factor that affect the succes regulatory to foster investment energi efficiency 2011

Upload: desiyantri-siti-pinundi

Post on 02-Jun-2018

219 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    1/18

    ORIGINAL RESEARCH

    The many factors that affect the success of regulatory

    mechanisms designed to foster investments in energy efficiencyJay Zarnikau

    Received: 24 January 2011 / Accepted: 5 September 2011 / Published online: 18 September 2011# Springer Science+Business Media B.V. 2011

    Abstract A utilitys profit-maximizing level of invest-

    ment in energy efficiency or demand-side management

    (DSM) programs and mix of programs is affected by

    natural load growth, the frequency of rate cases,

    program costs, and the structure of any mechanism

    designed to either compensate the utility for foregone

    profits or sever the link between sales and profits. Under

    a range of reasonable assumptions, decoupling can

    incent a utility to invest in DSM. However, a utility

    experiencing high natural load growth and little inflation

    is likely to resist the imposition of a decoupling

    mechanism, as it would tend to lower profits. A utilitywith low growth in per-customer sales will tend to favor

    decoupling, as it will tend to lead to higher profits than

    under traditional regulation. The results presented here

    are quite sensitive to the assumptions made regarding

    natural load growth, regulatory lag, the frequency of

    price changes, price elasticity of demand, and other

    factors. This suggests that there is not a single approach

    to promoting energy efficiency without penalizing

    utility profits that will work in all situations for all

    utilities.

    Keywords Energy efficiency. Regulatorydecoupling . Electricity pricing . Conservation

    Introduction

    The National Action Plan for Energy Efficiency

    prep ared by the U.S. Environmental Protection

    Agency (2007) reports that Few energy efficiency

    policy issues have generated as much debate as the

    issue of the impact of energy efficiency programs on

    utility margins.

    The reduction in profitable salesresulting from energy efficiency poses a disincentive

    to utility investments in energy efficiency. Regulatory

    schemes have been devised to remove this disincen-

    tive, including lost revenue adjustment mechanisms

    (LRAMs), decoupling mechanisms, and shareholder

    bonuses.

    LRAMs compensate the utility for the margins or

    earnings lost as a result of reduced sales. The impacts

    of energy efficiency programs upon the utilitys sales

    are estimated. The under-recovery of earnings or

    margins resulting from energy efficiency programs isthen calculated. Adjustments or true-ups are under-

    taken to compensate the utility for the earnings

    foregone as a result of its investment in energy

    efficiency. The implementation of this approach

    requires credible estimates of the impacts of the

    energy efficiency programs upon sales as well as the

    utilitys fixed and variable costs.

    Decoupling seeks to fully divorce earnings and

    revenues from sales, thus removing the throughput

    Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410

    DOI 10.1007/s12053-011-9139-1

    J. Zarnikau (*)

    Frontier Associates LLC,1515 S. Capital of Texas Highway, Suite 110,Austin, TX 78746, USAe-mail: [email protected]

    J. ZarnikauLBJ School of Public Affairs and Division

    of Statistics of the College of Natural Sciences,The University of Texas at Austin,

    Austin, TX 78713, USA

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    2/18

    incentive. Allowed revenue or allowed revenue per

    customer is calculated. Rates are periodically adjusted

    through true-ups to ensure that the utility receives its

    allowed revenues or margins. The revenue collection

    allowed by the regulatory authority may be either

    increased or decreased under decoupling. As a result,

    actual utility revenues track projected revenuerequirements despite unexpected fluctuations in sales

    (NARUC2007). The theory underlying decoupling is

    explained in some detail by Eto et al. (1997). Full

    decoupling not only addresses the recovery of

    margins lost due to energy efficiency but also negates

    the effects of other factors affecting projected sales

    (Moskovitz et al.1992). Decoupling may also reduce

    uncertainties associated with the use of volumetric

    charges to recover the level of revenues approved by

    a regulatory authority. This is of particular interest

    since utilities tend to recover many fixed coststhrough volumetric changes, leaving the utilitys

    earnings highly sensitive to unexpected swings in

    the weather and economic conditions impacting sales.

    Decoupling can remove much of this risk.

    Performance bonuses can be designed to provide

    an incentive for the utility to achieve higher levels of

    energy efficiency. Shareholders receive a bonus when

    a goal for energy efficiency is met or exceeded. The

    bonus may be designed to be sufficiently large to

    compensate shareholders for lost margins.

    There are many variations on these themes.Different states of the USA have adopted slightly

    different formulas when implementing LRAMs or

    decoupling (Edison Foundation 2011; Hirst et al.

    1994). At least seven states in the USA have

    approved some type of decoupling mechanisms for

    natural gas and/or electric utilities within their

    regulatory jurisdiction, led by California (Kushler et

    al. 2006). LRAMs have been introduced in Ohio,

    Arkansas, North Carolina, and South Carolina. Texas

    adopted a simple shareholder bonus approach.

    These regulatory mechanisms have been endorsed byorganizations which favor expanded utility energy

    efficiency programs. Consumer organizations tend to

    oppose such mechanisms, either over concerns that such

    mechanisms will increase short-term rates or over more-

    general unease related to the growing involvement of

    utilities in the delivery of energy efficiency services

    (Anderson 2007). The Edison Electric Institute has

    come to the defense of LRAMs while expressing

    concern over full decoupling (Tempchin 1993).

    Brennan (2010) notes that decoupling removes

    incentives for utilities to operate in an efficient

    manner. Kihm (2009) concludes that if a regulator

    sets the utilitys rate of return in excess of its cost of

    capital, then the utility will prefer sales growth that

    will lead to greater supply-side investments and

    decoupling will fail to remove the Averch

    Johnsoneffect (Averch and Johnson 1962).

    This paper complements recent analysis by Cappers

    et al. (2009). As in Cappers et al. (2009), a prototypical

    electric utility system is modeled. However, while

    Cappers et al. (2009) simulates the financial effects on

    a utility of a set of pre-determined demand-side

    management (DSM) program portfolios under various

    assumed regulatory mechanisms, this present analysis

    determines the utilitys optimal profit-maximizing level

    of DSM and the mix of DSM programs selected by the

    utility under various ratemaking schemes. The focushere is to explore a utilitys motivation to pursue

    energy efficiency investments under various market

    conditions and regulatory incentive mechanisms.

    Why is this a controversial topic? As shown here,

    the impacts of each of these regulatory mechanisms

    on utility profits are very sensitive to the economic

    environment faced by the utility. A regulatory

    mechanism structured in a particular manner for one

    type of utility facing a particular set of circumstances

    may not be fair if applied to other utilities facing

    different economic environments. Further, the struc-ture of regulatory mechanisms may lead utilities to

    pursue different types of programs. Certainly, a load

    management program has a different impact on utility

    rates, capacity needs, and power plant emissions than

    a base load DSM program. Consequently, the mix

    of programs pursued by a utility may be of interest

    and is explored here.

    Theory

    Incentives to invest in DSM under traditional

    regulation

    Under traditional regulation with annual rate adjust-

    ments, a utility with no regulatory mandate to pursue

    DSM will weigh certain benefits against certain costs

    in deciding whether to invest in DSM. The utility sees

    a benefit if it can avoid uneconomical salese.g.,

    peak period sales of electricity for which the cost of

    394 Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    3/18

    making the sale exceeds the retail price at which the

    electricity may be sold.1 The value of electricity

    obtained through a wholesale electricity market

    during a price spike may be many times greater than

    the retail prices set under regulation. This savings in

    operating cost increases the utilitys profit, provided

    prices are based on the utilitys cost of service in a

    previous year (a historical test-year). Prices in the

    subsequent years will be reduced to reflect the savings

    in operating costs achieved by the utility in the

    current year, so most of the benefit will be realized

    in the first year that the new DSM investment has an

    effect on reducing operating costs. This benefit to the

    utility may be completely negated if there is a

    subsequent true-up of costs or an automatic fuel cost

    adjustment. This efficiency gain through DSM fo-

    cused on reducing uneconomical sales has a second-

    ary effect (even in the presence of true-ups orautomatic cost adjustments)the resulting reduction

    in future retail prices may lead to higher future sales,

    revenues, and profits through the price elasticity of

    demand effect.

    Under traditional regulation, there may be a

    detrimental financial impact on the utility if the

    DSM reduces the utilitys future rate base and thus

    the future financial returns to the utility permitted by

    the regulatory authority. This impact is dependent

    upon the level of costs potentially avoidable as a

    result of the utilitys investment in DSM, the rate ofreturn on rate base permitted by the regulatory

    authority, and the utilitys cost of capital. Assuming

    the regulatory authority permits the utility to fully

    recover its DSM costs from ratepayers, the program

    costs may nonetheless impact the utility. There may

    be a lag in time between when DSM costs are

    incurred and when they may be recovered from

    consumers. And the increase in retail prices resulting

    from the recovery of DSM costs shall reduce future

    sales through price elasticity of demand impacts.

    An investment in DSM in a particular year haseffects which last many years into the future. A one-

    time payment by the utility to foster consumer

    investments in energy efficient equipment may impact

    demand on the utilitys system, the utilitys load

    shape, operating costs, and the utilitys capacity needs

    over the life of the equipment promoted through a

    DSM program. And through price elasticity effects,

    the impact on electricity rates of the recovery of DSM

    costs will place future demand growth on a certain

    trajectory.

    Further complicating the analysis, there is consider-able feedback among key variables. DSM investments

    affect retail prices, operating costs, and capital costs.

    Operating costs and retail prices affect the utilitys

    interest in pursuing DSM. Thus, the level and type of

    DSM investment, retail prices, operating costs, and

    capital costs should be treated endogenously.

    If rate cases become less frequent under traditional

    ratemaking, the utilitys interest in avoiding uneco-

    nomical retail sales will increase. Thus, investments

    in load management, for example, may grow. As rate

    changes become less frequent, the utility may retainany profits from savings in operating costs for a

    longer period of time, and any detrimental reductions

    in allowed return on rate base will be recognized in

    retail prices with a longer time lag.

    In summary, a utility under traditional regulation

    weighs various benefits and costs in order to

    determine whether to invest in various types of

    DSM. Investment in DSM requires that the profits

    resulting from avoiding uneconomical sales exceed

    foregone future returns on rate base. Price elasticity

    effects resulting from efficiency gains and programcosts also play a role. The DSM decision is affected

    by a variety of parameters, including the length of

    time between rate adjustments, the costs and impact

    of various types of DSM, the operating costs which

    may be avoided through reliance upon DSM, the

    supply-side investment costs potentially avoided by

    the DSM, the utilitys discount rate, the price

    elasticity of demand, and various regulatory practices.

    Our analysis extends beyond a simple Utility Cost

    Test (California Public Utilities Commission and

    California Energy Commission2001) by consideringprice elasticity effects and the AverchJohnson effect.

    The allegation that utilities under traditional regu-

    lation have no incentive to invest in DSM absent

    externally imposed goals or regulatory requirements

    (Moskovitz et al.1992) overstates the situation. While

    it is indeed unlikely that an investor-owned utility

    would take actions to reduce sales upon which profits

    can be earned, some types of retail sales are unlikely

    to prove profitable once all the relevant long-term

    1 Of course, non-economic motives may be considered in

    addition to the economic benefits and costs considered here.These may include customer service goals and corporate

    sustainability commitments.

    Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410 395

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    4/18

    revenues and costs are considered. Targeted DSM

    programs can be used to reduce these types of sales.

    Incentives to invest in DSM under decoupling

    Under the form of decoupling considered here, the

    regulatory authority seeks to assure the utility that itwill receive a certain level of margin or profit on

    providing service to each customer. The per-customer

    profit is calculated based on test-year costs and the

    test-year levels of sales. The utilitys expected

    recovery of this level of per-customer profit is

    unaffected by the incremental impact of DSM on the

    current years level of sales. Prices are adjusted each

    year. Any under- or over-recovery of margins in

    1 year that is attributable to deviations of actual sales

    from the level of sales upon which rates are set is

    reconciled through an adjustment in rates the followingyear.

    Under decoupling, the utilitys incentive to achieve

    efficiencies by reducing uneconomical sales is greatly

    weakened. The reconciliation process prevents the

    utility from keeping the profits resulting from effi-

    ciency gains, although the utility may see a small

    benefit from achieving such gains if the additional

    profits are returned to consumer during the following

    year without interest.

    Under the form of decoupling considered here, the

    utility has an incentive to invest in the types of DSMwhich will reduce the utilitys sales. Each year, retail

    prices are adjusted based on the difference between

    expected per-customer margins or profits before any

    DSM investments and the margins recalculated based

    on the actual level of sales taking into account the

    effects of the DSM programs on sales. This adjustment

    factor is:

    PtQt1 EXPENSEt1

    CUSTCOUNT

    PtQt EXPENSEt1

    CUSTCOUNT

    1

    which may be simplified to:

    PtQt1 Qt

    CUSTCOUNT 2

    Qt1 is the test-year level of sales. This historical sales

    level may be adjusted for known and measurable

    changes (e.g., customer growth), but not for the

    impacts of DSM programs. Qt is the actual sales

    volume in year t after any investment in DSM.

    EXPENSEt1 denotes the historical test-year level of

    expenses, while CUSTCOUNT represents the number

    of customers on the utility system.

    Once multiplied by the number of customers, Pt(Qt1Qt) becomes an addition to the utilitys

    revenue requirement. Note that the utility may

    increase its revenues by increasing the gap betweenhistorical sales and actual sales. The higher revenues

    will enhance profits.

    It is sometimes alleged that decoupling cannot

    encourage investments in DSM. It will merely

    remove disincentives (Moskovitz et al.1992), so that

    an additional external goal or explicit incentive is

    necessary in order to motivate the utility to pursue

    DSM investments. Yet decoupling can actually induce

    DSMparticularly forms of DSM which would result

    in large decreases in utility sales. The utility has a

    financial incentive to increase the rate adjustment toits revenue requirement since a higher adjustment to

    rates will lead to higher revenues and profits.

    As is the case under traditional regulation, price

    elasticity effects and the impact of DSM on opportu-

    nities to receive future returns on investments in new

    capacity which will expand its rate base complicate

    the story. Relative to traditional regulation, the utility

    has less interest in constraining its retail prices over

    time. Any per-customer increase in profits from an

    increase in sales which is induced by a price reduction

    is returned to consumers. Nonetheless, there is a(typically, small) countervailing effect. Price reduc-

    tions lead to increased future capacity needs, which

    may in turn lead to greater returns for the utility.

    The utilitys interest in earning returns from an

    increasing rate base may remain strong, but factors

    such as the cost of capital and avoided costs will

    determine the strength of this motive. These factors

    suggest that the type of DSM favored by a utility

    under decoupling will be quite different from the type

    of DSM pursued by a utility under traditional

    regulation. Particularly if there is significant timebetween rate changes, the utility under traditional

    regulation will favor the types of DSM which will

    permit it to reduce uneconomical salese.g., load

    management orpeak clippingprograms. In contrast,

    the utility under decoupling is more likely to pursue

    forms of DSM which will result in large reductions in

    overall energy sales or off-peak sales. While the

    utility under traditional regulation must weigh the

    benefits of higher profits from reduced uneconomical

    396 Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    5/18

    sales against reduction in long-term returns if load

    management or peak clipping reduces future capacity

    needs and the associated returns from rate base

    investments (albeit, complicated by the other factors

    noted here), the utility under decoupling sees the

    reduction in long-term returns but sees fewer rewards

    from reducing operating costs. As with the traditionalregulation case, the relative strength of all of these

    effects depends upon the values assumed for price

    elasticities, rates of return on rate base, the supply-

    side investment costs potentially avoided by the

    DSM, the utilitys discount rate, and other factors.

    Incentives to invest in DSM under an LRAM

    The LRAM mechanism considered here is the lost

    contribution to fixed cost approach used in Arkansas

    and the Carolinas in the USA. The LRAM iscalculated as the revenue loss associated with DSM

    (i.e., the megawatt hour sales lost as a result of DSM

    multiplied by the retail price) minus the operating

    costs which are avoided as a result of the foregone

    sales. This difference is divided by sales which are

    adjusted for the impact of DSM. Using this factor, the

    retail price is raised to compensate the utility for any

    revenue loss resulting from DSM investments. The

    prospect of this additional charge on retail bills seeks

    to ensure that the utilitys profits are no lower than

    under traditional regulation.A properly designed LRAM removes traditional

    regulations disincentive for the utility to reduce

    profitable types of retail sales (e.g., baseload or off-

    peak sales). The remaining factors (e.g., price elasticity

    effects and the ability to earn returns from future

    rate base additions) determine whether an LRAM

    can induce any DSM absent an external goal for

    energy efficiency. The utilitys incentive to reduce

    uneconomical retail sales (e.g., sales during peak

    periods) is muted, since the LRAM mechanism

    seeks to maintain the profit margins on retail saleswhich were established by the regulator.

    Modeling approach

    The typical regulated utility described in this analysis

    selects an optimal level and mix of DSM programs so

    as to maximize the present value of profits over T

    years subject to a demand constraint, requiring it to

    meet the energy needs of its ratepayers. A nonlinear

    optimization model was developed using General

    Algebraic Modeling Software (GAMS) to examine

    the impacts of various regulatory incentive mecha-

    nisms upon utility earnings and rates under various

    scenarios.2 The base-case scenario will first be

    described, providing calculations of a utilitys profits

    and optimal DSM portfolio under the following

    regulatory systems:

    1. Traditional ratemaking with an annual adjustment

    of prices

    2. Traditional ratemaking with rate cases every

    5 years

    3. Decoupling of margins or revenues from sales

    volumes with an annual adjustment of prices

    4. Traditional ratemaking is adjusted using an

    LRAM and new rates are set every year

    5. Traditional ratemaking is adjusted using an

    LRAM and new rates are set every 5 years

    We then alter some base-case assumptions to demon-

    strate how the results are sensitive to the natural

    growth in the utilitys demand, DSM program costs,

    the utilitys level of avoided capacity cost, the level of

    any externally established goals for DSM, and other

    factors. We assume that this is a vertically integrated

    utility with fuel costs.

    Base-case scenario: traditional ratemakingwith annual adjustment of prices

    Total energy consumption is assumed to be 43,800 MWh

    in yeart=0, corresponding to a utility system with a 10-

    MW peak demand and a 50% load factor. Under base-

    case assumptions, demand would grow at a 3% annual

    rate in the absence of any DSM.

    We define three different load levels: Low_Demand,

    Medium_Demand, and Peak_Load. In the absence of

    any DSM, total energy consumption is allocated to each

    category of load using the allocators presented inTable1.

    In yeart1, the utility faces a decision regarding the

    appropriate quantity of three different types of

    DSM in which to invest: Baseload_DSM (e.g.,

    efficiency programs targeting end-uses with long

    operating periods such as motors or refrigerators),

    2 The GAMS code used in this analysis is available from the

    author upon request.

    Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410 397

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    6/18

    Medium_DSM (e.g., programs that seek to reduce air

    conditioning or space heating needs by promoting the

    installation of insulation, other building shell meas-

    ures, or HVAC equipment efficiency measures), and

    Load_Management (e.g., the control of air condition-

    ing equipment or curtailments to industrial operations

    for a very limited number of hours per year). dis used

    to denote a type of DSM. Each of these types of DSMis expected to have different impacts on the energy

    consumption assigned to the three load level catego-

    ries, denoted . For example, Load_Management is

    assumed to impact energy consumption only during

    the periods of the highest demand. The allocation of

    the DSM program impact on future energy consump-

    tion is provided in Table2.

    DSM programs are assumed to impact current and

    future sales and peak demand over a 10-year horizon.

    QtQ

    Baseline

    t X

    d ALLOCDSMd DSMd

    h Pt1 Pt0 =Pt0 QBaselinet

    8; t> t0

    3

    The pre-DSM level of sales within each load level

    category denoted QBaselinet is adjusted to reflect

    the energy savings achieved through the DSM

    decision in year t1. Demand is further adjusted for

    the price elasticity of demand, based on price changes

    in the previous year.

    3

    The price elasticity of demandfor electricity, , is set to0.2.4 This results in a post-

    DSM level of sales,Qt. The DSM impact is assumed

    to persist over the 10-year life of the DSM measures

    with no degradation of savings. It is assumed that

    implementation of the DSM programs occurs gradu-

    ally within the year of implementation, t1, such that

    the impact of DSM on sales in t1 is one half of the

    impact of the DSM in subsequent years.

    The unit cost of the total savings (across all load levelcategories) of Baseload_DSM and Medium_DSM is

    modeled as an increasing function of the level of DSM

    investment, consistent with the concept of an upward-

    sloping supply curve for DSM. An exponential function

    is adopted here. The unit cost (in dollars per total

    megawatt hour savings) is multiplied by the DSM

    quantity (in megawatt hours) in order to calculate the

    total DSM cost.

    DSMCOSTd 2 e0:0295 DSM

    DSMd

    d Baseload DSM; Medium DSM4a

    This DSM cost function provides a reasonable rela-

    tionship between DSM investment and the unit cost of

    DSM, as noted in Fig.1.

    The cost of Load_Management is set at $1,141/MWh,

    such that the cost is $50/kW or $50,000/MW divided by

    the 43.8 h associated with the Peak_Load period.

    DSMCOSTLoad Management

    1; 141 DSMLoad Management 4b

    A cap is placed on the amount of Load_Ma-

    nagement that may be obtained by the utility, to

    reflect limits to the market potential. This cap,

    stated as a megawatt hour value, is equivalent to

    1 MW multiplied by the 43.8 h in the Peak_Load

    period.

    DSMLoad Management 43:8 5

    The utilitys variable operating cost varies for the three

    different load level categories, per Table3. If we assume

    a vertically integrated electric utility, operating costs

    might include fuel or generation costs. Note that prices

    during the short Peak_Load period may reach $1,000/

    MWh.

    DSM investments can result in the avoidance of

    future capacity costs. Thus, the utilitys future rate

    3 Efforts to permit demand to adjust to contemporaneous pricechanges resulted in convergence problems. Consequently, alagged response is modeled here.4 A wide range of long-term price elasticities are reportedin the literature. Espey and Espey (2004) report a range

    from2.25 to 0.04.

    Table 1 Baseline allocation of energy consumption amongload level categories

    Allocation

    Low_Demand 0.500

    Medium_Demand 0.495

    Peak_Load 0.005Total 1.000

    398 Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    7/18

    base is affected by DSM investments in year t1. The

    utilitys rate base in years t>1, after adjustments are

    made to reflect the DSM investment, is modeled as:

    ADJRBtRBt X

    d

    ALLOCDSMd;0Peak Load0

    DSMd=43:8 ACC 8t> 1

    6

    RB is the pre-DSM projection of the utilitys rate

    base, 43.8 is the number of hours in the Peak_

    Load period and is used to convert the energy

    conserved in that period into a megawatt value.

    ACC represents the annual capacity cost which

    can be avoided as a result of the DSM. The

    utilitys rate base is set at $10 million in year t0and assumed to increase by the same rate of growth

    as demand (3% under base-case assumptions) absent

    any DSM investment. Annualized avoided capacity

    costs are set at $100,000/MW.The utilitys non-DSM expenses are the sum of

    variable operating costs, depreciation on rate base,

    and interest payments to bondholders. None of

    these non-DSM expenses is reconcilable. In t1 the

    cost of the utilitys investment in DSM will also be

    treated as an expenseas is common under tradi-

    tional regulationbut is collected through a separate

    rate rider.

    EXPENSEt OpCost Qt dep ADJRBt

    debtcost ADJRBtX

    d

    DSMCOSTd 8t 1

    7a

    EXPENSEt OpCost Qt dep ADJRBt

    debtcost ADJRBt 8t> 1

    7b

    Operating costs for various load levels, OpCost, were

    provided in Table3. The average annual depreciation

    rate, dep, is set at 0.15, such that the annual

    depreciation expense is calculated as 15% of the rate

    base. Following the example provided by Weston

    (2008), we assume a capital structure of 55% debt and

    a cost of debt of 8%. Multiplication of the debt ratioby the cost of debt yields 0.044 for the weighted cost

    of debt, debtcost.

    For simplicity, we assume that the utility recovers

    its revenue requirement (the sum of expenses and

    return) through a volumetric charge. The revenue

    requirement is established based upon historical test-

    year revenue requirements (i.e., expenses, interest

    paid to bondholders, and return) and historical test-

    year sales. Taxes are ignored in order to facilitate

    model convergence.5 Presently, we assume that prices

    5 Attempts to explicitly model federal income taxes as afunction of profits (and, thus, implicitly, a function of all othervariables in the model) resulted in convergence problems.These problems persisted even when rates were set so as toinclude taxes paid in the previous year. Provided that profitsremain positive and the tax rate is a fixed percentage of profits,

    after-tax profits will be proportional to pre-tax profits. Andoptimization based on pre-tax profits should yield the same

    result as optimization based on after-tax profits.

    Fig. 1 Relationship between level of DSM investment and costof conserved energy

    Low_Demand Medium_Demand Peak_Load Total

    Baseload_DSM 0.500 0.497 0.003 1.000

    Medium_DSM 0.400 0.595 0.005 1.000

    Load_Management 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000

    Table 2 Allocation of DSM

    program impacts amongload level categories

    Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410 399

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    8/18

    are re-set each year. Later, we examine a common

    situation where rates are changed less frequently.

    Pt ADJRBt1 ROE EXPENSEt1 =Qt1 8t

    8

    The allowed rate of return on equity established by

    the regulatory authority for ratemaking purposes,

    ROE, is set at 0.0495. This is again based on the

    example provided by Weston (2008), which assumes

    a capital structure with 45% equity and a cost of

    equity of 11%. Multiplication of the equity ratio by

    the cost of equity yields 0.0495 for ROE.

    Utility revenue is determined by multiplying the

    current years price by the adjusted megawatt hour

    consumption for the current year.

    REVtPtQt 8t 9

    While prices are determined by costs in the previous

    year, actual utility profits are determined by costs in

    the current year:

    PROFITt REVt EXPENSEt 8t 10

    The level of profit is affected by the rate of return on

    equity and regulatory lag, i.e., the differences in costs

    and sales in the historical test-year versus the actual

    costs and sales which are realized.

    Finally, the objective function is the maximization

    of discounted profit over the 10-year modeling

    horizon:

    Max OBJXT10t1

    PROFITt1

    1 rt 11

    A 9% discount rate forr is used in the calculation of

    present values.

    The solution to Eqs.1 through10 yields the profit-

    maximizing level of DSM investment in t1 and the

    resulting levels of annual profits, annual revenues,

    annual operating cost, DSM cost, future rate base, annual

    expenses, annual adjusted demand, and annual prices.

    Base-case scenario: traditional ratemaking

    with adjustment of prices every 5 years

    Under traditional regulation, it is unusual for rates to

    be adjusted every year. In fact, in many US states, it

    takes far longer than 1 year for a regulatory authority

    to process an application by a utility to change rates.Consequently, a system where prices are changed

    every 5 years is also considered. Regulatory lag or the

    time between when costs are incurred and the utility is

    afforded a reasonable opportunity to recover its

    reasonable and necessary costs tends to benefit a

    utility with sales growth and low marginal costs, but

    fixed retail prices over an extended period of time

    may financially distress a utility facing a decline in

    sales, cost inflation, or sales growth combined with

    high marginal costs.

    To model this regulatory system, Eq. 8is replacedwith:

    Pt ADJRBt0 ROE EXPENSEt0 X

    d

    DSMCOSTd=Qt0

    t t1

    12a

    Pt ADJRBt1 ROE EXPENSEt1X

    d

    DSMCOSTd=Qt1

    8t2 t2 to t5

    12b

    Pt ADJRBt5 ROE EXPENSEt5 =Qt5 8t2 t6 to t10

    12c

    Thus, prices in years 2 through 5 are based on

    expenses and return on rate base in year 1, while costs

    in year 5 determine prices in years 6 through 10. The

    price in year t=1 reflects the costs of the DSM

    investment incurred in that year and the rate base andexpenses in year 0. Otherwise, the equations pre-

    sented earlier are applied.

    DSM expenses in t1 are fully recovered by the

    utility in yeart1through a rate rider or other means.

    They are a component of the price in t1. A full rate

    case is not necessary in order to enable the utility to

    recover these costs. These DSM costs are ignored

    when base rates are later changed through rate

    cases.

    $/MWh

    Low_Demand 30

    Medium_Demand 40

    Peak_Load 1,000

    Table 3 Variable operating

    cost

    400 Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    9/18

    Base-case scenario: decoupling

    To calculate the profit-maximizing level of DSM

    investment selected by a utility under a decoupling

    ratemaking scheme, the expected margin or profit

    to be earned on each customer is calculated based

    on test-year costs and test-year levels of sales. Theutilitys recovery of this level of profit for a set of

    customers is ensured, regardless of any incremental

    impact of DSM on the current years level of

    sales. Prices are adjusted each year. Any under- or

    o ve r- re co ve ry o f marg in s i n 1 y ea r t ha t i s

    attributable to deviations of actual sales from the

    l ev el of sa les u pon w hi ch r at es ar e s et is

    reconciled through an adjustment in rates the

    following year. Equations 8 and 9 are replaced by

    the following.

    The expected margin per customer is based ontest-year sales. CUSTCOUNT refers to the number

    of customers and is set at 100. It is assumed that

    there is no growth over time in the number of

    customers.

    ExpectedMarginPerCustomert PtQt1 EXPENSEt1 =

    CUSTCOUNT 8t> 0

    13a

    The expected margin per customer is based on

    actual sales, which may have been affected by theutilitys investment in DSM.

    ActualMarginPerCustomert PtQt EXPENSEt1 =

    CUSTCOUNT 8t> 0

    13b

    The difference between expected and actual margins

    per customer is then calculated.

    RateAdjustmentt

    ExpectedMarginPerCustomert ActualMarginPerCustomert

    CUSTCOUNT 8t> 0

    14

    Note that this formulation is algebraically equiv-

    alent to the revenue per customer decoupling

    approach that has been implemented in some

    jurisdictions, since expenses in the previous

    period appear in both Eqs. 13a and 14 and it is

    assumed that the customer count has not changed

    over time.

    Any under-recovery of margins from the previous

    year is added to the price charged in the current year

    to calculate the price under decoupling.

    PDECOUPLEDt

    ADJRBt1 ROE EXPENSEt1 RateAdjustmentt1

    =Qt1 8t> 0

    16

    Utility revenues are now determined by multiplying

    the price established by the decoupling scheme by the

    adjusted megawatt hour sales.

    REVtPDECOUPLEDt Qt 8t 17

    Base-case scenario: LRAM with annual rate cases

    and rate cases every 5 years

    This regulatory approach is a hybrid between

    traditional regulation and decoupling. Unlike tradi-

    tional ratemaking, lost revenues are calculated and

    added to the utilitys revenue requirement. Rates

    may be adjusted each year or every 5 years. If

    rates are set every year, this would be similar todecoupling where the adjustments for lost margins

    or lost revenues would occur every year. If rates

    are set every 5 years, these calculations are made

    only twice during the 10-year modeling horizon,

    similar to the case of traditional ratemaking with

    regulatory lag. Equations3 through7aand7band9

    through11are retained from the model of traditional

    regulation.

    Prices are adjusted in order to compensate the

    utility for lost contribution to fixed costs attributable

    to DSM. Fixed costs are all costs other than variableoperating costs and DSM costs. The rate adjustment is

    calculated as:

    RateAdjustmentt

    Pd

    DSMdPtP

    OpCostQBaselinet Qt

    P

    Qt

    8t> 0

    18

    Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410 401

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    10/18

    If rates are re-set every year, prices are set based

    on the prices set under traditional ratemaking with

    annual rate case, plus the rate adjustment for lost

    revenues:

    Pt ADJRBt1 ROE EXPENSEt1 =Qt1

    RateAdjustmentt 8t> 0

    19

    For the setting of prices every 5 years, we use:

    Pt ADJRBt0 ROE EXPENSEt0X

    d

    DSMCOSTd=Qt0

    RateAdjustmentt t t1

    20a

    Pt ADJRBt1 ROE EXPENSEt1X

    d

    DSMCOSTd=Qt1

    RateAdjustmentt 8t2 t2 to t5

    20b

    Pt ADJRBt5 ROE EXPENSEt5 =Qt5 RateAdjustmentt

    8t2 t6 to t10

    20c

    Again we assume that DSM expenses int1are fullyrecovered by the utility in year t1 through a rate rider

    or other means. They are a component of the price in

    t1. A full rate case is not necessary in order to enable

    the utility to recover these costs. These DSM costs are

    ignored when base rates are later changed through

    rate cases.

    In practice, the treatment of load forecast error

    would also distinguish the LRAM approach from

    decoupling. However, errors in load forecasts are not

    considered here.

    As noted earlier, various regulatory authoritieshave adopted different variations upon these themes

    when implementing LRAMs or decoupling mecha-

    nisms. A number of simplifying assumptions have

    been made here in hopes of keeping these calculations

    somewhat transparent. These simplifications have

    been balanced against the need to retain sufficient

    detail in order to allow an examination of utility

    motivations to invest in DSM under various economic

    conditions and ratemaking schemes.

    Base-case results

    Table 4 summarizes the results under the base-case

    assumptions described above. Under traditional rate-

    making with annual price changes, the utility would

    decline to invest in DSM. Under traditional regulation

    and regulatory lag, the utility invests in a maximumlevel of load management but declines to invest in

    other forms of DSM. Load management becomes an

    attractive investment, since it lowers the utilitys

    operating expenses and the utility can retain the

    resulting profits if prices are changed infrequently.

    As anticipated earlier in this paper, decoupling leads

    the utility toward investments in energy conservation

    (i.e., Baseload_DSM and Medium_DSM). The

    LRAM cases also lead to utility investments in

    conservation but at lower levels of DSM investment

    than under decoupling.Because load grows at a higher rate than costs

    under the base case, regulatory lag leads to higher

    profits for the utility under traditional regulation. And

    the more regulatory lag, the better, from the utilitys

    perspective. Up to 5 years of regulatory lag is

    preferred (i.e., leads to higher earnings for the utility)

    to traditional regulation with 1 year of lag.

    The shift in investment from load management under

    traditional regulation with infrequent rate cases to base

    load and medium load DSM under decoupling and

    LRAMs would seem consistent with the explanationoffered by Brennan (2010). Load management reduces

    the utilitys average operating costs and thus leads to

    some short-term efficiencies. Decoupling and LRAMs

    blunt the utilitys interest in pursuing these efficiencies.

    It is assumed that base rates are based on historical

    test-year costs, unlike the projected rate year costs

    which are applied in California and some other states

    for ratemaking purposes. This introduces an incentive

    for the utility to utilize DSM in order to change its

    level of sales and expenses from test-year levels if

    such changes will lead to higher profits.Since RateAdjustmentt in the decoupling case is

    essentially Pt (Qt1Qt), the utility may increase its

    revenues by increasing the gap between historical

    sales and actual sales, as noted earlier. In this

    particular case, the utility increases its profits from

    $2.88 million to $2.93 million by investing in DSM in

    order to reduce sales.

    As can be seen from Fig.2, prices are perfectly flat

    under traditional ratemaking with annual rate cases.

    402 Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    11/18

    Sales growth equals the growth in the utilitys rate

    base. Per megawatt hour operating costs are assumed

    to be fixed over time. Since the utility makes no

    investment in DSM under this scenario, there is no

    need to recover any DSM program costs through

    prices, and the proportion of sales within each of the

    load levels remains constant.Under traditional ratemaking with regulatory lag,

    there is an initial increase in price to enable the utility

    to recover its investment in load management. Over

    time, this investment in load management leads to

    lower prices to consumers.

    Decoupling and the LRAM cases lead to higher

    prices. The utility invests in DSM and the cost of

    DSM is recovered from ratepayers in t1. The invest-

    ments in base load and medium DSM results in lower

    sales, and the spreading of the utilitys fixed costs

    among fewer billing determinants (i.e., sales) leads toprices which are higher than under the scenarios

    assuming traditional regulation (and minimal DSM

    investment).

    Are these robust results which would hold over a

    variety of utilities and economic environments?

    Unfortunately, the answer is no. As shown below,

    these results are sensitive to the utilitys natural load

    growth, cost structure, DSM costs, price elasticity of

    demand, return on equity, and regulatory constraints

    faced by the utility. The approach favored by a utility

    may change under different economic environments.

    Changes in avoided capacity costs

    To explore the AverchJohnson effect, the model was

    solved under various assumed values for avoided

    capacity costs. Avoided capacity cost of $0 might

    reflect a utility with sufficient transmission and

    distribution capacity that relied entirely on purchased

    power (e.g., a distribution cooperative or a small

    municipal system) or that was not involved in power

    generation (e.g., a transmission and distribution utility

    in an unbundled electricity market). When avoided

    capacity costs are reduced, DSM would have a

    diminished effect on reducing the future rate base

    upon which the utility earns future returns. When theyare increased, DSM has a bigger impact on the

    erosion of future returns on rate base. Results for

    avoided capacity costs of $0 and two times the base-

    case assumption are reported in Tables 5and6.6

    A reduction in avoided capacity costs motivates

    the utility to now invest in load management under

    both traditional regulation and decoupling. This type

    of DSM will reduce the utilitys operating costs by an

    amount more than it will decrease the utilitys

    revenues, andgiven the assumption of no avoided

    capacity costit will not adversely impact theutilitys future rate base and return on rate base.

    Ironically, this increase in DSM investment would

    coincide with a situation where DSM (particularly,

    load management) may not pass some of the usual

    cost-effectiveness tests for screening DSM programs

    because of the zero avoided capacity cost (California

    Public Utilities Commission and California Energy

    Commission2001). This change in avoided costs has

    little effect on profits under any form of ratemaking.

    There is a small effect on investments in base load

    and medium DSM by the utility under decoupling.As shown in Table 6, there is investment in load

    management in only the case of traditional regulation

    with regulatory lag when avoided costs are doubled

    relative to the base-case assumption. Figure3further

    6 Because utility investments in infrastructure can have very

    long accounting lives and the model presented here examinesonly a 10-year planning horizon, some of the results presented

    here may be understated.

    Ratemaking

    scheme

    Frequency of

    rate changes

    Utility pre-tax earnings ($ millions

    in present value over 10 years)

    DSM investment (MWh)

    BaseloadDSM

    MediumDSM

    Loadmanagement

    Traditional Annual 3.67 0 0 0

    Traditional Every 5 years 3.87 0 0 43.8

    Decoupling Annual 2.94 999 1,008 0

    LRAM Annual 4.01 786 776 0

    LRAM Every 5 years 3.91 576 576 0

    Table 4 Results under base-

    case assumptions

    Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410 403

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    12/18

    displays the relationship between avoided cost and the

    utilitys investment in DSM. As the avoided cost

    increases, investment decreases gradually under the

    decoupling case. Changes in avoided costs appear to

    have little impact on DSM investment under theLRAM cases.

    External DSM goal

    As a variation from the base-case scenario, we

    consider a situation where a regulatory or govern-

    mental authority has set a minimum goal for DSM.

    This has become a common practice in US states and

    in nations which seek to meet targets for reductions in

    greenhouse gasses. This becomes an additionalconstraint to the model:

    DSM MinDSM 21

    MinDSM is set at 2,000 MWh. All other equations of

    the model are retained.

    Of course, the impacts upon the utility will depend

    upon how high the external goal is set. The external

    goal would have no effect on a utility which already

    planned to exceed the level of energy conservation

    imposed by the goal, as in the case of the utility under

    decoupling here. The level of avoided cost and the

    relative costs of the DSM options will also affect the

    preferred source of the energy savings. Results are

    provided in Table7.

    Variations in load growth

    It is frequently observed that decoupling is more

    popular among natural gas utilities, which often face

    declining per-capita natural gas consumption in North

    America and among electric utilities in regions where

    there is little or no growth in electrical demand (e.g.,

    California). By eliminating all load growth in the

    model, this can be demonstrated.As suggested by Table 8, utility profits are

    significantly reduced under traditional regulation if

    there is no natural load growth. The utility fails to

    realize a benefit from the regulatory lag inherent in

    traditional ratemaking if there is no load growth.

    While it is the least-preferred ratemaking treatment

    for the growing utility, decoupling yields profits

    similar to the other approaches in a system with no

    load growth. Profits under an LRAM decline if there

    $80

    $85

    $90

    $95

    $100

    $105

    t1 t2 t3 t4 t5 t6 t7 t8 t9 t10

    Dollars

    PerMWhPrice

    Traditional Ratemaking withAnnual Price Changes

    Traditional Ratemaking withRegulatory Lag

    Decoupling with Annual PriceChanges

    LRAM with Regulatory Lag

    LRAM with Annual RateChanges

    Fig. 2 Prices under fiveratemaking approaches

    Ratemakingscheme

    Frequency ofrate changes

    Utility profit ($ millions inpresent value over 10 years)

    DSM investment (MWh)

    Baseload

    Mediumload

    Loadmanagement

    Traditional Annual 3.70 0 0 43.8

    Traditional Every 5 years 3.74 0 0 43.8

    Decoupling Annual 2.96 1,023 1,042 43.8

    LRAM Annual 4.01 786 777 0

    LRAM Every 5 years 4.00 569 564 0

    Table 5 Results whenavoided capacity cost isreduced to $0

    404 Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    13/18

    is no load growth, although the LRAM remains an

    attractive option to the utility. The decoupling

    mechanism may be slightly preferred to traditional

    regulation if an external goal for energy savings is

    imposed on the utility and there is no load growth.

    When 10% annual decreases in sales are assumed,

    decoupling becomes favored over traditional regula-tion, as is evident from Table 9.

    DSM investments under higher returns on equity

    and decoupling

    Kihm (2009) finds that if a regulator sets the utilitys

    rate of return in excess of its cost of capital, then

    decoupling will fail. The utility will prefer sales growth

    that will lead to greater supply-side investments and

    higher dollar returns on rate base. While the utility willcontinue to invest in DSM under decoupling as the ROE

    increases in this model, the utilitys overall interest in

    DSM does indeed decline as the ROE is increased. This

    is depicted in Fig. 4. As the ROE increases, DSM

    investments shift away from load management, which

    has a high impact on the need for additional supply-

    side capacity (and rate base) and toward base load

    DSM. The base load and medium load DSM invest-

    ments have a lesser impact on the utilitys rate base and

    profits. A potential topic of further study is whether

    this effect could be negated if DSM expenses were

    capitalized, as permitted in some states.

    DSM investments under higher price elasticity

    of demand

    The price elasticity of demand also affects DSM

    investments. As indicated in Table10, when the price

    elasticity of demand is raised (in absolute value)

    from 0.2 to 0.3, the utility under traditional regulation

    and annual rate cases invests in load management. This

    investment reduces the utilitys operating cost, reduces

    prices, and increases sales and profits. Thus, ironically,

    load management may lead to a higher level of sales.With the higher elasticity, the AverchJohnson effect is

    somewhat overcome. The more-elastic demand curve

    results in higher levels of investment in baseload DSM

    and medium DSM under decoupling, as reported in

    Table10. Yet, DSM investment declines slightly under

    the LRAM mechanism, as demand becomes more

    responsive to price changes.

    0

    500

    1,000

    1,500

    2,000

    2,500

    $0

    $25,

    000

    $50,00

    0

    $75,

    000

    $10,00

    0

    $125

    ,000

    $150

    ,000

    $175

    ,000

    $200

    ,000

    $225

    ,000

    MWhofDSMInvestment

    Traditional Ratemaking withAnnual Price Changes

    Traditional Ratemaking with

    Regulatory Lag

    Decoupling with Annual Price

    Changes

    LRAM with Regulatory Lag

    LRAM with Annual Rate

    Changes

    Fig. 3 Relationship between

    avoided cost (dollar permegawatt) and total DSM

    investment (annual megawatthours)

    Ratemakingscheme

    Frequency ofrate changes

    Utility profit ($ millions inpresent value over 10 years)

    DSM investment (MWh)

    Baseload

    Mediumload

    Loadmanagement

    Traditional Annual 3.67 0 0 0

    Traditional Every 5 years 4.00 0 0 43.8

    Decoupling Annual 2.93 981 982 0LRAM Annual 4.00 785 775 0

    LRAM Every 5 years 3.93 583 587 0

    Table 6 Results whenavoided capacity cost isdoubled

    Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410 405

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    14/18

    Decouplings effects under further changes

    in assumptions

    This hypothetical utility continues to invest in DSM

    under decoupling under a wide range of assumptions

    regarding the cost of DSM, as can be seen from

    Table11. Base-case results were reported earlier. With

    a 500% increase in the cost of Baseload_DSM and

    Medium_DSM with no change in the cost of load

    management, there is a modest reduction in the

    utilitys investment in DSM. If the cost of load

    management is reduced by 75% and the base-case

    costs of the other two types of DSM are retained, thenthe utility invests in load management under decou-

    pling. Under a ten-fold increase in the costs of all

    types of DSM, the decoupled utility continues to

    invest in Baseload_DSM but drops any investment in

    other types of DSM.

    Economies of scale in DSM program costs

    Earlier, it was assumed that the utility faced an

    upward-sloping supply curve for DSM. That is,

    there were diminishing returns to additional DSM

    investments and the cost of achieving additional

    energy savings was increase on a dollar per

    megawatt hour basis. It has sometimes been

    reported that the cost of achieving additionalDSM may decline across relevant program scales,

    such that there are economies of scale of running

    such programs.

    Ratemaking

    scheme

    Frequency

    of rate changes

    Goal? DSM investment (MWh)

    Base load Medium load Load management

    Traditional Annual No goal 0 0 0

    Goal 972 984 43.8

    Traditional Every 5 years No goal 0 0 43.8

    Goal 940 1,017 43.8

    Decoupling Annual No goal 999 1,008 0

    Goal 999 1,008 0

    LRAM Annual No goal 786 776 0

    Goal 1,000 1,000 0

    LRAM Every 5 years No goal 576 576 0

    Goal 1,000 1,000 0

    Table 7 External DSMgoal placed upon utility

    Ratemaking scheme Frequency of rate changes Goal? Utility profit ($ millions in presentvalue over 10 years)

    3% growth No growth

    Traditional Annual No goal 3.67 3.19

    Goal 3.56 3.06

    Traditional Every 5 years No goal 3.87 3.40

    Goal 3.67 3.16

    Decoupling Annual No goal 2.94 3.22

    Goal 2.94 3.22

    LRAM Annual No goal 4.01 3.50

    Goal 4.05 3.54

    LRAM Every 5 years No goal 3.91 3.73

    Goal 3.74 3.17

    Table 8 Utility profits under3% growth versus nogrowth

    406 Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    15/18

    To model this situation, Eq. 4a is replaced with

    Eq.22:

    DSMCOSTd 0:06 DSMd 0:000004 DSMd2

    d Baseload DSM;Medium DSM

    22

    Under this scenario, the utility would invest in load

    management under all regulatory mechanisms, includ-

    ing traditional regulation with minimal regulatory lag

    and decoupling. As in the base case, decoupling would

    continue to be the only case which would elicit

    investments in medium load and baseload DSM, and

    the level of investment in those forms of DSM would be

    over four times greater (i.e., 4,660 MWh of baseload

    DSM and 4,748 MWh of medium load DSM).

    Alternative growth rates for the rate base

    It was earlier assumed that the rate baseprior for any

    adjustments for the effects of DSM on the utilitys

    capacity needswould rise at the rate of demand growth

    (3%). If it is instead assumed that RBt has no growth,

    then results identical to those presented in Table 4 for

    DSM investments continue to hold for the traditional

    regulation cases. The results for an LRAM with rate

    cases every 5 years are virtually the same as base-caseresults. However, a slightly lower investment in DSM

    under the decoupling case is found than under the base-

    case assumptions. Under an LRAM with annual rate

    adjustments, investments in DSM decline by about 4%.

    If we instead assume a 10% annual growth for RB t,

    then the results presented in Table 12 arise. The

    ratemaking treatment involving up to 5 years of

    regulatory lag hinders the utilitys ability to quickly

    change prices in order to recover its rising costs.

    Slightly higher levels of DSM investment are under-

    taken under decoupling and the LRAMs.

    Lower ROE under decoupling

    Regulatory authorities have sometimes lowered a

    regulated utilitys allowed rate of return on equity

    0.04

    0.05

    0.06

    0.07

    0.08

    0.09 0.

    10.11

    0.12

    Return on Equity Permitted by Regulator

    MWhofDSM

    Base Load DSM

    Medium Load DSM

    Load Management

    0

    200

    400

    600

    800

    1000

    1200Fig. 4 Under decoupling,DSM investments declineas return on equity increases

    Ratemaking scheme Frequency of rate changes Goal? Utility profit ($ millions in present

    value over 10 years)

    3% growth Negative 10% growth

    Traditional Annual No goal 3.67 2.05

    Goal 3.56 1.85

    Traditional Every 5 years No goal 3.87 2.29

    Goal 3.67 1.94

    Decoupling Annual No goal 2.94 3.51

    Goal 2.94 3.49

    Table 9 Utility profits under

    3% growth versus 10%annual negative growth

    Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410 407

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    16/18

    for a utility under a decoupling scheme, under the

    theory that risks of sales and revenue volatility havebeen reduced for the utility and shifted to ratepayers.

    Consequently, the utility may be able to attract capital

    at a lower cost.

    Table13compares base-case results to a model run

    where the allowed ROE used for ratemaking purposes

    was reduced from 0.0495% to 0.0395%. Base-case

    assumptions pertaining to the cost of debt are

    retained. With the lower ROE, the utilitys profits

    are understandably lower. The lower ROE leads the

    utility to slightly higher DSM investments, including

    some load management.

    Cost function for load management

    Under base-case assumptions, load management was

    modeled using a constant per megawatt hour cost and

    the quantity of load management that could be

    selected was limited. Upward-sloping unit cost supplycurves for load management were also developed,

    mimicking the approach used for the other two types

    of DSM. When simple linear functions were tested,

    the results were similar to the base-case findings

    load management was selected by a utility under

    traditional regulation, but not selected by utilities

    under decoupling or an LRAM (unless a goal was

    imposed upon the utility and load management was

    sufficiently inexpensive). However, the quantities of

    load management procured by the utility under

    traditional regulation were often unrealistically highand the inclusion in the model of realistic supply

    curves with polynomial or exponential forms tended

    to lead to convergence problems.

    Further considerations

    The set of variables examined above to show the

    economics of regulatory mechanism designed to

    foster energy efficiency is not exhaustive. The scope

    of the utilitys operations, the presence of automaticpass-through clauses for fuel, and political consider-

    ations will also have effects.

    The utility modeled in this paper was assumed to

    be a vertically integrated electric utility. Yet, in some

    competitive markets such as the Electric Reliability

    Council of Texas (ERCOT), unbundled regulated

    transmission and distribution utilities provide ratepay-

    er funded energy efficiency programs. Transmission

    and distribution services providers have a more-

    Table 11 Results for decoupling under alternative assumptions

    Scenario DSM investment (MWh)

    BaseloadDSM

    MediumDSM

    Loadmanagement

    Base case 999 1,008 0

    500% increase in cost of|baseload and mediumload DSM

    591 600 0

    75% decrease in cost ofload management

    1,001 1,010 43.8

    10-fold increase in cost ofall types of DSM

    1,616 0 0

    Ratemaking

    scheme

    Frequency

    of rate changes

    Price elasticity

    of demand

    DSM investment (MWh)

    Base load Medium load Load management

    Traditional Annual 0.2 0 0 0

    0.3 0 0 43.8

    Traditional Every 5 years 0.2 0 0 43.8

    0.3 0 0 43.8

    Decoupling Annual 0.2 999 1,008 0

    0.3 1,071 1,077 0

    LRAM Annual 0.2 786 776 0

    0.3 765 756 0

    LRAM Every 5 years 0.2 576 576 0

    0.3 558 559 0

    Table 10 Variation in priceelasticity of demand (and noexternal DSM goals)

    408 Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    17/18

    limited scope of operations. The models constructed

    here would need to be substantially revised to reflect

    their operations and economic incentives. Natural gas

    utilities which primarily provide a pipeline function

    might face different incentives and disincentives.

    Generation-only entities (e.g., independent power

    producers) or retail-only entities (e.g., retail electricproviders in the ERCOT market) pose other distinct

    cases for which the analysis presented here would

    probably not apply.

    Under base-case assumptions, only DSM expenses

    were reconcilable. Operating costswhich were

    assumed to include fuel costswere not necessarily

    reconcilable. Thus, regulatory lag could result in an

    under-recovery or an over-recovery of the utilitys

    fuel costs in the ratemaking process. However, many

    utilities have automatic fuel adjustment clauses. The

    presence of such clauses will tend to reduce theimpact of regulatory lag and would certainly affect the

    results presented here. Similarly, a natural gas

    distribution utility permitted to simply pass-through

    the commodity cost of natural gas should be treated in

    a different manner.

    Finally, it should be noted that political factors

    might have as much to do with a utilitys interest in

    energy efficiency as strictly economic incentives.

    Goals and expectations may be set by local or

    regional governments with little attention to what

    levels of DSM may prove economical. DSM spendingoften becomes a bargaining chip in rate case

    settlement negotiations. Corporate sustainability com-

    mitments and customer service goals may also affect a

    utilitys motives.

    Conclusions

    Using a nonlinear optimization model of the DSM

    investment decision of a hypothetical electric utility,

    we find that regulatory mechanisms designed to

    promote energy efficiency and economic conditions

    affect not only the level of a utilitys DSM investment

    but also the types of DSM programs preferred by the

    utility. Under the assumptions made here, decoupling

    will indeed lead the utility to greater investment in

    energy efficiency than traditional regulation over a

    broad range of alternative assumptions. Decoupling

    may be particularly effective in promoting DSMfocused on energy conservation, rather than peak

    d e ma n d r e du c ti o n ( e .g . , B a se l oa d _D S M o r

    Medium_DSM) although the relative costs of differ-

    ent types of DSM programs impact this. An LRAM

    mechanism may also lead a utility to conservation

    investments. But in only one case (i.e., exceptionally

    high growth in the utilitys rate base) was the optimal

    level of DSM investment higher under an LRAM than

    under decoupling.

    The type of DSM investments preferred by the utility

    is sensitive to avoided costs, program costs, and othervariables. Load management is attractive to a utility

    Ratemaking

    scheme

    Frequency of

    rate changes

    Utility pre-tax earnings ($ millions

    in present value over 10 years)

    DSM investment (MWh)

    BaseloadDSM

    MediumDSM

    Loadmanagement

    Traditional Annual 3.35 0 0 43.8

    Traditional Every 5 years 1.07 0 0 43.8

    Decoupling Annual 2.76 1,032 1,042 43.8

    LRAM Annual 3.56 1,087 1,081 0

    LRAM Every 5 years 0.94 788 783 0

    Table 12 Results with 10%

    growth in rate base beforeDSM

    Ratemakingscheme

    Utility profit($ millions in presentvalue over 10 years)

    DSM investment (MWh)

    Base load Medium load Load management

    Decoupling: base case 2.94 999 1,008 0

    Decoupling: lower ROE 2.21 1,034 1,048 43.8

    Table 13 Decoupling leadsto a lower ROE

    Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410 409

  • 8/10/2019 Factor That Affect the Succes Regulatory to Foster Investment Energi Efficiency 2011

    18/18

    under traditional regulation and infrequent rate cases.

    This utility reduces its operating costs through the load

    management and retains the resulting profits until rates

    are re-set at the time of a subsequent rate case. At a

    sufficiently high price elasticity of demand, load

    management becomes attractive under traditional regu-

    lation with annual rate changes, as well.Under the assumptions examined here, decoupling

    and LRAMs would promote DSM investments with low

    load factors (i.e., programs focused on energy conser-

    vation throughout the year, rather than peak load

    reduction). But this can change if load management

    becomes sufficiently cheap.

    In an environment of strong growth in energy

    demand, a utility is likely to favor traditional regulation

    with its built-in regulatory lag. A fast-growing utility

    may rightfully see decoupling as a threat to its profits

    and oppose any policy changes in that direction. In anenvironment of negative growth, a decoupling mecha-

    nism is likely to be preferred over traditional regulation

    by the utility. These results conform to the observation

    that natural gas utilities experiencing declining sales per

    customer and electric utilities in areas with little load

    growth tend to favor decoupling.

    Beware of those who claim that a single rate-

    making approach is the universally best policy to

    promote energy efficiency without damaging the

    profitability of regulated utilities. The number of

    possible situations is limitless and generalizationsare difficult. There is an enormous diversity among

    electric utilities with respect to their operating

    environment, cost structure, and available DSM

    opportunities, and it is not possible to model every

    utility or every economic condition. A regulatory

    approach that yields some level and mix of DSM

    consistent with policy goals in one situation may

    yield different results in another environment. And

    there are myriad ways to implement decoupling and

    LRAM schemes with subtle differences from the

    formulas examined here. Nonetheless, some of thefactors likely to affect the utilitys profits under

    various ratemaking schemes and the optimal level

    and mix of a utilitys DSM investments under various

    conditions can be readily identified.

    Acknowledgments The author benefited from earlierexchanges with C.K. Woo and I. Horowitz on this topic.

    Michele Chait, Parviz Adib, and George Mentrup providedvaluable comments on earlier versions. Three referees provided

    exceptionally detailed and invaluable suggestions on the initialsubmission, resulting in significant improvements to this paper.

    References

    Anderson, J. (2007). ELCON opposes utility revenue decoupling

    as a device to open doors to energy efficiency.Platts PowerMarkets Week. March 2.

    Averch, H., & Johnson, L. (1962). Behavior of the firm underregulatory constraint. American Economic Review, 52,10521069.

    Brennan, T. (2010). Decoupling in electric utilities. Journal ofRegulatory Economics, 38, 4969.

    California Public Utilities Commission and California EnergyCommission. (2001).California standard practice manual:

    Economic analysis of demand-side programs and projects.

    San Francisco: California Public Utilities Commission andCalifornia Energy Commission.

    Cappers,P., Goldman, C., Chait, M., Edgar,G., Schlegel, J., Shirley,

    W. (2009). Financial analysis of incentive mechanisms topromote energy efficiency: Case study of a prototypicalsouthwest utility. LBNL-1598E. March.

    Edison Foundation. (2011). State electric efficiency regulatoryframeworks. Washington, DC: Edison Foundation.

    Espey, J., & Espey, M. (2004). Turning on the lights: A meta-analysis of residential electricity demand elasticities.

    Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, 36(1),6581.

    Eto, J., Stoft, S., & Belden, T. (1997). The theory and practiceof decoupling utility revenues from sales. Utilities Policy,6(1), 4355.

    Hirst, E., Blank, E., & Moskovitz, D. (1994). Alternative ways

    to decouple electric utility revenues from sales. The

    Electricity Journal, 7, 5466.Kihm, S. (2009). When revenue decoupling will work. . . and

    when it won't. Electricity Journal, 22(8), 1928.Kushler, M., York, D., & Witte, P. (2006). Aligning utility

    interests with energy efficiency objectives: A review of

    recent efforts at decoupling and performance incentives.

    Report no. U061. Washington, DC: American Council foran Energy Efficient Economy.

    Moskovitz, D., Harrington, C., & Austin, T. (1992). Weighingdecoupling vs. lost revenues: Regulatory considerations.The Electricity Journal, 5, 5863.

    National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners.(2007).Decoupling for electric and gas utilities: Frequentlyasked questions. Washington, DC: National Association of

    Regulatory Utility Commissioners.Tempchin, R. (1993). Decoupling? Not so fast. The Electricity

    Journal, 6, 2.U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (2007). National Action

    Plan for Energy Efficiency. Aligning utility incentives with

    investment in energy efficiency (p. ES-3). Washington, DC:U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.

    Weston, F. (2008). Customer-sited resources and utilityprofits: Aligning incentives with public policy goals.US EPA Webinar presentation. Regulatory Assistance

    Project.

    410 Energy Efficiency (2012) 5:393410