prisoners Dilemma matrix, demonstrates this in

    the case of Iran (x-axis) and the United States (y-axis).1The optimal scenario for both countries is if

    both cooperate (CC), whereas the least desirable scenario is defection (DD).

    Figure 5- Iterated Prisoners Dilemma between Iran and the United States

    1The matrix is iterated since the situation can occur repeatedly for a single scenario.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    30/42

    29

    The case study on Iran conveys one final important neorealist concept: international anarchy. This

    is best understood as the geopolitical tensions faced by states that create fears of being cheated and

    prevent achieving autonomy and self-reliance (Hasenclever et al. 2000). The struggle for autonomy

    is brought about by a lack of a common government between states, denying [subordinated states]

    the luxury of being egoists who, by definition, are indifferent to how well others do (ibid: 9). In the

    case of Iran, the implication is that the federal government will choose not to comply with foreign

    demands as it takes both absolute andrelative gains into account; countries would thus be sensitive

    to the gains made by all other actors involved, despite accruing absolute gains (ibid). This was made

    evident during the Rafsanjani administration, as relations with the United States and other Western

    states remained poor due to foreign involvement in the Gulf War, increased financial sanctions, and

    differences with the American political system (Marschall 2003). Rafsanjani, a centrist conservative

    who focus economic reconstruction following a decade-long war, had his foreign policies dictated

    by convention and the doctrine of the Ayatollah Ali Khamenei. Despite the potential of normalising

    relations with the US, policies in Iran were nevertheless contingent on a decade-long revolutionary

    ideology that no longer represented the sentiments of Iranians.

    4.2.2. Reformism and the FYPDs: Liberal institutionalist applications

    4.2.2.1. Incremental change: The Khatami reforms (1997-2005)

    The institutional mechanism of reformism, while influenced by dynamics within Iran and occurring

    domestically, is only one of the factors causing international repercussions. Increased pressure from

    the EU - which is generally unsympathetic to sanctions - and many American business lobby groups

    have also forced the US Congress to focus its action in a targeted way on firms that violated specific

    international agreements (Clawson et al. 1998). However, internal developments during Khatamis

    presidency added to the views of Iran as compliant and accommodating rather than confrontational

    (ibid). The US continued to pursue a simultaneous foreign policy of sanctions and dialogue, in order

    to maintain a bargaining chip while attempting to make progress. This policy would end once Iran

    demonstrates that it has altered or abandoned the policies that led to the imposition of sanctions in

    the first place (ibid). Following from this logic, the Khatami reforms under the 2 ndand 3rdFYPDs

    represented much more than domestic change, altering the nationalist rhetoric that Tehran conveyed

    in favour of a more open and moderate image. After ILSA sanctions were eased, the importance of

    reformism became apparent, not just for policy on a domestic level but cooperation more broadly.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    31/42

    30

    In the long-term, the reforms launched under Khatami fit with liberal institutionalist beliefs, which

    identify agenda formation as one of the generative causes of mutual dependence (Keohane and Nye

    1987). Liberal institutionalist notions like linkages and agenda formation are becoming increasingly

    relevant as the US, the EU, and other states begin lifting sanctions on Iran following the ratification

    of the JCPOA (4.2.2.3). Despite the fact that Khatamis reforms failed to materialise in his term, his

    attempts at reform have paved the way for the signature and ratification of the 2015 nuclear deal. A

    former reformist member of the Majlis, Reza Yousefian, has stated in a similar vein that the concept

    of reform should be understood as a social rather than legal phenomenon: if you interpret reform as

    a movement within the government, this is the end. But if you regard it as a social phenomenon,

    then it is still very much alive (Yousefian, cited in Siddiqi 2006). Khatamis efforts are thus rooted

    in mutual dependence theory, because many of his initiatives aiming to curb issues related to human

    rights or civil liberties have generated the lifting of unilateral and multilateral sanctions in the long

    run. Despite power struggles with ruling clerics, the attempted reforms of Khatami would pave the

    way for lifting sanctions under a second-wave of reformists in 2013.

    4.2.2.2. Mitigating sanctions: The Ahmadinejad administration (2005-2013)

    The Iranian election of 2005 represented a significant turning point in domestic and foreign policies

    for the state following the win of hardline conservative Mahmoud Ahmadinejad, who garnered 62%

    of the electorate on a demagogic platform of self-reliance and isolationism (The Economist 2005).

    Ahmadinejads election represented the chance for structural reform, including solving issues such

    as poverty and corruption (ibid), but also illustrated worry over American intervention in the region.

    The election emboldened conservatives, particularly because high-ranking religious leaders and the

    Ayatollah Khamenei shared similar social and economic beliefs with Ahmadinejad, but also created

    tensions in the international community as the country became increasingly inward looking and was

    closer to developing a nuclear weapon (ibid). The longing to enact internal reform as a substitute formaking concessions to foreign states came in the form of the subsidy reform law, and illustrated the

    price Iran paid over this period to preserve its sovereignty. As economic success in Iran was largely

    dependent on the perceived cooperation of the state, which was high under Rafsanjani and Khatami,

    Irans performance during the Ahmadinejad administration has been dismal. Therefore, while Iran

    desires to achieve absolute gains from trade, the federal government has been sacrificing immediate

    sanctions relief to promote theocratic ideologies and isolationist policies.

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    32/42

    31

    The foreign and domestic policies under Ahmadinejad are anathema to liberal institutionalism since

    the desire for autonomy should not imply an isolationist mentality and putting an end to cooperation

    (Axelrod and Keohane 1985). However, the failure to mitigate sanctions and revitalise the economy

    corroborates the necessity to comply with states and IOs, so that a mutual dependency can arise, in

    which all states are better off (ibid). The theory of mutual dependence ultimately presupposes that

    the political process, and not structural factors, influence state behaviour. The 2005 election and the

    ensuing international response demonstrate how global uncertainty can impact domestic outcomes.

    Robert Axelrod (1943-) has expanded mutual dependence to incorporate a game theoretical view of

    collaboration: he posits that even in a world where independent states are jealously guarding their

    sovereignty and protecting their power, room exists for new and better arrangements to achieve

    mutually satisfactory outcomes (Axelrod and Keohane 1985: 253). This is clear repudiation of the

    neorealist understanding of cooperation within an iterative framework (figure 5), and of isolationist

    beliefs under Ahmadinejad - namely, refusal to cooperate with the IAEA and the choice to ignore

    the tightening of sanctions by supranational institutions (e.g. UN, IMF).

    4.2.2.3. Lifting sanctions: The second-wave reformists (2013-)

    The signature of the JCPOA in July 2015 represented extensive unilateral and multilateral sanctions

    relief on various Iranian business sectors (shipping, energy, automotive, etc.). The JCPOA followed

    two years of negotiation between the administration of Hassan Rouhani, a pragmatic centrist elected

    in 2013, and the P5+1, the five permanent members of the UNSC. The prospect of lifting sanctions

    has produced a number of social, political and economic benefits: the release of political prisoners,

    increased freedom of the press, landslide victories for centrists in legislative elections to the Majlis

    and Assembly of Experts, and economic growth in 2014-2015 of about 2-3% (Katzman 2016). The

    JCPOA also has the potential to bring Iran back to double-digit growth in the first year if Iran uses

    the sanctions relief mostly to try to rebuild its civilian economy (ibid). Critics of the JCPOA claimthis scenario is unlikely, and that the nuclear deal might benefit Iran to the detriment of its regional

    neighbours; in other words, lifting the embargo would provide the state with the resources to pursue

    its regional aims (ibid). Henry Kissinger, a neorealist, condemns the nuclear deal on the basis that

    Iran and the US have different objectives, and cooperation presupposes corresponding definitions of

    stability (Kissinger and Shultz 2015). Without linkages between political and nuclear restraint, an

    agreement freeing Iran from sanctions risks empowering [its] hegemonic efforts (ibid).

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    33/42

    32

    The JCPOA is the embodiment of liberal institutionalist views on cooperation. The theory of mutual

    dependence represents a situation where the optimal outcome is only reached if all actors involved

    cooperate under imperfect information (Axelrod and Keohane 1985). Axelrod and Keohane discuss

    the notion of reciprocity, which requires the ability to recognise and retaliate against defectors; this

    may cause problems of asymmetric information, which is in turn solved by the exercise of power

    over subordinate countries: powerful actors structure relationships so that countries committed to a

    given order can deal effectively with those that have lower levels of commitment (ibid: 249). The

    negotiations between Iran and the P5+1 demonstrate a situation of asymmetric information for all

    the actors involved, since success is dependent on more than just good will (e.g. internal dynamics).

    However, should Iran cheat or defect, a snapback process could reinstate economic sanctions, and

    would simply signify a return to the status quo (Taub 2015). Despite interdependence between Iran

    and the United States being beneficial to both states, Iran has more to lose from defecting (ibid). In

    the end, the JCPOA represents a situation of cooperation that is more institutionalist than neorealist:

    one that is characterized by dialogue and negotiations despite conflicting interests.

    4.3. Conclusion

    This report has narrowed its analytical focus to three mechanisms that intensify economic sanctions:

    interventionism, theocracy and reformism. However, these three pillars are contextually dependent,

    since they can have positive and negative effects depending on internal and external circumstances.

    The first section on interventionism found that foreign policies (political and economic) can trigger

    domestic policies within Iran that clash with the initial intention of intervention. The second section

    on theocracy found that while the embargo can intensify the economic burden, theocratic ideologies

    are also accountable for frayed relations with other states and the entrenchment of populist policies.

    Finally, the third section on reformism found that policies advanced in the FYPDs and by respective

    administrations can mitigate the burden of economic sanctions and encourage cooperation between

    states. The preceding analysis uncovered liberal institutionalist and neorealist applications to these

    institutional mechanisms, claiming that interventionism and theocracy support neorealist viewpoints

    of international anarchy and the damaging effects of IOs, while reformism (and FYPDs) encourages

    liberal institutionalist beliefs like agenda formation, interstate cooperation and mutual dependence.

    However, these institutional mechanisms cannot contribute to an understanding of empirical reality

    in isolation, and should instead be studied in relation to each other. Since critical realists argue that

    reality is open and differentiated, this entails that phenomena do not result from the sheer existence

  • 7/26/2019 International Sanctions on Iran

    34/42

    33

    of objects and mechanisms, but rather from their interactio