exogenous targeting instruments under differing ... · exogenous targeting instruments under...

37
1 Exogenous Targeting Instruments under Differing Information Conditions. September 10, 2003 John Spraggon Department of Economics Lakehead University 955 Oliver Rd. Thunder Bay, ON P7B 5E1 [email protected] Abstract This paper tests the ability of an exogenous targeting instrument to induce compliance when the regulator cannot observe the emissions of the individual polluters. Spraggon (2002 and 2001a) shows that although these instruments are able to induce groups to the target outcome they are not able to induce individuals to make the socially optimal decision. This study investigates whether the information individuals have about others payoffs effects how they make their decisions in this environment. Ledyard (1995) suggests that when subjects have less information in public goods experiments they are more likely to choose the Nash equilibrium decision. In the exogenous targeting instrument environment the Nash equilibrium decision is also the socially optimal decision. Thus, if this result carries over, subjects will be more likely choose the socially optimal decision. Keywords: Moral Hazard in Groups, Exogenous Targeting Instruments, Experiments, Information (JEL C72, C92, D70). Acknowledgements: This research is sponsored through a grant from the Senate Research Committee at Lakehead University. Please do not quote without permission, any comments would be appreciated.

Upload: docong

Post on 14-May-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

1

Exogenous Targeting Instruments under Differing Information Conditions.

September 10, 2003

John Spraggon Department of Economics

Lakehead University 955 Oliver Rd.

Thunder Bay, ON P7B 5E1

[email protected]

Abstract This paper tests the ability of an exogenous targeting instrument to induce compliance when the regulator cannot observe the emissions of the individual polluters. Spraggon (2002 and 2001a) shows that although these instruments are able to induce groups to the target outcome they are not able to induce individuals to make the socially optimal decision. This study investigates whether the information individuals have about others payoffs effects how they make their decisions in this environment. Ledyard (1995) suggests that when subjects have less information in public goods experiments they are more likely to choose the Nash equilibrium decision. In the exogenous targeting instrument environment the Nash equilibrium decision is also the socially optimal decision. Thus, if this result carries over, subjects will be more likely choose the socially optimal decision. Keywords: Moral Hazard in Groups, Exogenous Targeting Instruments, Experiments, Information (JEL C72, C92, D70). Acknowledgements: This research is sponsored through a grant from the Senate Research Committee at Lakehead University. Please do not quote without permission, any comments would be appreciated.

2

Introduction

Moral hazard in groups is a common social dilemma applicable in a wide range of

settings. Workers choosing effort levels, polluters choosing emission levels are two

primary examples. Moral hazard in groups is characterized by a principal who would

like to induce an agent to make a specific choice which is not in the agent’s best interest,

and the agent’s action is unobservable to the principal. Many authors discuss and

provide refinement to the use of “Exogenous Targeting Instruments” as a theoretical

solution to the moral hazard in groups problem (for example Holmstrom 1982, McAfee

and McMilan 1991, Segerson 1988 and Xepapadeas 1992, 1995). This paper is one in a

series that uses controlled laboratory experiments to provide some empirical evidence as

to the efficacy of these instruments. Recent papers by authors such as Cochard et al.

(2002), Spraggon (2002, 2000a) and Vossler et al. (2002) suggests that exogenous

targeting instruments are able to induce groups of individuals to comply with a standard

under a number of different circumstances, including when subjects have heterogeneous

payoff functions (Spraggon 2002a) and when subjects are also involved in a market

(Vossler et al. 2002).1 However, these instruments are typically unable to induce

individuals to choose the socially optimal decision on average. The purpose of this

experiment is to determine whether the information individuals have influences whether

or not their decisions correspond with theoretical predictions.

Clearly there are many different situations that involve moral harzard in groups.

In terms of the worker effort problem, some work groups may have excellent information

about the cost of effort of co-workers (sports teams, production shop floors) while some

1 Nalbantian and Schotter (1997) investigate a different exogenous targeting instrument which is unable to induce the group to the target outcome.

3

may not (management may not have a good idea of the cost of effort for production floor

workers and vice versa). Similarly, some non-point source pollution problems may

involve very similar polluters with excellent information about each other i.e. dairy

farmers. Other situations may involve many different types of polluters (agricultural,

industrial and municipal) who may not have good information about each other. Horan

(2001) lists ten different non-point source pollution sites. Of these at least two involve

different types of sources, and two (one of these and one which does not involve different

types of sources) cross state lines.2

The experiment involves two treatment variables: the information condition (full,

partial or no information), and the payoff functions (homogeneous or heterogeneous).

Under the full information condition subjects know the number of people in their group

and everyone's payoff function. This is the information condition under which Spraggon

(2002, and 2000a) were conducted. Under the partial information condition subjects

know the number of people in their group but have no information about the payoff

functions of the other people. Under the no information condition subjects only know

their own payoff function and have no information about the number of people in their

group or the payoff functions of the others in their group. This is similar to the

information treatment for public goods experiments investigated in Marks and Croson

(1999).3 Although there were no significant effects of information at the aggregate level,

they observed a greater degree of convergence to the Nash Equilibrium in their

incomplete information case than in their full or partial information case. Rondeau et al.

2 Specifically, Chesapeak Bay involves both agricultural and urban sources and Dillon Creek involves urban, septic and ski areas. 3 In Marks and Croson’s partial information condition subjects knew the sum of the groups valuation for the public good.

4

(1999) investigate information in a one-shot provision point with money back guarantee,

a proportional rebate and heterogeneous agents with large groups (N=45). They also find

no significant effects. As a result, I conjecture that under the no information condition

subjects will be more likely to choose the socially optimal decision over time. However,

it may be the case that subjects find the treatments in which they have less information

more difficult and as a result may be more likely to choose their decision number

randomly.

A secondary purpose of this paper is to investigate the hypothesis that subjects

use simple heuristic to make their decisions. Spraggon (2000b) discusses individual

decision making in the previous exogenous targeting instrument experiments. They show

that individual decision making is best described by a simple heuristic where subjects

choose the target divided by the number of people in the group in early periods. As a

result, reducing the amount of information that subjects have about the number of people

in their group, removes this heuristic as a possible solution strategy and may make the

decision process more difficult for the subjects. A censored form of Anderson, Goeree

and Holt’s (1998) quantal response model is used to differentiate between decision error

and preference explanations as to why subject’s decisions differ from the dominant

strategy Nash decision. By estimating the error in the decision making process we are

able to determine whether or not subjects found the environment more difficults.

The results are consistent with the results of previous experiments (Ledyrad 1995,

and Marks and Croson 1999) in that different information conditions have different

effects on groups where the subjects have homogenous or heterogeneous payoff

functions. The differences here seem to be due to homogenous subjects playing more

5

randomly when they know the number of people in the group but not their payoff

functions, and more risk-aversely when they have no information, whereas heterogeneous

subjects play more randomly when they have no information, and more risk-aversely

when they know the number of people in their group. Moreover, we observe

convergence to the Nash prediction for homogeneous groups under partial and full

information and convergence for the heterogeneous groups under no and partial

information.

The Moral Hazard in Groups Experiment

The design of the experiment is based on a standard model of non-point source

pollution used by authors such as Segerson (1988), Malik (1990) and Xepapadeas (1995)

and reported in Spraggon (2002).4 Subjects take the role of firms whose decisions, for

simplicity, correspond to the level of emissions. The larger the decision number the more

emissions that the firm releases and the higher the subject’s payoff up to some maximum

decision number which corresponds to the firms uncontrolled level of emission. This part

of the subject’s payoff is described as their private payoff and is provided to the subjects

in a table. It can be described by the following function:

2max )(004.025)( nnnn xxxB −−= (1)

where Bn is the benefit function, xn is the decision number, xnmax is the maximum

decision number and n indexes the individual subjects (n=1..6). This functional form and

the parameters where chosen for mathematical convenience.

4 Nalbantian and Schotter’s (1997) experiment was also used as a model specifically for the number of subjects per group and number of periods per session. This experiment differs from Nalbantian and Schotter’s in terms of being framed as a public bad rather than a public good. See Park (2001) for a comparison of these frameworks.

6

The primary research question is whether the instruments suggested by Segerson

(1988) are able to induce firms to reduce their emissions to the socially optimal outcome.

We look at one specific form of the instrument suggested by Segerson: The tax/subsidy

instrument taxes or provides a subsidy to everyone in the group depending on the

difference between the target aggregate group decision number (which I refer to as the

group total) and the actual group total. This instrument is a linear function of the

difference between the actual and the target group totals. To ensure that subjects were

clear that this group payoff could be positive or negative it was presented as:

<−≥−

=150)150(3.0150)150(3.0

)(XifXXifX

XT (2)

where T(X) is the group benefit function, X is the aggregate decision number (or group

total ∑ ==

6

1n nxX ), 150 is the target and 0.3 is the tax and subsidy rate. As a result each

subject faces the following payoff function:

)150(3.0)(004.025 6

12max −−−−=Π ∑ =n nnnn xxx . (3)

This payoff function has a unique maximum which can be found by differentiating Πn

with respect to xn, leading to the solution: 75max* −= nn xx . Thus, the payoff maximizing

decision is for each subject to reduce their decision number from the maximum by

seventy-five. There are three different subject types. For the homogeneous sessions all

six of the subjects are medium capacity: xnmax= 100, xn

*= 25, for the heterogeneous

sessions three of the six subjects are large capacity: xnmax= 125, xn

*= 50 and three small

capacity subjects: xnmax= 75, xn

*= 0. There is also a group optimal solution under this

instrument. If all subjects choose zero the payoff of the group is maximized. This is not

7

a Nash equilibrium as it is in each individual’s best interest to reduce their decision

number from the maximum by seventy-five.

Clearly subjects may not necessarily behave as payoff maximizers. There are

many studies including (Spraggon 2001b, Anderson, Goeree and Holt 1998) which

discuss this issue. The censored form of Anderson, Goeree and Holt’s (1998) quantal

response model will be used to estimate the importance of decision error and preference

explanations for any deviations from payoff maximizing behavior.

The level of information that the subjects have about the number and payoffs of

other people in the group is the treatment variable of interest in this paper. We

investigate three different cases: Full Information, Partial Information and No

Information. In all three cases subjects know their own payoff functions. Under the full

information condition subjects know the number of other subjects in their group as well

as the payoffs of the others in their group. Under the Partial Information condition

subjects know how many people are in their group but do not have information about the

payoffs of the others in their group. Under the No Information condition subjects do not

know either the number of people in their group or the payoffs of the others in their

group.

This experiment is concerned with data from two separate sources. Data for the

full information treatment was collected at McMaster University and the data for the

partial and no information treatments were collected at Lakehead University. A previous

set of experiments has been conducted at both of these sites in order to ensure

consistency between the results (Moir and Spraggon 2002). Moreover, the procedures

used to conduct the sessions were identical except for the information provided to the

8

subjects (the treatment variable) and the fact that a session at McMaster consisted of one

group of six subjects while a session at Lakehead consisted of two groups of six subjects.

This was done so that if subjects just assume that the other people in the room comprised

their group in the no information conditions the simple heuristic decision would not be

the Nash equilibrium.

Theoretical Predictions The primary questions addressed by this study concern the average level of

aggregate decision number (group total). The purpose of these exogenous targeting

instruments is to reduce the ambient level of pollution to the target level. As a result, the

first hypothesis concerns the ability of this instrument to reduce the group total to the

target level for each of the treatments. A secondary concern is whether this instrument is

able to induce individuals to reduce their emissions to the optimal level.

Hypothesis 1: The Tax/Subsidy Instrument will be able to induce the group to the target outcome independent of the information condition. The Tax/Subsidy instrument induces the optimal decision as a dominant strategy

regardless of the information that subjects have. Indeed the less information they have

about other subjects the more likely they should be to concentrate on their own payoff

function. Moreover, the Tax/Subsidy instrument is designed such that the larger the

deviation from the target outcome the larger the fine and as a result the more likely that

subjects will go bankrupt and be removed from the group.

Hypothesis 2: Less information will result in subjects decisions being closer to the Nash decision. This hypothesis comes from the results of the Marks and Croson (1999) study.

As discussed in the introduction they found that although on average there was no

9

difference across the information conditions they did find greater convergence to the

Nash equilibrium in the treatments with less information. If this result transfers over into

this environment we should observe similar convergence to both the target at the

aggregate level and the Nash decision numbers at the individual level.

Mark’s and Croson’s (1999) study suggested that in public goods environments

when information was removed decisions converged more closely to the Nash

equilibrium. There are two reasons why decisions may diverge from the Nash

equilibrium. The first is that subject’s decisions have a random component to them due

to some explanation such as error. The second is that preferences are such that subjects

are maximizing something other than their simple monetary payoff. Therefore, when

information is removed either the experimental environment becomes simpler and so the

amount of error is reduced or the reduction in information changes the subjects

preferences (for example if you do not know that your contributions will benefit 10 other

people you may not receive as much utility through altruism as if you did have this

information).5 The Tobit model allows us to estimate both the level of error as well as

the preference maximizing decision number.6 This will allow us to differentiate between

differences, which are due to error and differences that are due to preferences.

Results The results are separated into a number of different sections. The first two results

deal with the aggregate decision numbers. First the session means are discussed and then

the convergence properties are investigated. Then we look at the mean, Tobit estimates

5 See Goeree et al. (2002) for a detailed discussion of altruism. 6 Greene (2000) and StataCorp (2001) were used as guides for the econometrics with time-series of cross-section data.

10

and convergence of the individual decision numbers. Finally, the implications of the

number of subjects who went bankrupt under each treatment are discussed.

Result 1: Information has no effect on the aggregate decision number The first question is, are there significant differences at the aggregate level between the

different information conditions. Table 1 suggests that there are differences but Analysis

of Variance (Table 2) suggests that they are not significant.7 This is consistent with the

results for information found by previous experiments (Marks and Croson 1999).

Table 1: Mean Group Total by Treatment

Information No Info Partial Info Full Info Total

Heterogeneous 196.63 12.19

3

174.69 23.03

3

170.47 6.62

3

180.60* 8.76

9

Homogeneous 150.80 7.78

3

174.51 17.65

3

158.44 7.70

3

161.25 6.94

9

Total 173.71 12.12

6

174.60 12.98

6

164.45 5.28

6

170.92* 5.91 18

Each cell contains mean, standard error and frequency. An * indicates that the Group Total is significantly different from 150 and the 5% level. Table 2: Analysis of Variance, Mean Group Total Number of obs =18 R-squared = 0.3510 Root MSE =24.02 Adj R-squared = 0.0806 Source Partial SS Df MS F Prob >F Model 3746.12 5 749.22 1.30 0.3277 Information 378.98 2 189.49 0.33 0.7264 Homogeneity 1684.32 1 1684.32 2.92 0.1133 Info*Hom 1682.82 2 841.41 1.46 0.27 Residual 6926.17 12 577.18 Total 10672.29 17 627.78

7 These results are unchanged if we look at medians (see Appendix Tables 1 and 2).

11

Figures 1 and 2 show the average group totals over the three sessions in each cell. Notice

that both for heterogeneous (Figure 1) and homogeneous (Figure 2) groups there is not

much difference between the lines representing the average group total in any of the

periods.

This suggests that the information that polluters have about the other participants

under the tax/subsidy instrument will not have any significant effects on the ability of this

instrument to reduce the aggregate decision number to the target.

Result 2: There are significant reductions in efficiencies due to both Heterogeneity and Information. Efficiency is defined as the change in the value of the social planner’s problem as

a percentage of the optimal change in the social planner’s problem. In this experiment

the social planner’s problem is to maximize the producer’s payoffs minus the social cost

of pollution:

)(3.0)(004.025max 6

1

6

12max ∑∑ ==−−−=

n nn nn xxxSP . (4)

Efficiency is then given by:

StatusQuoOptimal

StatusQuoActual

SPSPSPSP

E−

−= (5)

where SPActual is the actual value of the social planner’s problem given the choices of the

subjects, SPStatusQuo is the value of the social planner’s problem if all of the subjects

choose their maximum decision (xnmax) and SPOptimal is the value of the social planner’s

problem if all of the subjects choose their optimal decision (xn*). The value of efficiency

ranges between 0 and 1 and is represented in Table 3 as a percentage. Notice that there

are real differences in efficiency across the treatments. The heterogeneous groups have

lower efficiencies and No and Partial Information sessions have lower efficiencies than

12

the Full information sessions. Also notice that Heterogeneous groups have lower

efficiencies under the No Information condition while Homogeneous groups have the

lowest efficiency under Partial Information. Analysis of variance confirms that these

differences are significant (Table 4).

Table 3: Mean Efficiencies by Treatment

Information No Info Partial Info Full Info Total

Heterogeneous 79.68% 2.80

3

82.41% 0.62

3

85.09% 4.88

3

82.39% 1.81

9

Homogeneous 89.16% 0.79

3

86.94% 2.84

3

96.33% 1.09

3

90.81% 1.68

9

Total 84.42% 2.49

6

84.68% 1.65

6

90.71% 3.36

6

86.60% 1.57 18

Each cell contains the efficiency as a percentage, standard deviation and frequency. Table 4: Analysis of Variance, Mean Efficiencies Number of obs =18 R-squared = 0.6686 Root MSE =0.045788 Adj R-squared = 0.5304 Source Partial SS Df MS F Prob >F Model 0.0507 5 0.01015 4.84 0.0118 Homogeneity 0.0319 1 0.03191 15.22 0.0021 Information 0.0152 2 0.00760 3.63 0.0586 Hom*Info 0.0036 2 0.00181 0.87 0.4452 Residual 0.2516 12 0.00209 Total 0.0759 17 0.00446

The significant differences in efficiency which are not observed in the group total

can be explained by variability in the individual decisions and the fact that efficiency

takes into account the costs of reducing decision number. Thus a heterogeneous group

who all choose 25 would have a group total of 150 but an efficiency of 88.9.

Unfortunately the other authors who have looked at heterogeneity and information

13

(Marks and Croson 1999 and Rondeau et al. 1999) look at the results with respect to

efficiency. Clearly both heterogeneity and reductions in information complicate the

environment and reduce efficiency. Moreover, we observe different effects of

information on groups with homogeneous and heterogeneous payoff functions as

observed for public goods (Ledyard 1995).

Result 3: Greater convergence is observed for the No Information case with Heterogeneous payoff functions and the Partial Information case with Homogeneous payoff functions. Marks and Croson (1999) use a random effects regression with period and period

squared to show greater convergence to the Nash outcome for their aggregate data. We

estimate this model (Table 5), an asymptotic convergence model suggested by Noussair

et al. (1995) (Table 6) and a combination of the two models (Table 7).

Table 5 Marks and Croson Convergence model

Heterogeneous Homogeneous No Info Partial

Info Full Info No Info Partial

Info Full Info

Observations Prob > X2*

75 0.0222

75 0.6126

75 0.0337

75 0.2112

75 0.1994

75 0.6712

Constant 178.28 (20.96) 0.000

168.84 (25.99) 0.000

157.01 (16.07) 0.000

145.91 (20.76) 0.000

150.88 (20.62) 0.000

168.21 (13.36) 0.000

Period 6.54 (3.43) 0.057

-0.143 (3.34) 0.966

-0.287 (2.82) 0.919

-1.55 (3.68) 0.673

4.96 (2.75) 0.071

-1.96 (2.19) 0.371

Period2 -0.302 (0.128) 0.019

0.0349 (0.125) 0.779

0.0778 (0.105) 0.460

0.113 (0.137) 0.409

-0.185 (0.103) 0.072

0.071 (0.082) 0.384

X2: ui=0 0.073 0.000 0.401 1.000 0.0000 0.078 Group Totalit = α + β1ti + β2ti

2 + + ui + Єit. Each cell contains the estimated coefficient, standard error and p-value. The Noussair et al. asymptotic model uses the inverse of period to estimate the

asymptotic starting value and (period-1)/period to estimate the asymptotic ending value.

14

Ordinary least squares, a random effects and a fixed effects models were used to estimate

all three of the models. The Hausman (1978) test suggests that there are no significant

differences between the coefficients for the fixed and random effects models. F: ui=0

refers to the p-value for an F test that the errors are equal to zero for the random effects

model. In all but two cases for both of these models (heterogeneous, full info and

homogeneous no info) the random effects model is consistent with the data

Table 6: Asymptotic Convergence Model Heterogeneous Homogeneous No Info Partial

Info Full Info No Info Partial

Info Full Info

Observations Prob > X2*

75 0.0000

75 0.0000

75 0.0000

75 0.0000

75 0.0000

75 0.0000

__1__ Period

172.26 (27.95) 0.000

171.29 (30.81) 0.000

126.73 (21.50) 0.000

107.34 (27.55) 0.000

147.74 (24.76) 0.000

162.47 (17.19) 0.000

(Period-1) Period

201.02 (11.01) 0.000

175.31 (19.31) 0.000

178.35 (6.58) 0.000

158.63 (8.01) 0.000

179.33 (14.87) 0.000

157.71 (6.92) 0.000

X2: ui=0 0.096 0.0000 0.418 1.000 0.000 0.080 Group Totalit = β(1/ti) + B(ti-1)/ti + ui + Єit. Each cell contains the estimated coefficient, standard error and p-value. Overall the convergence results are very robust to the econometric model

employed.8 The regressions with period and period squared suggest that there is only

significant convergence for heterogeneous groups with no information and homogeneous

groups with partial information. The asymptotic convergence model suggests that in all

of the heterogeneous cases the group totals are not converging to the target but are

increasing over time. Figures 3 and 4 plot the predictions with the mean data. Notice

that the combined model is most consistent with the data and suggest that the no

information with heterogeneous payoff functions and the partial information with

8 Indeed the estimates of the coefficients are the same when simple regressions (ignoring the time series of cross sections nature of the data) are conducted.

15

homogeneous payoff functions are converging to the target while the group totals for the

other treatments increase over time.

Table 7: Combined Model Heterogeneous Homogeneous No Info Partial

Info Full Info No Info Partial

Info Full Info

Observations Prob > X2*

75 0.0000

75 0.0000

75 0.0000

75 0.0000

75 0.000

75 0.000

__1__ Period

148.69 (27.76) 0.000

181.30 (31.74) 0.000

133.71 (21.97) 0.000

107.95 (28.27) 0.000

143.67 (25.52) 0.000

160.49 (17.94) 0.000

(Period-1) Period

236.45 (41.87) 0.000

144.33 (44.32) 0.001

202.81 (33.86) 0.000

220.52 (43.72) 0.000

165.05 (36.04) 0.000

183.37 (27.10) 0.000

Period -0.2721 (5.44) 0.960

2.73 (5.37) 0.611

-5.65 (4.47) 0.206

-10.29 (5.79) 0.075

3.30 (4.42) 0.455

-3.74 (3.52) 0.289

Period2 -0.1035 (0.1768)

0.558

-0.0485 (0.1744)

0.781

0.234 (0.145) 0.108

0.367 (0.188) 0.051

-0.136 (0.144) 0.342

0.123 (0.115) 0.283

X2: ui=0 0.065 0.000 0.385 1.00 0.000 0.390 Group Totalit = β1(1/ti) + β2(ti-1)/ti + β3ti + β4ti

2 + ui + Єit. Each cell contains the estimated coefficient, standard error and p-value. *Prob > X2* is the p-value for the joint test that all of the coefficients are equal to zero and X2: un=0 is the test that the mean of the random effect errors are equal to zero. Result 4: Individual decision making varies across treatments and capacity. Recall that equation (3) suggests that there is a unique payoff maximizing

dominant strategy for each of the subject types. This predicts that Large capacity

subjects will choose 50, medium capacity subjects will choose 25 and small capacity

subjects will choose 0. Table 8 reports the mean, standard error and frequency for the

decision number by subject type across information treatment. Notice that the decision

numbers are lower than the payoff maximizing decision number for Large and higher for

the Small capacity subjects in all cases.9

9 Analysis of variance (Appendix Table 3) suggests that the means are significantly different between each of the treatment variables.

16

Table 8: Average Decision by Treatment Subject Type No

Information Partial

Information Full

Information Total

Large 41.67* 2.18 185

41.42* 2.37 218

35.29* 1.57 225

39.29* 1.19 628

Medium 25.13

1.17 450

29.08 1.26 450

26.41 0.674 450

26.87 22.66 1350

Small 30.84*

1.64 225

17.71* 1.29 225

21.53* 1.41 225

23.36* 0.864 675

Total 30.18

0.907 860

29.22 0.961 893

27.41 0.647 900

28.92 0.489 2,653

Each cell contains the mean of subjects decision number, standard error and number of observations. Decisions of subjects who were bankrupt were eliminated. An * indicates that the mean differs from the Nash prediction at the 5% level.

Table 9 presents the median decision numbers by subject type and information. Notice

that the overall (total) medians are 30 for the Large, 23 for the Medium and 19 for the

Small capacity subjects, and that for all of the subject types the median under partial

information are lower than the median whereas the other two cases are higher. This

suggests that for the homogeneous groups subjects choose slightly lower numbers with

less information, while for heterogeneous groups the decision numbers are lower under

partial information but slightly higher under no information.

Tobit regressions run separately by information and subject capacity can be used

to determine whether the decision numbers are significantly different from the payoff

maximizing Nash prediction controlling for both error and the fact that the data is

censored (subjects cannot choose less than zero or greater than their maximum decision

number). Tobit analysis provides estimates of the peak of the distribution of individual

decisiaons and a parameter which can be used to compare the variability of the samples.

17

Anderson, Goeree and Holt (1998) argue that this error parameter represents the degree

of irrationality. The smaller the parameter the less variability there is in the data.

Table 9: Median Decision by Treatment

Subject Type No Information Partial Information

Full Information

Total

Large 33 29.69 185

25 35.00 218

30 23.60 225

30 29.84 628

Medium 20

24.72 450

20 26.82 450

25 14.31 450

23 22.66 1350

Small 25

24.60 225

19 19.36 225

20 21.10 225

19 22.45 675

Total 23

26.61 860

20 28.71 893

25 19.41 900

24 25.21 2,653

Each cell contains the median of subjects decision number, standard deviation and number of observations. Decisions of subjects who were bankrupt have been eliminated.

Table 10 presents the results of a Tobit estimation (Green 1993).10 The estimated

peak of the decision distribution is not significantly different from the payoff maximizing

decision for the Large and Small Capacity subjects under Partial Information, and the

Medium Capacity subjects under all information conditions. We also observe differences

in the estimated peaks of the distributions compared to the means. For the medium

capacity subjects the peak is higher under partial information and lower under no

information relative to the full information treatment. For Large Capacity subjects the

estimated peak is higher for both the no and partial information conditions and for the

Small Capacity subjects the peak is highest under no information and lowest under partial

10 White’s (1980, 1982) robust variance estimate was used as standard errors for the random effects model could not be estimated in a number of cases. However, the coefficients are very similar between the standard Tobit as well as the random effects Tobit.

18

information. There are also differences in the estimated error parameter. For the

Medium Capacity subjects having less information seems to complicate the environment

leading to more error in the decision process in both cases. For the Small Capacity

subjects the error is very consistent across the three treatments while for the Large

Capacity subjects the error is higher for both the no and partial information conditions,

but it is much higher for the partial information condition. Also notice that the standard

errors for the estimated coefficients are much higher than the other standard errors under

partial information under all of the information conditions.

Table 10: Robust Tobit Estimates of Individual Decisions by Type and Information.

Large Capacity Medium Capacity Small Capacity No Partial Full No Partial Full No Partial Full

Obs. 185 218 225 450 450 450 225 225 225

Constant 41.28* (2.30)

41.41 (9.03)

35.17*

(3.29) 22.60 (1.63)

27.88 (2.98)

26.27 (1.25)

31.24* (5.74)

11.84 (8.54)

18.99*

(2.13)

Error 31.06 (2.00)

37.47 (6.20)

24.22 (2.41)

28.99 (2.53)

29.24 (3.05)

14.73 (2.30)

26.92 (4.45)

26.93 (7.77)

24.95 (7.76)

Each cell contains the estimated coefficient, standard error and p-value. An * indicates that the estimate is significantly different from the Nash prediction at the 5% level.

The distributions of individual decisions are presented in Figure 5 for large

capacity subjects, Figure 6 for small capacity subjects and Figure 7 for medium capacity

subjects. For the Large Capacity subjects notice that decisions seem more variable for no

information with more decision below twenty-five for partial information. This is also

true for the Small Capacity subjects’ decisions are much more variable under no

information and much lower under partial information. The results are opposite for the

Medium Capacity subjects, Decisions are lower under no information and more variable

19

under partial information.11 This seems to suggest that less information results in greater

rates of subjects reducing their decision numbers by more than the optimal amount. This

may be due at least in part to loss aversion in that choosing lower numbers should result

in a lower group total and less chance of being fined. But again notice the different

effects of the information treatment on subjects with homogeneous and heterogeneous

payoff functions.

Result 5: Convergence in Individual Decisions.

The next question is, are the decision numbers converging towards the Nash

decision over time. Table 11 presents the combined convergence model estimated by

subject type and information on the individual decisions. Again, the regressions were

conducted using the standard Tobit, the robust Tobit and a random effects model. The

results from the standard model are presented although again all of the estimates were

very similar.12 The asymptotic convergence regressions suggest that individual decisions

converge towards the Nash predictions except for both the Large Small capacity subjects

under no information. The Large capacity subjects decisions are decreasing towards zero

while the Small Capacity subjects decisions are increasing. Figures 8 through 10 show

the time series of individual decisions for each of the subject types and information

conditions are consistent with this conclusion.

This result is concerning as it results in the Larger Capacity subjects who are

reducing their decision numbers below the optimal level to experience more bankruptcies

(Table 12, and the number of non-bankruptcy observations for Large capacity subjects

(185 for No and 218 for Partial Information)).

11 Notice that there does not seem to be any significant piling up of decisions at the target divided by 12, 6, 4, or 3 under no information for any of the subject capacities. 12 The standard errors for the random effects model could not be calculated in a number of cases.

20

Table 11: Asymptotic Convergence for Individual Decisions

Large Capacity Medium Capacity Small Capacity No Partial Full No Partial Full No Partial Full

Obs. 185 218 225 450 450 450 225 225 225

__1__ Period

22.22 (9.55) 0.020

42.59 (11.19) 0.000

19.70 (7.09) 0.005

18.15 (6.18) 0.003

22.65 (6.30)

(0.000)

26.61 (3.16) 0.000

24.06 (8.13) 0.003

16.19 (8.20) 0.048

24.53 (7.65) 0.001

(Period-1) Period

41.24 (15.27) 0.007

4.07 (17.45) 0.816

35.87 (10.97) 0.001

36.58 (9.68) 0.000

26.10 (9.75) 0.007

30.63 (4.88) 0.000

37.56 (12.68) 0.003

46.93 (12.73) 0.000

30.62 (11.82) 0.010

Period 0.779 (2.10) 0.711

3.80 (2.32) 0.101

-0.573 (1.45) 0.693

-2.00 (1.29) 0.118

0.731 (1.29) 0.572

-0.647 (0.647) 0.317

-0.88 (1.68) 0.600

-4.49 (1.70) 0.008

-1.50 (1.57) 0.339

Period2 -0.313 (0.071) 0.657

-0.080 (0.076) 0.290

0.0418 (0.047) 0.377

0.068 (0.042) 0.106

-0.033 (0.042) 0.439

0.021 (0.021) 0.316

0.033 (0.055) 0.552

0.126 (0.056) 0.023

0.040 (0.051) 0.437

Decisiont = β1(1/ti) + β2(ti-1)/ti + β3ti + β4ti2 + ui + Єit.. Each cell contains the estimated coefficient,

standard error and p-value.

Table 12: Bankruptcies by Session

Information No Info Partial Info Full Info Total

Heterogeneous 40 450

7 450

0 450

47 1350

Homogeneous 0

450 0

450 0

450 0

1350

Total 40 900

7 900

0 900

47 270000

Each cell contains the number of subject decision periods where subjects were bankrupt for each treatment, and the total number of subject decision periods.

A second place that this inequality shows up is in the final or cumulative payoffs.

Table 13 presents these cumulative payoffs by information subject capacity and

information. Notice that under the No Information condition, the medium capacity

subjects make more profits than both the Large and the Small capacity subjects, while in

the other two cases the Small capacity subjects make the highest payoffs at the expense

21

of the Large capacity subjects. This coupled with the observation that small capacity

subjects are much more likely to choose the Nash equilibrium decision (0) under partial

information is an interesting result. When heterogeneous subjects have no information

they seem to play more randomly, when they know the number of people in their group

(but nothing about payoffs) all subjects seem to be more risk averse (choosing much

lower decisions and indeed the Nash decision in the small capacity subjects case).

Whereas, homogeneous subjects seem to be more risk averse under the No information

treatment and play more randomly in the partial information condition.

Table 13 Cumulative Payoffs (in Lab Dollars) by Session Subject Type No Information Partial

Information Full

Information Total

Large 244.00 162.71

5

327.34 161.45

8

291.40 130.32

9

293.70 145.68

22

Medium 558.26 119.54

18

403.86 206.58

18

530.69 82.39

18

497.61 158.29

54

Small 397.69 122.00

9

507.01 250.04

9

556.38 108.26

9

487.03 178.85

27

Total 464.00 171.28

32

412.90 213.36

35

477.29 147.71

36

451.28 179.92

103 Each cell contains the mean cumulative payoff, standard deviation and number of observations.

22

Conclusions Information has no effect on the aggregate decision number in a controlled

laboratory moral hazard in group experiment. This suggests that an environmental

regulator could use tax/subsidy instruments for the control of non-point source pollution

without being concerned with how much information the participants had about each

other. There are, however, effects of information on individual decision making. For

subjects with heterogeneous payoff functions, partial information (knowing the number

of subjects in the group but not their payoffs) results in subjects being more risk averse

(playing lower decision numbers to avoid being fined), while having No information

results in heterogeneous subjects playing more randomly. The reverse is true for

Homogeneous subjects. They seem to be more risk averse under No information and

play more randomly under Partial information. This is consistent with previous

experimental results and goes a step towards providing an explanation for the observed

differences in outcome.

The policy implication of this is that it is important that participants in an

Exogenous Targeting Instrument regime must be fully informed of how they are expected

to behave and the consequences from deviating from this behaviour. Moreover, steps

must be taken to ensure that firms are unable to use these instruments in order to impose

significant monetary costs on their competitors by not complying when their competitors

choose to do so.

23

Appendix A- Supplemental Tables Table 1: Median Group Total by Treatment

Information No Info Partial Info Full Info Total

Heterogeneous 191 21.11

3

152 39.89

3

155 11.47

3

164 26.27

9

Homogeneous 144 13.78

3

162 30.59

3

149 13.34

3

148 20.82

9

Total 157 29.68

6

157 31.79

6

152 12.93

6

153.5 25.06

18 Each cell contains median of medians, standard deviation and frequency Table 2: Analysis of Variance, Median Group Total Number of obs =18 R-squared = 0.4090 Root MSE =23.93 Adj R-squared = 0.1627 Source Partial SS Df MS F Prob >F Model 4756.44 5 951.29 1.66 0.2184 Information 872.44 2 436.22 0.76 0.4883 Homogeneity 1283.56 1 1283.56 2.24 0.1603 Info*Hom 2600.44 2 1300.22 2.27 0.1459 Residual 6874.00 12 572.83 Total 11630.44 17 684.14

24

Table 3: Analysis of Variance, Decision Number of obs =2653 R-squared = 0.0736 Root MSE =24.30 Adj R-squared = 0.0708 Source Partial SS Df MS F Prob >F Model 124011 8 15501.42 26.25 0.0000 Information 9186.04 2 4593.02 7.78 0.0004 Subject Type 95791.08 2 47895.54 81.11 0.0000 Info*Type 25134.27 4 6283.57 10.64 0.0000 Residual 1561338.33 2644 590.52 Total 1685349.69 2652 635.50

25

Figure 1: Average Group Totals by Treatment and Period.

period

HetNoTot HetPartTot HetFullTot

0 10 20 30

0

200

400

600

26

Figure 2: Average Group Totals by Treatment and Period.

period

HomNoTot HomPartTot HomFullTot

0 10 20 30

0

200

400

600

27

Figure 3: Convergence Prediction Results, Heterogeneous Groups.

Group Totals, Partial Information, Heterogeneous Subjects

100

120

140

160

180

200

220

240

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25

Decision

Gro

up

To

tal

Mean Marks and Croson Asymptotic Full Model

Group Totals Full Info, Heterogeneous Agents

0

50

100

150

200

250

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25

Decision

Gro

up

To

tal

Mean Marks and Croson Asymptotic Full Model

Group Tota ls , No In format ion , Heterogeneous Subjects

100

150

200

250

300

350

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 0 11 1 2 1 3 1 4 1 5 1 6 1 7 1 8 1 9 20 21 22 23 24 25

D e c i s i o n

Mean Marks and Croson Asymptotic Full Model

28

Figure 4: Convergence Prediction Results, Homogeneous Groups.

Group Totals, No Info, Homogeneous Subjects

0

50

100

150

200

250

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25

Decision

Gro

up

To

tal

Mean Marks and Croson Asymptotic Full Model

Group Totals, Partial Information, Homogeneous Subjects

0

50

100

150

200

250

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25

Decision

Gro

up

To

tal

Mean Marks and Croson Asymptotic Full Model

Group Totals, Full Info, Homogeneous Subjects

0

50

100

150

200

250

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25

Decision

Gro

up

To

tal

Mean Marks and Croson Asymptotic Full Model

29

Figure 5: Distributions of Individual Decisions for Large Capacity Subjects, by Information. No Information

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115 120 125

Decision

Fre

qu

ency

Partial Information

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115 120 125

Decision

Fre

qu

ency

Full Information

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115 120 125

Decision

Fre

qu

ency

30

Figure 6: Distributions of Individual Decisions for Small Capacity Subjects, by Information. No Information

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75

Decision

Fre

qu

ency

Partial Information

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75

Decision

Fre

qu

ency

Full Information

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75

Decision

Fre

qu

ency

31

Figure 7: Distributions of Individual Decisions for Medium Capacity Subjects, by Information.

No Information

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Decision

Fre

qu

ency

Partial Information

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Decision

Fre

qu

ency

Full Information

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Decision

Fre

qu

ency

32

Figure 8: Average Decision N umber for Large Capacity Subjects by Period and Treatment.

period

Large, No Info Large, Partial Info Large, Full Info

0 10 20 30

0

50

100

150

33

Figure 9: Average Decision Number for Small Capacity Subjects by Period and Treatment.

period

Small, No Info Small, Partial Info Small, Full Info

0 10 20 30

0

20

40

60

80

34

Figure 10: Average Decision Number for Medium Capacity Subjects by Period and Treatment.

period

Medium, No Info Medium, Partial Info Medium, Full Info

0 10 20 30

0

50

100

35

References Anderson, Simon, Jacob Goeree, and Charles Holt, 1998. “A Theoretical Analysis of Altruism and Decision Error in Public Goods Games.” Journal of Public Economics, 70 (2), 297-323. Andreoni, James, 1995. “Warm Glow versus Cold-Prickle: The Effects of Positive and Negative Framing on cooperation Experiment”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 1-22. Cochard, François, Marc Willinger and Anastasios Xepapadeas, 2002. “Efficiency of Nonpoint Source Pollution Instruments with Externality among Polluters: An Experimental Study.” Université Louis Pasteur, BETA manuscript. Goeree, Jacob, K., Charles A. Holt and Susan K. Laury, 2002. “Private costs and public benefits: unravelling the effects of altruism and noisy behaviour.” Journal of Public Economics, 83, 255-276. Greene, William H., 1993. Econometric Analysis, Second Edition, Prentice-Hall, Inc. Hausman, J., 1978. “Specification Tests in Econometrics.” Econometrica, 49, 1251-1271. Holmstrom, B., 1982. “Moral Hazard in Teams.” Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 324-340. Ledyard, John O., 1995. “Public Goods: A Survey of Experimental Research.” The Handbook of Experimental Economics, eds. John Kagel and Alvin Roth, (Princeton University Press: Princeton NJ). Malik, Arun, 1990. “Markets for Pollution Control when firms are Noncompliant.” Journal of Environmental Economic Management, 18, 97-106. Marks, Melanie B. and Rachel T.A. Croson, 1999. “The effect of incomplete information in a threshold public goods experiment.” Public Choice, 99, 103-118. McAfee, P. R., and J. McMilan, 1991. “Optimal contracts for teams.” International Economic Review, 32(3), 561-576. Moir, Robert, and John Spraggon, 2001. “The Nash Equilibrium and Disequilibrium Effects: Cooperation is easier when there is more elbow room.” University of New Brunswick, St. John, Department of Economics, manuscript. Nalbantian, Haig and Andrew Schotter, 1997. “Productivity Under Group Incentives: An Experimental Study.” American Economic Review, June 1997, 87, 314-41

36

Noussair, C.N., Plott, C.R., and R.G., Riezman, 1995. “An Experimental Investigation of the Patterns of International Trade.” American Economic Review, 85, 462-491. Park, Eun-Soo, 2001. “Warm-Glow versus Cold-Prickle: A Further Experimental Study of Framing E_ects on Free-Riding.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 43, 4, 405-421. Rondeau, Daniel, William D. Schulze and Gregory L. Poe, 1999. “Voluntary revelation of the demand for public goods using a provision point mechanism.” Journal of Public Economics, 72, 455-470. Rose, Steven K., Jeremy Clark, Gregory L. Poe, Daniel Rondeau and William D. Schulze, 2002. “The private provision of public goods: tests of a provision point mechanism for funding green power programs.” Resource and Energy Economics, 24, 131-151. Segerson, Kathleen, 1988. “Uncertainty and incentives for nonpoint pollution control.” Journal of Environmental Economic Management, 15, 87-98. Shortle, James S. and Richard D. Hoarn, 2001. “The Economics of Nonpoint Pollution Control.” Journal of Economic Surveys, 15,3, 255-289. Sonnemans, Joep, Arthur Schram., and Theo Offerman, 1998. “Public Good Provision and Public Bad Prevention: The Effect of Framing.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 34, 143-161 Spraggon, John, 2002. “Exogenous Targeting Instruments as a Solution to Group Moral Hazard. Journal of Public Economics, 84, 3, 427-456. Spraggon, John, 2001a. “Exogenous Targeting Instruments with Heterogeneous Agents.” Lakehead University, Department of Economics Manuscript. Spraggon, John, 2001b. “Individual Decision Making in Exogenous Targeting Instrument Experiments.” Lakehead University, Department of Economics, manuscript. StatCorp. 2001. Stata Statistical Software: Release 7.0. College Station, TX: Stata Corporation. Vossler, Christian A, Gregory L. Poe, Kathy Segerson, and William D. Schulze, 2002. “An Experimental Test of Segerson’s Mechanism for Nonpoint Source Pollution Control.” Cornell University, Department of Economics Manuscript. White, Halbert, 1980. “A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity.” Econometrica, 48, 4, 817-838.

37

Xepapadeas, A. P., 1992. “Environmental Policy Design and Dynamic Nonpoint-Source Pollution.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 22, 22-39. Xepapadeas, A. P., 1995. “Observability and choice of instrument mix in the control of externalities” Journal of Public Economics, 56, 485-498.