how taxes and subsidies affect prices quantities

Upload: karina-chavez-enriquez

Post on 07-Apr-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    1/26

    4.How Taxes and Subsidies

    Affect Prices and Quantities

    The art of taxation consists in so plucking the goose as to obtain the largest amount of

    feathers with the least possible amount of hissing.

    J.B. Colbert, circa 1683

    (The quotation from Colbert captures the essence of Okuns [1975] argument that we

    will read later in the semester.)

    This class deals with the effects that taxes (and subsidies) have on prices and

    quantities. The issues are important because the public sector depends on taxes for the

    revenues to purchase services such as public school education. Consequently, it is

    important to understand how particular taxes influence the prices consumers pay, output

    levels (and consequently, employment levels), and tax revenues raised. We will focus

    particularly on the consequences of the imposition of sales taxes on a particular service,

    rental of hotel rooms, in part because they are common taxes imposed by local

    governments and states, and in part because the consequences of such taxes are somewhat

    easier to show than the consequences of other types of taxes.

    Think about the issue of taxes from the perspective of the mayor of a middle-sized

    city. She may wish to support the school superintendents desire for additional funds for

    the public schools, but she is also very concerned about the possible impacts that new

    taxes might have on the unemployment rate of local residents (unemployed people tend to

    vote against the incumbent), and on the prices paid by local residents (her constituency)

    for goods and services.

    One of the mayors advisors suggests a $10 per night, per room, tax on hotel

    rooms. Arguments in support of this tax are that it will generate $5 million per year in

    revenue (since the city has averaged 500,000 hotel rooms in use in each of the last few

    years), that the tax will be borne almost entirely by visitors (who do not vote), and that it

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    2/26

    4.2 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and Quantitieswill have virtually no impact on employment since the citys many hotels have been quite

    full. Analyze the impact of the tax, both in the short run and the long run, on revenue

    raised, on number of hotel rooms in use per year (which is a measure of employment), and

    on the price of a hotel room.

    Assume initially that the hotel market in the town is in equilibrium with 500,000

    rooms in use per year, at a price of $100 per room per night. Further assume that the

    supply of hotel rooms, QS, (in both the short run and the long run) is as follows:

    QS = 2,500 PS + 250,000,

    where PS is the price per room that hotel owners receive.

    Assume that the short run demand for hotel rooms is as follows:

    QD

    SR = 600,000 - 1,000PD

    ,where PD is the price that hotel guests pay,

    and that the long run demand is as follows:

    QDLR = 900,000 - 4,000PD.

    To verify that the initial equilibrium price = 100, set QS = QDSR or QS = QDLR, and solve for P.

    Notice that in the absence of a tax, PS = PD.

    Then verify that the equilibrium quantity is 500,000, by substituting P = 100 into

    the QS

    function, the QD

    SR function, or the QD

    LR function.

    Now consider the effect of the tax in the short run. One immediate effect is that

    the price owners receive, PS, is going to be $10 less than the amount that the consumers

    pay, PD. In other words, PS = PD - 10.

    Substitute this expression, PD 10, into the supply function.1

    QS = 2,500(PD - 10) + 250,000

    QS = 2,500PD + 225,000

    1 Another way to think about the effect of the tax here is that the total cash (PS) that the owner, when all issaid and done, will get to keep from any transaction is $10 less than whatever amount of cash that theconsumer will have to pay out of her pocket. That is, there is a $10 difference between the gross amountpaid by consumers (that appears as theirtotalon the hotel receipt) and the net amount that the owners get tokeep. What is more, by algebraic manipulation, we see thatPD =PS + 10. This is an alternate way ofexpressing thePS =PD 10 equation; by saying thatPD =PS + 10, we are simply saying that the full price thatthe consumer has to pay includes the amount seller will get to keep (PS) plus $10.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    3/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.3

    Now set QS = QD, and solve for PD, PS, and Q (in the short run).

    2,500 PD + 225,000 = 600,000 - 1,000PD

    PD = 107.14

    P

    S =P

    D - 10

    PS = 97.14

    QS = 2,500(97.14) + 250,000

    = 492,850

    In other words, the effect of the tax in the short run was to increase the price

    consumers paid by $7.14. Since the tax totalled $10, consumers bore 71 percent of the

    burden of the tax, or 71 percent of the incidence of the tax. The number of hotel rooms

    used declined by 7,150, or 1.4 percent.One might ask why consumers did not bear the full burden of the tax in the short

    run. The reason is that competition among hotel owners to fill their empty rooms led

    Quantity of Hotel Rooms

    Price

    ($)QS

    QDSR

    A

    C

    B

    PD=107.14

    PS=97.14

    100

    493 500

    Figure 1. The Short-Run Effect of the $10 Hotel Tax.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    4/26

    4.4 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and Quantitiesgthem to reduce the price slightly. As a result, their net revenue per room fell to $97.14, or

    $2.86 less than the amount received before the tax was introduced. Thus, in the short run,

    the suppliers bore 29 percent of the burden of the tax (2.86/10.00).Also, notice that even in the short run the tax proceeds were not quite the

    anticipated $5 million, a projection based on the assumption of no decline in the number of

    hotel rooms rented. In the short run, the annual proceeds from the tax amounted to $4.93

    million. Figure 1 displays the pre-tax equilibrium values of P and Q, and the post-tax short

    run equilibrium values of PD, PS, Q, and the amount of tax revenue collected.

    One important point to notice is that the impacts of the tax on the equilibrium

    prices (PS and PD) and quantity were derived without knowing whether it was the buyers

    or the sellers who were legally liable for the tax. In fact, this is always the case: The legalincidence of the tax does not influence the actual incidence in perfectly competitive

    markets. In this case, the actual incidence was that 29 percent of the tax was borne by the

    sellers and 71 percent of the tax was borne by the consumers. The actual incidence of the

    tax depends on the elasticities of demand and supply (as reflected in the shapes of the

    demand and supply curves), not on the legal incidence.

    To this point, we have focused on the short run effects of the tax. The long run

    effects are likely to be somewhat different because both demand functions and supply

    functions tend to be more elastic in the long run than in the short run. The reason is that

    both consumers and providers have more time to adjust. To keep the algebra simple, we

    assume that there is no change in the supply function, and focus on the effects of having

    the long run demand function be more elastic than the short run demand function. The

    reason that the long run demand is more sensitive to price than the short run demand is

    that consumers have more time to seek out alternative sites for vacations that would avoid

    the $7.14 price increase resulting from the tax. Also, organizations booking convention

    space may have commitments to the hotels in the short run, but they can seek other sites

    for subsequent conventions.

    Following the same methods used to calculate the short run effects of the tax, we

    can show that in the long run the price consumers pay will be $103.85, implying that they

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    5/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.5

    bear 39 percent of the burden of the tax. The price suppliers receive falls to $93.85, and

    they bear 61 percent of the tax. The number of hotel rooms rented per year falls to 484,615,

    a reduction of 3.1 percent from the number rented before the tax. If employment is

    proportional to output, this implies that local employment in the hotel industry fell by 3.1

    percent as a result of the tax. Total revenue per year from the tax will be $4.84 million.

    These long run effects are displayed in Figure 2. The rectangle BCGF depicts the tax

    revenue. Note that if we had assumed that the long run supply curve was more elastic

    than the short run supply curve, the reductions in the number of hotel rooms rented and

    in local employment in the hotel industry would have been greater. Can you explain why

    the long-run supply would be more elastic than the short-run supply?

    In fact, experimentation with the curves in Figure 1 and Figure 2 will show that,

    holding the demand function constant, the more sensitive the quantity supplied is to price

    (i.e., the higher the supply elasticity), the larger the portion of the tax that will be borne by

    consumers and the larger will be the decrease in the equilibrium quantity (and

    consequently the larger will be the decrease in the number of people employed in the

    Quantity of Hotel Rooms

    Price

    ($)QS

    QDLR

    A

    C

    B

    PD=103.85

    PS=93.85

    100

    484 500

    Figure 2. The Long-Run Effect of the $10 Hotel Tax.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    6/26

    4.6 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and Quantitiesindustry). There is an implication here for tax policy. When the policy goal is to raise tax

    revenue, imposing a tax on goods for which the supply elasticity is very high is not

    effective policy because such a tax raises consumer prices, reduces employment, and does

    not raise much tax revenue.

    Experimentation with the graphs will also show you that, holding the supply

    function constant, the more elastic the demand function is, the smaller the proportion of

    the tax that will be borne by consumers and the larger will be the reduction in the

    equilibrium quantity. Thus, imposing taxes on commodities, such as alcohol sold in

    Massachusetts, that have many substitutes, such as alcohol purchased in New Hampshire,

    is likely to have significant employment effects on the Massachusetts retail alcohol

    business. The same can be said about New Jerseys tax on heavy trucks (see the N.Y. Timesarticle at the end of the notes for this class).

    Come to class prepared to explain why the New Jersey tax wasineffective and whether a national tax on heavy trucks would have had

    different consequences.

    Also read the N.Y. Times article on the consequences of differences in

    the alcohol taxing policies of England and France.

    In addition, come prepared to discuss the Business Week article by Gary

    Becker on the consequences of the proposed increase in the cigarette tax.

    Using the information in the Becker article, calculate the short-run own-

    price elasticity of demand for cigarettes. What is the long-run own-price

    elasticity? Would a tax increase that raised the price of cigarettes by 25

    cents result in an increase or a decrease in the total amount of money

    consumers spend on cigarettes? Why? How would cigarette

    manufacturers react to a government policy requiring that they raise the

    price of a pack of cigarettes from the current level of about $2.25 to aminimum of $3.00? Calculate the long run percentage reduction that this

    price increase would have on the number of cigarettes purchased.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    7/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.7

    The important lesson for tax policy is that if the goal of the tax is to raise revenue

    and to minimize the reduction in output and employment brought about by the tax, then

    the tax should be imposed on goods for which the demand is very price inelastic; in which

    case the price paid by consumers will rise, but output will not fall very much. Or the tax

    should be imposed on goods for which the supply is very price inelastic, in which case the

    price consumers pay will not rise very much, and output will not fall very much. (The

    price firms receive will fall by almost the amount of the tax.)

    The difficulty in implementing this policy is that, while the short run elasticities of

    demand and supply may be quite low for certain goods, long run elasticities are typically

    much higher because consumers find substitutes and so do producers. Nonetheless, the

    lesson does have some implications. For example, sales taxes imposed by municipalitiesare likely to bring about greater reductions in output than are sales taxes imposed by

    states. One reason is that, with municipal taxes, consumers need only drive to the next

    town to make their purchases and avoid the tax. With state taxes, the drive is longer and

    many consumers wont bother. Also, firms can avoid the sales taxes by relocating in the

    next town. The bigger the geographical area covered by the tax, the longer the move that

    firms must undertake to avoid the tax. Similarly, a state imposed hotel tax is less likely to

    result in a large employment loss than a local hotel tax.

    Thus, there are many reasons why local citizens should be cautious in their

    assessment of local taxes. First, writing the tax law in a manner that states that producing

    firms rather than consumers are legally responsible for the tax does not mean that the tax

    will not affect the prices consumers pay. Second, in the long run, firm relocation and

    subsequent loss of employment may be a consequence of the imposition of local taxes.

    These arguments do not mean that taxes are necessarily a bad idea. In fact, taxes to

    pay for good schools may attract industry, increase employment, and raise property

    values. The point here is that taxes imposed by higher levels of government, especially

    the federal government, may result in less loss of employment than local taxes would. In

    fact, this is one of the main arguments that motivated the federal revenue sharing

    program, under which federal tax revenues were distributed to state and local

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    8/26

    4.8 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and Quantitiesgovernments. (This program was introduced under the Nixon administration and ended

    under the Reagan administration.)

    In a book published in 1992, economist Alice Rivlin has suggested that the federal

    government institute a nationwide value-added tax (VAT) (which is similar to a national

    sales tax) and distribute all of the proceeds to states on a per capita basis. Two arguments

    underlie this proposal. First, the VAT is seen as replacing state sales taxes. Since the

    national VAT would have a uniform rate, it would eliminate the employment losses

    incurred by states with higher sales taxes than neighboring states. Second, the tax would

    redistribute revenues from wealthier states to poorer states, thereby facilitating

    equalization in the quality of public services, including education, provided by states.

    (The reason the tax and distribution plan is progressive is that wealthier states wouldcontribute more VAT revenues than they would receive back, and the opposite would be

    true for poorer states.

    For an interesting discussion of the justification of providing firms with tax

    incentives to locate within a specific geographic jurisdiction (for example, Boeing moving

    its headquarters to Chicago), see Edward Glaesers comments in Gale and Pack (eds.),

    Brookings-Wharton papers on Urban Affairs 2002.

    In the November 2006 elections, the voters in eight states voted to raise the

    minimum wage in their states. Now, more than 20 states have minimum wages above the

    federal minimum wage of $5.15. Given this situation, does it make sense to leave

    minimum wage policies to states?

    Tuition Tax Credits for Private Schools

    Periodically, governments (including that of the United States) debate the virtues

    of passing tuition tax credit legislation, under which families could deduct a specific

    amount, say $75, from their income tax liability, for each child that attends a private

    school. Among the questions that arise in these debates are:

    1. What will the tuition tax credit cost the government in terms of lost taxrevenue?

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    9/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.9

    S

    D2

    D1

    V

    Q2Q1

    P1T

    C

    1. Case of perfectly elastic supply. Tuition (P1) does not change. Number of

    children attending private schools increases from Q to Q2.

    O

    OQ2VP1= Total tuition revenue to private schools

    OQ2TC= Net tuition paid by families after tax rebate

    CTVP1= Total value of income taxes rebated to families. This is the loss in

    tax revenue from the tax credit. 2. How will tuition tax credits affect the number of children attending private

    schools?

    3. How will tuition tax credits affect the prices of private schools?These questions can be analyzed using the tools developed to analyze the

    consequences of sales taxes (such as the tax on hotel rooms). The reason is that a tuition

    tax credit of $75 can be viewed as a negative sales tax of $75. This negative tax creates a

    $75 differential between the tuition that private schools receive from parents and the

    ultimate price, after the tax credit, that consumers pay.

    As we know from the tax incidence example, the effect of tuition tax credits

    depends on the elasticity of demand for private schooling and on the elasticity of supply.

    Only if supply is perfectly elastic (as illustrated in Figure 3) will the credit have no upward

    effect on price and, consequently, will save families $75 per child attending private school.

    Figure 3. The Geometry of Tuition Tax Credits:Perfectly Elastic Supply.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    10/26

    4.10 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and QuantitiesTo get a better sense of the answers to the three questions listed above concerning

    the consequences of the introduction of a tuition tax credit, try to work out answers to the

    questions below before coming to class. (Question 3 is difficult!)

    In Nebula, a poor developing country, the only secondary schools are private. All

    private schools are of equal quality. Due to competition among them all schools

    currently charge the same tuition of $500 per year. Currently 10,000 students attend

    secondary school. The families of all students pay the $500 tuition level. A new

    government has come to power with a commitment to expand access to secondary

    school. One proposal is to offer all families an income tax credit of $75 for every child

    that completes a year of secondary school. The proposal is that the tax credit would be

    refundable. Assume initially that the introduction of the tuition tax credit has no

    impact on the tuition at private secondary schools and that every family can find

    secondary schools to send their children to.

    1. Assume for the parts to this question that the own price elasticity of demandfor secondary schools in Nebula is zero. Under this assumption,

    a. How will the tuition tax credit plan affect the number of students

    attending secondary school in Nebula?

    b. Under this assumption about the own price elasticity of demand, what

    will be the annual cost to the government of the tuition tax credit

    program?

    2. Assume for the parts to this question that the own price elasticity of demandfor secondary schools in Nebula is 1.20. Under this assumption:

    a. How will the tuition tax credit plan affect the number of studentsattending secondary school in Nebula?

    b. Under this assumption about the own price elasticity of demand, what

    will be the annual cost to the government of the tuition tax credit

    program?

    3. Assume for the parts to this question that the demand for secondary schools inNebula can be described by the following equation:

    QD = 20,000 20PN, where

    QD is the number of students whose families want to send them to school and are

    willing to pay a net price of PN to do so. Net price is defined as the tuition

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    11/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.11

    secondary schools receive from families minus the income tax credit.

    a. Once families have adjusted to the tuition tax credit program,

    the government finds that 10,500 students are now attending

    secondary school. From this information calculate the net

    price families pay to send a child to secondary school.

    b. What is the gross price (PG) that families pay to send a child

    to secondary school, where gross price is defined as the

    tuition level that the secondary school receives?

    c. Draw a supply and demand diagram that is consistent with

    the information conveyed in this set of questions (parts of

    question 3). The relevant information includes the demand

    equation, the values of QD associated with different prices,

    and the values of PG and PN. Label the values of QD, PG, and

    PN on your diagram. State the numerical values of each.

    d. Write out an equation that describes the relationship

    between

    quantity supplied (QS) and gross price (PG) Explain how you

    derived the equation. (You should assume that the supply

    equation is linear.)

    I will put the answers to the above questions on the course website after we discuss them

    in class.

    An infinite elasticity of supply in the short run would mean that existing private

    schools could expand enrollments markedly without experiencing increased costs. This

    seems highly unlikely. An infinite elasticity in the long run means that new schools

    would spring up, or existing schools would expand, to meet increased demand without

    upward pressure on tuitions. Again, this seems unlikely. In fact, many Catholic school

    educators have lobbied for tuition tax credits because they hope that credits would enablefiscally stressed Catholic schools to remain open. However, the main mechanism through

    which Catholic schools would benefit from tuition tax credits is by higher tuition. This is

    not consistent with the assumption of infinite elasticity of demand.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    12/26

    4.12 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and QuantitiesIn fact, little is known about the elasticities of demand and supply for private

    schools. Moreover, the relevant elasticities may differ markedly among the different types

    of private schools. For example, supply may be quite elastic among Christian

    fundamentalist schools. Supply may be quite inelastic at elite private schools such as

    Andover and Choate. The logic to the hypothesis about low elasticity is that these schools

    may respond to a higher price not by admitting more students, but by being more

    selective among applicants. This situation is depicted in Figure 4. In this case, the credits

    result in a significant increase in price, perhaps $150, thereby leaving the net price families

    pay only $50 lower than the price before the credits were introduced. Also, in this case,

    tuition tax credits resulted in only a small increase in the number of students attending

    private schools.One other issue that is critical to understanding the consequences of tax credits for

    expenditures on particular goods (whether they be private schooling or health insurance)

    is whether the tax credit is refundable. This provision concerns families with such low

    S

    D2

    D1

    V

    Q2Q1

    P2T

    C

    1. Case of upward sloping supply. Tuition increases after tax credit is introduced

    from P1 to P2. P2 - P1 < size of tax credit.

    O

    OQ2VP2= Total tuition revenue to private schools.

    OQ2TC= Net tuition paid by families after tax rebate.

    CTVP2= Total value of income taxes related to families. This is the loss in

    tax revenue from the tax credit.

    P1

    Figure 4. The Geometry of Tuition Tax Credits:Upward-Sloping Supply.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    13/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.13

    income that they pay no taxes. In the case of a refundable credit, a family with no tax

    liability that sent a child to private school would receive a check from the government

    equal to the value of the tax credit. If the credit were not refundable, poor families that

    sent their children to private schools would receive no benefits. Thus, the issue of

    refundability is critical to understanding the impact of a tax credit on the welfare of poor

    families.

    On June 27, 2002, the U.S. Supreme Court ruled that the voucher program in

    operation in Cleveland Ohio does not violate the U.S. Constitution.

    (See http://edweek.org/context/topics/issuespage.cfm?id=30 for details on the decision.)

    There are many questions that need to be answered to understand how any particular

    voucher program will impact on the number of students attending non-public schools inthe U.S. and on what the characteristics of attending students will be.

    Consider the simplest of cases in which a state passes legislationthat provides every child in the state with a voucher that is worth $3,000

    toward the cost of a years education at a non-public school. Further

    assume that non-public schools can set their tuitions and may accept

    whatever children they choose. Further assume that prior to the passage of

    the voucher legislation the market for private schooling in the state was in

    equilibrium with all private schools charging $4,000, and 100,000 of the

    states one million school-aged children attending private schools.

    Draw a demand and supply diagram illustrating the equilibrium in the

    private school market in the state before the passage of the voucher

    legislation.

    Explain how the passage of the voucher legislation will impact on the

    curves in the supply and/or demand diagram. How will the passage of the

    legislation impact on the number of students in the state attending privateschools? How will the passage of the legislation impact on the equilibrium

    price of a year of private schooling in the state?

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    14/26

    4.14 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and QuantitiesReferences

    Kirby, Sheila Nataraj and Linda Darling-Hammond. Parental Schooling Choice: A

    Case Study of Minnesota,Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 7(Spring 1988)3:

    pp. 506-517.

    Glaeser, Edward. Comments in Williams Gale and Janet Pack (eds), Brookings-

    Wharton papers on Urban Affairs 2002, Washington, D.C.: Brookings, 2002.

    Rivlin, Alice M. Revising the American Dream, Washington, D.C.: Brookings, 1992.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    15/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.15

    August 17, 1990

    Section B; Page 1

    New Jersey May Scrap Tax on Trucks as Sales Plunge.

    By Joseph F. Sullivan

    Gov. Jim Florio, who has thus far resisted pressure to

    change any part of his $2.8 billion tax program, is

    prepared to rescind the sales tax on heavy trucks if the

    Legislature can find other sources for the $44 million in

    revenue that the tax was expected to produce,

    administration officials and legislative leaders say.

    The state sales tax was increased to 7 percent from 6

    and several exemptions - including one for heavy trucks and

    parts -were eliminated as part of the Governors tax

    program approved by the Legislature in June.

    But instead of beginning to raise $44 million, all the

    sales tax on heavy trucks has done, industry spokesmen

    contend, is to chase business to adjacent states like New

    York and Pennsylvania, which do not tax heavy-truck sales.

    The dealers complaints come amid taxpayer attacks

    across the state on the Governors sweeping tax program. In

    a television address Wednesday night, the Governor pleaded

    for time to see if his changes will produce more revenue and

    make the tax system more equitable.

    Shortly before the Legislature passed the tax package in

    June, trucking industry spokesmen warned that it would

    produce little revenue and force truck dealers from the

    state. Several lawmakers said they were convinced that the

    industrys arguments were valid, but no action was takenfor fear it would open the door to demands for last-minute

    changes from other interest groups.

    Drastic Drop in Sales

    Charles E. Walton, president of the New Jersey Automobile

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    16/26

    4.16 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and QuantitiesDealers Association, said that in the six weeks

    since the state began taxing sales of trucks weighing

    18,000 pounds and more, millions of dollars in truck sales

    had been lost, along with the tax revenue the Governor was

    looking for to help balance the state budget.

    Mr. Walton estimated that at least 65 percent of

    heavy-truck sales would move from New Jersey to other

    states in the year starting July 1. In the previous year

    trucks sales in the state came to about $328 million, he

    said.

    At a meeting in Edison on July 24, more than two dozen

    of the states 50 heavy-truck dealers reported that they

    had sold only 12 trucks in the three weeks since the sales

    tax was extended to their industry, compared with 702 inthe same period in 1989, Mr. Walton said.

    This has the makings of a disaster, he said. There

    isnt going to be much here in the way of truck and parts

    sales. In addition, the truckers will simply set up small

    terminals across the borders in Delaware, Pennsylvania or

    New York, and the state will lose registration fees, which

    range from $600 to $800 a truck.

    If new trucks are registered in New Jersey, the owners

    must pay the sales tax at that time, no matter where they

    bought the vehicles.

    Michael Porcelli, the head of Porcelli GMC Trucks Inc.

    in Elizabeth, said he had lost a deal for 80 heavy tractors

    worth $4.5 million to a Syracuse dealer when the buyer

    decided he did not want to pay $300,000 in New Jersey sales

    taxes.

    That tax has got everybody scared, Mr. Porcelli

    said. It wont affect the sales of one or two trucks, butwhen the deal is for 40 trucks, the buyer starts to figure

    up that 7 percent tax.

    He said parts dealers in Pennsylvania, which still

    exempts heavy trucks from its sales tax, had already begun

    aggressively seeking new business in New Jersey.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    17/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.17

    Exemption Spurred Sales

    In 1977, New Jersey was the first state in the Northeast

    to exempt heavy trucks from the sales tax, Mr. Walton said,

    and in the four years it took for Pennsylvania, New York

    and most of New England to follow suit, the statestrucking industry boomed.

    We became the trucking hub for New York and Long

    Island, he said.

    The only Northeast state that did not exempt heavy

    trucks from its sales tax was Connecticut, and the number

    of heavy-truck dealers in that state has dropped to seven

    from 42 in the last decade, Mr. Walton said. If we dont

    restore our exemption, well go the way of Connecticut,he said.

    Paul McMillan, executive vice president of the

    Pennsylvania Automotive Association, said New Jerseys tax

    change was an immediate topic of conversation in

    Harrisburg. Were so accustomed to seeing Pennsylvania

    adopt changes that chase business, he said, it was nice

    to see someone else shoot themselves in the foot for a

    change.

    Norma Sharp, director of the New York State Automobile

    Dealers Association, said she felt sorry for New Jersey but

    was thankful that in the pressure of adopting its own

    budget, the New York Legislature left in place the sales-tax

    exemption for heavy trucks. Thats one of the few things

    they didnt tax, thank goodness, she said.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    18/26

    4.18 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and Quantities

    July 28, 1993

    Section C; Page 8

    Wine Talk.

    By Frank J. Prial

    CALAIS, France. IT was just after 5 A.M. when Simon Judd

    sped along a darkened road in England, hurrying to Dover, where

    he planned to catch the 6 A.M. cross-channel ferry that would

    bring him to this French port.

    Mr. Judd was not alone; not in his car, and not on the

    roads of southern England leading toward the channel portsand the breaking dawn. He and his family, along with

    hundreds of other Britons, had forsaken their beds that

    morning and were heading for France. And bargains.

    For the Judds and shoppers all over Western Europe, a

    single market became a reality last Jan. 1. Import barriers

    on hundreds of products disappeared while unequal tax

    barriers remained. The result: wonderful cross-border price

    disparities for dedicated bargain hunters.

    By noon, the Judds had parked their station wagon in the

    lot of a Mammouth supermarket in a shopping center just

    south of Calais, 10 minutes from the ferry terminal where

    they had disembarked two hours earlier.

    By 1 P.M., Mr. Judd and Brian Cooke, his son-in-law, had

    loaded the trunk and back seat of their car with 40 cases

    of beer, each containing 25 small 25-centiliter bottles. An

    average American beer can holds 33 centiliters. There were

    also bottles of wine and some cordials and whiskies.

    At home, the Judds and other British shoppers may buy

    warm Watneys, but here in Calais, they load up on

    Kronenbourg from Alsace, Holsten from Germany, Stella

    Artois from Belgium and even Budweiser from the United

    States. So much for brand loyalty.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    19/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.19

    We figure we save anywhere from 40 to 60 percent over

    English prices, Mr. Judd said, looking with satisfaction

    at his overloaded car. And now were off for a good French

    picnic.

    The Judds had paid L15, about $25, for their round-tripferry voyage. The fare is usually closer to $100 but they

    were taking advantage of a newspaper subscription

    promotion. Take the paper for the week and get a cheap

    fare to France, Mr. Judd said.

    There was time for a picnic because the Judds had no

    long line at customs to face on the return trip. They could

    bring back whatever and as much as they chose. Indeed,

    there were dozens of large vans in the Mammouth lot, all

    with British license plates and all being loaded with beer,wine, spirits, cigarettes -- and an occasional loaf of

    French bread.

    A case of 25 Kronenbourg splits (about 9 ounces each)

    costs $7.50 here in Calais. The equivalent would be $23 in

    London. But then beer sold in London carries an excise tax

    of about 50 cents a pint; here in France the tax is about

    two and a half cents. A carton of Marlboro cigarettes, $35

    in Britain, is $20 here.

    The wine and beer section at Mammouth is large, but

    then, so is the store. The French call these immense places

    hypermarkets.

    Mammouths beer business is so brisk that management has

    broken through a rear wall and erected a large tent to hold

    only cases of beer. It is not unusual to see a British

    couple struggling with a chain of five food carts filled

    with beer.

    The wine selection -- after all, this is France -- islarge and varied. But this is no connoisseurs heaven. Most

    so-called bargains are in anonymous wines from the south of

    France.

    On the day the Judds shopped here, Mammouth was offering

    a nondescript rose from somewhere in the south of France

    for $1.30. A red table wine from the Herault, also in the

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    20/26

    4.20 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and Quantitiessouth, called Domaine des Felines, was moving briskly at

    $1.10. A commercial Cotes du Rhone from the Burgundy

    shipper Moillard was $3, not much less than it would cost

    in London.

    British shoppers buying wine concentrated on low-endproducts, most of them in the $2 to $5 category. An

    assistant manager said specials like the $1.30 rose are

    particularly popular with British customers.

    There are some fine wines, but they seem to be ignored

    by the mostly blue-collar customers from across the

    channel. A Chateau Lynch-Bages 1987 -- not a great vintage

    -- was about $39; a Chateau Pichon Baron from 1985, a much

    better year, was $57, and a Chateau Ducru-Beaucaillou from

    1982, another good year, was $52. No bargains here, byEnglish, American or French standards. One bargain that

    seemed to have few takers: a 1990 chardonnay from Wente

    Brothers, in California, for $6.75.

    British brewers are urging their Government to reduce

    excise taxes on beer, which is the best bargain and the

    favorite purchase among British shoppers here. Their

    Governments response has been to urge France to raise its

    excise taxes, a step the French have no desire to take.

    Denmark, faced with a similar exodus due to the new

    single-market changes, has reacted, lowering its excise

    taxes to bring back shoppers who were driving across the

    border to Germany to buy their Carlsberg.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    21/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.21

    August 15, 1994

    Copyright 1994 McGraw-Hill, Inc.

    Warning: A Higher Cigarette Tax May Be

    Hazardous to Health Financing

    By Gary S. Becker

    08/15/1994

    Some members of Congress advocate a massive federal taxhike on cigarettes to help defray the costs of a

    health-care bill. The medical profession and other

    opponents of smoking agree on a large tax increase, though

    their goal is not to raise revenue but to cut down smoking.

    Recent research, however, indicates that a sizable cigarette

    tax would not generate much tax revenue, although it would

    cut smoking by a lot.

    These findings appear in the June issue of The American

    Economic Review, in an article by Michael Grossman, Kevin

    M. Murphy, and me. In it, we estimate the response of

    cigarette smoking in the U.S. to changes in retail price,

    income level, and other variables. The research can be used

    to obtain reliable calculations of the effects of increases

    in the federal cigarette excise tax on government revenue.

    These calculations assume that each 25 cents increase in

    the tax raises retail prices by the same amount--even

    though various studies indicate that prices may rise by a

    little more than the tax increase. Higher retail prices

    reduce smoking mainly by discouraging some people frombeginning and by encouraging others to quit earlier than

    they otherwise would have, although higher prices also

    reduce the number of packs smoked by those who continue to

    smoke. Teenage smoking is especially sensitive to the cost

    of cigarettes.

    Initially, a higher price for a pack of cigarettes does not

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    22/26

    4.22 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and Quantitiescut smoking by a lot, since many smokers cannot quickly

    break the habit. But the impact is cumulative as each

    reduction in smoking further weakens the habit and

    encourages additional reductions. Indeed, our article

    estimates that the impact of a rise in price is about twice

    as large after the price has been in effect for a year:After one year, a 10% increase in price cuts smoking by

    about 4%, but after three years the reduction doubles to

    about 8%.

    HOOKED POLITICIANS.

    The present 24 cents federal

    tax on a pack of cigarettes yields about $6 billion

    annually in federal revenue. The estimates of demand in our

    article imply that to reach maximum revenue in the long runwould require a tax revenue of about 95 cents a pack and

    would raise only $6 billion annually more than the present

    tax. Note that somewhat larger tax revenues would be raised

    during the years it takes smokers to fully adjust to the

    higher price.

    This estimate of tax revenue is much lower than that of the

    Congressional Budget Office because, in sharp contrast to

    our estimate of an 8% reduction in smoking per 10% increase

    in price, the CBO assumes that smoking falls at a constant

    rate, by about 4% for each 10% increase in the cost of a

    pack.

    Some members of Congress are proposing a still larger

    increase of $1 a pack to raise the total federal tax to

    $1.24. That tax, in the long run, would raise only $9

    billion in annual revenue--a mere $3 billion more than at

    present--but would cut smoking by more than 70%. Tax

    revenue rises and smoking falls as the total federal tax is

    increased to 95 cents, according to our estimates, but both

    smoking and tax revenue fall as the tax is made larger.

    The conflict between tax revenue and consumption reduction

    may seriously affect government policies toward smoking. If

    the feds get hooked on the revenue generated by smoking

    taxes, Congress may hesitate to impose severe regulatory

    restrictions on smoking. State lotteries provide a telling

    warning of how this pressure works: Despite the still

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    23/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.23

    considerable moral and other opposition to gambling and

    even though lotteries are actuarially very bad bets, many

    states advertise extensively to the poor and others to

    encourage the purchase of lottery tickets.

    BOOTLEGGERSS BOOTY.

    Smuggling of cigarettes from neighbor nations would

    reduce still further the federal revenue generated by a tax

    hike. Canada recently was forced to reduce its draconian

    $2.69-per-pack cigarette tax by $1.82 because of massive

    smuggling from the U.S. A large U.S. tax hike would spur

    smuggling from Mexico and other Latin American nations with

    much lower taxes and would illegally divert some cigarettes

    meant for export to domestic use.

    Cigarette taxes fall largely on the poor, since the

    heaviest smokers are in the lowest income and education

    brackets. Some smokers would be discouraged from starting

    if the cost of a pack rose from $1.80 to $2.80 with a

    $1-per-pack tax increase. But those who couldnt break the

    habit and continued to smoke, say, 11/2 packs a day would

    pay $1,533 a year in cigarette taxes, a large amount for

    people on welfare and those with modest incomes. It makes

    little sense to help finance the increased cost of the

    Presidents health plan partly with a tax that falls mainly

    on the poor and less educated--groups that are supposed to

    be helped by his health reforms.

    The case for much higher cigarette taxes is very shaky in

    light of the regressive nature of the tax, the limited

    amount of revenue that would be generated, the

    encouragement of cross-border smuggling, and the temptation

    that it would pose to the federal government to encourage

    smoking in order to raise tax revenue.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    24/26

    4.24 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and QuantitiesOptional Appendix: Alternate Representations of the Effect of a Tax

    In this set of class notes, we have used diagrammatic as well as algebraic

    representations of the effects of a tax. Earlier, in Figures 1 and 2, the effects on QD and QS

    are shown before and after the imposition of a tax. However, these diagrams depict theeffect of a tax without showing a shift in either the demand curve or the supply curve.

    Instead, the diagrams show how the price consumers pay (PD) and the price that sellers

    actually receive (PS) are driven apart by the imposition of the tax. Though perhaps less

    intuitively appealing, it is possible to represent the post-tax change in the effective prices

    for consumer and seller by showing either a shift in the demand curve or a shift in the

    supply curve. That is, we can also think about the effective prices, PS and PD, as resulting

    from either an upward shift in the supply curve (see Figure 5) or a downward shift in theshort-run demand curve (see Figure 6).

    Why would either of these representations work equally well? Because both

    scenarios can be shown to incorporate the effects of the $10 relative difference occasioned by

    the tax.

    If we assume that the tax shifts the supply curve upward at all points by $10,

    this is the same as saying that after the tax is imposed, sellers will desire $10 more than

    they used to collect in order to remain whole. The price sellers get to keep is now $10

    less than the amount that buyers will actually pay. After the tax, sellers will be willing to

    supply fewer hotel rooms at every price because they are now effectively required to remit

    to the government $10 from every sale. When the take for sellers feels as if its only

    $97.14, then they will only be willing to sell 493 rooms.

    If we assume, instead, that the tax shifts the demand curve downward at all

    points by $10, this would specify that after the tax is imposed, buyers will want to pay $10

    less, the relative price they faced before the tax was imposed. Buyers now have to pony

    up $10 more than sellers will actually keep. After the tax, buyers will purchase fewer

    hotel rooms at every price because they are now effectively required to give $10 to the

    government at each sale. When the full price felt by the consumer goes up to $107.14, they

    will only be willing to purchase 493 rooms.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    25/26

    How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Quantities and Prices 4.25

    Figure 5. The Effect of a $10 Tax Represented asan Upward Shift in the Supply Curve.

    Quantity of Hotel Rooms

    Price

    ($)QS1

    QDSR

    Supply curveshifts upward

    by $10

    C

    B

    PD=107.14

    PS=97.14

    100

    493 500

    QS2

    Quantity of Hotel Rooms

    Price

    ($)QS

    QDSR 1

    A

    C

    B

    PD=107.14

    PS=97.14

    100

    493 500

    Demand curve

    shifts downward

    by $10

    QDSR 2

    Figure 6. Effect of a $10 Tax Represented as aDownward Shift in the Demand Curve.

  • 8/6/2019 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices Quantities

    26/26

    4.26 How Taxes and Subsidies Affect Prices and Quantities

    It may still not be obvious why the effect of a tax can be represented equally

    well, with the same mathematical results, whether you choose to shift supply upward or

    demand downward. You can think of these two alternate representations as two sides of

    the same coin. For simplicity, you can imagine that, if you choose to shift the supply curve

    upward, you are assuming that the seller is the person who actually has to remit the tax to

    the government and therefore directly responds to the pinch. Likewise, if you choose to

    shift the demand curve downward, you are assuming that the buyer is the person who

    remits the tax to the government and therefore directly responds. In either case, we arrive

    at the same post-tax equilibrium quantity (in our example, 493 rooms). However we

    choose to depict the response to the tax, the ultimate market result is the same. In eithercase, the new equilibrium and the relative burden of the tax for buyer and seller are

    products of the interaction between the supply and demand curves.