economics project (4th sem)- srijan chakravorty

Upload: srijan-chakravorty

Post on 05-Apr-2018

231 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    1/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 1

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    SUBMITTED TO: MRS. SHIVANI MOHAN,

    FACULTY FOR ECONOMICS

    SUBMITTED BY: SRIJAN CHAKRAVORTY

    ROLL- 474

    B.A. LL.B (HONS.), 4TH

    SEMESTER

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    2/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 2

    TABLE OF CONTENTS

    1. ACKNOWLEDGEMENT.3

    2. RESEARCH METHODOLOGY..4

    3. INTRODUCTION ..... ...5

    4. TRADE POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT: A HISTORICAL

    OVERVIEW ..6

    5. RECENT TRENDS IN TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT IN DEVELOPING

    NATIONS10

    6. TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND THE MILLENIUM DEVELOPMENTGOALS..17

    7. CONCLUSIONS..24

    8. BIBLIOGRAPHY25

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    3/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 3

    ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

    I would like to take this opportunity to express my humble gratitude to

    the faculty of Economics, Mrs. Shivani Mohan for assigning such an

    interesting topic to me. I would also like to thank my parents for their

    support in encouraging me to work harder on this assignment. I would

    further extend my heartiest regards to the authors of the books and

    articles on the Internet which I have referred to in my project work as

    their information provided vital insights in the course of making the

    project.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    4/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 4

    RESEARCH METHODOLOGY

    AIMS AND OBJECTIVES:

    The aim of the project is to present an overview of Free Trade and

    Development through various writings and articles. The aim has been to

    identify the relationship between free trade and development and their

    relevance in the economic growth of a country.

    SCOPE:

    Though the study of Economics is an immense project and pages can be

    written over the topic but due to certain restrictions and limitations I was

    not able to deal with the topic in detail.

    SOURCES OF DATA:

    The following secondary sources of data have been used in the project-

    1. Websites

    2. Books

    METHOD OF WRITING:

    The method of writing followed in the course of this research paper is

    primarily analytical.

    MODE OF CITATION:

    The researcher has followed a uniform mode of citation throughout the

    course of this research paper.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    5/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 5

    INTRODUCTION

    One of the foremost challenges facing the world this century is dealing

    with the persistent problem of world poverty. A world in which a majority

    of the globes population lives in impoverished conditions is unacceptable.

    What Adam Smith, wrote in relation to a country applies to the world at

    large:

    No society can be flourishing and happy, of which the far greater part

    of the members are poor and miserable.1

    In past decades, various schemes have been proposed as the key to

    promoting economic growth and development: development aid,population control, capital accumulation and investment in heavy

    industry, and the like.2 Each of these schemes has failed to unlock the

    door to greater prosperity in the developing world. As a result, the search

    for a single universal measure that will stimulate economic growth has

    given way to the less ambitious, but more realistic, search for the

    combination of policies that tend to encourage, though not guarantee,

    economic development.

    One clear lesson from the past several decades, however, is that

    countries taking advantage of the tremendous expansion in world trade

    have also made substantial progress in promoting economic development

    and reducing poverty. Experience has shown that there are many

    different ways in which countries can take advantage of the opportunities

    provided by trade, but nearly all involve some liberalization of domestic

    trade policies. While trade liberalization often poses difficult political

    challenges to governments, the tangible economic payoff to countries that

    undertake such reforms makes it imperative that countries seriously

    consider moving forward with new policies.

    1The Wealth of The Nations (1776)

    2 See William Easterly, The Elusive Quest for Growth , Cambridge: MIT Press, 2001.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    6/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 6

    This paper reviews this link between trade and development. It

    provides an overview of the recent evidence on the relationship between

    trade and growth, trade and poverty reduction, and trade and income

    distribution. The aim is to provide the background context for tackling

    more specific issues, such as the agenda for trade negotiations in key

    sectors such as agriculture and services, and the role of the World Trade

    Organization in fostering the interests of developing countries.

    TRADE POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT: A HISTORICAL

    OVERVIEW

    One of the oldest and most important questions in all of economics is the

    relationship between a countrys trade policy and its economic

    development. Simple economic analysis informs us that international

    trade is not an end unto itself, but a means to an end, a vehicle for

    achieving a higher standard of living through the more effective use of

    national resources. If openness to trade helps improve economic

    conditions in developing countries, then the policy implications are

    relatively straightforward governments should pursue trade

    liberalization as part of a general framework of policies aimed at

    improving economic performance. Alternatively, if openness poses an

    obstacle to economic development or if there are important exceptions to

    free-trade rule, then certain restrictions on trade may prove beneficial

    and government regulations may be warranted.

    Economic theory can provide a framework for analyzing the

    relationship between trade and development, such as sorting out the

    various mechanisms by which one can affect the other, but theory does not

    offer guidance that is decisive when it comes to policy. In part, this is

    because of a tension between two alternative views of the impact of trade

    on development. The classical view, often associated with Adam Smith, is

    that free trade will lead to the most efficient use of a countrys resources

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    7/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 7

    and therefore yield the highest national income. Openness to trade

    improve economic performance by increasing competition and by giving

    domestic firms access to the best foreign technology, which can be

    adopted to raise domestic productivity. An alternative view, associated

    with the nineteenth century political economist Friedrich List, suggests

    that developing countries should protect their infant manufacturing

    industries from foreign competition to foster their growth and allow them

    to catch up to industrial leaders. This view suggests that government

    assistance to shift resources out of primary products and into

    manufacturing would promote economic development and prevent

    prolonged specialization in low value-added a ctivities.

    While economic theory provides a framework for thinking about

    these issues, the answer to the question of which trade regime best

    promotes economic development ultimately depends on empirical

    evidence: what have been the actual country experiences in terms of the

    impact of liberalization on economic performance?

    In the past, the answer given has not always been favorable to open

    trade policies. For example, economic historian Paul Bairoch and others

    have argued that Friedrich List was correct in the nineteenth century:

    countries with relatively low tariffs (such as the Britain) grew relatively

    slowly while other developing countries (such as the United States,

    Canada, and Argentina) imposed high tariffs and grew rapidly.3 For the

    period 1870 to 1913, high tariffs and economic growth rates are positively

    correlated.

    Yet more recent analysis suggests that this simple correlation does

    not support the conclusion that high tariffs were responsible for the rapid

    growth in those countries. Rather, countries that chose largely for fiscal

    reasons to impose high tariffs were also those with a high growth

    3 Ha-Joon Chang, Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical

    Perspective , London: Anthem Press, 2002

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    8/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 8

    potential (i.e., they had high land to labor ratios and were therefore

    magnets for foreign capital inflows and immigration). 4 The historical

    record suggests that tariffs were not critical and may have been

    counterproductive to these countries development. The United States

    overtook Britain in per capita income in the 1890s largely because of

    strong productivity performance in the (non-traded) service sector, not in

    manufacturing. Argentina and Canada were among the most rapidly

    growing countries around the turn of the century due in large part to a

    commodity-based export boom. Per capita income grew more rapidly in

    Malaya than in Japan in the early twentieth century, although Malaya did

    not industrialize while Japan did. Thus, the historical experience of the

    late nineteenth century suggests that there was a diversity of country

    experiences with respect to economic development, and that tariffs on

    imported manufactures were not the key to success.5

    The tension between the benign and the malign view of free trades

    impact of economic development persisted into the twentieth century. Yet

    the most influential thinking on trade and development from the 1930s

    through the 1960s was characterized by certain observations and

    assumptions that gave support to protectionist import substitution trade

    policies. The first assumption was that, because most developing

    countries were producers of primary products, these countries were poor

    because they produced primary products. Furthermo re, it was assumed

    that open trade policies would perpetuate the specialization of these

    countries in primary commodities, trapping them in the production of low

    value-added goods for which export demand was believed to be stagnant

    4 Precisely because labor was not densely populated, these countries relied on tariffs

    as a f iscal device to raise revenue, as other tax instruments ( land taxes, income taxes)

    were not feasible. Douglas A. Irwin, Interpreting the Tarif f-Growth Correlation of

    the Late Nineteenth Century, American Economic Review 91 (May 2002): 165-169.

    5 Douglas A. Irwin, Tariffs and Growth in Late Nineteenth Century America, The

    World Economy 24 (January 2001): 15 -30

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    9/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 9

    (export pessimism). Observing that developed countries often had much

    larger manufacturing sectors, developing countries sought to mimic this

    mix by subsidizing industry and taxing agricultural and primary activities.

    Thus, industrialization with a stress on capital accumulation andmanufacturing was believed to be the key to economic growth and

    development. Many policymakers therefore concluded that import

    substitution protecting domestic manufacturers from import

    competition would be the best trade and development strategy. As the

    one-time chief economist for the World Bank, Hollis Chenery, once stated,

    industrialization consists primarily in the substitution of domestic

    production of manufact ured goods for imp orts.6

    The ideas behind the inward oriented development approach

    justified government interference with trade, but did not lay out specific

    blueprints for policy. And the actual policies pursued in the name of

    import substitution proved to be less coherent than the theory. In many

    cases, the degree of protection given to domestic industry was high and

    idiosyncratic across sectors. Trade barriers served to shelter relatively

    inefficient industries from competition, not promote the growth of infant

    industries. The trade restrictions implicitly involved substantial

    discrimination against exports. As a result, import substitution

    constrained the ability of domestic firms to take advantage of the

    opportunities presented by the world market and, consequently, the payoff

    of import substitution policies in terms of economic growth and

    development was disappointing. 7

    6 see Anne O. Krueger, Trade Policy and Economic Development: How We Learn .

    American Economic Review 87 (March 1997), pp. 1 -22.

    7 6 Ian Little, Tibor Scitovsky, Maurice Scott , Industry and Trade in Some

    Developing Countries: A Comparative Study , New York, Published for the

    Development Centre of the OECD by Oxford University Press, 1970.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    10/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 10

    A major change in the assumptions underlying the imp ort

    substitution view of the world resulted from the economic success of

    several East Asian countries, South Korea, Taiwan, and Hong Kong among

    them, in the 1970s. These countries were very poor in the 1950s, but

    chose an outward or export-oriented development path. They

    demonstrated that developing countries open to trade did not necessarily

    have to remain primary products producers, but could gain a niche in

    producing labor-intensive manufactured goods and see their exports grow

    rapidly. The rapid growth in trade came along with rapid rate of economic

    growth, with associated reductions in poverty, malnutrition, infant

    mortality, and other indices of well-being.

    The achievements of these countries, in contrast to the

    disappointments associated with import substitution, put new and

    favorable light on the economic benefits accompanying economic reforms

    and trade liberalization. While there continues to be a debate about the

    degree to which East Asian countries did or did not implement industrial

    policies, there is no doubt that openness to trade was an important factor

    behind their economic success. The trade to GDP ratios of these co untries

    rose significantly over this period. These countries may not have all

    adopted laissez-faire policies with regard to industry, but they did allow

    the free world market to dictate to a large degree the success or failure of

    domestic industries.8

    The East Asian experience undermined the export pessimism of

    earlier decades and gave rise to a new appreciation for the gains from

    trade, both importing foreign goods and technology, and the possibilities

    of exporting a new range of goods. As a result of a changing intellectual

    climate and the demonstration effect of the East Asian countries, more

    8 See Marcus Noland and Howard Pack, Industrial Policy in an Era of Globali zation:

    Lessons From Asia , Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, March

    2003

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    11/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 11

    countries began experimenting with trade liberalization and economic

    openness in the 1970s and 1980s. How have these experiments fared?

    RECENT TRENDS IN TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT IN

    DEVELOPING NATIONS

    As the previous section indicated, there are good reasons for believing

    that openness to trade can help the development process of poor

    countries. But before countries are advised to undertake significant

    changes in their trade regime, clear empirical evidence that greater

    integration with the world economy will produce economic benefits must

    be presented. The past several decades has been a period of rapid global

    economic integration in which countries have chosen a v ariety of different

    policies. This period provides a testing ground for answering the question

    posed earlier: under which set of trade policies have countries performed

    best? How has openness to trade affected economic growth, poverty

    reduction, income inequality, technological progress, and the like?

    Over the past decade, dozens of studies have sifted through the link

    between trade openness and economic performance evidence. The

    evidence strongly suggests that more open countries, and countries

    choosing to liberalize their trade policies, reap tangible economic

    benefits.

    The study by Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Warner (1995) has been the

    starting point for many recent studies on trade openness and economic

    growth. They divided countries into two simple categories, open and

    closed, based on various indicators of import tariffs, export policy, blackmarket exchange rate premia, etc. They found that per capita income in

    open economies grew, on average, over 2 percentage points more rapidly

    than in closed economies between 1970 and 1989. This is an astoundingly

    large figure, and suggests that the gains from more open policies are

    enormous.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    12/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 12

    However, the Sachs and Warner study has been subjected to several

    important criticisms. First, Rodriguez and Rodrik (2000) noted that the

    statistical results came mainly from the black market premium, an

    indicator of macroeconomic dysfunction, and not the trade policy

    variables. Furthermore, they found that the results on openness were not

    robust to the inclusion of other geographic variables, such regional

    dummy variables and distance from the equator. Second, Wacziarg and

    Welch (2002) reexamined the Sachs-Warner analysis using data for the

    more recent period 1990-1999 and found a much weaker relationship

    between the openness dummy variable and growth over that period. In

    other words, while the Sachs-Warner dummy variable effectively

    partitioned fast growing countries from slow growing ones in the 1980s, it

    failed to do so in the 1990s.

    As Wacziarg and Welch (2002) noted, however, a better way of estimating

    the effect of openness on growth is to examine the within-country impact

    of discrete changes in trade policy openness. They formulated openness

    indicators based on the date at which individual countries liberalized

    their import policies. Studying a panel of countries over the period 1950

    to 1998, they found that the within-country difference in growth between

    a liberalized and a non-liberalized regime is +1.5 percentage points, on

    average, controlling for country and year effects. Because trade reforms

    sometimes occur during periods of macroeconomic instability, the authors

    exclude the three years surrounding the reform and fou nd similar results.

    Broad cross-country empirical studies such as these are useful for

    highlighting general tendencies and relationships between trade and

    development over the past several decades. Although questions of

    measurement, statistical specification, and interpretation can be posed of

    each individual study, the general conclusion is uniform: openness to

    trade is associated with higher incomes and better economic

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    13/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 13

    performance.9 There may be some doubts about the magnitude and the

    strength of that finding, but the direction of effect is not in doubt. No

    study of recent experience has concluded that closed or isolated

    economies perform better than those integrated into the world economy.

    The cross-country empirical studies, however, fail to dramatize the

    importance of policy changes on economic outcomes in specific instances.

    A complementary approach is to focus on individual cases to see if the

    results are consistent with the broader dat a analysis.

    In fact, the recent experiences of the two largest developing

    countries, China and India, support the findings of the cross-country

    studies. Each with a population of over 1 billion, these countries sharply

    changed their trade policies at different points in time: China abolished

    the governments monopoly on foreign trade in 1978, while India

    undertook tentative moves to liberalize imports of capital goods in the

    mid-1980s and then drastically revised its vast and arcane import

    licensing process in 1991. While neither country immediately adopted

    free trade policies, they did open up their economies to world trade in a

    sharp and distinct way.

    For both China and India, the results have been astounding. In both

    countries, the expansion of trade both exports and imports has been

    very rapid over the past decade. This rapid growth in trade has been

    accompanied by much faster rates of economic growth. In the twenty

    years after 1980, real GDP grew at an average annual rate of 10 percent in

    China and 6 percent in India. No other country grew as rapidly as China,

    whereas fewer than ten other countries grew mo re rapidly than India.9

    9 One study therefore used dozens of statistical specifications to examine the l ink

    between trade pol icy indicators and the level of per capita income. More open trade

    policies are invariably associated with higher per capita income, although the

    magnitude and significance of the relationship varied considerably. Jones (2001).

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    14/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 14

    This rapid growth has translated into material improvements in the

    standard of living of these countries. For example, higher incomes have

    meant a sharp reduction in poverty. According to government statistics,

    the incidence of poverty fell from 28 percent in 1978 to 9 percent in 1998

    in China, and from 51 percent in 1977 to 27 percent 1999 in India.10

    The demonstration effect of the Chinese and Indian experience is

    perhaps even more profound than that of the earlier East Asian

    experience. Here we have two of the most populous and poorest countries

    in the world, with completely different political systems (a single party

    communist state and a multiparty representative democracy), which for

    decades pursued inward-oriented economic policies, suddenly changing

    the direction of trade policy. The change in course was followed by

    dramatic increases in foreign trade and economic activity. As a result,

    both countries have succeeded in moving mi llions of people above the

    poverty line. These are astounding and monumental achievements.

    China and India did not follow the same economic policy blueprint,

    but took advantage of their different attributes to opening to the world

    market. China has welcomed foreign investment in labor -intensive

    sectors, while India shares a comparative advantage in labor-intensive

    manufactures and skill-intensive services, such as the software industry

    around Bangalore. Unlike the earlier East Asian experience, neither

    country is known for wise industrial policies that manipulated resource

    allocation in a way often alleged to be the case elsewhere in Asia.

    Of course, the tremendous economic payoff to China and India

    resulted from their starting far behind the technological frontier with

    highly distorted trade policies. Countries closer to the frontier with lower

    trade barriers will not reap as enormous benefits as these countries, but

    10 On India, see T. N. Srinivasan and Suresh D. Tendulkar, Reintegrati ng India with

    the World Economy , Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, March

    2003.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    15/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 15

    many millions of people live in countries just as poor and China and India

    once were.

    How it is possible that trade liberalization can provide such

    substantial benefits? Recent studies have isolated two particular channelsby which openness is related to higher incomes: one is through greater

    investment, and the other is through higher productivity.11

    Empirical research has uncovered an indirect link between trade and

    growth: the share of investment in GDP is positively correlated with

    growth in per capita income, and trade is positively correlated with

    investment. This means that while trade may not be directly correlated

    with growth, it might stimulate growth indirectly through investment.12

    Over the 1950 to 1998 time period, Wacziarg and Welch (2002) found that

    within-country capital investment as a percent of GDP is 1.9 percentage

    points higher in a liberalized regime than in a non-liberalized regime.

    Trade policies that increase the domestic relative price of imported

    capital goods are harmful to investment and therefore to growth as well.

    Tariffs and other trade barriers that raise the domestic price of capital

    goods means that each investment dollar buys less capital, reducing the

    efficiency of investment spending. Empirical evidence tends to support

    the idea that the free importation of intermediate and capital goods is an

    effective way of promoting inve stments that increase growth.13

    In addition, trade contributes to productivity growth in at least two

    ways: it serves as a conduit for the transfer of foreign technologies that

    11

    Of course, the two can be related: higher investment ( in capital goods, for example)can lead to higher productivity.

    12 Levine and Renalt (1992).

    13 See, for example, Wacziarg (2001). Lee (1995) finds that the ratio of imported to

    domestically produced capital goods is significantly related to growth in per capita

    income, particularly in developing countries, and Mazumdar (2001) reaches a similar

    conclusion.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    16/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 16

    enhance productivity, and it increases competition in a way that

    stimulates industries to become more efficient and improve their

    productivity. The first channel, that trade serves as a conduit for the

    transfer of foreign technologies, operates in several ways. One is through

    the importation of capital goods. Imported capital goods that embody

    technological advances can greatly enhance an economys productivity.

    To the extent that trade barriers raise the price of imported capital goods,

    countries are hindering their ability to benefit from technologies that

    could raise productivity. 14

    The second channel by which trade contributes to productivity is by

    forcing domestic industries to become more efficient. Trade increases

    competition in the domestic market, diminishing the market power of any

    firm and forcing them to behave more competitively. Competition also

    stimulates firms to improve their efficiency, otherwise they risk going out

    of business. Over the past decade, study after study has documented this

    phenomena. After the Cte dIvoire reformed its trade policies in 1985,

    overall productivity growth tripled, growing four times more rapidly in

    industries that became less sheltered from foreign competition. Another

    study examined industry productivity in Mexico before and after its trade

    liberalization in 1985 and found that productivity increased significantly,

    especially in traded goods sectors. Detailed studies of Indias trade

    14 Productivity advances are usually the result of investment in research and

    development (R&D), and the importation of foreign ideas can be an important source

    of productivity improvement. Sometimes foreign research can be imported directly.

    For example, China has long been struggling against a devastating disease known as

    rice blast. The disease had destroyed mill ions of tons of rice a year, costing farmersbil l ions of dollars. Recent ly, under the direct ion of an internat ional team of

    scientists, farmers in Chinas Yunnan province started planting a mixture of two

    different types of rice in the same paddy. By this simple technique of bio-diversity,

    farmers nearly eliminated rice blast and doubled their yield. Foreign R&D enabled the

    Chinese farmers to abandon the use of chemical fungicides that had been used to fight

    the disease and increase yields of a critical staple commodity. Yoon (2000).

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    17/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 17

    liberalization in 1991 and Koreas trade liberalization in the 1980s reached

    essentially the same conclusion: trade not only disciplines domestic firms

    and forces them to behave more like a competitive industry, but helps

    increase the productivity of domestic firms.15 And the higher is an

    economys productivity level, the higher is that countrys standard of

    living.

    Many developing countries fear that trade liberalization will force

    painful adjustments on their manufacturing sector or even de-

    industrialize the country. Yet both China and India have not de-

    industrialized as a result of openness to trade. While some

    manufacturing firms will be forced to close or consolidate as a result of

    import competition, increased trade allows developing countries the

    opportunity to exploit their strong comparative advantage in producing

    labor intensive manufactures. Often exports from other ma nufacturing

    industry depend on access to inexpensive and quality industrial inputs,

    obtainable on the world market, so that import liberalization can promote

    exports in other sectors. For example, although New Zealand has a strong

    comparative advantage in agricultural goods, the reduction in trade

    barriers in the mid-1980s resulted more in a reallocation of resources

    between manufacturing plants the shutdown of inefficient plants and

    the expansion of relatively efficient ones, in a way that served to raise

    average industry productivity rather than a reallocation of resources

    between sectors.

    TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND THE MILLENIUM

    DEVELOPMENT GOALS

    The higher income levels or growth rates that accompany trade

    liberalization are critical to achieving important development objectives.

    15 See the studies by Harrison (1994). Tybout and Westbrook (1995). Kim (2000) and

    Krishna and Mitra (1998).

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    18/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 18

    The United Nationss Millennium Development Goals, 1990-2015 include,

    among other goals, to:

    eradicate extreme hunger and poverty provide universal primary education reduce child mortality improve material health

    All of these goals are promoted by the greater income that results from

    economic policy reforms.

    Poverty and Income Distribution:

    Economic growth is essential for poverty reduction. As Figure 1 shows,

    rapidly growing countries such as China and India have seen sharp

    reductions in poverty rates.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    19/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 19

    Although this link is clear, many observers worry about the impact of

    trade liberalization and economic growth on income distribution. In some

    sense, worries about income distribution miss the point of focusing on the

    absolute well-being of the poor. If a policy raises income the income of

    the rich 20 percent but that of the poor only 10 percent, it does not makesense to forego the policy and do nothing merely because the gains accrue

    disproportionately to the rich even as it helps lift the poor from dire

    poverty.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    20/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 20

    Evidence suggests, however, that growth is roughly neutral in its effect on

    the distribution of income within a country. The percentage changes in

    incomes of the poor are equal on average to percentage changes in average

    income; in other words, the share of income that accrues to the poor is not

    systematically associated with the growth rate (Dollar and Kray 2001).

    Other evidence from China points to that cities that experience a greater

    degree of openness in trade also tend to see a greater decline in urban-

    rural income inequality, i.e., trade may help reduce, rather than increase,

    the urban-rural income inequality (Wei and Wu 2001). This pattern in the

    data suggests that inferences based solely on China's national aggregate

    figures (overall openness and overall inequality) can be misleading.

    Indeed, data on the distribution of income are extremely hazardous to

    work with because of different concepts of that distribution. Some studies

    examine inequality between households, others between regions and

    countries.

    A frequently mentioned concern is that trade l iberaliz ation or an open

    system of world trade may exacerbate world income inequality. Many

    observers are disturbed by trends in the world distribution of income. But

    whether there has been a divergence or co nvergence of world inco mes

    depends largely upon the approach taken by various studies. Three

    conceptual approaches have been taken. The first compares the

    unweighted average of incomes across countries. The second compares

    the population-weighted average of incomes across countries. The third

    ignores national boundaries and examines income inequality between all

    the worlds citizens.

    Most studies examining average incomes across countries finds that those

    incomes have diverged. However, in these studies, each country

    constitutes a unique observation, giving Trinidad and Tobago (population

    1.3 million) the same weight as China (population 1.3 billion). Most

    studies examining population-weighted average incomes across countries

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    21/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 21

    finds that income inequality has been reduced in recent decades. This is

    primarily because a few, large countries (notably China and India) have

    been growing more rapidly than other countries. One cannot ignore the

    improvement in absolute and relative well-being of nearly 2 billion people

    in these countries alone.

    The final set of studies examines inequality among the world population,

    ignoring country borders (i.e., individuals rather than countries are the

    unit of observation). These studies tend to be relatively recent but also

    tend to suggest no trend toward greater inequality.

    Surjit Bhalla (2002, p. 205) summarizes the issue as follows:

    While the average poor country may be losing ground (the divergence

    literature), the average person in a poor country is gaining ground

    because her income is increasing at a faster rate than the income of the

    average rich person in a rich country. This is the result of several big,

    poor countries doing very well the giants, China and India, and also

    Indonesia and Vietnam. . . . the conclusion that the world is becoming

    more equal must be accepted if one believes that there are more than 1

    billion people in China and that their incomes are rising at a faster rate

    than the average.

    Child Labor and Schooling

    Economic growth also helps reduce child labor. Figure 2 plots the

    relationship between per capita income and the incidence of child labor

    and shows an unmistakable relationship.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    22/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 22

    As an example, per capita inco me in Vietnam grew at an annual rate of

    nearly 7 percent between 1993 and 1997, after the country adopted

    economic reforms. During this same period, the incidence of child labordeclined 28 percent. Recent studies have shown that 80 percent of the

    decline in child labor in households that move from below to above the

    poverty line is due to increases in the standard of living. In addition,

    such increases in the standard of living can be linked specifically to trade

    liberalization. After 1993, the relaxation of Vietnams export quota on

    rice contributed to an increase in the real domestic price of rice of nearly

    30 percent. The greater integration of Vietnamese rice farmers with the

    world market contributed to a rise in domes tic income that allowed those

    farmers to reduce the use of child labor.16 Reducing the disincentives on

    16 Eric Edmonds, Will Child Labor Decline with Improvements in Living Standards?

    Working paper, Dartmouth College , November 2002. Eric Edmonds and Nina Pavcnik,

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    23/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 23

    agricultural exports helps raise rural incomes and helps alleviate poverty,

    and thereby the employment of child l abor.

    Health

    It has long been recognized that wealthier is healthier, that the benefits

    of higher income are strong in terms of reducing infant mortality and

    raising life expectancy. 17 Higher income households can afford medicines

    and better health care, better nutrition and diets as well as better housing,

    all of which benefit health status.

    Some remarkable recent results point to a negative association between

    tariff levels and life expectancy and a negative association between tariffs

    and infant mortality. According to the results, an el even percentage point

    increase in tariffs (approximately equal to a one standard deviation of the

    change in tariffs over a five year period) is associated with a decline in l ife

    expectancy of 1.3 years and an increase in infant mortality of 6 per 1,000

    births.18 This statistical correlation survives even after controlling for per

    capita income and other factors (such as schooling and number of doctors

    per capita), suggesting that openness to trade may be beneficial for these

    outcomes for reasons that go beyond any indirect effect through raising

    income.

    In sum, the payoff of higher income is directly measurable in terms of le ss

    poverty, less infant mortality, less malnutrition, less child labor, and

    longer and better lives. Trade may not directly affect these outcomes, but

    indirectly contributes to these vital development goals by leading to

    higher income.

    Does Globalization Increase Child Labor? Evidence from Vietnam, NBER Working

    Paper No. Xxxx, January 14, 2002.

    17 Lant Pritchett and Lawrence H. Summers, Wealthier Is Healthier, Journal of

    Human Resources 31 (Fall 1996), pp. 841-68.

    18 Shang-j in Wei and Yi Wu, The Life-and-Death Implications of Globalization,

    unpublished paper, International Monetary Fund, December 2002.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    24/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY Page 24

    CONCLUSIONS

    Economists know more about what can destroy economic growth and

    activity than what creates it. However, countries that have found a way to

    take advantage of the rapid growth in world trade have generally found it

    to be an escalator out of poverty.

    Yet many developing countries remain suspicious of freer trade.19 In

    addition, many politically powerful groups in developing countries have

    vested interests in the status quo and therefore oppose efforts to liberalize

    and open up the economy. But as the former Director General of the

    WTO, Mike Moore (p. 173), has noted:

    More and more, developing countries have come to see protectionism as

    a self-inflicted wound. It not only punishes consumers, grossly inflating

    the price they pay for necessities like food or clothing, but it also

    handicaps exporters and entrepreneurs, who cant hope to compete on

    world markets without access to world-priced inputs, efficient services

    and modern technology.

    The evidence from countries as diverse as South Korea and Chile, Chinaand India, Vietnam and Uganda, confirms that protectionism is indeed a

    self-inflicted wound. The opportunity to take part in the tremendous

    expansion of world trade is one that leads to tangible economic benefits.

    Once dire economic conditions in those countries are now improving.

    Trade reform has played an important role in helping mill ions of people to

    see a better world.

    19 It is sometimes difficult for sophisticated e conomists and politicians to understand

    the deep historic and cultural problems some countries have with the idea of free

    trade. Some sti l l equate it with their oppression from colonial days. Mike Moore, A

    World Without Walls: Freedom, Development, Free Trade, and Global Governance ,

    Oxford University Press, 2003, p. 133.

  • 8/2/2019 Economics Project (4th Sem)- Srijan Chakravorty

    25/25

    FREE TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT

    CHANAKYA NATIONAL LAW UNIVERSITY P 25

    BIBLIOGRAPHY

    BOOKS REFERRED: Aksoy, A. and G. Salinas (2006); Growth Before and After

    Trade Liberalisation.

    Santos-Paulino, A.O. (2005), Trade Liberalisation andEconomi c Performance : Theory and Evidence for Developing

    Countries.

    Das., B.L. (2005), The Current Negotiations in the WTO:Options, Opportunities and Risks for Developing Countries ,

    Zed Books/ TWN Press

    NEWSPAPERS AND MAGAZINES REFERRED: India Today The Outlook The World Economy The Economic Times The Economist

    ONLINE JOURNALS: Manupatra Hein Online Westlaw International