excerpt from thailand political peasants by andrew walker

Upload: jlwilliamsjr

Post on 04-Jun-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/13/2019 Excerpt From Thailand Political Peasants by Andrew Walker

    1/3

    Excerpt from Thai land Poli tical Peasants by Andrew Walker

    Four interrelated transformations have created a new environment for political action (in

    Thailand)

    First, peasants in Thailand are, for the most part, no longer poor. They are now middle-

    income peasants. They are not necessarily well-off, nor do they enjoy the consumer comfortsof the urban middle class, but dramatic improvements in the rural standard of living have

    raised most of them well above the water level of outright livelihood failure. In most areas of

    rural Thailand, the primary livelihood challenges have moved away from the classic low-

    income challenges of food security and subsistence survival to the middle-income challenges

    of diversification and productivity improvement.

    Second, Thailand's middle-income peasants have a diversified economy. Subsistence

    cultivation is now only a modest component of agricultural activity. There has been a

    dramatic increase in cash crop production for local and international markets. Even more

    important is the fact that nonagricultural sources of income have proliferated and they are

    now more significant than farming for a great many rural households. Only about one in five

    peasant households rely solely on agricultural income. Agriculture is still important, but

    peasant livelihoods are no longer predominantly agricultural livelihoods. Peasants are no

    longer just farmers.

    Third, peasants in Thailand confront a new form of economic disparity. Thailand has been

    remarkably successful in tackling absolute poverty, but its performance on relative poverty

    (inequality) has been much worse. This inequality is not the product of surplus extraction by

    dominating elites; it is a product of uneven economic development. Disparity is caused by the

    relatively low productivity of the rural economy, especially the agricultural sector. Incomes

    in rural areas have certainly improved, but not as fast as incomes in other parts of theeconomy. In this context, the political challenge for middle-income peasants is not to avoid

    subsistence-disrupting extractions but to attract productivity-enhancing inputs.

    Fourth, the Thai state now plays a central role in supporting the peasant economy . As

    countries develop, their governments often try to address economic disparity by subsidizing

    the rural economy. The Thai government has enthusiastically taken up this challenge,

    especially since the mid-1970s. Recognizing the implications of this fiscal shift requires a

    radical conceptual reorientation. The peasantry has conventionally been defined in terms of

    its subordinate relationship with external power. An enormous amount of scholarly attention

    has been placed on the political tussle between state extraction and local resistance. However,

    in Thailand a new relationship has developed between the state and the rural economy,characterized not by taxation but by subsidy. Thaksin Shinawatra's government epitomized

    this new arrangement, but it did not create it: Thaksin's rural populism was the product of a

    long-term shift in the structural dynamics of Thailand's political economy. The contemporary

  • 8/13/2019 Excerpt From Thailand Political Peasants by Andrew Walker

    2/3

    moral reckoning of the middle-income peasant is not concerned with limiting the state's

    impositions but with maximizing its largesse

    POWER IN RURAL THAILAND

    Studies of power relations in rural Thailand have emphasized three different dimensions: (1)

    vertical linkages between people of different social status, (2) horizontal class or community

    solidarities, and (3) dispersed networks of power and potency. The first two approaches tell

    us a lot about the politics, or lack of it, of Thailand's poor peasantryand they provide some

    useful insights into recent political developmentsbut they struggle to account for the

    ambitions and strategies of the new middle-income peasantry. The third, though seemingly

    somewhat tangential in its attention to supernatural affairs, points in some useful new

    directions.

    Vertical L inkages

    During the 1960s and early 1970s, discussions of politics in rural Thailand were dominated

    by the patron-client model. American anthropological research, much of it conducted in the

    village of Bang Chan on the outskirts of Bangkok, played a crucial role in introducing thisidea to Thai studies. In two influential articles, Lucien M. Hanks, one of the principle

    researchers at Bang Chan, argued that social hierarchies in Thailand were based on the

    differential accumulation of Buddhist merit and, secondarily, inequalities in power and

    material resources.7These pervasive hierarchies provided a framework for the development

    of reciprocal relationships in which those of higher status provided protection and other

    benefits to those below them in return for tribute, loyalty, and personal service. Patron-client

    ties extended from the poor peasant household to the king himself, organizing Thai society

    into numerous overlapping entourages that cut across status divisions. Within these

    entourages, relations between patrons and clients were multistranded, drawing together

    economic, social, religious, and legal connections. Yet, despite this intertwining of roles,

    patron-client relationships were flexible, both because of movement up and down thehierarchy as merit and status were accumulated and lost and because the relationships were

    easily terminated if they failed to satisfy either party. The system has the familiar shape of

    Adam Smith's free enterprise, a major study of Bang Chan pointed out, as each person

    bargains in the open market for the best arrangement he can make, and if this is not

    satisfactory, he may move elsewhere.

    In the Cold War context of communist rebellion in Indochina, the idea that the gap between

    rich and poor in Thailand was mediated by amiable and flexible relations of patronage was

    reassuring to Thailand's powerful backers. The American government, which was pouring aid

    and counterinsurgency funds into Thailand, hoped that its investments would create an

    effective bulwark against communism. American social science provided the perfectrationale, portraying Thailand as a country where a peasant uprising was unlikely due to the

    lack of horizontal classlike affiliations: There are no publics, no masses, nor even a

    proletariat; instead of these, segments of the population are provided for more or less

    adequately according to the circle of their affiliation. In a study of peasant personality in

    Bang Chan, Herbert P. Phillips found that there was a strong emphasis on the munificence,

    security and benevolence of the authority figure. This political outlook contributed to a

    placid community characterized by gentleness, affability, and politeness in most face-

    to-face relationships. Writing about the 1957 national election, Phillips argued that those

    who voted for the prime minister did so because he is our Master. He has been very good

    and kind to us. He is like our father, and we are like his children. A similar study in the

    remote northeast of Thailand by Stephen B. Young described a non-participatorydemocracy based on peasant expectations that their involvement with government should be

    minimal, powerful people should be obeyed, and duties were unquestioned obligations

    imposed by the conditions of life.

    http://www.readability.com/articles/xfbbiecehttp://www.readability.com/articles/xfbbiecehttp://www.readability.com/articles/xfbbiecehttp://www.readability.com/articles/xfbbiece
  • 8/13/2019 Excerpt From Thailand Political Peasants by Andrew Walker

    3/3

    Given the apparent passivity and disengagement of the peasantry, the search was on for local

    luminaries who could provide political leadership and form a vanguard for rural

    advancement. Likely candidates included village headmen, monks, teachers, health workers,

    irrigation group leaders, crop traders, rich landowners, and merchants. Based on research in

    three northern Thai villages, the political scientist Clark D. Neher proposed that village

    leaders operated as a bridge between the great masses of villagers and the minority group of

    authorities. These leaders comprised a narrow political stratum that was actively involved

    in dealings with government officials and in implementing development projects. They stoodin contrast to the apoliticals who comprised the vast majority of rural households for whom

    the political system bears no meaningful relationship to daily activities. These apolitical

    villagers expressed their needs not on the basis of their own livelihood challenges but

    according to the specific development agenda of the village leadership. In another important

    study from northern Thailand, Michael Moerman suggested that village headmen were

    synaptic leaders who managed transactions between villagers and the national bureaucracy

    and, perhaps even more important, prevented state officials from meddling in village affairs.

    Although the role of local leaders has continued to be a core preoccupation of studies of rural

    politics in Thailand, in the 1980s and 1990s the reputation of such leaders shifted sharply. In

    a national economy experiencing extraordinarily rapid economic growth, accounts of

    benevolent patrons and village notables pursuing rural improvement were pushed aside by

    more confronting profiles of godfathers (jaw pho) who used charisma, money, and strong-

    arm tactics to create local and provincial fiefdoms. These godfathers embodied an unpleasant

    combination of business and politics. They used money from provincial enterprises, many of

    them illegal, to mobilize electoral support, and they used the power of political office to

    convert public resources into private wealth. In this context, a new paradigm emerged to

    explain the political behavior of the peasantry: vote buying. The exchange of votes for money

    was said to be coordinated by provincial power brokers and implemented by teams of cashed-

    up canvassers who operated at the district and village levels. In studies of political behavior

    this electoral corruption was described as a typically rural phenomenon, arising out ofpoverty, parochialism, low levels of education, and a lack of civic morality. Whereas

    members of the urban middle class made political decisions on the basis of policies and

    public interest, gullible and grateful voters in the countryside were readily persuaded to

    exchange their votes for cash, development projects, or protection. This division in political

    culture was famously described by the political scientist Anek Laothamatas as a tale of two

    democracies that could only be united when rural development transformed patronage-

    ridden villages into small towns of middle-class farmers or well-paid workers.Most studies

    of modern patronage and vote buying describe the political influence of local leaders in

    morally negative terms, although some have pointed out that provincial godfathers emerged

    out of a quite specific cultural milieu and often derived legitimacy from old-style idioms of

    patronage, generosity, and local identity. Some accounts pointed out that vote buying itselfwas embedded in local systems of evaluation and exchange, belatedly granting the

    beleaguered peasant a modicum of agency within the overarching patron-client framework.