how much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of korea

18
How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? The case of Korea Duo Qin* Economics Department, Queen Mary and Westfield College, University of London, Mile End Road, London E1 4NS UK Received 1 March 2000; received in revised form 1 December 2000; accepted 1 January 2001 Abstract It is widely believed that seriously excess debt problems form a major cause of the 1997 Asian financial crisis. This paper investigates empirically the role of the debt problems using Korea’s won/US$ rate as the guinea pig. The problems are represented by two institutional variables in nonlinear equilibrium-correction models. The variables are found to exert positive feedback effects on Korea’s won rate returns in three forms: disequilibrium in levels, short-run shocks, and explosive bubbles. However, the estimated effects are not so singly conspicuous as to serve as the predictor of a likely collapse in the won rate in late 1997. Excess debt is hence found to only constitute one of the many factors that brought about the 1997 won crisis. © 2001 Elsevier Science Inc. All rights reserved. JEL classification: D50; E22; E44; F31; F34; F41; G20; O16; O23; O53 Keywords: Disequilibrium; Currency crisis; Excess debt; Institutional variable; Self-fulfilling effect; Intrinsic bubble; Soft-budget constraint 1. Introduction The 1997 East Asian financial crisis has led to rapidly mounting studies in currency volatilities and crises. 1 While theorists wrestle with feasible explanations for sudden cur- rency crashes, empirical modelers delve extensively into data for possible crisis predictions. * Tel.: 171-975-5095; fax: 171-0181-983-3580. E-mail address: [email protected] (D. Qin). Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104 1049-0078/01/$ – see front matter © 2001 Elsevier Science Inc. All rights reserved. PII: S1049-0078(01)00074-4

Upload: duo-qin

Post on 18-Sep-2016

218 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

How much does excess debt contribute to currencycrises? The case of Korea

Duo Qin*

Economics Department, Queen Mary and Westfield College, University of London, Mile End Road,London E1 4NS UK

Received 1 March 2000; received in revised form 1 December 2000; accepted 1 January 2001

Abstract

It is widely believed that seriously excess debt problems form a major cause of the 1997 Asianfinancial crisis. This paper investigates empirically the role of the debt problems using Korea’swon/US$ rate as the guinea pig. The problems are represented by two institutional variables innonlinear equilibrium-correction models. The variables are found to exert positive feedback effects onKorea’s won rate returns in three forms: disequilibrium in levels, short-run shocks, and explosivebubbles. However, the estimated effects are not so singly conspicuous as to serve as the predictor ofa likely collapse in the won rate in late 1997. Excess debt is hence found to only constitute one of themany factors that brought about the 1997 won crisis. © 2001 Elsevier Science Inc. All rights reserved.

JEL classification:D50; E22; E44; F31; F34; F41; G20; O16; O23; O53

Keywords:Disequilibrium; Currency crisis; Excess debt; Institutional variable; Self-fulfilling effect; Intrinsicbubble; Soft-budget constraint

1. Introduction

The 1997 East Asian financial crisis has led to rapidly mounting studies in currencyvolatilities and crises.1 While theorists wrestle with feasible explanations for sudden cur-rency crashes, empirical modelers delve extensively into data for possible crisis predictions.

* Tel.: 171-975-5095; fax:171-0181-983-3580.E-mail address:[email protected] (D. Qin).

Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

1049-0078/01/$ – see front matter © 2001 Elsevier Science Inc. All rights reserved.PII: S1049-0078(01)00074-4

Page 2: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

There are, however, still relatively few empirical works that try to verify or test certaintheoretical explanations by using country-specific data information.

This paper presents such an attempt. It examines how much, from time-series data, we canidentify and estimate the contribution of Korea’s excess debt problems to the won crisis inthe November of 1997. The choice of the subject stems from several considerations. Koreahas long been recognized as a model of state-directed, export-led economy that has sustainedrapid and continuous growth, and it is the strongest of the Asian economies which sufferedcurrency crises during the 1997 financial turmoil. In fact, the macroeconomic managementin Korea was considered generally sound by the international community and the countryobtained its OECD membership shortly before the won collapsed. Indeed, there was littleforewarning that the Korean currency would not be able to ride out the Asian financial crisis.

The won has been under close control by the Korean government until recent years. Thisis best seen from the macroeconometric models built by the Bank of Korea, e.g. BOK, 1993,in which the exchange-rate variable is assumed exogenous. The government exchange-rateintervention management has nevertheless undergone several phases of liberalization. Priorto 1980, the Korean won had been pegged to the U.S. dollars. During the 1980s, the won wasfixed according to a certain weighted average formula centered around the U.S. dollars(Haggard et al., 1994; Chapter 9). In 1993, the government launched a 5-year programme offinancial liberalization, in which the exchange rate was to float gradually via wideningmargins of its fixed fluctuation zones, see e.g., OECD surveys (1994; 1996). Unfortunately,the program was soon affected adversely by the slowdown of the economy since the late1995 and brought eventually to a disastrous currency collapse in November 1997 (see Fig.1), in the wake of financial turmoils in Malaysia, the Philippines, Thailand, and Indonesia.

It has been widely recognized that a series of bankruptcies of chaebols, i.e., large Koreanconglomerates, in early 1997 seriously damaged foreign investors’ confidence in the Koreaneconomy and eventually exposed the won to severe speculative attacks in October 1997 (seefootnote 1 for a chronology of the won crash). It is widely known that the bankruptcies weremainly caused by hefty debts due to cumulation of seriously underperforming investmentprojects that had been undertaken under weak banking supervision and strong state-directeddevelopment policies. The link between currency crises and cumulative debt-ridden invest-ment projects thus serves as key evidence for a number of recent theories and diagnoses. Forexample, Stiglitz (1998) maintains that deregulated capital accounts combined with under-regulated domestic financial sector is a key weak point of the 1997 Asian financial crisisbecause it makes the national financial system very vulnerable to external shocks for an openeconomy, especially shocks from international capital markets (Radelet and Sachs, 1998).The underderegulation is further related to moral-hazard investment behaviour, e.g., seeKrugman (1998), and linked with the soft-budget syndrome, which is believed to generatedeteriorating economic fundamentals for transitional economies (Huang and Xu, 1999).These diagnoses suggest that the recent crisis was not entirely an unforeseeable burst of anexplosive bubble fostered by widespread financial panic over external shocks, and that thereare certain internal factors with disequilibrium potentials, which have contributed positivelyto the crisis.

Several recent empirical studies have actually made use of the diagnoses. For instance,Kaminsky et al. (1998) use banking crisis, money-to-reserve ratio, domestic credit-to-GDP

88 D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 3: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

ratio, and other ratios as possible leading indicators of currency crises. Kumar et al. (1998)choose external debt-export ratio, budget deficit-GDP ratio, etc. as explanatory variables inmodeling currency crises. Similar variables are also employed by Esquivel and Larraı´n(1998) and Glick and Rose (1998). However, most of these studies focus on the predictabilityof currency crises conditioned upon these explanatory variables by means of binary choicemodels, such as probit or logit models.2 What remain largely untackled empirically arequestions such as whether such disequilibrium factors have been propagating into currencymovements regularly, and how different institutional mechanisms in different emergingmarkets exert their roles in destabilizing the currency market.

To seek answers to these questions, detailed country-specific econometric models ofexchange-rate determination are required. The next section reports such an experiment on theKorean won. The modeled effects of excess debt are discussed in Section 3. The mainimplications of the experiment are summarized in the concluding section.

2. Modeling the impact of excess debt

In a way, we can view both the first-generation and the second-generation models ofcurrency crises as models that try to explain the crises as resulting from agents’ over-reactionto disequilibrium shocks. Here, we choose the equilibrium-correction model (ECM) frame-work because it enables us to explain empirically the dynamic movement of modeled

Fig. 1. Won/US$ rates and their returns. Won/US$ rates5 R; Returns5 Dr .

89D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 4: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

variables by long-run disequilibrium shocks, short-run exogenous shocks, and randominnovative shocks, respectively, see Hendry (1995) and Qin and Gilbert (2001).

We start by adopting the theory of purchasing power parity (PPP) as the anchor for thelong-run equilibrium exchange rate, e.g., see Froot and Rogoff (1995), namely setting theexpected nominal exchange rates,E[Ru(], for a given information set,(, to be determinedin the long run by the real exchange rates, defined in terms of the, i.e.,R z Pf/Ph (the ratiobeing the foreign price levelPf to the domestic price levelPh). This long-run relationshipis further extended by the interest parity,Id 5 Ih 2 I f (i.e., the difference between thedomestic and foreign interest rates). Specifically, we assume the following functional form:

E@Rtu(# 5 SR z Pf

PhD

t

exp$d z Idt21%, 0 , d,,1(1)

E@r tu(# 5 r t 2 lnSPh

PfD

t

1 d z Idt21, r 5 ln R

Notice that the above theoretical model implies the long-run disequilibrium shocks being{ln( Ph/Pf)t 2 dIdt21}, and that, for very smalld, R * R z Pf/Ph when Ih . I f, i.e., thenominal rates are slightly undervalued with respect to the PPP defined real rates, and viceversa, a phenomenon that seems to fit the won situation depicted in Fig. 2. Specifically, wesee from the top two graphs of Fig. 2 a more or less continuous and narrow gap between thenominal and the PPP defined real rates prior to the 1997 crisis, whereas the gap largelydisappears when we take the interest parity into consideration (the bottom two graphs; seealso Fig. 3 for the graphs of the interest parities).

Embedding Eq. (1) into an ECM ofDr t 5 ln(Rt 2 Rt21), i.e., the nominal rate returns,we get:

Dr t 5 u0 1 u1F lnSPh

PfD

t21

2 dIdt22G 1 a~L!Dr t21 1 b~L!DIdt21

1 g~L!D lnSPh

PfD

t

1 «t «t cIID ~0, s«2! (2)

wherec denotes claimed distribution, the feedback coefficientu1 , 0, anda(L), b(L), andg(L) are polynomial in lag operatorL of orderk such that {«t} will not be autocorrelated.

Because ECMs normally suffer very little from colinearity problems, we should be ableto augment Eq. (2) easily by a set (vector) of country-specific, excess debt variables,S* 5(S1, . . . Si, . . . Sq), which exacerbate the nominal rate fluctuations in a way that neitherinterest rates nor inflation differentials would capture. These variables can be regarded asrepresenting disequilibrium shocks due to particular institutional characteristics of the econ-omy under investigation, and have thus been referred to as institutional variables by Qin andVanags (1996) and Qin (1998). Here, the effects of the excess debt can be specified into threetypes: disequilibrium level effect, short-run shock effect and intrinsic bubble or self-fulfillingeffect,3 i.e.:

90 D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 5: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

«t 5 f~S, DS, uSut!t21 1 nt, t . 1, ntc IID ~0, sn2! (3)

Taking a log-linear form of Eq. (3) and combining it into Eq. (2), we get:

Dr t 5 u0 1 u1F lnSPh

PfD

t21

2 dIdt22 2 O ûisi,t22G 1 a~L!Dr t21

1 b~L!DIdt21 1 g~L!D lnSPh

PfDt

1 Oli~L!Dsi,t21 1 Oriusi,t21uii 1 nt, si 5 ln Si

(4)Two problems are in need of solution before we attempt to estimate Eq. (4). One is concernedwith the choice ofSt21 and the other the nonlinearity of Eq. (4). It should be noted that thebubble effect may not be the only source of nonlinearity. Another source is the possibleARCH (AutoRegressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity) effect innt, i.e.

Fig. 2. Nominal versus real rates and their ratios.

Note: The real (PPP) is calculated byRPf

Ph, and the real (PPP1 interest parity) is calculated by the log form

in model (1), where the values ofd come from tables 1 and 2. Notice that the middle and bottom graphs are in

logs, and that the log(price ratio)5 lnPh

Pf5 lnR 2 lnSR

Pf

PhD.

91D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 6: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

snt

2 5 v0 1 Oj51

l

vjnt2j2 , (5)

an effect observed frequently from empirical models of nominal rate returns, see, e.g., deVries (1995). To circumvent the problem, model specification via estimation is carried outhere in two sequential steps. First, a simplified Eq. (4) without the term¥ ri usi ,t21ui i isestimated by OLS methods to enable us to gradually reduce the model following the general3 simple dynamic specification approach, see, e.g., Hendry (1995). Once the reduction hasreached a dynamically most parsimonious form, we augment it by both the bubble effect andthe ARCH effect, and re-estimate the model by the ML method.

As for the choice of variables representing excess debt, Kaminsky et al. provide a list(Table A2, 1998) of leading indicators used by empirical modelers, see also the variablesused in Esquivel and Larraı´n (1998) and Kumar et al. (1998). The variables mostly take theforms of growth rates and ratios, e.g., the credit growth, the ratio of foreign reserve to GDP,the ratio of external debt to total bank loans etc. They cover broadly two aspects: unbalanceddebt profile in either domestic or foreign financial markets, e.g., the ratio of investment creditto GDP, and disproportionate loan terms, e.g., the ratio of short-term borrowing to long-termcapital liabilities. Huang and Zhang (1997) provide a theoretical explanation of the formationof the capital structure in terms of debt-equity ratio by a general intertemporal equilibriummodel. Their model actually offers a feasible rationale for the unbalanced debt profileproblem in a closed economy. Specifically, excess debt can be viewed as disequilibrium

Fig. 3. Interest parityId and inflation differentialsD ln SPh

PfD.

92 D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 7: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

between the asset-demand (wealth-equity) ratio and the debt-equity ratio, which can then beembodied statistically by the ratio of wealth to debts.4 Here, we use M2 as the proxy towealth and total commercial bank loans as the proxy to debts and designate the variable bySl.5 Notice that this variable also represents, to a large extent, the aggregate saving-investment ratio, a variable implied in the Feldstein–Horioka definition of internationalcapital mobility, see Feldstein and Horioka (1980). Thus, it reflects, to a certain degree, theopenness of Korean economy to the international capital markets.6 However,Sl only coversdomestic imbalance in the debt profile. We therefore bring in another variable,Sf, the shareof foreign liabilities in the debt composition. As mentioned earlier, indicators based on thebalance of payments account have been used frequently in empirical studies for similarpurposes. However, there is a major practical drawback in using data from the balance ofpayments account. Its update publication is usually very slow, especially in comparison withbanking data.7 As for the aspect of disproportionate loan terms, the available data series forshort-term capital balance is unfortunately very short. The alternative of using variouscombinations of the current balance and the capital balance from the balance of paymentsaccount has been tried, but turned out to be insignificant during the model specification-estimation procedure.

Fig. 4 illustrates the time series of both monthly and quarterlysf (5 ln Sf) and itschanging rates, as well as quarterlysl (5 ln Sl) and its changing rates.8 It is observable thatthere is a sharp rise in the foreign liability-debt ratio since the mid-1990s (Fig. 4a and c), andthat its growth rates also shift upwards since the 1990s (Fig. 4b and d), although there is nodiscernibly drastic increase in the volatilities immediately before the crisis. On the otherhand, the wealth-debt ratio exhibits a steady increase since the mid-1980s (Fig. 4e), implyinga gradual improvement of the overall debt situation. It is equally hard to discern anysignificant abnormal signs from this variable immediately prior to the crisis.

The modeling experiment is carried out by using two data sets: one quarterly set coveringthe period of 1980Q1 to 1998Q2 and the other monthly set covering the period of 1980M1to 1998M6).9 The end part of the data sets starting from the crisis (1997Q4 or 1997M10) isreserved for forecasting and thus not used in the model specification-estimation process. Themain results from the two modeling steps are summarised in Tables 1, 2, 3, and 4. Table 5reports the unit-root tests of all the variables.

It is clear from the tables that the part of the model results that correspond to Eq. (1) isin conformity with many other empirical findings, e.g., small, but significant interest-rateparity effect and the PPP effect, and the weakening of these effects as well as the goodnessof fit as the data frequency increases, see, e.g., Hallword and MacDonald (1994), Froot andRogoff (1995), and de Vries (1995). This enables us to focus on the two institutionalvariables,sf andsl. We find that bothsf andsl exert significantly leading short-run shockimpact on the exchange rate returns in the quarterly model, but thatsl drops out in themonthly model, whereas laggedsf exhibits both short-run shock and disequilibrium leveleffects, and that onlysf demonstrated a significant bubble or self-fulfilling effect. Noticeably,both linear models have failed the diagnostic ARCH test (see Tables 1 and 2).10 A significant1st-order ARCH effect is thus captured by the nonlinear models (see Tables 3 and 4).

Before examining closely the economic implications ofsf andsl from these model results,we need to look at the possible “collinearity” between these institutional variables and the

93D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 8: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

other explanatory variables. Table 6 reports their correlation coefficients as well as thepercentage changes in the partial correlation coefficients of the other explanatory variableswith the returns when bothsf andsl are dropped out from the models. It is discernible fromTable 6 that there exist certain degrees of correlation but the correlation is mostly comple-mentary, except for the case of the inflation ratio variables.11 However, it is worth noting thatthe inflation ratio variable and the institutional variables do not appear simultaneously in themodels, implying that part of the excess debt shocks must have been fed subsequently intothe inflation differentials.

3. How much did excess debt contribute to won crisis?

Let us now concentrate on the question of how much we can identify from the models thecontribution of excess debt to the 1997 won crisis. The modeling results have definitely

Fig. 4. Institutional variables of excess debt.Note: All the series in the right-side panels appear in the models as short-run shock variables (see tables 1–4);

(b) appears in the monthly models and (d) and (f) in the quarterly models.

94 D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 9: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

shown that both institutional variables propagate shocks and volatilities into the nominal ratereturns. Specifically, Tables 1 and 3 show that wealth-debt ratio,sl, exerts a negativelyleading, growth-rate effect onDr t, with an estimated impact multiplier of the range (20.16,20.12). This implies that a sudden increase of debt over a given level of wealth (i.e., a dropin Sl) would generate,ceteris paribus, a subsequent depreciatory pressure on the won rate(i.e., an increase inR). However, such pressure does not seem to be enormous given the lackof highly abnormal movements of this variable prior to the crisis (see Fig. 4e and f). Norshould it be cumulative unless there exists a nonvanishing growth rate inSl on average.Calculation using the quarterly data set demonstrates that the sample mean ofD4sl isinsignificant from zero.

In comparison, the variableSf, i.e., the foreign liability-debt ratio, is found to have playeda much more substantial role. Its modeled impact on the nominal rates take all the three typesspecified in Eq. (3). First of all, it is worth noting that both the levels and the growth ratesof this variable exhibit a few phases of mean shifting, as easily seen from Fig. 4. For instance,D3sft (Fig. 4b) had a mean of20.09 (sd5 0.049)12 during 1986 to 1990 and a mean of 0.05(sd5 0.04) during 1995 to 1997 prior to the crisis in the monthly set, whileD4sft (Fig. 4d)had a mean of20.324 (sd5 0.01) during 1986 to 1990 and a mean of 0.224 (sd5 0.06)during 1995 to 1997 prior to the crisis in the quarterly set. Therefore, the positively leading,short-run impact of this variable could cumulate over several years, resulting in a largerpositively feedback effect than the impact multiplier, as estimated around 0.08 in the

Table 1Quarterly linear model

Coefficient OLS estimate t-value PartialR2 Constancy test5% critical value: 0.47

u0 0.0099 3.995 0.2048 0.09u1 20.141 22.608 0.0989 0.11a1 0.2738 2.93 0.1216 0.24b1 0.0015 2.682 0.1039 0.20g0 20.3512 23.462 0.1620 0.05l11 0.0505 5.275 0.3098 0.05l21 20.1627 24.152 0.2175 0.10Sample size: 80(1)–97(3) R2 5 0.677 s 5 0.0125 RSS5 0.00976

The fitted model:

Drt 5 u0 1 u1FlnSPh

PfD

t21

2 0.004Idt22G 1 a1Drt21 1 b1D2Idt21 1 g0D2 lnSPh

PfD

t

1 l11D4sft21 1 l21D4slt21

Diagnostic tests

Alternative hypotheses Test statistics p-value

Residual autocorrelation F(3, 60) 5 1.6468 0.188Residual ARCH F(3, 57) 5 3.1049 0.034Residual heteroscedasticity F(12, 50)5 1.3404 0.227Residual non-normality x2(2) 5 5.4791 0.065RESET F(1, 62) 5 0.0024 0.961

The constancy test is a parameter instability test due to Hansen (1992);RSSstands for residual sum of squares;RESET stands for Ramsey regression error specification test.

95D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 10: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

quarterly model (see Table 3) and around 0.13 (see Table 4) in the monthly model. Moreover,sf is found to exert disequilibrium level effect in the monthly model, a result that seems tocorrespond to the medium-term mean-shifting feature of the data (see Fig. 4a). To evaluatemore precisely the cumulative effect ofsf in the models, we plot in Fig. 5 the lag weightswi of sf based on the ML results of Tables 3 and 4, and the lagged cumulative effect,¥

wi21sft2i21, on r t from 1994 to the end of 1997.13 The significantly positive leading effectsof sf preceding the crisis are strikingly evident from the graphs.

Let us now turn to the intrinsic bubble effect ofsf. The positive exponential coefficientestimates are remarkably large and significant, i.e.,t ' (5.5, 6), implying that the foreigncurrency market has been extremely sensitive to news concerning Korea’s foreign liability-debt positions. Moreover, the sensitivity increases proportionately as we move from thequarterly modelr1 5 0.0003 to the monthly modelr1 5 0.0009. This is intuitivelyunsurprising because higher frequency data contain more information than lower frequencydata on instant reactions, often overreactions, of agents to unexpected news. However, wecannot perceive any omen of the imminence of a collapse in the nominal returns from thebubble effects plotted in the bottom two graphs in Fig. 5. But we must not forget thatt isnot the only self-reinforcing factor in the models. The strong first-order ARCH effect, i.e.,v1 ' (0.42, 0.52), should be regarded as another factor.14

In spite of the reasonably good explanatory power of the institutional variables, the modelstotally mispredict the 1997 won collapse, as shown in Fig. 6. Notice, however, that thepredictive power of the models has recovered quickly towards the end of the predictionperiod (i.e., the mid 1998). We could thus infer with a comfortable degree of confidence thatexcess debt on the whole has only contributed to, rather than triggered, the 1997 won crisis.

Table 2Monthly linear model

Coefficient OLS estimate t-value PartialR2 Constancy test5% critical value: 0.47

u0 0.0068 3.102 0.0448 0.12u1 20.0371 22.302 0.0252 0.15a1 20.1185 22.195 0.0230 0.06g0 0.3712 2.595 0.0318 0.23l11 0.0495 3.784 0.0653 0.37Sample size: 80(3)–97(9) R2 5 0.146 s 5 0.0127 RSS5 0.0033

The fitted model:

Drt 5 u0 1 u1FlnSPh

PfD

t21

2 0.01Idt22 2 0.089sft21G 1 a1Drt21 1 g0D lnSPh

PfD

t

1 l11D3sft21

Diagnostic tests

Alternative hypotheses Test statistics p-value

Residual autocorrelation F(3, 202)5 0.495 0.6861Residual ARCH F(3, 119)5 4.724 0.003Residual heteroscedasticity F(8, 196)5 1.2106 0.2945Residual non-normality x2(2) 5 26.12 0.000RESET F(1, 204)5 0.17857 0.6730

96 D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 11: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

In other words, the won crisis remains largely unpredictable even conditioned upon theadverse situation in the external capital markets, as reflected by the liability-debt ratio.

Diba and Grossman (1988) propose to use tests for breakdowns in cointegrated relationsas the tests for the presence of explosive, rational bubbles, which are assumed to come froma latent martingale process in the form of an extraneous variable with respect to a specifiedstructural model (Cuthbertson, 1996; Chapter 7).15 In Table 5, Dickey–Fuller and augmentedDickey–Fuller tests for unit roots are reported for two different samples, one for the periodpreceding the crisis and the other for the whole period. Notice from the last row of Table 5that the inclusion of the crisis in the second sample has turned the property of stationarity intothat of a unit root for the log price ratio series, i.e., the cointegrated relation between the lognominal and the log real rates (see also the middle two graphs in Fig. 2), whereas theI (1)properties of the both rates and theI (0) properties of their returns remain unchangedirrespective of the different sample periods. Combining these unit-root tests with the modelresults, we can conclude that external spillover and contagion are more likely to have

Table 3Quarterly nonlinear model

Coefficient Estimate(OLSML )

t-value(OLSML )

PartialR2

(OLSML )

Constancy test5% critical value: 0.47

u0 0.0100 5.087 / /0.0191 4.250 0.2258 0.04

u1 20.0932 21.960 / /20.1058 21.966 0.0596 0.06

a1 0.2160 2.212 / /0.1954 2.055 0.0647 0.14

b1 0.0017 3.600 / /0.0017 3.044 0.1318 0.18

g0 20.295 23.301 / /20.302 23.034 0.1318 0.02

l11 0.0774 5.458 / /0.0780 5.430 0.3259 0.08

l12 20.119 23.515 / /20.129 23.207 0.1443 0.10

r1 0.0003 3.283 / /0.0002 2.490 0.0923 0.04

t 6.0199 18.813 / /56 /

v1 0.4172 2.069 / // /

Drt 5 u0 1 u1FlnSPh

PfD

t21

2 0.004Idt22G 1 a1Drt21 1 b1D2Idt21 1 g0D2 lnSPh

PfD

t

1 l11D4sft21 1 l21D4slt21

1 r1D4~usft21ui! 1 nt

snt

2 5 0.00011 v1nt212

Sample period: 80(1)–97(2)

The value ofv0 is fixed at the estimated residual variance of the linear models (see Tables 1 and 2). Theestimation would run into singularity problems if this coefficient is not fixed.

97D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 12: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

triggered the 1997 won crash, in comparison with the domestic debt problems, seeMasson (1998) and Glick and Rose (1998).16

Table 5Unit root tests

Quarterly Monthly

Sub-sample80(1)–97(2)

Full-sample80(1)–98(2)

Sub-sample80(1)–97(8)

Full-sample80(1)–98(6)

Variables DF test[5% c.v.: 22.904]

ADF(3) test[5% c.v.: 22.906]

DF test[5% c.v.: 22.875]

ADF(6) test[5% c.v.: 22.876]

Log nominal rater t 22.893/21.07 21.943/20.2777 24.827/20.9723 21.914/21.34Log real rate

r t 2 ln(Ph/Pf)t

21.33/22.355 23.139/20.215 22.138/21.774 22.617/21.382

Nominal returnsDr t 27.525/210.77 22.952/20.786 214.04/213.68 23.621/25.252Real returns

D[ r 2 ln(Ph/Pf)] t

29.772/213.07 24.557/22.288 213.35/213.49 24.69/25.625

ln(Ph/Pf)t 25.119/22.075 26.199/22.448 28.345/22.995 26.56/23.0

DF, Dickey–Fuller test; ADF(n), augmented DF test withn lags; c.v., critical value.

Table 4Monthly nonlinear model

Coefficient Estimate(OLSML )

t-value(OLSML )

PartialR2

(OLSML )

Constancy test5% critical value: 0.47

u0 0.0145 7.263 / /0.0063 2.962 0.0406 0.07

u1 20.0860 25.952 / /20.0302 21.947 0.0180 0.07

a1 20.118 22.748 / /20.240 24.445 0.0871 0.09

g0 0.6252 4.819 / /0.9344 9.629 0.3094 0.11

l11 0.1352 8.797 / /0.1163 5.438 0.1250 0.03

r1 0.0009 6.141 / /0.0007 4.325 0.0829 0.05

t 5.4492 31.647 / /55.5 /

v1 0.5245 3.794 / // /

Drt 5 u0 1 u1FlnSPh

PfD

t21

2 0.01Idt22 2 0.089sft21G 1 a1Drt21 1 g0D lnSPh

PfD

t

1 l11D3sft21 1 r1D3~usft21ui!

1 nt

snt

2 5 0.00011 v1nt212

Sample period: 80(1)–97(10)

The value ofv0 is fixed at the estimated residual variance of the linear models (see Tables 1 and 2). Theestimation would run into singularity problems if this coefficient is not fixed.

98 D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 13: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

4. Concluding remarks

The present empirical study renders mainly the following:

1. Excess debt in Korea is found to continuously exert perturbing feedbacks to thewon/US$ rates, and thus have contributed significantly to Korea’s currency collapse inlate 1997. Excess debt is represented here by two institutional variables: wealth-debtratio and liability-debt ratio, with the latter variable being the most important one. Theeffects of the two variables are further specified into three types: disequilibrium leveleffect, short-run shocks and self-fulfilling explosive bubbles.

2. In spite of the reasonably sound model results, the 1997 won crisis remains virtuallyunpredictable. This reinforces the common view that the exchange-rate policiesper sein Korea have been prudent and well in line with the markets by and large.

3. Theoretically, the modeled effects of excess debt can be regarded as being caused bydisequilibrium not only in the internal capital structure of the economy, but also in theexternal debt structure. The effects also fit, in principle, with the theorization of thesoft-budget constraint syndrome by Huang and Xu (1999). However, the effectsestimated in the models are less direct, less dominant and dynamically more compli-cated than what Huang and Xu suggest. In particular, the effects are found to be mainlyexplanatory rather than predictive. This finding inclines us to ascribe the main cause ofthe won crisis to “spillover” or “contagion,” as theorized by Masson (1998), and torational, short-term speculative activities in the international currency market, asanalyzed by Osler (1998).

4. Practically, the model results carry interesting policy implications. Primarily, greatcaution should be exercised in the design of any macro policies relating to financialmarket liberalization when the currency is in virtually free floatation, irrespective of theexisting degrees of exchange-rate controls, because the closer the currency is allowedto take its market values, the more susceptible the exchange rate becomes to amultitude of random shocks and, hence, the less predictable its volatility. Under suchcircumstances, it is far from sufficient for policy makers to monitor the band of thenominal return movements narrowly by the movements of the economic fundamentals.What becomes crucially important is to maintain exchange-rate policies well in coor-dination with any other policy programmes on financial liberalization.17 Financialmarketisation has reduced the scope, or increased the risk, of disequilibrium policy

Table 6Correlation coefficients

Quarterly D2 ln(Ph/Pf)t D2Idt [ln(Ph/Pf)t 2 0.004Idt21]

D4slt 20.31 0.058 0.39D4sft 20.54 0.041 20.12Change in partialR2 284% 237% 297%

Monthly D ln(Ph/Pf)t (ln Ph/Pf 2 0.01Idt21 2 0.089sf)t

D3sft 0.105 20.078Change in partialR2 143% 260%

99D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 14: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

maneuvering domestically. Finally, policy makers should pay more attention not onlyto the possible dynamic complications of short-term shocks to the exchange raterelating to speculative activities in the world currency market, but also to the possible

Fig. 5. Modelled effects of liability-debt ratios.

100 D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 15: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

cumulative effect of the past or existing disequilibrium problems in the domesticeconomy, once they have decided to unleash the home currency into the world market.

The present modeling exercise is limited to finding empirically the role of the debt problemsin the won rate fluctuations. Many issues have been left aside. Further model extensions aredefinitely desirable, especially in relation to the questions of how the debt problems feed intointernational capital markets, how the Korean case compares with other open economies withcomparably serious debt problems, whether certain safety boundaries of the debt ratios areestimable with respect to the exchange rate fluctuations under different policy scenarios, andhow the degrees of institutional disequilibrium effects could be related to the susceptibilityof the economy to regional spillover and contagion.

Notes

1. There are several Web sites that are devoted to the issue of the Asian currency crisis.For example, see “Chronology of the Asian Currency Crisis” at the web address:

Fig. 6. Model forecasts.

101D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 16: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

http://www.stern.nyu.edu/nroubini/asia/. For survey papers, see Griffith–Jones andPfaffenzeller (1998), Kaminsky et al. (1998), and Komulainen (1999).

2. Here, binary choice models suffer from a major drawback in that they throw out mostof the raw data information on volatilities of currency returns by rigidly categorizingthe returns into a zero-and-one (i.e., no-crises versus crises) series. Because crises arevery rare in one economy within a certain time period, such models have to rely onmerging data from different countries over different time periods, thus losing thecapacity of tracing country-specific characteristics.

3. The idea of modeling intrinsic bubbles was originally proposed by Froot and Obstfeld(1991) in the context of stock pricing determination.

4. Huang and Zhang (1997) show that there is a certain inverse relationship between thedebt-equity ratio and the asset-demand (wealth-equity) ratio. It is then easy to see thatthe ratio between these two ratios should be constant in a steady state. Notice thatequity is cancelled out when we take the ratio of these two ratios, yielding us simplya wealth-debt ratio. Therefore, the time-series properties of this ratio should reflect theinvestment equilibrium/disequilibrium state of the economy in question.

5. Admittedly, there is the problem of under representation in both indices. M2 does notfully cover the definition of wealth. The total loans of deposit money banks do notcover all the debts either. However, we expect that the ratio of the two indices wouldalleviate the problem.

6. Here, we have to be cautious in the use of the Feldstein–Horioka definition as ameasure of international capital mobility, as Frankel (1991) points out.

7. Various lagged variables in the form of ratios using both the current account balance/deficit and the capital account balance/deficit series have actually been experimentedduring the model specification-estimation process. None of them has survived themodel reduction.

8. Graphs of monthlysl are omitted because the variable is found insignificant in themonthly models.

9. The sources and the definitions of the data used here are given in the appendix.10. It is also found that the order of the ARCH relation in Eq. (5) isl 5 1 from the tests.

The actual results are not reported here for simplicity.11. When the correlation between two explanatory variables is substitutive rather than

complementary, the partial correlation coefficient would decrease substantially if oneof the variables is dropped out, see Hamilton (1987).

12. Here, sd stands for standard deviation.13. The lag weights and the cumulative effects are calculated by rewriting the models in

Tables 3 and 4 into final equations. To facilitate the illustration, the means of thecumulative effects are matched with the means of the nominal rates in the two middlegraphs of in Fig. 5.

14. For related issues on ARCH modeling, see e.g., Harvey et al. (1992), Sentana (1995),and Hafner (1998).

15. Similar methods have been used by Sarno and Taylor (1999) in their recent empiricalinvestigation of the impact of stock market bubbles on the East Asian crisis.

102 D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 17: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

16. This has been empirically modelled and confirmed in a subsequent study by thepresent author, see Qin (2000).

17. Take the two institutional variables for example. The debt problems that they embodyappear to be no worse for the post-1990 period than the period before 1985 (see Fig.4). But the won has become much more sensitive to debt problems for the post-1990period due to the opening up of the economy to the international capital markets.

Appendix: Data Sources

Most of the data series come fromMonthly Statistical Bulletinpublished by the Bank ofKorea. The Bank also maintains a web-site data bank at http://www.bok.or.kr/kobank/owa/.The rest of the series come from theInternational Financial Statistics Monthlyby the IMF.

R: exchange rate of won per U.S. dollar, end of the period, MSB.Ih: money market interest rate of Korea, code 60b, IFS.I f: Federal Funds rate of US, 60b, IFS.Ph: wholesale price index of Korea (19905 100), code 63, IFS.Pf: wholesale price index of US (19905 100), code 63, IFS.Sl: M2/total loans of deposit money banks of Korea, end of period, in million won, MSB.Sf: foreign liability/total loans of deposit money banks of Korea, end of period, in million

won, MSB.

References

BOK (1993). The macroeconometric model of the Korean economy. Institute for Monetary and EconomicResearch, the Bank of Korea.

Cuthbertson, K. (1996).Quantitative Financial Economics. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons.Diba, B. T., & Grossman, H. L. (1988). Explosive rational bubbles in stock prices.American Economic Review,

78, 520–530.Esquivel, G., & Larraı´n, F. B. (1998). Explaining currency crises.Development discussion papersno. 666.

Harvard Institute for International Development.Feldstein, M., & Horioka, C. (1980). Domestic saving and international capital flows.Economic Journal, 90,

314–329.Frankel, J. A. (1991). Quantifying international capital mobility in the 1980s. In B. D. Bernheim & J. B. Shoven

(Eds.),National saving and economic performance(pp. 227–270). Chicago: the University of Chicago Press.Froot, K. A., & Rogoff, K. (1995). Perspectives on PPP and long-run real exchange rates. In G. Grossman & K.

Rogoff (Eds.).Handbook of international economics, vol. III (pp. 1647–1688). North-Holland: ElsevierScience.

Froot, K. A., & Obstfeld, M. (1991). Intrinsic bubbles: the case of stock prices.American Economic Review, 81,1189–1214.

Glick, R., & Rose, A. K. (1998). Contagion and trade: why are currency crises regional? (Revised draft fromhttp://haas.berkeley.edu/;arose).

Griffith–Jones, S., & Pfaffenzeller, S. (1998). The East Asian currency crisis: a survey of the debate on its causesand possible solutions, draft for Commonwealth Secretariat Expert group meeting, London, June 1998 (athttp://www.ids.ac.uk/ids/research/easia.html).

103D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104

Page 18: How much does excess debt contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea

Hafner, C. M. (1998). Estimating high-frequency foreign exchange rate volatility with nonparametric ARCHmodels.Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference, 68, 247–269.

Hallwood, P., & MacDonald, R. (1994).International Money and Finance, 2nd edition. Oxford: Blackwell.Hamilton, D. (1987). SometimesR2 . ryx1

2 1 ryx2

2 : Correlated variables are not always redundant.The AmericanStatistician, 41, 129–132.

Harvey, A., Ruiz, E., & Sentana, E. (1992). Unobserved component time-series models with ARCH disturbances.Journal of Econometrics, 52, 129–157.

Hendry, D. F. (1995).Dynamic Econometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Haggard, S., Cooper, R. N., Collins, S., Kim, C., & Ro, S.-T. (1991).Macroeconomic Policy and Adjustment in

Korea, 1970–1990. Cambridge: Harvard Institute for International Development and Korea DevelopmentInstitute, Harvard University Press.

Hansen, B. E. (1992). Testing for parameter instability in linear models.Journal of Policy Modelling, 14,517–533.

Huang, H.-Z., & Xu, C.-G. (1999). Financial institutions and the financial crisis in East Asia.European EconomicReview, 43, 903–914.

Huang, H.-Z., & Zhang, J.-X. (1997). A general intertemporal equilibrium model of capital structure and portfolioselection, draft.

Kaminsky, G., Lizondo, S., & Reinhart, C. M. (1998). Leading indicators of currency crises.IMF Staff Papers,45, 1–48.

Kumar, M., Moorthy, U., & Perraudin, W. (1998). Predicting emerging market currency crashes.The Institute forFinancial Research Working Papers51, Birkbeck College, University of London.

Komulainen, T. (1999). Currency crisis theories—some explanations for the Russian case.BOFIT DiscussionPapersno 1, Institute for Economies in Transition, Bank of Finland.

Krugman, P. (1998). What Happened to Asia? mimeo, MIT, 1998.Masson, P. (1998). Contagion: monsoonal effects, spillovers, and jumps between multiple equilibria.IMF

Working Papers142, International Monetary Fund.OECD (1994).OECD Economic Surveys. Korea, OECD.OECD (1996).OECD Economic Surveys. Korea, OECD.Osler, C. L. (1998). Short-term speculators and the puzzling behaviour of exchange rates.Journal of International

Economics, 45, 37–57.Qin, D. (1998). Disequilibrium institutional factors in aggregate money demand: evidence from three economies.

Journal of Development Economics, 57, 457–471.Qin, D. (2000). How much does trade and financial contagion contribute to currency crises? the case of Korea.

Economic Department Discussion Papers 410, Queen Mary and Westfield College, University of London.Qin, D., & Gilbert, C. L. (2001). The error term in the history of time series econometrics.Econometric Theory,

17, 424–450.Qin, D., & Vanags, A. (1996). Modelling the inflation process in transition economies: empirical comparison of

Poland, Hungary and Czech Republic.Economics of Planning, 29, 147–168.Radelet, S., & Sachs, J. (1998). The East Asian financial crisis: diagnosis, remedies, prospects. Mimeo, Harvard

Institute for International Development.Sarno, L., & Taylor, M. P. (1999). Moral hazard, asset price bubbles, capital flows, and the East Asian crisis: the

first test.Journal of International Money and Finance, 18, 637–657.Sentana, E. (1995). Quadratic ARCH models.Review of Economic Studies, 62, 639–661.Stiglitz, J. (1998). Bad private-sector decisions.Wall Street Journal, February 4.de Vries, C. G. (1995). Stylized facts of nominal exchange rate returns. In G. M. Grossman & K. Rogoff (Eds.),

Handbook of International Economics(pp. 348–389). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

104 D. Qin / Journal of Asian Economics 12 (2001) 87–104