emu-risk synchronisation and financial fragility through...

34
Portsmouth Business School http://www.port.ac.uk/portsmouth-business-school/ Working Papers in Economics & Finance 2019-07 EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through the Prism of Dynamic Connectedness Ioannis Chatziantoniou, Portsmouth Business School David Gabauer, Webster Vienna Private University & Johannes Kepler University

Upload: others

Post on 21-Sep-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

Portsmouth Business School http://www.port.ac.uk/portsmouth-business-school/

Working Papers in Economics & Finance

2019-07

EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through the Prism of Dynamic Connectedness

Ioannis Chatziantoniou, Portsmouth Business School

David Gabauer, Webster Vienna Private University & Johannes Kepler University

Page 2: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

EMU Risk-Synchronisation and Financial Fragility

Through the Prism of Dynamic Connectedness

Ioannis Chatziantoniou† and David Gabauer‡,§

†Economics and Finance Subject Group, University of Portsmouth, Portsmouth Business School, Portland Street,

Portsmouth, PO1 3DE, United Kingdom.

‡Institute of Applied Statistics, Johannes Kepler University, Altenbergerstraße 69, 4040 Linz, United Kingdom.

§Department of Business and Management, Webster Vienna Private University, Praterstraße 23, 1020 Vienna, Austria.

Abstract

This study employs dynamic connectedness as a measure of financial risk synchro-

nization considering government bond yields in 11 EMU member states. In partic-

ular, large values of the relevant index can be an indication of comparable levels of

risk further implying that the common currency area consists of a financially sensi-

ble set of countries. By contrast, small connectedness values can be an indication of

fragmentation whereupon certain countries are considered to be safer than others.

The latter would be detrimental for the EMU as it fuels financial fragility, which

practically stipulates that crises occur as a result of self-fulfilling market fears. The

results are based on a daily dataset which spans between 1st September 2003 and

31st August 2018. Findings show that fragmentation was present at the height of

the European sovereign debt crisis and that the interconnectedness has not yet re-

verted to its pre-2009 levels. In addition, core countries appear to transmit shocks

to periphery countries although, occasionally, there are noteworthy disparities. Fur-

ther investigating these disparities on a pairwise connectedness level – which helps

to identify sensible pairs of countries in terms of financial risk – shows that core

countries dominate this exercise, with the exception of the bilateral relation between

Italy and Spain. The fact that most periphery countries of our sample are not in-

cluded in these pairs raises concerns and calls for a more substantial integration.

Keywords: OCA; ERM II; EMU; Fragmentation; Fragility Hypothesis.

JEL codes: C32; C50; F15; F33; F36; F45.

Page 3: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

1 Introduction

Ever since the days of the Treaty that enacted the European Coal and Steel Community

(ECSC ) in the 1950s, European countries have actively sought ways to collaborate ef-

fectively within an environment that promoted lasting peace and prosperity. A common

market that allowed free movement of certain products was regarded at the time as a

crucial factor for closer partnership and stronger economic development. These e↵orts

further intensified in the years that followed and culminated with the Maastricht Treaty

in 1991 and the establishment of the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU ). The Euro

was o�cially introduced in January 2002 and at the time of writing, the common cur-

rency area counts 19 member states. In the light of these developments and in view of

further expansion of the EMU, researchers, politicians and economic agents have been

very keen on revisiting the Optimal Currency Area (OCA) requisite conditions (Mundell,

1961; McKinnon, 1963) in order to assess the extent of integration among partners and

to identify potential sources of financial turbulence.

Unequivocally, integration issues gained much prominence in the light of the recent

European debt crisis (2010), when European authorities had to develop economic ad-

justment programmes for a number of economies of the European South. The Stability

and Growth Pact (SGP) that was initially introduced in the late 1990s to promote fiscal

synchronisation across EMU member states proved to be insu�cient to prevent the said

crisis. What is more, authorities had to lift the ’no bailout ’ clause of the Lisbon Treaty

and the European Central Bank (ECB) had to act as a lender of last resort for escalating

turbulence to eventually ease o↵. Subsequently, the capacity of EMU to act as an OCA

has been under heavy criticism since, while at the same time, the importance of further

economic and political integration has also been brought to the fore.

The poor performance of the EMU as an OCA has been thoroughly discussed by au-

thors such as O’Rourke and Taylor (2013), Eichengreen (2014), as well as De Grauwe

(2016). Some of the topics that recur regarding the discussion around OCAs and the

European sovereign debt crisis include, among others, the sudden stop of increased cap-

ital flows from the core to the periphery (i.e., following the rise of market uncertainty

and doubts regarding the sustainability of this model), the excessive current account im-

1

Page 4: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

balances across countries, the necessity of a banking union and a common supervisor

to oversee the financial system, ECB’s role as a lender of last resort, mechanisms for re-

structuring national debt when the latter is practically unsustainable, both obstacles (e.g.,

acknowledgement of skills obtained abroad) and consequences (e.g., brain-drain) of labour

mobility, as well as, a clear path towards the fiscal and political union. In turn, this study

focuses on market uncertainty and perceived risk by investors. We strongly believe that

the future prospect of an OCA is closely related to market expectations in connection

with financial risk and that reassuring markets that EMU economies are progressively

integrating would help avert future crises.

In this regard, our study is primarily concerned with the extent of sovereign bond

yield convergence across the Euro Area. It should be noted at this point though, that

methodologically, our paper deviates from standard empirical approaches employed in

the relevant literature (see, inter alia, Antonakakis et al., 2017; Ehrmann and Fratzscher,

2017; Reboredo and Ugolini, 2015; Caporin et al., 2018). As we further discuss below, we

focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014) and further introduce

refined measures of the latter. In this regard, our method investigates a rather crucial

topic from a di↵erent angle, considering bond-synchronisation as an indicator of financial

risk convergence within the EMU.

What is more, our paper is a good fit of the literature that investigates spillovers across

EMU sovereign debt and further purports to explore how decision making within the EMU

a↵ects financial risk. There is a wealth of literature that investigates government bond

convergence (i.e., studies that mainly utilise yields, spreads or credit default swaps on

sovereign debt). Indicatively we quote Christiansen (2014), Falagiarda and Reitz (2015),

Reboredo and Ugolini (2015), Bhatt et al. (2017), Ehrmann and Fratzscher (2017), as well

as, Afonso et al. (2018) among others. The general consensus that emerges from these

studies is that prior to the sovereign debt crisis of 2010 there was increased convergence

of bond yields across the Euro Area, which deteriorated at the onset of the crisis. At the

same time, ECB’s intervention in the summer of 2012 was paramount in restoring (i.e., to

a great extent) confidence in the markets, thereby facilitating the convergence of financial

risk across EMU member states.

2

Page 5: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

Another related strand of the literature utilises findings relating to financial risk con-

vergence in order to propose some insightful clustering (i.e., convergence groups) of the

countries involved. According to Antonakakis et al. (2017) identifying convergence clubs

is important as it allows for investigating the long run common trend of EMU member

states, as opposed to limiting the analysis to the customary core versus periphery ap-

proach. On a parallel note, authors such as Basse (2014) investigate whether the very

composition of core and periphery countries remains fixed over time and especially in the

light of developments in the sovereign bond market. Interestingly enough, in most cases

the resulting classification will deviate from the customary distinction. Our study fur-

ther utilises results pertaining to dynamic pairwise connectedness to further investigate

convergence groups within our sample.

Finally, our study is also related to the work of authors such as De Grauwe (2013),

De Grauwe and Ji (2013), as well as, Saka et al. (2015) who emphasise that changes

in the perception of risk revolving around sovereign debt could be put down to self-

fulfilling dynamics in the sense that, the decoupling of yields (or of spreads, etc.) might

be indicative of decoupling of macroeconomic fundamentals (i.e., the Eurozone fragility

hypothesis). Within the framework of our analysis potential decoupling of connectedness

across EMU member states would be detrimental for the future of the Euro Area as it

could potentially fuel a new series of financial crises.

With these in mind, the objective of this study is threefold. First, we investigate

patterns of connectedness across countries throughout the period of analysis in order to

elucidate issues pertaining to risk synchronisation and fragmentation. Second, we shed

light into specific events that inject uncertainty into the market and discuss the corre-

sponding responses by member states, distinguishing countries into net transmitters and

net receivers of shocks. Third, on the basis of pairwise connectedness, we identify pairs

that would potentially constitute sensible candidates for a monetary union. It should be

noted that, in close relation to this discussion, the European Commission (2017) has re-

cently issued a White Paper on the Future of Europe investigating various future scenarios

and whether (and how far) integration should go beyond the Single Market. We strongly

believe that our framework of analysis, which assesses financial risk synchronisation across

3

Page 6: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

member states, allows for an explicit answer on whether countries should do less together,

or more.

To this end, we utilize daily data on sovereign bond yields for a period spanning from

1st September 2003 to 31st August 2018. We collect data on 6 core and 5 periphery

EMU countries; namely, Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, the Netherlands,

Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain. In turn, we obtain results from a time-varying

parameters vector autoregression (TVP-VAR) based dynamic connectedness approach

(Antonakakis and Gabauer, 2017; Korobilis and Yilmaz, 2018) which practically consti-

tutes a refined version of the rolling-window VAR based dynamic connectedness approach

of Diebold and Yılmaz (2014)1.

This specific framework of analysis allows for two main contributions. The first one

relates to the employment of connectedness as a measure of financial risk coordination.

To the best of our knowledge this is an angle that has not been investigated by existing

literature. The second contribution relates to the investigation of financial risk coordi-

nation by utilizing an empirical method which refines typical measurement-deficiencies

of the standard rolling windows approach such as (i) the arbitrary choice of the forecast

horizon and the window length, (ii) the distorting e↵ect of outliers that are inevitably

included, as well as (iii), the subsequent loss of observations as we move across windows.

Main findings indicate that interconnectedness across EMU member states is much

stronger prior to 2009. In addition, there is strong evidence of fragmentation at the

height of the crisis, while, in the post-2012 period interconnectedness intensifies without

reverting though to its initial pre-2009 levels. Furthermore, net pairwise connectedness

results indicate that the core transmits shocks to the periphery; however, there are sharp

contrasts among core countries, while, the net transmission results are also highly event-

dependent. In order to shed additional light to the inherent disparities in the transmission

of connectedness across EMU countries we proceed with a classification of pairs of coun-

1The estimation procedure relies on a generalised connectedness framework whereby, contrary to theorthogonalised connectedness approach, results are invariant of the variable ordering. We further opine,that an orthogonalised framework of analysis would be inappropriate in this study, given that thereappears to be no underlying theoretical framework that describes structural relationships among dailybond yields. In this regard, in line with the existing seminal literature on connectedness (Diebold andYılmaz, 2009, 2012, 2014), we are referring to spillover ”shocks”; however, it should be noted, thatthese shocks are not similar to the structural macroeconomic shocks that we encounter in the relevantmacroeconomic literature.

4

Page 7: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

tries by virtue of financial risk coordination. We find that core countries are clearly better

candidates for participating in a common currency area. Findings have obvious policy

implications in connection with the role of the ECB, the development of institutions, in-

ternal capacity and financial fragility in EMU, as well as, the extent of European economic

and political integration.

The remainder of this study is organised as follows: Section 2 presents information

with regard to the employed data and empirical methods. Then, Section 3 proceeds with

the exposition and interpretation of the relevant findings. Section 5 concludes the study.

2 Data and Methods

2.1 Summary Statistics

This study is based on a daily dataset which consists of 11 core and periphery EMU

sovereign bond yields retrieved from Datastream. The sample countries can be split up in

6 core countries, Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany and the Netherlands and in

5 periphery EMU countries, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain. Our data spans

over the period from 1st September 2003 to 31st August 2018.

Figure 1 illustrates the relevant sovereign bond yields. Notably, strong co-movement

is evident in the pre-2009 period and particularly before the onset of the Global Financial

Crisis. From that point on, we note that government bond yields exhibit disparate move-

ments which diverge significantly until the European governmental debt crisis (2010).

Focusing on Greece, another divergence pattern can be observed in the beginning of 2015.

Note that Greece entering a third economic adjustment programme in 2015 strengthened

bond convergence with other EMU member states. Since government bond yields are

considered to be unit root processes according to the unit root test statistics proposed by

Stock et al. (1996), we can analyze the first di↵erenced series, yit = xit � xit�1. This is

shown in Figure 2.

[Insert Figures 1 and 2 around here]

In turn, as can be seen in Table 1, all means and medians – except for Greece – are

negative which in turn means that the trend for all sovereign bond yields has been negative

5

Page 8: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

over time. In addition, the volatility of sovereign bond yields of the periphery countries

is much higher compared to that of the core countries. We find that the sovereign bond

yields of all periphery countries, except for Portugal, are negatively skewed whereas all

core countries exhibit positively skewed bond yields. Those di↵erences aside, all series are

significantly leptokurtic, non-normally distributed, stationary, autocorrelated and exhibit

ARCH/GARCH errors. On a final note, we find that unconditional correlations across

core countries are highest whereas the correlation across periphery countries and between

periphery and core countries are moderately high to low. Interestingly, Greek bond yield

movements seem to be independent or even slightly negatively correlated with other EMU

bond yields.

[Insert Table 1 around here]

2.2 TVP-VAR based Dynamic Connectedness Approach

To accurately estimate the transmission mechanism of the Euro Area’s sovereign bond

yields we base the dynamic connectedness measures (Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014) on the

estimation results of a TVP-VAR with time-varying covariances (Koop and Korobilis,

2014). This combined methodology overcomes the burden of (i) lossing valuable obser-

vations, (ii) choosing – in most cases rather arbitrarily – a rolling-window size and (iii)

outlier sensitivity as stressed out by Antonakakis and Gabauer (2017) and Korobilis and

Yilmaz (2018). According to the Bayesian information criterion (BIC), we are employing

a TVP-VAR with one lag which can be formulated as follows,

xt =�txt�1 + ✏t ✏t|⌦t�1 ⇠ N(0,⌃t)

vec(�t) =vec(�t�1) + ⇠t ⇠t|⌦t�1 ⇠ N(0,⌅t)

where ⌦t�1 illustrates all available information until t � 1, xt, xt�1, and ✏t are m ⇥ 1

vectors, and �t and ⌃t are m ⇥ m dimensional matrices. Furthermore, vec(�t) and ⇠t

are m2 ⇥ 1 dimensional vectors and ⌅t is an m2 ⇥m2 dimensional matrix.

For the initialization of the Kalman Filter we are using the Primiceri (2005) prior.

Hence, in our study we set �OLS, ⌃�OLS

and ⌃OLS equal to the VAR estimation results

6

Page 9: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

of the first 250 days Korobilis and Yilmaz (2018):

vec(�0) ⇠N(vec(�OLS),⌃�OLS

)

⌃0 =⌃OLS.

Due to numerical stability we decided to implement decay factors in the Kalman Filter

algorithm. The choice of decay factors resembles the choice of priors in general and

depends on the expected amount of time-variation in the parameters. Since this study

analyzes daily data the benchmark model is based on 1 = 0.99 and 2 = 0.992. Hence,

the multivariate Kalman Filter can be formulated as follows:

vec(�t)|x1:t�1 ⇠N(vec(�t|t�1),⌃�t|t�1)

�t|t�1 =�t�1|t�1

✏t =xt ��t|t�1xt�1

⌃t =2⌃t�1|t�1 + (1� 2)✏0t✏t

⌅t =(1� �11 )⌃�t�1|t�1

⌃�t|t�1 =⌃

�t�1|t�1 �⌅t

⌃t|t�1 =xt�1⌃�t|t�1x

0t�1 +⌃

t

We update �t, ⌃�tand ⌃t given the information at time t by the following steps:

vec(�t)|x1:t ⇠N(vec(�t|t),⌃�t|t)

Kt =⌃�t|t�1x

0t�1⌃

�1t|t�1

�t|t =�t|t�1 +Kt(xt ��t|t�1xt�1)

⌃�t|t =(I �Kt)⌃

�t|t�1

✏t|t =xt ��t|txt�1

⌃t|t =2⌃t�1|t�1 + (1� 2)✏0t|t✏t|t

2Keep in mind that this specification allows for more monthly parameter variability compared to Koopand Korobilis (2014). In addition, fixed decay factors have been used as time-varying decay factors aresubstantially increasing the computation burden of the algorithm and since the value added with respectto the forecast performance is questionable (Koop and Korobilis, 2013). Robustness checks based onvarious decay factor combinations are provided.

7

Page 10: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

where Kt represents the Kalman Gain that explains by how much the parameters, �t,

should be changed in a given state. On the one hand, if the parameter uncertainty, ⌃�t|t�1,

is small (large) it means that the parameters, �t, should be similar to (adjusted) their

prior states. On the other hand, if the error variance ⌃t is small (large) – meaning that

the estimation is very accurate (inaccurate) – the parameters, �t, should be similar to

(adjusted) their prior values.

After we have estimated the time-varying parameters, we need to transform the TVP-

VAR to a TVP-VMA using the Wold representation theorem, xt =P

p

i=1 �itxt�i + ✏t =P1

j=1 ⇤jt✏t�j+✏t. In a next step, the TVP-VMA coe�cients are extracted to calculate the

generalised forecast error variance decomposition (GFEVD) (Koop et al., 1996; Pesaran

and Shin, 1998) on which the dynamic connectedness framework (Diebold and Yılmaz,

2014) is built on.

To compute all dynamic connectedness measures seven steps are required.

Step I: The (scaled) GFEVD, g

ij,t(K) – representing the pairwise directional connected-

ness from j to i which in turn is the influence variable j has on variable i in terms of its

forecast error variance share – is defined as follows:

g

ij,t(K) =

⌃�1ii,t

PK�1t=1 (◆0

i⇤K,t⌃t◆j)2

Pm

j=1

PK�1t=1 (◆i⇤K,t⌃t⇤

0K,t

◆i) g

ij,t(K) =

g

ij,t(K)

Pm

j=1 g

ij,t(K)

withP

m

j=1 g

ij,t(K) = 1 and

Pm

i,j=1 g

ij,t(K) = m, where K represents the forecast horizon

and ◆i a selection vector with a one on the ith position and zero otherwise.

Step II: The total directional connectedness TO others measures how much of a shock in

variable i is transmitted to all other variables j:

Cg

i!j,t(K) =

Pm

j=1,i 6=j g

ji,t(K)

Pm

j=1 g

ji,t(K)

Step III: The total directional connectedness FROM others measures how much variable

i is receiving from shocks in all other variables j:

Cg

i j,t(K) =

Pm

j=1,i 6=j g

ij,t(K)

Pm

i=1 g

ij,t(K)

Step IV: The net total directional connectedness represents the di↵erence between the

8

Page 11: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

total directional connectedness TO others and the total directional connectedness FROM

others, which can be interpreted as the influence variable i has on the analyzed network.

Cg

i,t= Cg

i!j,t(K)� Cg

i j,t(K)

If the Cg

i,t> 0 (Cg

i,t< 0) variable i is considered as a net transmitter (receiver) since it is

influencing all others more (less) than being influenced by them.

Step V: The net pairwise directional connectedness (NPDC) provides us with information

about the bilateral transmission process between variable i and variable j:

NPDCij(K) = jit(K)� ijt(K).

If NPDCij(K) > 0 (NPDCij(K) < 0) variable i is driving (driven by) variable j.

Step VI: Traditionally the total connectedness index (TCI) expresses the average amount

of one variable’s forecast error variance share explained by all other variables:

Cg

t (K) =

Pm

i,j=1,i 6=j g

ij,t(K)

m.

Based on Monte Carlo simulations it can be shown that the own variance shares are by

construction always larger or equal to all cross variance shares3. This means that this

TCI is ranging between [0, m�1m

]. Since we want to know the average amount of network

co-movement in percent – which should range between [0,1] – we have to slightly adjust

the TCI:

Cg

t (K) =

Pm

i,j=1,i 6=j g

ij,t(K)

m� 10 Cg

t (K) 1.

Step VII: The pairwise connectedness index (PCI) measures the interconnectedness be-

tween variable i and j – which is masked by the TCI – and can be written as:

Cg

ijt(K) =2

g

ij,t(K) + g

ji,t(K)

g

ii,t(K) + g

ij,t(K) + g

ji,t(K) + g

jj,t(K)

!0 Cg

ijt(K) 1.

A high (low) PCI suggests high (low) synchronization and thus is indicative of risk equality

(inequality). Therefore, it is more (less) likely that variable i and j are in the same

3Code for Monte Carlo simulation is available upon request.

9

Page 12: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

monetary union.

3 Empirical Results and Discussion

3.1 Overview of Averaged Connectedness Dynamics

We begin our discussion by providing an overview of the averaged connectedness measures

which are depicted in Table 2. It shows that the main transmitter of shocks is Germany

followed by the Netherlands, Belgium, Finland, Austria, France, and Italy whereas the

net receivers of shocks are Greece followed by Portugal, Ireland and Spain. The same

pattern can be observed by looking at the number of net pairwise directional transmission

dominance.

In addition, the TCI explains that on average the comovement of the sovereign bond

yields and hence the risk equality of the whole network is 83.3% which in turn means

that on average 75.7% (= 83.3% · 1011) of the forecast error variance of one sovereign bond

yield can be explained by the influence of all other sovereign bond yields. In turn, this

practically means that this sort of analysis is masking specific episodes (i.e., economic

shocks) that have had a distinct impact on the Euro Area and on its interconnectedness.

Therefore, the dynamic total connectedness captures the time-variation of the TCI for

the full sample period of the study.

[Insert Table 2 around here]

3.2 Financial Risk Coordination

In this regard, we focus our analysis on the dynamic total connectedness measure which

allows us to trace the interconnectedness of our network over time. These results are

given by Figure 3. In particular, we note that prior to 2009 bond yields are highly

interconnected; that is, the value of the dynamic total connectedness reaches almost 100%

which in turn, is suggestive of the very strong linkages at the time. Most importantly, the

large value of the dynamic total connectedness prior to 2009 is rather indicative of the fact

that up to that point EMU member states are regarded as being equally risky. The latter

predicates, of course, on the notion that interest paid on sovereign debt is closely related

10

Page 13: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

to a country’s financial health and further reflects risk assessments by rating agencies.

Therefore, the broader picture is that the period until 2009 is a relatively tranquil period

for the EMU with increased levels of confidence both in the compliance e↵orts of member

states regarding Maastricht’s convergence criteria and in the broader prospects of the

common market and the monetary union.

[Insert Figure 3 around here]

By contrast, from 2009 onwards, we note that the dynamic total connectedness follows

a downward trend, reaching a trough in 2012. As evident in Figure 3, during the year 2012

the dynamic total connectedness experiences its lowest values for the sample period of the

study; that is, values in the region between 55% and 60%. Obviously, this decoupling of

bond yield levels is associated with the outbreak of the European debt crisis and the need

for European authorities to develop economic adjustment programmes for certain EMU

member states, starting with Greece in May 2010. Given notable deviations from the

Maastricht criteria, especially in relation to government debt-to-GDP ratio, government

budget deficit levels, as well as, mounting uncertainty in relation to the creditworthiness

of specific EMU member states, 2009 marks the beginning of an era whereupon, interest

rates on sovereign debt start to exhibit sharp contrasts. According to Bølstad and Elhardt

(2018) from October 2009 onwards investors in EMU sovereign debt, begin to question

the willingness of European institutions to rescue specific economies. On one hand, these

economies are ranked low, in terms of fiscal space or capacity to repay their debts (e.g.,

Greece), however, on the other, these countries had issued debt within the EMU which

provided confidence to investors. What is more, our findings of plummeting dynamic

total connectedness in the period following the outbreak of the debt crisis in Europe,

resonate with authors such as Ehrmann and Fratzscher (2017) and BenSaıda (2018) who

put forward the argument that fragmentation – which reflects the e↵ort on behalf of the

European authorities to reduce spillovers across markets and protect financially healthy

member states from contagion e↵ects stemming from troubled economies – marked the

period during the height of the crisis (i.e., early 2010 and until the spring of 2012). In

addition, authors such as Beetsma et al. (2017) emphasize the role of decisions made by

11

Page 14: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

the ECB at the time such as the Securities Markets Programme (SMP) initiated in May

2010.

Evidentially, dynamic total connectedness appears to be picking up in the period af-

ter 2012; nonetheless, it does not revert back to its initial levels, but rather, from 2015

onwards, it narrowly oscillates around the 80% mark until the most recent dates of our

sample period. At this point, it would be instructive to note that the upward trend that

commences in 2012 coincides with a period that encompasses two crucial developments

that take place within the EMU and help to further promote confidence among economic

agents. First, a second programme for Greece is agreed in March 2012, following the

rather unsuccessful first programme. Irrespective of whether or not the appropriate mix

of measures is again employed regarding the recovery of the Greek economy, this de-

velopment is considered to be a positive step forward, as it practically underscores the

commitment on behalf of the European authorities to resolve the Greek matter. Second,

and in close relation to the previous point, in July 2012, the president of the ECB reas-

sures markets by committing to that ’the ECB is ready to do whatever it takes to preserve

the Euro’; a statement that clearly fosters confidence and mitigates the eventuality of the

default of a member state undergoing financial aid programmes. In further support to the

arguments that we put forward and the situation that is illustrated in Figure 3, Afonso

et al. (2018) show that following Mario Draghi’s statement in July 2012 there is a regime

shift in connection with the pricing of European sovereign bonds. The e↵ectiveness of

unconventional ECB policies such as the Outright Monetary Transactions (OMT ) – an-

nounced in September 2012 – is also reported by authors such as Jager and Grigoriadis

(2017) and Roch and Uhlig (2018).

Nonetheless, the rising dynamic total connectedness trend disappears around 2015,

mainly reflecting the persistent character of specific imbalances that help preserve uncer-

tainty in European markets. In particular, in the period that begins in 2015, turbulence

still remains in Europe and this could be the aftermath of the change in helm of the Greek

government (i.e., the January 2015 elections, followed by the referendum in July 2015, as

well as, the third economic adjustment programme in August 2015), the political unrest

in Spain (i.e., the October 2017 referendum in Catalonia), or the very recent controversies

12

Page 15: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

of the Italian government with EU o�cials, over a series of matters (following the March

2018 elections). In point of fact, the slight decrease in the dynamic total connectedness

in the most recent months of our sample that is evident in Figure 3, might be capturing

these specific developments in Italy. On a final note, it would also be reasonable to assume

that, even though the UK is not part of the common currency, the decision to exit the EU

(i.e., June 2016 referendum) has played its part in raising European market uncertainty.

In this regard, we opine that even though certain problems have been resolved (a fact

that helps explain why the dynamic total connectedness has recovered from the low levels

of 2012) there are still sources of uncertainty that torment the EMU (justifying perhaps

why the dynamic total connectedness has not fully returned to its initial levels; that is,

before 2009). Relevant considerations that highlight current problems within the EMU

and further relate to the broader question of whether Europe should integrate more or

become more fragmented, have also been raised by authors such as Hodson (2017) and

Verdun (2018).

These findings are further supported in the following sections where we show that

periphery countries have been at the epicenter of these episodes and that connectedness

levels with respect to Ireland and Italy recovered faster compared to other periphery

countries after the European governmental debt crisis (2010). In this regard, although

stressed economies do exhibit a more pronounced or lengthier decline in connectedness,

we should not lose sight of the fact that individual di↵erences between core countries

or between periphery countries are indeed possible. This point is further emphasized in

Sections 3.3 and 3.4 where we discuss net total and net pairwise directional connectedness,

respectively. What is more, in Section 3.5 we make use of the pairwise connectedness

indices in order to identify potential ideal candidates for putting together a monetary

union.

3.3 The Complicated Nature of Coordination

In turn, we focus on net total directional connectedness across the EMU countries in-

cluded in our study. In particular, given that the framework of our analysis facilitates

not only the investigation of risk-discrepancies across member states over time, but also,

13

Page 16: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

the establishment of the source and direction of the shocks that bring forth such discrep-

ancies in the first place; it would be instructive to explore the dynamic process of net

connectedness measures across countries.

In this respect, Figure 4 presents results regarding net total directional connectedness

across countries. It is important to clarify that positive values correspond to net transmit-

ters of shocks in the sovereign debt market, whereas, negative values reveal net receivers

of such shocks. It should also be noted that irrespective of whether a country assumes

one role or the other, increased levels of connectedness reflect periods whereupon there

is a convergence across countries with respect to sovereign debt level of risk. To put it

di↵erently, increased levels of connectedness are indicative of the fact that confidence is

progressively being restored in the market or that European authorities have gained some

degree of control over the crisis. Nonetheless, wider discussion further revolves around

which countries are net transmitters and which are net receivers of shocks in the market

for sovereign debt.

[Insert Figure 4 around here]

As evidenced in Figure 4, despite that certain countries assume one specific role for almost

the entirety of the sample period (e.g., Germany or the Netherlands clearly assume a net

transmitting role, whereas, Greece is mainly a net receiver), there are many instances

where other countries assume both roles (e.g., France or Ireland). This finding is in line

with authors such as BenSaıda (2018) who argues that core EMU countries typically a↵ect

their peripheral counterparts. A closer look would in fact indicate that Italy (and perhaps

Spain to a lesser extent) appear to be an exception to this rule, given perhaps the size

of their economies and their global economic influence (Italy is a member of the G7 and

Spain a permanent invitee of G20). Notably though, in the case of Greece, Ireland and

Portugal, evidence suggests that there is a very limited role deserved for these countries

as net transmitters of shocks. To be more explicit, it appears that for most periphery

countries, net transmitting capacity coincided with the onset of the sovereign bond crisis in

2010, but also, with time intervals around their agreement on some economic adjustment

programme (see, for example, Greece and Ireland in 2010, or, Portugal in 2011). What is

more, it is rather obvious that following the outbreak of the crisis, there is a decrease in

14

Page 17: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

both transmitting and receiving dynamics in periphery countries. This is more pronounced

considering Greece, Ireland and Portugal. Clearly in the case of Greece, there is a collapse

of said dynamics that stays in place until after Greece’s second adjustment programme in

2012. This result might also be associated with the argument put forward by Fernandez-

Rodrıguez et al. (2016) that during a crisis period, the positive influence of core economies

on the periphery is practically lost, given that – as already mentioned in previous sections

– economic agents begin to question (i) the actual financial state of the troubled countries

and (ii) the extent to which core countries will choose to protect the stressed economies

of the periphery (i.e., matters of capacity and willingness).

In turn, with the passing of time and the deployment of the relevant unconventional

monetary policy tools Greece, Ireland and Portugal, appear to persistently act as net

recipients of shocks. Besides, Bratis et al. (2018) provide an interesting point of view,

arguing that after February 2012 core EMU countries started to feel immune against the

complications stemming from the Greek economy, which in turn, might help explain why

it was not before long that stressed economies reverted back to their initial role as net

receivers. Nonetheless, we should stress that Ireland appears to transmit on a net basis

again towards the more recent months of our sample; more likely reflecting developments

in relation to Brexit, which unequivocally increase market uncertainty.

Another interesting finding illustrated in Figure 4 is that both Austria and Belgium

appear to be di↵erently a↵ected compared to other core countries during the height of the

European debt crisis. In particular, contrary to other core countries, the net receiving role

assumed by both Austria and Belgium during that time interval is rather persistent. This

fact, coupled with the observation made earlier that Italy and Spain – probably because

of the size of their economy and their economic importance behaved di↵erently vis-a-vis

other periphery countries – prompts the question of whether the current classification of

EMU countries into core and peripheral is useful to making generalisations when it comes

to assessing the e↵ects of a shock in the Euro Area and whether, we could somehow come

up with di↵erent classifications.

15

Page 18: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

3.4 Pairwise Insights

Turning to the investigation of bilateral connectedness between specific countries, the

case of Germany is rather striking in that further investigation of connectedness across

member states shows that the picture is not very clear and that generalisations are not

always pertinent. In this regard, Figure 5 presents net pairwise connectedness of all EMU

member states vis-a-vis Germany which in this case serves as the reference country4.

Starting with the years that marked the height of the crisis and in line with previous

arguments, during this period, connectedness deteriorates while it is rather evident that

most periphery countries receive less from Germany overall. In addition, country-specific

results are indicative of sharp contrasts across periphery countries. For instance, Greece

appears to receive around the time when some adjustment programme was in place (e.g.,

May 2010, March 2012, as well as, August 2015). Nonetheless, there is no improvement

after that given that Greece only exited the third adjustment programme in August 2018.

Connectedness with regard to Ireland on the other hand, which started its programme

in November 2010, resumed immediately after December 2013; that is, when the country

exited its programme. Furthermore, results for Italy may di↵er since Italy never entered

a programme at all. It is worth noting however, that in the most recent observations in

our sample, there is a collapse in connectedness between Germany and Italy, probably re-

flecting uncertainty fueled by recent political frictions between the European Commission

and the Italian Government. Portugal entered its programme in May 2011. In turn, con-

nectedness in Portugal strengthened after January 2014; that is, when the country exited

its programme. Similar results can be reported for Spain which underwent an economic

adjustment programme between June 2012 and January 2014.

[Insert Figure 5 around here]

Considering the connectedness relating to core countries during the crisis, we note that

Germany transmits to all of these countries for most of the time with the exception of

the months immediately before (and in some cases immediately after) year 2012. There

4Hereby, we are following authors such as Von Hagen and Fratianni (1990), Von Hagen and Neumann(1994) and Antonakakis et al. (2017). Additionally, it seems also plausible from a theoretical point ofview to utilize Germany as reference since the German mark was de facto the European currency unit(ECU ) and Germany is the main net pairwise transmitter of shocks as shown in Table 2.

16

Page 19: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

are of course notable discrepancies among core countries as well, when it comes to Ger-

man transmissions of shocks; such as, the fact that Austria transmits more to Germany

compared to Belgium and Finland, or that, France mainly receives, without ever really

transmitting to Germany. At the same time, this process is rather balanced for Nether-

lands. On a final note, in order to further emphasize that transmission patterns are not

very clear when countries are distinguished between core and periphery, we concentrate

on the most recent months of our sample. As shown in Figure 5 Germany, in the months

following 2017, transmits considerably (for example) to both Austria (core) and Portugal

(periphery) but less so to both Belgium (core) and Ireland (periphery).

In retrospect, results presented in this section clearly illustrate that it is not always

easy to make generalisations on the basis of the customary classification of EMU countries

to core and periphery. What is more, on the premise that economies are subject to

shocks, identifying the appropriate mechanisms to alleviate imbalances within a diverse

group of countries becomes all the more di�cult. Understandably, the discussion stirs

towards identifying the necessary conditions for putting together an optimal currency

area. As previously mentioned, we attempt to identify potential groups of countries that

could actually form a successful monetary union, given the results that we from pairwise

connectedness indices. The relevant findings are presented in the section that follows.

3.5 A Connectedness Approach to Forming Groups

Following the discussion in previous sections, we would like to further investigate whether

the customary classification of countries into core and periphery further entails that eco-

nomic agents conceive of EMU as a union consisting of a rather diverse set of countries.

To this end, we utilize pairwise connectedness indices to identify pairs of countries that

move much closer with each other and would therefore constitute ideal matches towards

making a more sensible union (i.e. higher synchronization). It should be clearly empha-

sized that, the objective of this exercise is to identify countries that are considered to be

equally risky, as the latter is being captured by the degree of their pairwise co-movements.

However, before we discuss the averaged pairwise connectedness values per se, we focus

on their time-varying behavior. Figure 6 depicts interconnectedness between all countries

17

Page 20: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

of interest and Germany. Findings indicate that all countries, except for Austria, have

decreased co-movements with the German bond yield during the European government

debt crisis (2010). Interestingly though, core countries recovered from their lowest levels

in a faster pace whereas the sluggish recoveries of periphery countries – with the exception

of Ireland – have not even been close to their pre-crisis levels. Particularly in the case of

Greece, we see that the co-movement with the German bond yield broke down completely

and there is no evidence of recovery within our sample period. Notably, all periphery

countries, except Ireland, decoupled again in 2018 whereas the Italian case seems to be

the most pronounced since its interconnectedness dropped to its 2010 level. The repeated

decoupling of periphery pairwise connectedness could be a signal of a new imminent crisis.

[Insert Figure 6 around here]

In this respect, Figure 7 illustrates that 16 pairs of countries tend to move closer

together which is indicative of the fact that the countries included in these pairs could

form a more sensible (i.e., equally risky) union. To put it di↵erently, the intercept of the

relevant model changes significantly after the 16th pair. The latter practically implies

that after the 16th pair, the bilateral connectedness is clearly decoupled from the others

and hence it would not be sensible from a connectedness point of view to consider the

ensuing pairs as good matches.

[Insert Figure 7 around here]

Results with regard to specific pairs are given by Table 3. It would be instructive

at this point to note that although the analysis in this section refers to the baseline

model; that is, to the TVP-VAR(0.99/0.99), Table 3 also reports results from alternative

specifications to the e↵ect that a sensitivity/robustness analysis is possible. In addition,

robustness analysis is presented in greater detail in the section that follows. On general

principles, results are qualitative similar across models. In this respect, concentrating on

the first 16 pairs represented in Table 3, turns out that core countries have better chances

to constitute good candidates for an equally risky union. Nonetheless, in line with our

previous findings, even across core countries there exist noteworthy di↵erences (e.g. the

Netherlands-Finland pair, which occupies the top of the relevant column, is apparently

18

Page 21: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

less diverse than the France-Belgium one, which, by contrast lies at the bottom of that

list). These findings could help explain the di↵erences we pointed out in the previous

sections. What is also evident in Table 3 is that Spain and Italy might consider setting

up a separate union on their own. This finding resonates with Galariotis et al. (2016) and

Leschinski and Bertram (2017) who point out that Italy and Spain are the most important

when it comes to exerting influence on other EMU member states. Nevertheless, we do

not have any evidence that other periphery countries qualify for another monetary union.

[Insert Table 3 around here]

On general principles, results from this connectedness exercise appear to justify the

customary distinction of countries into core and periphery. Apparently, with the exception

of Italy and Spain, the top 16 groups exclusively consist of countries from the core. In

this regard, given that most periphery countries are not regarded as being equal in terms

of risk and future prospects to their core counterparts, then, the extent of integration

and e↵ort to mitigate economic asymmetry across member states has so far been rather

insu�cient.

In turn, existing literature underscores potential problems in close relation to these

results. More particularly, in the work of De Grauwe and Ji (2013) and Saka et al. (2015)

we find evidence in favour of the fragility hypothesis according to which the European

debt crisis (2010) was fueled by self-fulfilling market fear (i.e., regarding the capacity of

the EMU to overcome the crisis) that was eventually quelled by ECB’s intervention in

2012. A fact that further highlights how crucial the role of the ECB as a lender of last

resort has been. With reference to the role of the ECB, authors such as Genschel and

Jachtenfuchs (2018) put forward the argument that the very fact that the ECB acted as

a lender of last resort implies that currently the Euro Area is practically characterized by

a shortfall in internal capacity-building. That is, EMU countries have not yet explicitly

developed the necessary mechanisms and the appropriate regulatory framework in order

to successfully calm the markets and avert future crises from occurring. Understandably,

the lack of capacity-building does not reassure economic agents and does not help mitigate

the self-fulfilling expectations hypothesis that is mentioned above.

19

Page 22: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

Furthermore, as regards the shortfall in regulations, Bayoumi and Eichengreen (2018)

stress out that one common supervisor for the European banking and financial system is

rather imperative and that the sovereign debt crisis in Europe was also associated with the

huge lending in the early years of the adoption of the common currency, from core countries

to EMU periphery. The latter has also been underscored in the work of Fingleton et al.

(2015) who explicate that given the inherent regional disparities in productivity within the

EMU, tranquil periods are advantageous for the European South (i.e., exactly because of

the capital transfers mentioned above); however, turbulent periods are further aggravated

by these disparities (i.e., which foster market fear and lead to capital flights towards what

investors conceive of as safety). Flight to safety (i.e., mainly toward Germany) and its

impact on the sovereign debt crisis has also been emphasized by Paniagua et al. (2016).

It follows that the findings of our study – in line with the fragility hypothesis – stress

the importance of deeper integration of EMU member states. This deepening should focus

on the development of policies and mechanisms that target market fear and rationalize

(i.e., justify) capital inflows and outflows across countries. Otherwise, the pairwise con-

nectedness results presented in this study suggest that if the periphery countries of our

sample remain in the common currency area, then, the underlying di↵erences and the dif-

ferent perceptions of riskiness across member states, coupled with the lack of appropriate

support mechanisms, will merely perpetuate the occurrence of financial crisis episodes.

This issue becomes even more relevant in view of the desired expansion of EMU and the

accession of new countries.

In consonance with Fingleton et al. (2015) we also argue that nominal integration as

currently supported by Maastricht criteria, may not be su�cient to promote economic

symmetry across the participants of the Euro Area; and that, real integration, which

involves actual growth provisions is in fact, what should matter the most. That is, the

Euro Area should act beyond the framework drawn up by the SGP that focuses mainly on

regulations pertaining to fiscal imbalances. On a final note, in accordance with Genschel

and Jachtenfuchs (2018) we opine that, political initiatives purporting to enhance soli-

darity across member states by enhancing the sharing of specific disturbances are rather

imperative (e.g., explicit decisions regarding the refugee crisis that currently torments

20

Page 23: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

mostly the Southern countries of Europe).

In retrospect, this study provides evidence – based on pairwise connectedness indices

– that sensible currency areas should not include periphery EMU countries. The reason

being, that currently, these countries lead to additional asymmetric sovereign bond yield

dynamics vis-a-vis to their core counterparts which, by contrast, rather facilitate symme-

try in the sovereign bond market. The latter is quite alarming considering the argument

that the sovereign debt crisis was associated with self-fulfilling expectations in connection

with the capacity to respond and the willingness to resolve the crisis. Evidentially, there

is a void in the relevant regulations that is currently being filled by the ECB which acts as

the lender of last resort. In this regard, European authorities should consider mechanisms

and policies to enhance confidence in the common currency area.

4 Robustness Check

Even though the time-varying dynamics of connectedness provide important insights in

the transmission mechanism of bond yields, our main interest lies with the creation of

a European optimum currency area. To test the validity of our pairwise connectedness

results retrieved from the TVP-VAR(0.99,0.99), we provide a battery of robustness checks.

First of all we compare our results against a simple constant coe�cient VAR-based

connectedness approach on the full sample. In turn, given that a standard VAR model can

be seen as an equation-by-equation OLS procedure – which produces conditional mean

estimators that are outlier sensitive – we propose a Quantile-VAR where each equation is

estimated via quantile regression.

Second, we provide the ranking results based on di↵erent TVP-VAR(1,2) specifi-

cations. Even though setting both decay factors equal to 0.99 seems to be a reasonable

prior-choice we are also interested in capturing di↵erent outcomes considering di↵erent

settings. Hence, as an additional robustness and sensitivity check we allow both decay

factors to vary. On the one hand, 1 is allowed to be between 0.97 and 0.99 whereas on

the other side 2 varies between 0.96 and 0.99.5

5Please keep in mind that for analyzing monthly data Koop and Korobilis (2014) set 1 = 0.99 and2 = 0.96.

21

Page 24: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

Finally, we estimate two DCC-GARCH copula models (Patton, 2006) and employ

averaged dynamic conditional correlations – as opposed to average pairwise connectedness

indices – as a measure to form groups. Since the pairwise connectedness index can be

seen as a measure of co-movement, using dynamic conditional correlations seems to be

an appropriate alternative. In addition to the DCC-GARCH Gaussian-copula, we have

estimated a DCC-GARCH t-copula which allows for heavy tailed distributions.6.

As mentioned earlier in the text, Table 3 shows that all results across models are

qualitatively similar. Interestingly, the first 16 pairs of our benchmark model are identical

to the first 16 pairs of all alternative models even though rankings sometimes di↵er.

This provides strong evidence of a large European monetary union consisting of Austria,

Belgium, Finland, Germany, and the Netherlands and a small European monetary union

between Italy and Spain.

5 Concluding Remarks

In view of further expansion of the common currency area – given that more countries are

expected to adopt the Euro in the future – it is important for research to concentrate on

the factors that determine the successful integration of the EMU’s diverse participants.

Existing studies in the field typically investigate member states convergence, considering a

broad spectrum of macroeconomic and financial indicators. In this regard, it is rather cus-

tomary to investigate the degree of financial risk synchronisation by considering sovereign

bond yield spreads or credit default swaps (CDS) contracts. Furthermore, it is also typical

to make use of these results in order to propose some insightful classification/clustering

of the countries under investigation. Within a much related strand, our study develops

an enhanced version of the dynamic connectedness approach in order to test pairwise

disparities of sovereign bond yield connectedness across a set of both core and periphery

EMU member states over the period from August 2003 and September 2018.

Within the framework of our study, dynamic total connectedness reveals financial risk

coordination (e.g., a large value of the pairwise connectedness between two member states

6As the detailed description of quantile regressions and DCC-GARCH copulas is beyond the scope ofthis study interested readers are referred to Koenker and Bassett Jr (1978) and Patton (2006), respectively.

22

Page 25: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

implies that they are very close in terms of financial risk; that is, they are influencing each

other by the same amount). It follows that we are able to (i) investigate synchronisation

or decoupling at the height of the crisis, (ii) identify net transmitters and net receivers

of sovereign debt shocks, as well as (iii), utilize connectedness results in order to identify

pairs that are better coordinated by virtue of financial risk and that would, therefore,

constitute appropriate partners within a currency union. This line of research is rather

important given that low levels of coordination of financial risk across member states

challenge the notion of the optimal currency area and further question the capacity of the

EMU to abate the likelihood of some future sovereign debt crisis.

Results for dynamic total connectedness provide support to the fragmentation argu-

ment regarding the variation of spillovers across member states over time (i.e., e↵orts to

reduce financial contagion forestalled interconnectedness across member states). Clearly,

interrelations across member states is much higher in the period prior to 2009. By con-

trast, it is evident that at the height of the crisis, investors question both the capacity

and the willingness of the parties involved to resolve the disturbance. Nonetheless, fol-

lowing the ECB’s intervention in 2012 connectedness is restored without having thus far

reverted to its initial levels. The latter is indicative of the fact that there are still sources

of turbulence and uncertainty that corrode confidence within the EMU.

On general principles, findings associated with net total directional connectedness im-

ply that the core is mainly a net transmitter of shocks to the periphery although clearly,

this influence wanes (or is even reversed) considerably at the height of the crisis. The

positive influence from the core during tranquil times could be related to capital inflows

to Southern economies. What is more, periods of very low net connectedness (e.g., Greece

immediately after 2012) might be indicative of very strong fragmentation (i.e., core coun-

tries managed to immunize themselves against certain stressed economies). Nonetheless,

a closer examination of the results reveals that with the exception of Germany – at the

height of the crisis but also in the later months of our sample – certain member states

may assume either role, irrespective of whether they are core or periphery. This finding,

is suggestive of the fact that, the goal of convergence across EMU member states is rather

challenging and further questions, whether, the customary distinction between core and

23

Page 26: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

periphery countries is sensible in terms of financial risk.

To this end, we identify pairs of countries that exhibit high bilateral connectedness

levels in order to suggest a sensible currency area. Consistent with the customary dis-

tinction, we find that there are 16 ’ideal’ pairs, dominated indeed by core countries, with

the exception of Italy and Spain. In turn, we stress that this finding indicates a weakness

for the current structure of the EMU given that periphery countries that do not make

the cut of the top 16 pairs, will always be likely sources of uncertainty and market panic,

that might trigger future financial crises (i.e., in line with the fragility hypothesis). With

reference to the European Commission (2017) White Paper on the Future of Europe, we

opine that further integration across EMU members is necessary to secure a more stable

structure and hence a more viable future. In agreement with existing relevant literature,

we emphasize that part of the current predicaments of the EMU could be resolved by

enhanced regulation on the financial sphere and increased solidarity on the political one.

References

Afonso, A., Arghyrou, M. G., Gadea, M. D., and Kontonikas, A. (2018). ”Whatever ittakes” to resolve the European sovereign debt crisis? Bond pricing regime switches andmonetary policy e↵ects. Journal of International Money and Finance, 86:1–30.

Anscombe, F. J. and Glynn, W. J. (1983). Distribution of the kurtosis statistic b 2 fornormal samples. Biometrika, 70(1):227–234.

Antonakakis, N., Christou, C., Cunado, J., and Gupta, R. (2017). Convergence patternsin sovereign bond yield spreads: Evidence from the Euro Area. Journal of InternationalFinancial Markets, Institutions and Money, 49:129–139.

Antonakakis, N. and Gabauer, D. (2017). Refined Measures of Dynamic Connectednessbased on TVP-VAR. Technical report, University Library of Munich, Germany.

Basse, T. (2014). Searching for the EMU core member countries. European Journal of

Political Economy, 34:S32–S39.Bayoumi, T. and Eichengreen, B. (2018). Aftershocks of Monetary Unification: Hysteresiswith a Financial Twist. Journal of Banking & Finance.

Beetsma, R., de Jong, F., Giuliodori, M., and Widijanto, D. (2017). Realized (co) vari-ances of eurozone sovereign yields during the crisis: The impact of news and the Secu-rities Markets Programme. Journal of International Money and Finance, 75:14–31.

BenSaıda, A. (2018). The contagion e↵ect in European sovereign debt markets: A regime-switching vine copula approach. International Review of Financial Analysis, 58:153–165.

Bhatt, V., Kishor, N. K., and Ma, J. (2017). The impact of EMU on bond yield con-vergence: Evidence from a time-varying dynamic factor model. Journal of Economic

Dynamics and Control, 82(C):206–222.Bølstad, J. and Elhardt, C. (2018). Capacity, Willingness, and Sovereign Default Risk: Re-assuring the Market in Times of Crisis. Journal of Common Market Studies, 56(4):802–817.

Bratis, T., Laopodis, N. T., and Kouretas, G. P. (2018). Contagion and interdependence

24

Page 27: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

in Eurozone bank and sovereign credit markets. International Journal of Finance &

Economics, 23(4):655–674.Caporin, M., Pelizzon, L., Ravazzolo, F., and Rigobon, R. (2018). Measuring sovereigncontagion in Europe. Journal of Financial Stability, 34:150–181.

Christiansen, C. (2014). Integration of European bond markets. Journal of Banking &

Finance, 42:191–198.D’Agostino, R. B. (1970). Transformation to normality of the null distribution of g1.Biometrika, pages 679–681.

De Grauwe, P. (2013). The European Central Bank as lender of last resort in the govern-ment bond markets. CESifo Economic Studies, 59(3):520–535.

De Grauwe, P. (2016). The legacy of the Eurozone crisis and how to overcome it. Journalof Empirical Finance, 39:147–155.

De Grauwe, P. and Ji, Y. (2013). Self-fulfilling crises in the Eurozone: An empirical test.Journal of International Money and Finance, 34:15–36.

Diebold, F. X. and Yılmaz, K. (2009). Measuring Financial Asset Return And Volatil-ity Spillovers, With Application To Global Equity Markets. Economic Journal,119(534):158–171.

Diebold, F. X. and Yılmaz, K. (2012). Better to give than to receive: Predictive directionalmeasurement of volatility spillovers. International Journal of Forecasting, 28:57–66.

Diebold, F. X. and Yılmaz, K. (2014). On the network topology of variance decom-positions: Measuring the connectedness of financial firms. Journal of Econometrics,182(1):119–134.

Ehrmann, M. and Fratzscher, M. (2017). Euro area government bonds–Fragmentationand contagion during the sovereign debt crisis. Journal of International Money and

Finance, 70:26–44.Eichengreen, B. (2014). The Eurozone Crisis: The theory of optimum currency areasbites back. Notenstein Academy White Paper Series.

European Commission (2017). White paper on the future of Europe: Reflections andscenarios for the EU27 by 2025. Brussels: European Commission.

Falagiarda, M. and Reitz, S. (2015). Announcements of ECB unconventional programs:Implications for the sovereign spreads of stressed euro area countries. Journal of Inter-national Money and Finance, 53:276–295.

Fernandez-Rodrıguez, F., Gomez-Puig, M., and Sosvilla-Rivero, S. (2016). Using connect-edness analysis to assess financial stress transmission in EMU sovereign bond marketvolatility. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 43:126–145.

Fingleton, B., Garretsen, H., and Martin, R. (2015). Shocking aspects of monetary union:the vulnerability of regions in Euroland. Journal of Economic Geography, 15(5):907–934.

Fisher, T. J. and Gallagher, C. M. (2012). New weighted portmanteau statistics fortime series goodness of fit testing. Journal of the American Statistical Association,107(498):777–787.

Galariotis, E. C., Makrichoriti, P., and Spyrou, S. (2016). Sovereign CDS spread deter-minants and spill-over e↵ects during financial crisis: A panel VAR approach. Journal

of Financial Stability, 26:62–77.Genschel, P. and Jachtenfuchs, M. (2018). From market integration to core state powers:the Eurozone crisis, the refugee crisis and integration theory. Journal of Common

Market Studies, 56(1):178–196.Hodson, D. (2017). Eurozone Governance in 2016: The Italian Banking Crisis, FiscalFlexibility and Brexit (Plus Plus Plus). Journal of Common Market Studies, 55:118–132.

Jager, J. and Grigoriadis, T. (2017). The e↵ectiveness of the ECB’s unconventionalmonetary policy: Comparative evidence from crisis and non-crisis Euro-area countries.

25

Page 28: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

Journal of International Money and Finance, 78:21–43.Jarque, C. M. and Bera, A. K. (1980). E�cient tests for normality, homoscedasticity andserial independence of regression residuals. Economics Letters, 6(3):255–259.

Koenker, R. and Bassett Jr, G. (1978). Regression Quantiles. Econometrica, pages 33–50.Koop, G. and Korobilis, D. (2013). Large time-varying parameter VARs. Journal of

Econometrics, 177(2):185–198.Koop, G. and Korobilis, D. (2014). A new index of financial conditions. European Eco-

nomic Review, 71:101–116.Koop, G., Pesaran, M. H., and Potter, S. M. (1996). Impulse response analysis in nonlinearmultivariate models. Journal of Econometrics, 74(1):119–147.

Korobilis, D. and Yilmaz, K. (2018). Measuring Dynamic Connectedness with LargeBayesian VAR Models.

Leschinski, C. and Bertram, P. (2017). Time varying contagion in EMU government bondspreads. Journal of Financial Stability, 29:72–91.

McKinnon, R. I. (1963). Optimum currency areas. American Economic Review,53(4):717–725.

Mundell, R. A. (1961). A theory of optimum currency areas. American Economic Review,51(4):657–665.

O’Rourke, K. H. and Taylor, A. M. (2013). Cross of euros. Journal of Economic Perspec-

tives, 27(3):167–92.Paniagua, J., Sapena, J., and Tamarit, C. (2016). Sovereign debt spreads in EMU: Thetime-varying role of fundamentals and market distrust. Journal of Financial Stability.

Patton, A. J. (2006). Modelling asymmetric exchange rate dependence. International

Economic Review, 47(2):527–556.Pesaran, H. H. and Shin, Y. (1998). Generalized impulse response analysis in linearmultivariate models. Economics Letters, 58(1):17–29.

Primiceri, G. E. (2005). Time varying structural vector autoregressions and monetarypolicy. Review of Economic Studies, 72(3):821–852.

Reboredo, J. C. and Ugolini, A. (2015). Systemic risk in European sovereign debt markets:A CoVaR-copula approach. Journal of International Money and Finance, 51:214–244.

Roch, F. and Uhlig, H. (2018). The dynamics of sovereign debt crises and bailouts. Journalof International Economics, 114:1–13.

Saka, O., Fuertes, A.-M., and Kalotychou, E. (2015). ECB policy and Eurozone fragility:Was De Grauwe right? Journal of International Money and Finance, 54:168–185.

Stock, J., Elliott, G., and Rothenberg, T. (1996). E�cient tests for an autoregressive unitroot. Econometrica, 64(4):813–836.

Verdun, A. (2018). Institutional Architecture of the Euro Area. Journal of Common

Market Studies, 56:74–84.Von Hagen, J. and Fratianni, M. (1990). German dominance in the EMS: evidence frominterest rates. Journal of International Money and Finance, 9(4):358–375.

Von Hagen, J. and Neumann, M. J. (1994). Real exchange rates within and betweencurrency areas: how far away is EMU? Review of Economics and Statistics, pages236–244.

26

Page 29: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

Table 1: Summary Statistics: Bond Yield Changes

Austria Belgium Finland France Germany Netherlands Greece Ireland Italy Portugal Spain

Mean -0.00093 -0.00091 -0.00094 -0.00098 -0.00091 -0.00096 0.00012 -0.00092 -0.00029 -0.00061 -0.00072Median -0.00090 -0.00115 -0.00110 -0.00115 -0.00120 -0.00120 0.00010 -0.00170 -0.00040 -0.00100 -0.00050Variance 0.00170 0.00192 0.00165 0.00164 0.00166 0.00155 0.28326 0.00519 0.00382 0.01137 0.00372Skewness 0.413⇤⇤⇤ 0.308⇤⇤⇤ 0.249⇤⇤⇤ 0.102⇤⇤⇤ 0.201⇤⇤⇤ 0.198⇤⇤⇤ -34.664⇤⇤⇤ -0.150⇤⇤⇤ -0.601⇤⇤⇤ 1.236⇤⇤⇤ -1.012⇤⇤⇤

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.009) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)Excess 3.157⇤⇤⇤ 5.845⇤⇤⇤ 2.130⇤⇤⇤ 2.080⇤⇤⇤ 2.550⇤⇤⇤ 1.673⇤⇤⇤ 1826.728⇤⇤⇤ 32.164⇤⇤⇤ 18.967⇤⇤⇤ 49.409⇤⇤⇤ 18.225⇤⇤⇤Kurtosis (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)JB 1737⇤⇤⇤ 5634⇤⇤⇤ 781⇤⇤⇤ 712⇤⇤⇤ 1087⇤⇤⇤ 482⇤⇤⇤ 544982473⇤⇤⇤ 168727⇤⇤⇤ 58905⇤⇤⇤ 399129⇤⇤⇤ 54837⇤⇤⇤

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)ERS -43.038⇤⇤⇤ -40.721⇤⇤⇤ -43.648⇤⇤⇤ -44.356⇤⇤⇤ -44.037⇤⇤⇤ -43.601⇤⇤⇤ -44.564⇤⇤⇤ -36.829⇤⇤⇤ -44.516⇤⇤⇤ -37.462⇤⇤⇤ -41.649⇤⇤⇤

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)Q(20) 44.326⇤⇤⇤ 128.956⇤⇤⇤ 21.270⇤⇤⇤ 32.811⇤⇤⇤ 31.166⇤⇤⇤ 29.281⇤⇤⇤ 178.358⇤⇤⇤ 280.303⇤⇤⇤ 89.981⇤⇤⇤ 336.424⇤⇤⇤ 216.141⇤⇤⇤

(0.000) (0.000) (0.010) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)LM(20) 234.001⇤⇤⇤ 453.241⇤⇤⇤ 134.367⇤⇤⇤ 152.724⇤⇤⇤ 285.833⇤⇤⇤ 140.032⇤⇤⇤ 15.917⇤⇤ 297.497⇤⇤⇤ 299.260⇤⇤⇤ 201.494⇤⇤⇤ 152.599⇤⇤⇤

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.086) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Unconditional Correlations

Austria 1.000 0.815 0.847 0.813 0.898 0.864 0.014 0.348 0.421 0.193 0.428Belgium 0.815 1.000 0.726 0.665 0.842 0.752 0.054 0.445 0.582 0.274 0.562Finland 0.847 0.726 1.000 0.917 0.847 0.919 -0.003 0.316 0.301 0.153 0.325France 0.813 0.665 0.917 1.000 0.814 0.909 -0.033 0.261 0.226 0.106 0.258Germany 0.898 0.842 0.847 0.814 1.000 0.878 0.016 0.352 0.475 0.198 0.458Netherlands 0.864 0.752 0.919 0.909 0.878 1.000 -0.008 0.315 0.333 0.155 0.342Greece 0.014 0.054 -0.003 -0.033 0.016 -0.008 1.000 0.119 0.099 0.153 0.125Ireland 0.348 0.445 0.316 0.261 0.352 0.315 0.119 1.000 0.420 0.485 0.454Italy 0.421 0.582 0.301 0.226 0.475 0.333 0.099 0.420 1.000 0.382 0.784Portugal 0.193 0.274 0.153 0.106 0.198 0.155 0.153 0.485 0.382 1.000 0.395Spain 0.428 0.562 0.325 0.258 0.458 0.342 0.125 0.454 0.784 0.395 1.000

Notes: ***,**,* denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% significance level; Skewness: D’Agostino (1970) test; Kurtosis: Anscombe and Glynn(1983) test; JB: Jarque and Bera (1980) normality test; ERS: Stock et al. (1996) unit-root test; Q(20) and LM(20): Fisher and Gallagher (2012)

weighted portmanteau test.

Table 2: Averaged Dynamic Connectedness Table

Austria Belgium Finland France Germany Netherlands Greece Ireland Italy Portugal Spain FROM

Austria 17.6 11.7 11.9 10.8 13.7 12.4 2.7 5.7 5.1 3.6 4.8 82.4Belgium 11.6 19.0 9.5 8.7 12.5 10.2 2.8 6.5 7.9 4.2 7.0 81.0Finland 11.8 9.7 17.1 13.8 11.8 13.9 2.6 6.0 4.9 3.6 4.8 82.9France 11.4 9.2 14.6 17.9 11.5 14.3 2.8 5.6 4.6 3.5 4.6 82.1Germany 13.2 12.0 11.5 10.5 17.0 12.4 2.6 6.0 5.6 3.9 5.3 83.0Netherlands 12.0 10.0 13.7 13.3 12.5 16.8 2.7 5.7 5.0 3.6 4.6 83.2Greece 3.5 3.7 3.5 4.2 3.4 3.7 51.7 5.4 6.8 8.1 6.1 48.3Ireland 6.2 7.9 6.9 6.3 7.1 6.6 4.7 27.8 9.2 8.3 9.1 72.2Italy 5.8 8.8 5.7 5.2 6.9 5.9 4.6 8.3 24.0 8.9 15.8 76.0Portugal 4.3 5.4 4.6 4.2 5.1 4.5 6.4 9.4 11.5 33.4 11.3 66.6Spain 5.6 8.2 5.7 5.3 6.6 5.5 4.3 8.6 16.5 9.0 24.8 75.2

Contribution TO others 85.3 86.5 87.7 82.4 91.1 89.5 36.3 67.2 77.0 56.7 73.5 833.1NET directional connectedness 2.9 5.5 4.7 0.3 8.0 6.3 -12.0 -5.1 1.0 -9.9 -1.7 TCINPDC transmitter 6.0 8.0 7.0 5.0 10.0 9.0 0.0 2.0 4.0 1.0 3.0 83.3

Notes: Results are based on a TVP-VAR(0.99,0.99) model with lag length of order 1 (BIC) and a 10-step-ahead forecast.

27

Page 30: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

Table 3: Ranking Based On VAR, Quantile-VAR, TVP-VAR and DCC-GARCH Copula Models

Rank TVP-VAR(0.99/0.99) TVP-VAR(0.99/0.98) TVP-VAR(0.99/0.97) TVP-VAR(0.99/0.96)

1 Netherlands-Finland Netherlands-Finland France-Finland France-Finland2 France-Finland France-Finland Netherlands-Finland Netherlands-Finland3 Netherlands-France Netherlands-France Netherlands-France Netherlands-France4 Germany-Austria Germany-Austria Germany-Austria Germany-Austria5 Netherlands-Germany Netherlands-Germany Netherlands-Germany Netherlands-Germany6 Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria7 Germany-Belgium Germany-Belgium Germany-Belgium Germany-Belgium8 Germany-Finland Germany-Finland Germany-Finland Germany-Finland9 Finland-Austria Finland-Austria Finland-Austria Finland-Austria10 Belgium-Austria Spain-Italy Germany-France Germany-France11 Spain-Italy Belgium-Austria Belgium-Austria Belgium-Austria12 Germany-France Germany-France Spain-Italy Spain-Italy13 France-Austria France-Austria France-Austria France-Austria14 Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium15 Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium16 France-Belgium France-Belgium France-Belgium France-Belgium

Rank TVP-VAR(0.98/0.99) TVP-VAR(0.98/0.98) TVP-VAR(0.98/0.97) TVP-VAR(0.98/0.96)

1 Netherlands-Finland Netherlands-Finland Netherlands-Finland France-Finland2 France-Finland France-Finland France-Finland Netherlands-Finland3 Netherlands-France Netherlands-France Netherlands-France Netherlands-France4 Germany-Austria Germany-Austria Germany-Austria Germany-Austria5 Netherlands-Germany Netherlands-Germany Netherlands-Germany Netherlands-Germany6 Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria7 Germany-Belgium Germany-Belgium Germany-Belgium Germany-Belgium8 Germany-Finland Germany-Finland Germany-Finland Germany-Finland9 Finland-Austria Finland-Austria Finland-Austria Finland-Austria10 Spain-Italy Spain-Italy Germany-France Germany-France11 Belgium-Austria Belgium-Austria Spain-Italy Belgium-Austria12 Germany-France Germany-France Belgium-Austria Spain-Italy13 France-Austria France-Austria France-Austria France-Austria14 Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium15 Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium16 France-Belgium France-Belgium France-Belgium France-Belgium

Rank TVP-VAR(0.97/0.99) TVP-VAR(0.97/0.98) TVP-VAR(0.97/0.97) TVP-VAR(0.97/0.96)

1 Netherlands-Finland Netherlands-Finland Netherlands-Finland Netherlands-Finland2 France-Finland France-Finland France-Finland France-Finland3 Netherlands-France Netherlands-France Netherlands-France Netherlands-France4 Germany-Austria Germany-Austria Germany-Austria Germany-Austria5 Netherlands-Germany Netherlands-Germany Netherlands-Germany Netherlands-Germany6 Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria7 Germany-Belgium Germany-Belgium Germany-Belgium Germany-Belgium8 Germany-Finland Germany-Finland Germany-Finland Germany-Finland9 Finland-Austria Finland-Austria Finland-Austria Finland-Austria10 Spain-Italy Spain-Italy Germany-France Germany-France11 Belgium-Austria Belgium-Austria Spain-Italy Belgium-Austria12 Germany-France Germany-France Belgium-Austria Spain-Italy13 France-Austria France-Austria France-Austria France-Austria14 Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium15 Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium16 France-Belgium France-Belgium France-Belgium France-Belgium

Rank VAR Quantile-VAR DCC-GARCH Gaussian-Copula DCC-GARCH t-Copula

1 Netherlands-Finland Netherlands-Finland Netherlands-Finland France-Finland2 France-Finland France-Finland France-Finland Netherlands-Finland3 Netherlands-France Netherlands-France Netherlands-France Netherlands-France4 Germany-Austria Germany-Austria Netherlands-Germany Netherlands-Germany5 Netherlands-Germany Netherlands-Germany Germany-Austria Germany-Austria6 Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria Netherlands-Austria7 Germany-Finland Germany-Finland Germany-Belgium Germany-Belgium8 Finland-Austria Finland-Austria Germany-Finland Germany-Finland9 Germany-Belgium Germany-Belgium Finland-Austria Finland-Austria10 Germany-France Belgium-Austria Germany-France Germany-France11 France-Austria Germany-France Belgium-Austria Belgium-Austria12 Belgium-Austria France-Austria France-Austria France-Austria13 Spain-Italy Spain-Italy Spain-Italy Spain-Italy14 Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium Netherlands-Belgium15 Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium Finland-Belgium16 France-Belgium France-Belgium France-Belgium France-Belgium

Notes: Estimation of the VAR(1) and Quantile-VAR(1) is based on the full sample. DCC-GARCH(1,1) Gaussian and t-copula averaged dynamicconditional correlation measures are used as alternative to VAR-based model connectedness measures. Finally, various TVP-VAR(1,2) results

are provided as robustness check to benchmark model. VAR-based results use a lag length of order 1 (BIC) and a 10-step-ahead forecast.

28

Page 31: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

Figure 1: Sovereign Bond Yields

Figure 2: Sovereign Bond Yield Changes

29

Page 32: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

Figure 3: Dynamic Total Connectedness

Notes: Results are based on a TVP-VAR(0.99,0.99) model with lag length of order 1 (BIC) and a 10-step-ahead forecast.

Figure 4: Net Total Directional Connectedness

Notes: The black areas represent the overlap of the dynamic total directional connectedness TO and FROM others. A positive net totalconnectedness is marked blue (TOi > FROMi) whereas a negative net total connectedness is marked yellow (TOi < FROMi). Results are based

on a TVP-VAR(0.99,0.99) with one lag.

30

Page 33: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

Figure 5: Net Pairwise Directional Connectedness

Notes: The black areas represent the overlap of the dynamic pairwise directional connectedness Germany transmits TO and receives FROM i. Apositive net pairwise connectedness is marked blue (TOGermany > FROMi) whereas a negative net total connectedness is marked yellow

(TOGermany < FROMi). Results are based on a TVP-VAR(0.99,0.99) with one lag.

Figure 6: Pairwise Connectedness Index

31

Page 34: EMU-Risk Synchronisation and Financial Fragility Through ...repec.port.ac.uk/EconFinance/PBSEconFin_2019_07.pdf · focus on dynamic connectedness (see, Diebold and Yılmaz, 2014)andfurtherintroduce

Figure 7: Forming Groups Based On Pairwise Connectedness Indices

Notes: Results are based on a TVP-VAR(0.99,0.99) model with lag length of order 1 (BIC) and a 10-step-ahead forecast.

32