frank musella senior thesis: the impact of high-frequency trading regulatory regimes on european...

Upload: fjmusella

Post on 17-Oct-2015

131 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

I examine the impact of three different national regimes for regulating high-frequency trading: a licensure regime in Germany, establishment of an HFT order cancellation tax in Italy, and a combined order cancellation tax and general financial transactions tax in France. Using GARCH and EGARCH models, I find that the German regime significantly reduces the persistence of volatility shocks. The French regime significantly reduces long-run volatility, reduces the size of bid-ask spreads, and increases intraday volatility. It also weakly reduces volatility persistence and the sensitivity of bid-ask spreads to volatility. The Italian regime significantly reduces long-run volatility, increases the persistence of volatility shocks, increases intraday volatility, and reduces the sensitivity of bid-ask spreads to volatility. It weakly increases the size of bid-ask spreads. The French and German regimes were associated with a significant reduction in trade volume, which was not the case with the Italian regime. Overall, I find that the three regimes improve market quality more often than they detract from it.

TRANSCRIPT

  • THE IMPACT OF HIGH-FREQUENCY

    TRADING REGULATORY REGIMES

    ON EUROPEAN MARKET QUALITY

    BY

    Francis Joseph Musella

    Submitted to Princeton University

    Department of Economics

    In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the A.B. Degree

    April 15, 2014

  • i

    Abstract

    I examine the impact of three different national regimes for regulating high-frequency

    trading: a licensure regime in Germany, establishment of an HFT order cancellation tax

    in Italy, and a combined order cancellation tax and general financial transactions tax in

    France. Using GARCH and EGARCH models, I find that the German regime

    significantly reduces the persistence of volatility shocks. The French regime significantly

    reduces long-run volatility, reduces the size of bid-ask spreads, and increases intraday

    volatility. It also weakly reduces volatility persistence and the sensitivity of bid-ask

    spreads to volatility. The Italian regime significantly reduces long-run volatility,

    increases the persistence of volatility shocks, increases intraday volatility, and reduces

    the sensitivity of bid-ask spreads to volatility. It weakly increases the size of bid-ask

    spreads. The French and German regimes were associated with a significant reduction in

    trade volume, which was not the case with the Italian regime. Overall, I find that the three

    regimes improve market quality more often than they detract from it.

  • ii

    Acknowledgements

    I want to thank my advisor, Professor Stephen Redding, for helping shape my

    ideas into a concrete thesis. My JP advisor, Professor Valentin Haddad, taught me to take

    a rigorous approach to econometrics, and I owe much of my knowledge of ARCH models

    and demonstrating exogeneity to his teachings. Professor Harrison Hong gave me my

    first exposure to theoretical finance, which proved intensely useful when combing the

    existing literature. I also want to thank Professor Hank Farber, who inspired my passion

    for econometrics while giving me the tools to pursue significant original research.

    Additionally, Bobray Bordelon and Todd Hines proved invaluable in helping me gather

    data for this thesis, which would have been an impossible undertaking otherwise.

    My experience as a Princeton senior would not have been the same without the

    support of my friends. I owe thanks to a wide variety of people. To Tierney Kuhn, my

    intellectual partner in crime, who inspired me to push through every obstacle life could

    throw my way. To Bryton Shang, whose experience in High-Frequency Trading at

    Eladian Partners helped inspire this thesis. To Anthony Paranzino, whose endless games

    of billiards kept me sane in the face of the abyss. To James di Palma-Grisi, who reviewed

    a draft of my thesis over WaWa hoagies and coffee. To Christiana Lloyd-Kirk, whose

    keen eye for the English language helped me extract meaning from the complex. And to

    all the members of Colonial Club, who made the experience of writing my thesis far less

    painful than imagined.

    Finally, I owe the ultimate debt of gratitude to my parents, Marianne Musella and

    Joseph Whittick, for giving me their love, support, and gametes. They have given me a

    joyous life for the past twenty-two years, and I wouldnt be here without them.

  • iii

    Contents

    Abstract i

    Acknowledgements ii

    1. Introduction 1

    2. Literature review: Benefits of HFT 4

    2.1 Volatility reduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4

    2.2 Improved price discovery . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

    2.3 Liquidity improvements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

    3. Literature review: Drawbacks of HFT 8

    3.1 Volatility increases . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8

    3.2 Quote stuffing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

    3.3 Risk events . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

    4. Existing and proposed regulatory mechanisms 13

    4.1 Transactions tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13

    4.1.1 2012 French implementation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

    4.1.2 2013 Italian implementation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

    4.1.3 Planned 2015 Eurozone FTT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

    4.2 Licensure regime . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

    4.2.1 German HFT Act of 2013 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

    4.3 Price limits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

    4.4 Trading halts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

    4.5 Maximum order-to-trade ratios . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

    4.6 Proposed novel ideas yet to be implemented . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20

    4.6.1 Minimum order durations/holding periods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20

    4.6.2 Quoting obligations for market makers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20

  • iv

    5. Methodology 21

    5.1 Impact on daily trade volume . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

    5.2 Impact on long-run volatility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23

    5.3 Models of intraday volatility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28

    5.4 Models of liquidity provision . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28

    5.5 Potential threats to validity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

    6. Data 31

    7. Hypothesis 33

    8. Results and analysis 34

    8.1 Change in trade volume . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

    8.2 Change in long-run volatility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

    8.3 Change in intraday volatility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39

    8.4 Change in liquidity provision . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40

    9. Conclusion 42

    References 46

    Appendix 1: Results of EGARCH model regressions 51

    Appendix 2: Results of GARCH model regressions 53

    Appendix 3: Results of AR(1) model regressions 55

    Appendix 4: A day in the life of duopolistic market-making HFTs 56

    Pledge 59

  • 1

    1. Introduction

    High-Frequency Trading (HFT) is a form of algorithmic trading in which orders are

    rapidly placed, modified, or cancelled in accordance with market changes occurring at the

    millisecond or microsecond level. HFT has seen widespread adoption in the early twenty-

    first century. While HFT trade volumes were minimal at the start of the century, by 2008,

    HFT accounted for a majority of all daily trading volume in the United States. Though

    HFT volumes peaked in 2009, HFT still comprises roughly half of daily trading volume

    in the US, and 30-40% of trading volume in Europe and Canada.1

    Multiple different trading strategies can be classified as HFT. The first strategy,

    market making, is as old as financial markets themselves. A trader simultaneously places

    offers at the best bid and ask price, updating the offers several times per second. The

    trader effectively sells liquidity: he takes on inventory risk and is compensated by

    capturing the bid-ask spread. Depending on exchange policies, the trader may also

    receive a small rebate from the exchange for providing liquidity via limit orders.

    Another major HFT strategy is arbitrage between exchanges. Arbitrage consists of

    strategies designed to profit from different asset prices across different exchanges. This

    might consist of buying assets on exchanges where the price is low and reselling those

    assets on exchanges where the price is high. Arbitrage can also take advantage of the

    expected relationship between two related assets: buying an Exchange Traded Fund while

    shorting its components would produce risk-free profits if the ETF traded at a discount.

    These price disparities tend to be short-lived, meaning that HFTs must have access to the

    1 Kumar et al, 2011, p. 2

  • 2

    fastest available data feeds to profit from them. Arbitrage strategies help ensure the

    convergence of prices across different exchanges.

    More sophisticated HFTs may try to predict price movement, instead of making

    money on spreads or arbitrage. The simplest price prediction strategy is event-based

    trading. HFTs will attempt to be the first to trade after important economic events for

    example, the release of the monthly unemployment report. Since economic events drive

    prices, there are tremendous profits to be made by being the first to trade. Event-driven

    strategies gained attention in September 2013, when an unknown trader placed more than

    a billion dollars of buy orders on a major gold ETF, coinciding with the release of the

    Federal Reserves minutes. The order was placed at exactly 2 PM, suggesting that the

    report was leaked early: it would take 7 milliseconds for information to travel at the

    speed of light from Washington, D.C. to Chicago.2 As long as event-driven strategies are

    profitable, there will be incentives to leak information and commit insider trading.

    Another strategy to predict price movements is analyzing order book depth. A

    relative abundance of sell orders may imply that prices will move down, and a flood of

    buy offers suggests that prices will move up. This is a form of momentum trading, since

    it relies solely on past price movements to predict future price movements. However,

    strategies rely on order book depth are vulnerable to exploitation by other HFTs. The

    practice of spoofing involves placing phantom orders away from the best bid and offer

    to create artificial depth in the order book. The phantom orders encourage other traders to

    place real orders on the other side of the book, which the abusive HFT can trade against

    at a profit. The abuses are considered serious enough that the Securities and Exchange

    2 Foxman, 2013

  • 3

    Commission has begun acting to shut down trading shops that engage in spoofing, most

    recently Visionary Trading in 2014.3

    By far the most controversial form of HFT consists of ultra-low latency trading.

    Ultra-low latency strategies depend on accessing data faster than other market

    participants. This might involve colocation, where traders place their computers in the

    same data centers as the exchanges computers to reduce communication time to

    practically zero. Low latency strategies also involve the use of proprietary

    communication technology, such as private fiber optic cables or microwave

    communication networks. These traders generally spend significant amounts of money on

    direct data feeds, instead of relying on the slower Securities Information Processor (SIP)

    feed, which is publicly available. The difference in speed between the two data feeds

    about 25 milliseconds creates frequent price dislocations that HFTs can trade on and

    consistently profit from.

    The two-tiered structure of information is troubling from an efficiency standpoint.

    In order to be competitive, firms must spend millions of dollars on data and

    infrastructure, raising significant barriers to entry for smaller firms. In Flash Boys,

    Michael Lewis relates the story of Spread Networks, a company that charged firms

    upwards of $10 million for access to a single fiber optic cable connecting New York and

    Chicago. Due to the winner-take-all nature of HFT, firms were forced to buy access to

    the line, which was the fastest in existence at the time. By reducing the number of firms

    that can afford to be competitive, proprietary data feeds and communication networks

    may harm market efficiency. After all, why would Low-Frequency Trading firms with

    imperfect information attempt to compete against HFT firms with perfect information?

    3 Lynch, 2014

  • 4

    In addition to efficiency concerns, it is possible that ultra-low latency strategies

    violate existing US securities law. At issue is whether colocation and high-speed data

    feeds give HFT firms selective access to material nonpublic information. If so, these

    practices would be considered insider trading. In 2013, the FBI, SEC, and New York

    Attorney Generals office launched a joint investigation into the practice of selling direct

    feeds to firms engaging in HFT.4 This investigation has the potential to dramatically alter

    the trading landscape in the United States.

    Designing an optimal HFT regulatory policy is challenging. An ideal policy must

    mitigate the harms of HFT while preserving any social benefits HFT provides. This thesis

    will examine the effectiveness of HFT regulatory regimes recently imposed in three

    countries: Germany, Italy, and France. Policy efficacy will be measured by the

    preservation or improvement of market quality, specifically volatility and bid-ask

    spreads. I will attempt to answer two research questions. First, what effect did the

    regulations have on market quality? Second, what is the optimal HFT regulatory policy?

    2. Literature review: Benefits of HFT

    2.1 Volatility reduction

    Several studies have found that HFT activity reduces intraday volatility. Hasbrouck and

    Saar examine quotes at the millisecond level, using strategic runs, or sequences of

    consecutive order modifications, as a proxy for HFT activity. They find that increased

    HFT activity is associated with a decrease in short-term volatility. Of course, the

    4 Geiger & Mamudi, 2014

  • 5

    direction of causality is uncertain: it might be the case that volatility chases HFTs away

    instead of HFTs reducing volatility with their presence. Hasbrouck and Saar acknowledge

    this problem and attempt to address it by using trading activity on other exchanges as

    instrumental variables. Their results are robust to their IV specification, though they

    hinge on the validity of their instruments.

    Brogaard employs a different methodology, which more closely matches the

    methodology of my own paper. He conducts an event study, examining the impact of the

    SECs temporary ban on short sales imposed immediately after the collapse of Lehman

    Brothers. Using a policy change helps eliminate the problem of endogeneity, because the

    change in HFT activity during the sample period can be attributed to the short sale ban

    and not to a rise in volatility. Brogaard finds that decreases in HFT activity caused

    increases in short-run volatility, though the effect was only significant at the 10% level

    due to a small sample size.

    Brogaard also tests the volatility hypothesis by examining a counterfactual: how

    would market quality change if there were no HFTs? He constructs a hypothetical price

    path by removing all trades in which HFTs participated, then compares the volatility of

    prices on the real price path to the volatility on the hypothetical one using one-minute

    intervals. He finds that the HFT price path has significantly less volatility than the non-

    HFT price path. However, the size of the effect was less than 1% of total volatility.

    Furthermore, when examining the volatility of individual stocks instead of the aggregate

    market, only one of the 120 analyzed stocks saw a significant decrease in volatility

    attributable to the presence of HFTs.5

    5 Brogaard, 2010, p. 75

  • 6

    2.2 Improved price discovery

    Hendershott and Riordan study the impact of Algorithmic Trading (AT) on price

    discovery6, using data from the 30 DAX stocks trading on the Deutsche Borse during

    January 2008. They find that AT initiated trades have a more than 20% larger permanent

    price impact than human trades. In other words, AT is more likely to lead to successful

    price discovery than human-generated trades. However, their dataset does not distinguish

    between high-frequency and low-frequency AT strategies. It may be the case that low-

    frequency strategies, such as an institutional investor placing a large order, contribute

    more to price discovery than high-frequency or market-making strategies.

    Brogaard replicates the results of Hendershott and Riordan with high-frequency

    data taken from the NASDAQ during 2008-2010. Using a Vector Autoregression (VAR)

    model, Brogaard finds that an innovation in HFT tends to lead to a 34% greater

    permanent price change than does a trade by a non-HFT.7 This effect is present in both

    short-run prices and long-run prices. Unlike Hendershott and Riordan, Brogaards dataset

    includes information about whether orders were placed by HFTs, which increases the

    validity of his results.

    Aitken, Cumming, and Zhan examine the impact of HFT on end-of-day price

    dislocations. There exist strong financial incentives to manipulate the closing price on

    certain days because closing prices are used at the option expiry dates to determine the

    value of options, and can strongly influence portfolio allocations at the end of each fiscal

    quarter. The question is whether HFTs reduce or increase these dislocations. The authors

    find that the presence of HFTs reduces the probability of an EOD price dislocation by

    6 Roughly speaking, price discovery is the ability of traders to incorporate new information in asset pricing.

    7 Ibid, p. 33

  • 7

    about 21%. To address possible concerns about endogeneity, the authors use press

    releases announcing new colocation agreements as a proxy for HFT activity.

    2.3 Liquidity improvements

    Hasbrouck and Saar examine the impact of HFT on two measures of liquidity: bid-ask

    spreads and order book depth. They find that an increase in HFT activity significantly

    reduces bid-ask spreads while increasing order book depth, both of which can be

    considered improvements in liquidity and market quality. As in their analysis of

    volatility, the effect is only significant over the aggregate market, and not for any

    individual stocks.

    Hendershott, Jones, and Menkveld analyze the impact of Algorithmic Trading on

    bid-ask spreads on the New York Stock Exchange. They use the 2003 introduction of

    automated quote dissemination (autoquote) as an exogenous instrument that should

    increase AT. They find a significant negative relationship between AT volumes and bid-

    ask spreads, suggesting that ATs increase the provision of liquidity.

    Hendershott and Riordan examine the quoting behavior of ATs versus human

    traders on the Deutsche Borse. Although algorithmic and human traders each supply 50%

    of liquidity in realized trades, they find that ATs are significantly more likely than

    humans to quote at the best bid and ask prices. The effect size is roughly one additional

    hour per day with the best offer. However, the authors do not attribute this difference to

    improved liquidity provision. Instead, they cite two factors relating to the nature of ATs.

    First, ATs tend to place much smaller offers than human traders, due to inventory

    aversion. Second, human quotes are more likely to be stale and adversely selected

  • 8

    against. The quoting disparity is particularly strong when spreads are high, suggesting

    that ATs only supply liquidity when it is expensive.

    At-Sahalia and Saglam develop a theoretical model of HFTs. In the model, an

    HFT has a modified mean-variance utility function, with his profit increasing in the

    expected bid-ask spread and decreasing in his inventory and inventory aversion. Latency

    is modeled with a Poisson process: the trader has a constant probability of receiving a

    signal about the future direction of prices, and quotes based on his signal. As latency

    decreases, the profitability of quoting increases, as does the fill rate of the LFTs market

    orders. Speed thus increases the provision of liquidity by reducing risk aversion in market

    makers.

    3. Literature review: Drawbacks of HFT

    Although many authors have written about the successes of HFT, their findings are not

    unanimous. Several studies find that HFT actually increases market volatility, and other

    authors allege that HFTs withdraw liquidity in times of high volatility, thereby increasing

    bid-ask spreads and exacerbating market crashes. The latter is a particularly strong

    concern, since sound markets require robustness to negative shocks.

    3.1 Volatility increases

    Zhang studies the impact of HFTs on long-run volatility. Using the same methodology as

    Hendershott, Jones, and Menkveld, Zhang uses the 2003 introduction of autoquote on the

    NYSE as an exogenous instrument. He studies all equities covered by the Thomsen

  • 9

    Reuters Institutional Holdings database over the period from 1985 to 2009. Zhang finds

    that volatility significantly increases as the market share of HFTs increases. He also

    analyzes the price discovery process by using analyst forecasts and earnings surprises,

    finding that prices are significantly more likely to overreact to news when HFT is

    widespread. He attributes this result to the interplay between two different types of HFTs:

    event-driven and momentum-driven investors. Event-driven HFTs respond first to new

    information. Momentum traders, who disregard fundamentals, then respond to the price

    change generated by the first HFT group, magnifying the original price movement. This

    implies that new information is effectively double-counted, as both types of traders

    respond to it for different reasons.

    Jarrow and Protter develop a theoretical model of latency arbitraging HFTs. The

    model is highly stylized and uses several strong assumptions such as continuous time,

    zero bid-ask spreads, and zero-latency trading. Nevertheless, they find that the

    introduction of high-frequency trades both increases market volatility and generates

    abnormal profit opportunities for the high-frequency traders at the expense of the

    ordinary traders.8 These abnormal profits may represent a pure arbitrage, which would

    contradict the efficient markets hypothesis. The authors describe latency arbitrage as a

    transfer of wealth from mutual funds, pension funds, and other financial institutions, to

    the firm doing high-frequency trading.9 It is unclear whether their results would hold if

    the model were generalized to include bid-ask spreads or imperfect liquidity, or if a

    similar general equilibrium model were used.

    8 Jarrow & Protter, 2012, p. 14

    9 Ibid, p. 5

  • 10

    3.2 Quote stuffing

    Egginton, Van Ness, and Van Ness examine the practice of quote stuffing, which

    occurs when HFTs submit excessive orders with the goal of causing latency to confound

    competitors algorithms. Using data from the NYSEs Trade and Quote database, they

    define an episode of quote stuffing as a one-minute period that includes quoting activity

    exceeding the mean level of activity over the trailing 20 days by at least 20 standard

    deviations. After accounting for major events like corporate earnings releases, they find

    that 24,733 instances of quote stuffing occurred during 2010.10

    They find that these

    episodes of quote stuffing caused decreased liquidity, increased volatility, and increased

    trading costs. Once again, however, there is the problem of identifying causality: HFTs

    might initiate quote stuffing as a response to changes in market volatility and liquidity,

    instead of quote stuffing causing those changes. The results would also be less robust if

    the authors failed to remove every instance of news-driven quote stuffing.

    3.3 R isk events

    Another common criticism is that HFT is a strategy that works until it doesnt. In other

    words, while HFT may improve market quality under normal conditions, it will

    occasionally create or exacerbate major risk events. The classic example of such an event

    is the May 6, 2010 Flash Crash. Over the course of 15 minutes, the Dow Jones and

    S&P 500 both lost and recovered over 5% of their value, with several stocks briefly

    trading for one cent per share.11

    There was no apparent fundamental cause for the sudden

    10

    Egginton, Van Ness, and Van Ness, 2012, p. 12 11

    Trades against these one-cent stub quotes were generally broken after the fact.

  • 11

    drop. A joint report by the SEC and Commodities Futures Trading Commission (CFTC)

    attempted to uncover the trigger that started the decline. They find that at 2:32 PM, the

    beginning of the crash, the hedge fund Waddell & Reed placed a $4.1 billion sell order on

    the S&P 500 mini contract. What followed was a complex interplay between HFTs

    employing different strategies, each of which contributed to the precipitous price

    declines.

    The sudden influx of supply in the S&P mini contract overwhelmed market

    making HFTs, who sought to quickly unload the positions they had acquired. While

    HFTs traded over 1 million contracts on the day of the Flash Crash, they never held net

    positions of greater than 3000 contracts long or short, due to inventory aversion.12

    When

    market makers hit their inventory constraint, they began selling off their contracts to

    other HFTs. At this point, momentum-driven HFTs sensed a preponderance of selling

    activity, and began to short the contract, driving the price down even further. Of course,

    for every seller there must be a buyer. On May 6, the buyers were arbitrage-driven HFTs,

    who bought the S&P mini contract while shorting the underlying stocks. While

    arbitrageurs generally improve market efficiency, this time they had the effect of

    spreading the original mispricing like wildfire, creating a perfect storm.

    Compounding the issue was the general withdrawal of liquidity from the market.

    The SEC interviewed employees at over 30 HFT firms in the wake of the crash. Many of

    them noted that their algorithms had built-in data-integrity pauses, which means the

    HFT algorithms were designed to stop trading when large price movements occurred, due

    to concerns over potentially erroneous price data.13

    These trading halts resulted in the

    12

    Kirilenko et al, 2011, p. 3 13

    SEC, 2011, p. 35

  • 12

    withdrawal of more than 80% of liquidity in stocks, and more than 90% of liquidity in

    ETFs.14

    Since HFTs tend to trade in the most liquid assets possible, this drop in liquidity

    significantly affected the 100 largest stocks by market capitalization.

    The withdrawal of liquidity caused trades to occur far outside of the range of

    sanity. Exchanges often require registered market makers to continuously quote on both

    sides of the market. Instead of completely discontinuing their quoting practices, these

    HFTs converted their quotes to stub quotes quotes so far from the market price that

    they are never expected to be executed. These quotes were generally one cent for bid

    offers, and $100,000 for ask offers.15

    Due to the extreme withdrawal of liquidity, in a few

    cases, these stub quotes were the only active quotes for a stock. When incoming market

    orders hit the stub quotes, trades were executed. As a result of the Flash Crash, the SEC

    broke more than 20,000 trades, and later formally banned the practice of stub quoting.

    Although not rising to the level of the Flash Crash, the August 1, 2012 meltdown

    of the HFT firm Knight Capital had the potential to create systemic contagion.

    Immediately after the start of trading, a faulty algorithm caused Knight to purchase

    billions of dollars worth of unwanted positions. The error caused dramatic mispricings in

    over 140 equities; one company, Wizzard Software Corp, saw prices shoot from $3.50 to

    over $14.70.16

    While some of the trades were broken, Knight ultimately lost roughly

    $440 million after unwinding its positions. The incident led Knight to be acquired by

    Getco to remain in business. To add insult to injury, the SEC fined Knight $12 million for

    violating its standards for firms with direct market access standards that were

    14

    Ibid, p. 40 15

    Ibid, p. 63 16

    Valetkevitch & Mikolajczak, 2012

  • 13

    implemented as a result of the 2010 Flash Crash.17

    Clearly, these examples demonstrate

    that HFTs can create or exacerbate extreme market conditions, and should be regulated in

    a responsible manner.

    4. Existing and proposed regulatory mechanisms

    4.1 Transactions tax

    The simplest possible way to regulate trades by HFTs would be to tax them. This tax

    could take the form of a general Financial Transactions Tax (FTT), sometimes referred to

    as a Tobin tax after the economist James Tobin. The tax would consist of a small levy,

    generally in the range of 0.1%-1%, on the purchase of stocks or other securities. A

    general FTT would impact all securities traders, not just HFTs. FTTs are highly

    controversial, and a comprehensive literature review would span hundreds of pages.

    One of the most famous advocates of an FTT is Lawrence Summers, former

    Secretary of the Treasury. He and his wife authored a paper advocating for a limited FTT.

    They found that an increase in stock speculation was driving a corresponding increase in

    market volatility, and that an FTT would throw sand into the gears of the market

    structure that facilitated that speculation.18

    They cite the examples of Britain and Japan,

    two nations that successfully implemented their own FTTs. Though the paper does not

    specifically address HFT, which did not exist at the time, it can be seen as a response to

    program trading the early form of algorithmic trading which was heavily blamed for

    the market crash in 1987.

    17

    Stevenson, 2013 18

    Summers & Summers, 1989, p. 1

  • 14

    At-Sahalia and Saglam model the Tobin tax as an exogenous shock to bid-ask

    spreads. They find that a FTT would make HFTs less likely to supply liquidity,

    particularly in times of low volatility. However, their analysis primarily applies to low-

    latency arbitrageurs, and would likely not apply to market makers, who are often

    exempted from the tax in practice.

    A more novel and more targeted concept is a tax specifically applying to order

    cancellations or modifications. Such a tax would dramatically reduce the incidence of

    quote stuffing and latency arbitraging, while leaving market makers relatively unscathed.

    At-Sahalia and Saglam examine the theoretical impact of an order cancellation tax, and

    find it much less disruptive than a general FTT. In fact, they find that the HFTs optimal

    response to an order cancellation tax is to increase his inventory limits, leaving him more

    likely to quote and leaving market orders more likely to be filled.

    4.1.1 2012 French implementation

    In August 2012, France became the first country in the world to specifically tax high-

    frequency trading. The regulations called for a 0.01% tax on the value of orders cancelled

    or modified within 0.5 seconds of being placed. It also stipulates a maximum order

    cancellation/modification rate of 80%; trades modified or cancelled below this threshold

    are not subject to the tax. The regulations only apply to principal traders, and not to

    brokers acting on behalf of their clients.19

    The law also creates an exemption for market-

    making activities.

    19

    France, FTT and HFT, 2013

  • 15

    In addition to the HFT tax, France implemented a general tax on financial

    transactions. The tax was set at the rate of 0.2% of the value of the transaction. The tax

    only applies to securities of companies with market capitalizations over 1 billion.

    Interestingly, the FTT only applies to traditional traders, not high-frequency traders.

    Euroclear, the company responsible for settling transactions and assessing the tax, only

    settles transactions at the end of the day. If a trader maintains zero net inventory at

    market open and close, as the majority of HFTs do, then no general FTT can be assessed.

    In 2012, the French government raised 199 million from the FTT, far less than the 530

    million they had anticipated.20

    4.1.2 2013 Italian implementation

    In 2013, Italy followed Frances lead by implementing its own FTT and HFT tax. The

    provisions of the Italian version are somewhat stricter than those for the French version.

    The Italian regime calls for a 0.02% tax on order modifications or cancellations taking

    place within 0.5 seconds of the original order. The general FTT was assessed at the rate

    of 0.22% until January 1, 2014, when it was lowered to 0.2%. Exemptions were made for

    designated market makers and securities of companies with a market capitalization under

    500 million.21

    Unlike the French implementation, the Italian regime was introduced in two steps.

    Italy first implemented the FTT on March 1, 2013, and then introduced the HFT tax on

    September 2, 2013. My analysis focuses on the second phase, since this more directly

    impacts HFT.

    20

    Bisserbe, 2013 21

    Salvadori di Wiesenhoff & Egori, 2013

  • 16

    4.1.3 Planned 2015 Eurozone FTT

    A group of 11 EU nations, led by France and Germany, are attempting to implement a

    general financial transactions tax across Europe. The original proposal to cover the entire

    European Union was defeated, but the nations have agreed to implement the policy

    multilaterally through the process of enhanced cooperation. Similar to the notion of an

    interstate compact in the United States, enhanced cooperation states that the FTT will

    only become law upon the unanimous agreement of all 11 interested countries.

    The most recent draft of the proposal calls for a 0.1% tax on equity and bond

    transactions and a 0.01% tax on derivatives. There is no specific tax implemented on

    high-frequency transactions or cancellations. Several points of contention, including the

    lack of exemption for pension investors and the questionable legality of collecting the tax

    from non-EU citizens, have prevented the speedy implementation of the proposal. While

    the European FTT was scheduled to take effect on January 1, 2014, it now appears that it

    will be implemented in 2015 at the earliest.22

    4.2 Licensure regime

    Another proposed means of regulating HFTs is through a licensure regime. Instead of

    leaving market entry relatively unregulated, this regime would require firms to seek

    government approval before engaging in HFT. A licensure regime would have the

    advantage of being able to distinguish between beneficial and harmful HFT algorithms

    as long as the regulators in charge of licensure are competent enough to understand the

    difference. The main drawback of a licensure regime is the difficulty of implementing it,

    22

    Fairless, 2013

  • 17

    including defining terms, hiring experts, and analyzing firm strategies. By raising barriers

    to market entry, licensure may also increase the risk of market oligopolies.

    4.2.1 German HFT Act of 2013

    On May 15, 2013, Germany implemented a series of reforms designed to regulate high-

    frequency trading. The core reform was a requirement for firms engaging in HFT to

    obtain a license. The act defines HFTs as proprietary traders who access markets by a

    high frequency algorithmic trading technique characterized by the use of infrastructure

    intended to minimize latencies, by automated order initiation, generating, routing or

    execution without human intervention for individual trades or orders and by a high

    volume of intraday messages which constitute orders, quotes or cancellations.23

    Licensure in Germany requires a capital base of at least 730,000. The German

    government can compel firms to disclose their algorithms, and suspend trading in the

    event of market abuse. Market abuse is defined as the placing of orders without a

    trading intention, but (a) to disrupt or delay the functioning of the trading system, (b) to

    make it more difficult for a third party to identify genuine purchase or sale orders in the

    trading system, or (c) to create a false or misleading signal about the supply of or demand

    for a financial instrument.24 This provision is intended to prevent phantom quoting from

    occurring. The exchange may also fine people for excessive use, or for exceeding a fixed

    order-to-trade ratio. Unlike the other regimes, the German regime allows this ratio to

    differ between different equities.

    23

    Schuster & Dreibus, 2013, p. 2 24

    Ibid, p. 4

  • 18

    4.3 Price limits

    One potential remedy for systemic risk events like the 2010 Flash Crash is the notion of

    price limits. Price limits would prevent market participants from quoting more than a

    given percentage away from the previous days closing price. Kim, Liu, and Yang

    analyze the effectiveness of the price limit regime imposed by the Shenzhen Stock

    Exchange in December 1996. The exchange imposed a 10% price limit for normal

    stocks, and a 5% price limit for Special Treatment (i.e. underperforming) stocks.

    Using a single-difference methodology, the authors find a significant reduction in

    transitory volatility under the price limit regime. Price limits also helped volatility return

    to normal levels more quickly after volatility shocks.

    The United States implements a de facto price limit regime. In the wake of the

    2010 Flash Crash, the SEC imposed a blanket ban on stub quotes. Market makers must

    place limit orders within 8% of the National Best Bid and Offer (NBBO). The exchanges

    and FINRA also make it a policy to break clearly erroneous trade executions.

    Depending on several factors including stock price and the presence of circuit breakers,

    trades may be broken if they occur anywhere from 3% to 30% away from a stocks

    reference price.25

    4.4 Trading halts

    Many exchanges, including all of the major exchanges in the United States, impose

    mandatory trading halts (Circuit Breakers) on stocks after large price movements. Circuit

    breakers were instituted in the wake of the October 1987 stock market crash. The original

    25

    For a more comprehensive summary, see SEC, 2010, p. 7

  • 19

    regime called for all trading to be halted for 15 minutes after a 10% or 20% decline in the

    DJIA, and for trading to end for the day after a 30% decline in the index. In 2013, the

    system received a dramatic overhaul. Under the current system, known as Limit

    Up/Limit Down (LULD), trading may be halted for five minutes if the price of a stock

    moves up or down by more than 5% in five minutes. This system would have stopped the

    vast majority of erroneous trades that took place on May 6, 2010. Unfortunately, single-

    stock circuit breakers were not yet in effect, and exchanges only broke trades occurring

    more than 60% away from the reference price.

    Santoni and Liu analyze the effectiveness of the original circuit breakers

    implemented in the wake of the 1987 crash. Similar to my own methodology, they

    construct a GARCH model of volatility in the S&P 500 from 1962 to 1991. They find no

    evidence that the circuit breakers moderated long-run volatility, both on normal days and

    on days with 50+ point moves in the index.

    4.5 M aximum order-to-trade ratios

    Yet another idea to regulate HFTs is to impose a cap on a firms order-to-trade ratio. In

    2012, the Borsa Italiana implemented such a restriction. Firms placing more than 100

    orders for every trade were subjected to a tax of up to 1000 per day. Friedrich and Payne

    analyze the effects of the order-to-trade ratio (OTR), using a difference-in-difference

    methodology matching my own. They find that bid-ask spreads in Italy significantly

    increased after the implementation of the OTR. They also find a negative impact on order

    book depths. They conclude that an OTR fails to distinguish between efficiency-

    generating HFTs and rent-seeking HFTs, harming liquidity in the process. However, their

  • 20

    results are somewhat weakened by the fact that spreads rose on competing Italian

    exchanges that did not implement an OTR at the same time.

    4.6 Proposed novel ideas yet to be implemented

    4.6.1 M inimum order durations/holding periods

    One potential method of curbing abusive HFT practices would be to require traders to

    leave their orders unmodified for a minimum length of time usually on the order of one

    second or less. These minimum order durations would effectively ban the practices of

    quote stuffing and phantom quoting. At-Sahalia and Saglam address the idea of

    minimum order durations in their theoretical paper on HFT. They find that imposing a

    minimum time limit before allowing order cancellation would have two key benefits.

    First, it would improve liquidity by increasing the probability of the HFT quoting at any

    given time. Second, it would eliminate the HFTs sensitivity to volatility. Instead of

    withdrawing liquidity when the market needs it most, the HFT would continue quoting at

    normal levels. A speed bump of as little as 20 milliseconds could achieve this desirable

    impact.26

    4.6.2 Quoting obligations for market makers

    Another proposal to mitigate risk events is to impose quoting obligations on HFT market

    makers. In a speech before the Economic Club of New York, SEC Chairwoman Mary

    Schapiro questioned whether the firms that effectively act as market makers during

    normal times should have any obligation to support the market in reasonable ways in

    26

    At-Sahalia and Saglam, 2013, p. 44

  • 21

    tough times.27 Forcing market makers to quote during the Flash Crash might have

    alleviated the problems caused by the withdrawal of liquidity. Schapiro also implied that

    HFTs should be banned from short-selling during periods of crisis, analogous to the

    uptick rule which prevented firms from placing short positions on equities with falling

    prices until 2007.

    However, Rijper, Sprenkeler, and Kip argue that quoting obligations would be

    unreasonably strict. Noting the extreme financial stress these obligations would cause

    market makers during times of crisis, they claim that No company can simply be asked

    to commit suicide voluntarily. They point out that existing quoting obligations failed to

    stop market crashes in 1987, 1998, and 2007, and that no existing obligations require

    designated market makers to quote 100% of the time.

    5. M ethodology

    My analysis will attempt to determine the impact of recent HFT regulations on several

    different measures of market quality. A significant portion of this analysis focuses on

    volatility. I measure the impact of regulations on both intraday and long-run volatility, as

    well as the persistence of volatility shocks. I also measure how regulation affected

    liquidity by examining the change in bid-ask spreads. Finally, I examine the relationship

    between volatility and bid-ask spreads.

    27

    Schapiro, 2010

  • 22

    5.1 Impact on daily trade volume

    Before beginning my analysis of market quality, I must determine whether the European

    HFT regulations had any impact on the market at all. Presumably, any law designed to

    make HFT more difficult will monotonically decrease trading volume. I will thus

    determine whether the expected decrease in overall volume took place. I model trading

    volume with the following specification:

    (1) ln(Vt) = + * D + * Mt +

    Alpha is a baseline trading volume. Beta is the percentage change in volume

    created by D, a dummy variable to indicate observations after regulations were

    introduced. I also include 12 different dummy variables (Mt) for months to account for

    seasonality. I will then perform a difference-in-difference test on the model on the date of

    the implementation of the regulatory regime. Finding a significant difference in betas

    between the experimental sample and the control sample implies that the regulatory

    regime changed the level of trading volume. The specification is as follows:

    (2) Et = -

    (3) SEt =

    Et denotes the effect size of treatment t, where and are regression

    coefficients derived from equation 1. SEt, the standard error of the effect size, is a pooled

    variance estimator constructed from the sample standard deviations and sample sizes of

    the treatment and control groups. My methodology follows Zhang, who constructs

    difference estimates in the same manner. I use the same methodology to construct

    difference-in-difference estimators for the remainder of my analysis.

  • 23

    5.2 Impact on long-run volatility

    Volatility in financial markets is a property undesirable to all market participants, save

    for a few options traders and short sellers. One of the oft-claimed benefits of HFT is a

    reduction in overall volatility. By this logic, any HFT regulations should cause an

    increase in volatility. Lanne and Vesala examined the theoretical effects of a Tobin tax,

    using transaction cost data as a proxy, and found that transaction costs have a significant

    positive effect on volatility. Their reasoning is as follows: transaction taxes push

    informed participants (i.e. HFT) out of the market, leaving uninformed participants

    in charge of price discovery. This adverse selection of parties impedes the price discovery

    process, creating more price volatility.

    However, HFT detractors are quick to point out that HFT exacerbates volatility

    clustering. At-Sahalia and Saglam model HFT as a Poisson process. They find that in

    periods of high volatility, HFT are less likely to quote, effectively withdrawing liquidity

    from the market when it needs it the most. This amplifies volatility by making further

    price movements more likely.28

    When HFT do choose to quote in periods of high

    volatility, they decrease the size of their orders below normal levels. The authors also

    examined the theoretical effects of a Tobin tax, the form of regulation at the heart of the

    French and Italian regimes. They found that The HFTs quoting has the same sensitivity

    to volatility when compared to the scenario in the absence of a Tobin tax.29 In other

    words, regulation should not impact the autoregressive component of volatility, though it

    may change the baseline level.

    28

    At-Sahalia and Saglam, p. 31 29

    Ibid, p. 40

  • 24

    There is much discussion in the financial literature about which types of models

    should be used to fit volatility. Poon and Granger analyzed no fewer than 93 different

    papers on volatility forecasting in their 2003 literature review. They concluded that the

    best models incorporated implied volatility extracted by using the Black-Scholes model

    on option prices. However, since the HFT regulations under consideration specifically

    target equity markets, interpolating equity volatility from option prices seems

    inappropriate.

    The simplest way to model volatility is with an autoregressive process. An AR(p)

    model regresses volatility on p lags and a constant. The specification is as follows:

    (4) ti2 = i +

    +

    AR processes have a few convenient properties. They are generally stationary,

    with the beta coefficients having values between zero and one. In the long run, AR

    processes mean revert to some natural level. They model the phenomenon of volatility

    clustering fairly well: a shock to volatility at time t will impact volatility for a long time.

    The AR regression specification also allows for the use of entity-fixed effects, which can

    account for different levels of unconditional volatility in different stocks.

    However, simple AR processes have a few drawbacks. The first is the assumption

    of homoscedasticity: by definition, errors are i.i.d. and drawn from a Gaussian

    distribution. This assumption is generally unrealistic, since errors are neither Gaussian

    nor independent in most financial data. AR processes also depend heavily on the

    selection of the correct number of lags. I use an AR(1) process to describe the long-run

    volatility change, since

    converges to the true value of long-run volatility regardless

  • 25

    of the number of lags selected, but omit the AR process from my discussion on volatility

    persistence, which relies heavily on lag selection.

    Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity (ARCH) models are conceptually

    related to AR(p) models. Instead of regressing volatility on a constant term and lagged

    values of volatility, ARCH models regress on a constant term and lagged values of the

    squared error term. The ARCH(q) specification is:

    (5) t2 = +

    Generalized ARCH, or GARCH, models improve on ARCH by including lagged

    values of volatility. A GARCH(p, q) model is simply an ARCH(q) model with a set of

    AR(p) autoregressive terms. The GARCH(p, q) specification is:

    (6) t2 = +

    +

    The GARCH(1, 1) model is by far the most popular model in modeling financial

    volatility.30

    I will include a GARCH(1, 1) model in my analysis of long-run volatility and

    the persistence of volatility shocks.

    Exponential GARCH provides several more improvements to volatility modeling.

    First, it removes the constraint that coefficients must be positive. Second, it more closely

    resembles a normal distribution by accounting for outliers. Third, it reflects the fact that

    the autocorrelation of volatility is asymmetric: negative shocks create more volatility than

    positive shocks.31

    Poon and Granger find that In general, models that incorporate

    volatility asymmetry such as EGARCH and GJR-GARCH perform better than

    GARCH.32

    30

    Tersvirta, p. 4 31

    Poon and Granger, p. 484 32

    Ibid, p. 507

  • 26

    However, there are drawbacks to using complex models like EGARCH. The

    largest difficulty is in ensuring convergence of the parameters. When estimating GARCH

    family models, STATA uses two different algorithms: the Berndt-Hall-Hall-Hausman

    (BHHH) algorithm, and the Broyden-Fletcher-Goldfarb-Shanno (BFGS) algorithm. Both

    algorithms are quasi-Newtonian iterative methods designed to maximize the log

    likelihood function. Unfortunately, there is no guarantee of convergence: the algorithms

    may encounter a flat log likelihood function and fail to converge. Failure to converge

    would result in estimated parameters that were not global maxima.

    The second major difficulty comes in applying univariate econometric techniques

    to data with multiple panels. In order to fit multiple equities into a single model, I must

    constrain the coefficients to be the same for every stock within a country. This may be a

    suboptimal constraint, particularly if different industries are governed by different

    volatility processes. However, by analyzing only the stocks on each nations benchmark

    index, I hope to correct for industry effects by ensuring a diversity of industries are well-

    represented in my sample. Multivariate GARCH techniques do exist, but are

    inappropriate for my purposes; since the number of coefficients increases in proportion to

    N2, each model would require estimating at least 900 parameters, which is effectively

    impossible with iterative maximum likelihood estimation.

    I include an EGARCH(1, 1) process as one of my volatility estimating techniques.

    The EGARCH(1, 1) specification is as follows:

    (7) Ln(RVit2) = + * Ln(RVi,t-1

    2) + * |

    | + *

    The debate over the best method of modeling volatility will, to borrow a

    colloquialism if you please, continue to rage until the end of time. I include multiple

  • 27

    models of volatility as a means of determining whether model specification significantly

    impacts the results. Note that I do not include models of Stochastic Volatility, which lack

    a closed form expression and are thus even less likely to achieve convergence than

    EGARCH.

    I will fit EGARCH models for each of the different countries, with separate

    fittings for the period before and after regulations were implemented. There are 16

    EGARCH models in total after accounting for control models. For Italy, the hypothesized

    break date is September 2, 2013. For Germany, there are two hypothesized break dates:

    the passage of the law, on May 15, 2013, and the deadline for obtaining a license to

    perform HFT, on November 14, 2013. In France, the hypothesized break date is August

    1, 2012.

    After fitting the models, I use pooled variance to construct difference estimators,

    allowing for a difference-in-difference between sample and control to be derived. The

    difference-in-difference methodology should ensure exogeneity of the results, since no

    major changes in regulatory policy occurred on the London Stock Exchange in 2012 or

    2013.

    A significant difference-in-difference would imply that the HFT regulations had a

    significant impact on volatility. There are two possible impacts I will consider: a change

    in

    , the baseline level of volatility, and a change in beta, the volatility persistence

    coefficient. To simplify my analysis, I will consider a reduction in either value to be an

    improvement in market quality.

  • 28

    5.3 M odels of intraday volatility

    The characteristics of intraday data make the use of GARCH family models intractable in

    modelling volatility. Ghalanos describes the main problem with the data: volatility is not

    mean-reverting. Instead, it exhibits strong time-of-day effects, peaking at the daily open

    and close of the market. This trait means that convergence of the parameters in any

    maximum likelihood estimation is nearly impossible. Therefore, I use a simple AR(1)

    model of volatility. My specification is as follows:

    (8) = + *

    + * D + * D *

    My volatility measure is the standard deviation in midprice movements over the

    course of one minute, per Brogaard. Midprice is the average of the best bid and offer. is

    a baseline volatility coefficient, and is the change in that coefficient after the

    introduction of regulations. is an autoregressive coefficient, and is the change in

    that coefficient caused by regulations. D is a dummy variable for observations after the

    imposition of regulations. Average volatility can be recovered as

    in the period

    before regulations, and

    in the period after. To account for excess volatility at the

    open and close of trading, I omit observations from the first and last five minutes of

    trading each day.

    5.4 M odels of liquidity provision

    There are two main ways to measure the provision of liquidity: bid-ask spreads and order

    book depth. Ironically, data on depth is generally proprietary and reserved for HFT

    clients, so the former will be my metric of choice. Using high-frequency data, I will

  • 29

    measure bid-ask spreads at one minute intervals. My objective is to determine to what

    extent volatility impacts the size of spreads, and whether HFT regulations increased or

    decreased the size of the effect. My specification is as follows:

    (9) ln(St) = + * ln(St-1) + * + + * D * ln(St-1) + * D *

    St is the quoted spread of the benchmark ETF at time t, measured as the natural

    log of the percentage spread. Taking the log of spreads helps account for situations where

    baseline spreads are dramatically different in different countries; in particular, the FTSE

    spread typically hovered around 3 basis points, while the MIB spread was in the

    neighborhood of 17 basis points. is the constant before regulations are imposed. is

    an autoregressive coefficient, since spreads are highly autocorrelated. is the coefficient

    of interest: the change in spread caused by a unit change in volatility. D is a dummy

    variable equal to 1 for observations after the implementation of regulations. After fitting

    the model, I will perform a Chow test to see if the relationship between bid-ask spreads

    and volatility changed. An increase in gamma implies that the regulations make spreads

    more sensitive to volatility, and thus hurt the price discovery process. A decrease in

    gamma suggests that bid-ask spreads become less correlated with volatility, which would

    vindicate the regulations.

    I will also measure the long-run value of spreads before and after the change. This

    is denoted by

    + *

    in period 1 and

    + ( + ) *

    in period 2, with

    volatility defined using the long-run values from section 5.2. (The potential difference

    between average and realized volatility is relatively unimportant in this application, since

    volatility contributes less than 1% of the value of the spread.)

  • 30

    5.5 Potential threats to validity

    In spite of my confidence about ensuring exogeneity, my study has a few limitations. The

    most obvious potential pitfall is the use of univariate volatility modelling techniques on

    panel data. Constraining multiple different assets to have the same coefficients may

    introduce substantial upward bias in estimates for volatility persistence. This could be

    corrected by creating a separate model for each asset, or by simply testing the benchmark

    ETF instead of the indexs individual components. However, the decision to use multiple

    assets was an effort to address the small T, large N problem of having too few

    observations.

    Another study design decision that might have impacted my results is the decision

    to use the London Stock Exchange as a control group. My rationale for doing so was

    fairly straightforward: it is the largest stock exchange in Europe, yet did not implement

    any regulations on high-frequency trading during the sample period. However, the LSE

    also trades in Pounds Sterling instead of Euros, since Britain is not a Eurozone member.

    This raises the complication of accounting for the Euro crisis. I excluded data points

    before 2012 in an effort to keep the Euro crisis from biasing my long-run volatility

    estimates. However, it is possible I failed to truncate enough data for example, Mario

    Draghis whatever it takes speech, which definitively secured the future of the

    Eurozone, did not occur until July 26, 2012. The model might interpret the economic

    recovery in early 2012 as a period of high volatility, thereby exaggerating the extent to

    which regulations decreased volatility.

    Yet another potential issue is the relative lack of datapoints in some cases. The

    most egregious case is the German HFT licensure deadline: there are only 30 trading days

  • 31

    represented in the period after the deadline passed. This makes it difficult to draw strong

    inferences about the effects of the policy, and explains the relative lack of significant

    results. I would strongly encourage academics to continue to study the empirical impacts

    of HFT regulations over the course of the next few years.

    A further complication is the introduction of multiple regulatory changes

    simultaneously. This is not a major issue in the case of Germany, which implemented

    HFT-specific regulations, or Italy, which delayed the implementation of an HFT tax until

    several months after the introduction of a financial transactions tax. However, France

    implemented their HFT tax and FTT at the same time. It is thus difficult to determine

    which effects were caused by the HFT tax, and which were caused by the FTT. It would

    be convenient if a country adopted an HFT tax without having an FTT in place, but alas,

    countries dont design their regulatory policy around the dreams of econometricians.

    6. Data

    Data on long-run equity volatility will be drawn from Thomson Reuters Datastream

    International and the CompuStat Global database. The data will span from January 1,

    2012 to December 31, 2013. Data from the French, Italian, and German stock exchanges

    will form the experimental groups, and British equities will form the control group. Per

    Poon and Granger, I will use squared returns to calculate volatility, instead of squared

    deviation from the mean return.

    My sampling frequency will be daily, due to the relatively short timeframe of my

    analysis. I follow the methodology of Guo, Kassa, and Ferguson, who recommend using

    a two year rolling window of daily returns to ensure robustness and make the model less

  • 32

    sensitive to the initial values. There are 512 trading days in the sample period. Our

    desired dependent variable, Realized Volatility, is defined as the following:

    (10) RVit =

    For each country, I will analyze the stocks included in the primary exchanges

    benchmark index. The exchanges are summarized below.

    Country Index # Stocks Trading days

    Germany DAX 30 16,380

    France CAC-40 40 21,840

    Italy FTSE MIB 40 21,840

    Britain FTSE 100 100 54,600

    Total trading days = 114,660

    Data on bid-ask spreads and intraday volatility will be drawn from TickWrite.

    Experimental data are available for France and Italy, and Britain will again serve as the

    control sample.33

    Data will be drawn at the tick level and aggregated into one-minute

    intervals. The sample period will consist of a 23-day window around the implementation

    of new regulations in Italy, and a 25-day window in France. Due to the large volume of

    data generated at the tick level, I will only analyze the ETF representation of each

    benchmark index, in lieu of the actual components. These data are summarized below:

    33

    German data exists, but is proprietary. Unfortunately, Princeton didnt want to spend $120,000 to help me write my thesis. Cest la vie.

  • 33

    Country Index (ETF) Minutes Tick Observations

    France CAC-40 (FP) 12,750 1,379,735

    Italy FTSE MIB (IMIB) 11,730 119,182

    Britain FTSE 100 (ISF) 24,480 1,824,754

    Total trading minutes = 48,960

    # Observations at tick intervals = 3,323,671

    7. Hypothesis

    All things considered, any form of HFT regulation should reduce the daily trading

    volume of assets. I hypothesize that all of the implemented regulations will cause a

    significant decrease in the equilibrium trading volume.

    In terms of volatility, different empirical papers imply different outcomes. Those

    who believe HFT moderate volatility would predict an increase in omega following

    regulation. Those who think HFT withdraw liquidity during times of high volatility

    believe regulation would cause a decrease in beta. These two theoretical results are not

    incompatible. To accommodate both, I make the following hypothesis: beta will decrease,

    but overall volatility (in terms of

    ) will increase.

    The results should be largely the same when looking at bid-ask spreads. I predict

    a decrease in gamma, the parameter representing sensitivity to volatility. This reflects the

    intuition that HFT are less likely to quote in periods of high volatility, a behavior which

    increases the size of spreads. I also anticipate an increase in the bid-ask spread size.

    In terms of magnitude, I predict the largest effects in Italy, which imposed the

    strictest regulations on HFT. A slightly smaller effect should be seen in France, which

  • 34

    implemented similar restrictions to Italy. In Germany, I predict a very small effect size,

    perhaps not statistically significant. This is due to the relatively lax nature of a licensure

    regime, combined with the fact that the Deutsche Borse already monitored algorithmic

    trading as early as 2007. Since Britain forms the control group, and adopted no new

    regulations on HFT or other trading since 2012, there should be no effect during the

    introduction of regulations in other countries.

    8. Results and analysis

    8.1 Change in trade volume

    I begin by analyzing the change in trade volume caused by the implementation of

    regulations. Our coefficient of interest is from regression 1. My results are summarized

    below.

    Table 1: Change in trade volume after imposition of regulations

    Country % Change in sample

    volume

    % Change in control

    volume

    Difference-in-

    difference

    Germany (5/13) -18.06%***

    (2.29%)

    -10.26%***

    (1.33%)

    -7.8%***

    (2.48%)

    Germany (11/13) -14.37%***

    (5.12%)

    -4.82%*

    (2.91%)

    -9.55%*

    (5.67%)

    France -19.6%***

    (1.89%)

    -15.67%***

    (1.37%)

    -3.93%*

    (2.12%)

    Italy -9.78%

    (6.13%)

    -13.15%***

    (1.83%)

    3.37%

    (5.97%)

    Standard errors in parentheses

    * denotes 0.1>p>0.05, ** denotes 0.05>p>0.01, *** denotes 0.01>p

  • 35

    In Germany, both the May 15 announcement and the November 14 licensure

    deadline were associated with a significant decline in trading volume. The results

    remained significant when compared to the change in British trading volume during the

    same time period. The effect size was 7.8% for the announcement, and 9.55% for the

    licensure deadline a modest decline, to be sure, but still significant.

    In France, the implementation of a combined financial transactions tax and HFT

    cancellation tax caused a 19.6% decline in trading volume. After accounting for the

    British control group, the relative decline in trading volume was 3.93%. This effect was

    significant at the 10% level, though not as large as the German effect.

    In Italy, trading volume declined by 9.78% after the implementation of an FTT

    and HFT tax. The decline in volume barely misses significance at the 10% confidence

    level, with a P value of 0.1108. Surprisingly, the decline in trade volume in the British

    control group during the same time frame was larger. The relative effect was a 3.37%

    increase in trade volume, though this effect is not statistically distinguishable from zero.

    The difference between France and Italy is easy to explain: while France implemented a

    generic FTT and HFT tax simultaneously, Italy introduced its FTT six months before

    implementing an HFT tax. The HFT tax may have encouraged LFTs to reenter the market

    after being driven away by perceived unfairness.

    8.2 Change in long-run volatility

  • 36

    The change in regulatory policy generally resulted in a decline in long-run volatility.

    Model selection had an impact on the effect size and direction, with two models

    producing an increase in volatility. A summary of the different models is offered below34

    :

    Table 2: Summary of long-run volatility across different models

    Country EGARCH GARCH AR(1)

    Vol? Significant? Vol? Significant? Vol? Significant?

    Germany

    (5/13) Increase Yes Decrease Yes Decrease No

    Germany

    (11/13) Decrease No Increase Yes Decrease No

    France Decrease No Decrease Yes Decrease Yes

    Italy Decrease Yes Decrease Yes Decrease Yes

    In France and Italy, regulation caused a decline in volatility relative to the

    benchmark, regardless of the model used. In almost all cases, this decline was statistically

    significant at the 1% confidence level. This finding strongly vindicates Larry Summers

    and other advocates of transaction taxes, who claim that excess speculation increases

    market volatility.

    The case for the German licensure regime is much less clear. The announcement

    of the regime in May 2013 caused a significant increase in long-run volatility in the

    EGARCH model, a significant decrease in the GARCH model, and an insignificant

    decrease in the AR(1) model. Of note is the nonstationarity of volatility in the GARCH

    model in the period after the announcement. The alpha and beta coefficients sum to more

    than 1, making volatility a random walk process instead of a mean reverting process. In

    the long run, volatility is always mean reverting, but nonstationarity may persist for some

    34

    Coefficient values are reported in appendices 1 - 3

  • 37

    time. I attribute this to the relatively short timeframe (7.5 months) of the regime. This

    makes it somewhat difficult to draw strong inferences about regime effectiveness.

    The German licensure deadline causes an insignificant decline in volatility in the

    EGARCH and AR(1) specifications, and a significant increase in volatility in the

    GARCH specification. Again, this difference may be due to the sample size, which is

    even smaller (1.5 months) in the post-licensing regime. It may also be caused by the

    different natures of GARCH and EGARCH with respect to shocks. EGARCH tends to

    magnify large shocks, and magnifies negative shocks more than positive shocks.

    Depending on the number, sign, and magnitude of shocks, different models may produce

    significantly different results. Given the different sign changes produced by different

    models, and the statistical insignificance of three of them, I conclude that the licensure

    regime had no impact on long-run volatility.

    Figure 1: Conditional volatility as a function of past shocks35

    35

    Chart from Bollerslev, 2011, p. 24

  • 38

    Interestingly, the impact of HFT regulations on the persistence of volatility shocks

    is generally the opposite of the impact on long-run volatility. The following table

    summarizes changes in , or volatility persistence, relative to the British benchmark:

    Table 3: Relative change in volatility persistence

    Country EGARCH GARCH

    Persistence? Significant? Persistence? Significant?

    Germany (5/13) Decrease No Decrease No

    Germany (11/13) Decrease Yes Decrease No

    France Increase No Decrease Yes

    Italy Increase Yes Increase No

    Both the announcement of the German licensure regime and the licensure

    deadline were associated with a decrease in volatility persistence, regardless of model

    selection. Unfortunately, only the EGARCH model of the licensure deadline found a

    result significant at the 1% confidence level.

    In the case of France, the EGARCH model found a moderate but insignificant

    increase in the persistence of volatility shocks, while the plain GARCH model produces a

    significant decrease in persistence. For Italy, both models produce an increase in

    volatility persistence, though this is only significant in the EGARCH model. In fact, the

    EGARCH model gives a beta of greater than 1 for Italy, implying nonstationarity of

    volatility. Also of note is that both French and Italian regulations produced an increase in

    the absolute length of volatility persistence, but the French regulations produced a

    decrease in the relative length, due to a substantial increase in persistence in the control

    group.

  • 39

    Table 4: Half-life of volatility shocks, measured in days, GARCH model

    Country

    Sample group British control group

    in Pre Post Pre Post

    Germany(1) 16.64 15.71 -0.93 18.15 18.29 0.14 -1.07

    Germany(2) 20.36 7.78 -12.58 18.59 9.51 -9.08 -3.5

    France 18.45 20.91 2.46 11.37 15.68 4.31 -1.85

    Italy 19.24 19.45 0.21 18.96 17.56 -1.4 1.61

    8.3 Change in intraday volatility

    In both France and Italy, the implementation of regulations was associated with a

    significant increase in intraday volatility. This is in line with the expectations of HFT

    advocates, who argue that HFT acts as a stabilizing force in the markets. In France, the

    persistence of volatility shocks significantly increased, while persistence declined in

    Italy.

    Table 5: Impact of regulations on intraday volatility, France

    Constant Vol Chow(P) R2

    France Baseline 4.19***

    (0.255)

    0.24***

    (0.048)

    5.51***

    (0.063) 71.94

    (0) 0.2009

    Change -0.551

    (0.546)

    0.235***

    (0.088)

    1.41***

    (0.094)

    Britain Baseline 2.25***

    (0.781)

    0.451*

    (0.194)

    4.09***

    (0.053) 7.01

    (0.0009) 0.1635

    Change 0.266

    (0.838)

    -0.109

    (0.211)

    -0.27***

    (0.091)

    Difference-in-

    difference

    -0.817

    (0.683)

    0.343**

    (0.152)

    1.68***

    (0.093)

    Standard errors in parentheses

    * denotes 0.1>p>0.05, ** denotes 0.05>p>0.01, *** denotes 0.01>p

    Constant and Vol multiplied by 100,000

  • 40

    Table 6: Impact of regulations on intraday volatility, Italy

    Constant Vol Chow(P) R2

    Italy Baseline 9.23***

    (2.31)

    0.366**

    (0.177)

    14.55***

    (0.921) 2.91

    (0.0543) 0.0529

    Change 5.35**

    (2.53)

    -0.291

    (0.186)

    1.21

    (1.27)

    Britain Baseline 3.62***

    (0.31)

    0.109

    (0.075)

    4.06***

    (0.039) 68.70

    (0) 0.0726

    Change -1.47***

    (0.34)

    0.223**

    (0.088)

    -0.84***

    (0.423)

    Difference-in-

    difference

    6.82***

    (1.78)

    -0.513***

    (0.144)

    2.05**

    (0.889)

    Standard errors in parentheses

    * denotes 0.1>p>0.05, ** denotes 0.05>p>0.01, *** denotes 0.01>p

    Constant and Vol multiplied by 100,000

    8.4 Change in liquidity provision

    The impact of regulations on bid-ask spreads is not as clear cut as I had anticipated. In

    Italy, as predicted, spreads increased relative to the control sample, though the effect

    barely misses significance at the 10% confidence level. Surprisingly, spreads

    significantly decreased in France, in both absolute and relative terms. The specific

    implementation of the French law may hold the key. In France, HFTs are only taxed for

    order cancellations, and not for completed transactions, as long as they clear their

    inventory by the end of the day. It is possible that HFTs only altered their order

    cancellation behavior in response to the regulations, and not their quoting behavior. This

    would leave an HFT offer at best bid or ask more frequently, and, in theory, reduce

    spreads. Indeed, At-Sahalia and Saglam acknowledge that the probability of an HFT

    quoting at a given time is increasing in the level of a cancellation tax.

  • 41

    Table 7: Impact of regulations on bid-ask spreads and their responsiveness to

    volatility, France, August 1, 2012

    Constant Spread36 Chow(P) R2

    France Baseline -2.832***

    (0.332)

    0.617***

    (0.045)

    1715***

    (304)

    6.76***

    (0.199) 51.19

    (0) 0.6441

    Change 0.514

    (0.366)

    0.076

    (0.05)

    -392

    (392)

    -15.8%***

    (4.58%)

    Britain Baseline -2.36***

    (0.163)

    0.705***

    (0.021)

    1268***

    (111)

    3.47***

    (0.094) 34.28

    (0) 0.5395

    Change -0.541**

    (0.216)

    -0.075***

    (0.028)

    -162

    (133)

    14.1%***

    (3.24%)

    Difference-in-

    difference

    1.056**

    (0.425)

    0.151***

    (0.057)

    -230

    (414)

    -29.9%***

    (5.61%)

    Standard errors in parentheses

    * denotes 0.1>p>0.05, ** denotes 0.05>p>0.01, *** denotes 0.01>p

    Table 8: Impact of regulations on bid-ask spreads and their responsiveness to

    volatility, Italy, September 2, 2013

    Constant Spread36 Chow(P) R2

    Italy Baseline -1.009***

    (0.148)

    0.842***

    (0.023)

    90**

    (42.3)

    17.32***

    (0.537) 19.92

    (0) 0.6549

    Change -2.148***

    (0.347)

    -0.332***

    (0.054)

    78.5

    (60.5)

    -5.35%*

    (3.15%)

    Britain Baseline -3.027***

    (0.154)

    0.621***

    (0.019)

    110

    (756)

    3.42***

    (0.168) 14.82

    (0) 0.4313

    Change -0.731***

    (0.234)

    -0.073***

    (0.028)

    3142***

    (893)

    -21%*

    (11.3%)

    Difference-in-

    difference

    -1.417***

    (0.418)

    -0.259***

    (0.061)

    -3064***

    (895)

    15.63%

    (11.73%)

    Standard errors in parentheses

    * denotes 0.1>p>0.05, ** denotes 0.05>p>0.01, *** denotes 0.01>p

    My empirical findings with respect to gamma, the volatility sensitivity parameter,

    exactly match my hypothesis. In both Italy and France, sensitivity to volatility decreased

    relative to the control sample. In France, sensitivity decreased in both the absolute and

    relative senses, though neither change was significant at the 10% confidence level. In

    36

    Baseline spread is reported in basis points, while change is measured as a percentage of the baseline

  • 42

    Italy, sensitivity only declined relative to the British control sample, though the relative

    decline was significant at the 1% confidence level.

    In every case, there is a positive correlation between volatility and bid-ask

    spreads. The findings confirm the theoretical results of At-Sahalia and Saglam, who state

    that HFTs are less likely to quote during periods of high volatility, widening spreads in

    the process. Cancellation taxes directly incentivize HFTs not to withdraw liquidity during

    periods of high volatility, when liquidity is most needed.

    9. Conclusion

    The problem of regulating high-frequency trading is especially difficult to solve. There

    are many different stakeholders with dramatically different interests to satisfy. A central

    regulator must balance the demands of traders, exchanges, and institutional investors, all

    while ensuring the stability and robustness of markets.

    Additionally, the rapidly-evolving nature of HFT means that regulators lack any

    meaningful precedent to turn to for informing their policymaking. European governments

    appear to be entering a test and learn phase, in which new policies are implemented and

    tweaked until they appear to work.

    My analysis underscores the difficulty of finding an optimal regulatory policy. In

    several cases, the significance and even direction of the change in market quality

    measures differed between different models. Even when the models do agree, the policies

    themselves generally produce different results. And no form of regulation is perfect

    each regulation improved some measures of market quality while worsening others.

    Nevertheless, there are some useful pieces of information we can extract.

  • 43

    The German licensure regime appears to have modestly improved market quality.

    The impact on long-run volatility is ambiguous, though a majority of models found some

    decrease in the unconditional variance of returns. However, all models tested found a

    decrease in volatility persistence. Licensure may reduce conditional heteroscedasticity by

    discouraging HFTs from withdrawing liquidity at key moments or exacerbating volatility

    with phantom orders designed to move the market. Indeed, the true success of licensure is

    its ability to distinguish between abusive practices and legitimate market-making

    activities.

    Both the French and Italian regulatory regimes appear to have substantially

    decreased long-run volatility. Model selection had little to no impact on this result. Since

    a reduction in volatility means an improvement in market quality, the policies were

    dramatically successful on this front. However, there appears to be a tradeoff between

    long-run volatility and persistence. The persistence of volatility shocks significantly

    increased in Italy; in France, the models disagreed on the direction of the change. This

    inverse relationship is surprising: if we held constant, then long-run volatility and

    volatility persistence would move in tandem by definition.

    There are more tradeoffs to consider when analyzing market microstructure. The

    French and Italian regulations both substantially increased intraday volatility measured at

    one-minute intervals. However, both regulations decreased the sensitivity of bid-ask

    spreads to volatility. This tradeoff might strike different stakeholders very differently. An

    institutional investor, for example, might not care about intraday volatility if his holding

    period is measured in months or years, but might care a lot about preventing potential

    flash crash situations. Meanwhile, a market maker who ends each day with zero net

  • 44

    inventory would be tremendously harmed by an increase in intraday volatility, but

    wouldnt particularly care that HFTs withdraw liquidity in times of high volatility

    indeed, he would be one of the first traders to cancel his orders.

    My final analysis considered how bid-ask spreads responded to regulatory

    changes. I was surprised to find that spreads in France significantly contracted after

    regulations were introduced. This might simply be a result of HFTs leaving limit orders

    in place that they would have cancelled in the absence of a tax. However, I am faced with

    the classic joint-causality problem, due to the FTT introduced at the same time. In Italy,

    spreads expanded, but not significantly so. This hints that the FTT was responsible for the

    contraction of spreads. It may be the case that the FTT, which only applies to stocks held

    at the end of the day, increases inventory aversion, leading HFTs to quote more

    frequently to clear their inventories and avoid the tax.

    In light of all this information, what is the optimal HFT regulatory policy? At the

    risk of sounding indecisive, I would recommend an all-of-the-above strategy. The

    licensure regime, while failing to change long-run volatility, decreased volatility

    persistence, ensuring that shocks to volatility dissipate more quickly. Moreover, licensure

    would force HFTs to disclose their algorithms to the government, allowing efficiency-

    generating algorithms like market-making to proliferate, while curtailing rent-seeking

    algorithms like low-latency frontrunning.

    Cancellation taxes appear to decrease unconditional volatility, decrease bid-ask

    spreads, and decrease the sensitivity of spreads to volatility. The latter property is

    particularly important: robustness in the face of high volatility helps prevent flash crash

    style events from occurring. These benefits do come at the cost of increased intraday

  • 45

    volatility and increased volatility persistence, but the benefits appear to outweigh the

    harms. Cancellation taxes would primarily hamper algorithms designed to artificially