economic review: fall 1989, number 4 - fraser · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from...

53
Economic Review Federal Reserve Bank of San. Francisco Fall 1989 Number 4 Ronald H. Schmidt John P. Judd and Bharat Trehan James A. Wilcox Natural Resources and Regional Growth Unemployment-Rate Dynamics: Aggregate- Demand and -Supply Interactions Liquidity Constraints on Consumption: The Real Effects of "Real" Lending Policies

Upload: others

Post on 10-Jun-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

EconomicReviewFederal Reserve Bankof San. Francisco

Fall 1989 Number 4

Ronald H. Schmidt

John P. Judd andBharat Trehan

James A. Wilcox

Natural Resources and Regional Growth

Unemployment-Rate Dynamics:Aggregate-Demand and-Supply Interactions

Liquidity Constraints on Consumption:The Real Effects of "Real" Lending Policies

Page 2: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

Natural Resources and Regional G row th........................................................................... 3Ronald H. Schmidt

Unemployment-Rate Dynamics:Aggregate-Demand and-Supply Interactions ...........................................................................................................20John P. Judd and Bharat Trehan

Liquidity Constraints on Consumption:The Real Effects o f 6‘Real” Lending P olicies.................................................................. 39James A. Wilcox

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 1

Page 3: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

Opinions expressed in the Economic Review do not neces­sarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research Department under the supervision of Jack H. Beebe, Senior Vice President and Director of Research. The publication is edited by Barbara A. Bennett. Design, production, and distribution are handled by the Public Information Department, with the assistance of Karen Rusk and William Rosenthal.

For free copies of this and other Federal Reserve publicatons, write or phone the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, PO. Box 7702, San Francisco, California 94120. Phone (415) 974-2163.

2 Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 4: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

Natural Resources and Regional Growth

Ronald H. Schmidt

Senior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of San Fran­cisco. The author would like to thank Stephen O. Dean forhis assistance. Editorial committee members were AdrianThroop, Carolyn Sherwood-Call, and Gary Zimmerman.

Evidence from the Gross State Product data suggeststhat natural resource-dependent states out-performedless resource-dependent states over the 1964-86 period.Closer examination, however, suggests that the gainslargely were due to an increase in wealth associatedwith positive resource-price shocks during the period.Interestingly, unlike the Dutch disease problem of theinternational literature, the non-resource industries ofresource-dependent states were theprincipal beneficiariesoffavorable natural resource price shocks.

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

What is the relationship between a state's dependence onnatural resource production and its economic perform­ance? Can differential growth rates of state economies betraced in part to differences in their dependence on agricul­ture, forestry, mining, and energy?

Past studies have provided mixed evidence on the rela­tionship between natural resources and relative economicperformance. The international literature has documentedcases where dependence on natural resources has haddetrimental side-effects on the economic structure of thosecountries. Moreover, the boom-bust cycle of mining townsoffers evidence of the potentially ephemeral nature ofnatural resource industries. In contrast, however, othercases explicitly have linked spurts of economic growth tonatural resource industry stimulus.

The purpose of this article is to address the linkagesbetween a region's natural resource dependence and itseconomic performance using information from the GrossState Product (GSP) data prepared by the U.S. Bureau ofEconomic Analysis. These data, which offer relativelyconsistent information on the value added by each majorindustry in each state, allow some cross-state comparisonsover the period from 1964 to 1986.

Using descriptive statistics from the data, the relativeeconomic growth of resource-dependent states is com­pared to that of less dependent states. In general, theresults show that resource-dependent states, particularlyenergy and mining states, had economies that grew morerapidly than average over the period, although they hadgreater variance around their trend growth rates as well.The evidence suggests, moreover, that the relative gainswere more likely a result of strong price movements thatgenerated significant wealth effects, rather than a resultof intrinsic advantages associated with natural resourceproduction.

The data also indicate that the "Dutch disease" problemcited in the international literature may not apply toregional economies. The "Dutch disease" refers to theeffects of a sharp increase in world natural resource priceson a resource-dependent economy. The resource priceincrease can cause the resource-dependent economy's cur­rency to appreciate, making its other commodities lesscompetitive on world markets. As a result, a resource price

3

Page 5: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

increase can work to the detriment of non-resource in­dustries.

At the regional level, the exchange rate effect is notpresent because ofa.common currency, but the increaseddemand for factors from the resource sector can bid upcosts of those factors in the region and make its otheroutputs less competitive with those of other regions.Results from the state-level data, however, indicate thatcontrary to the Dutch disease problem, non-resourceindustries were the principal beneficiaries of resource

price shocks. The price shocks apparently stimulated non­resource production even more than resource production.

Differences in resource endowments across states aredescribed in the first sectionofthis article, followed in thesecond sectionbyanexamination oithe variety ofchannelsthrough which natural resource dependence might affectthe level, growth, and structure of a state's economy. Thethird and fourth sections present empirical findings. Con­clusions are then presented in the fifth section.

I. Differences in Natural Resource Dependence

In this section the degree to which natural resourceproduction varies across states is documented using GSPdata. These data, released in 1988for the first time, providea measure of the value added annually by each majorindustrial grouping for the period from 1963 to 1986, andgenerally provide a better measure of activity than do theincome or employment data.'

Each state's share of national output, both for the totaleconomyand by resource industry, are shown in Table 1for1986. The first column presents each state's share of totalnational output (the latter being the sum of state GSPacross states). The second column gives the share ofnational natural resource output, comprising agriculture,forestry and lumber, mining, and energy, that is contrib­uted by each state.? By comparing these two columns, it isclear that the states' shares of natural resource output

differ from their contributions to total output. Twentystates can be categorized as relatively dependent on naturalresource production, in the sense that they contributed alarger proportion of total national natural resource produc­tion than would be predicted by their share of nationaloutput.

As shown in the table, the distribution of resourceproduction is highly skewed across states and across re­sources. Rhode Island contributes only 0.05 percent oftotal natural resource production, while Texas provides20.78 percent. The top 10 states in each natural resourcesubcategory, respectively, account for 50.4 percent of U.S.agricultural production, 54.8 percent of the nation's for­estry and lumber, 56.9 percent of mineral mining, and84.7 percent of national energy extraction. 3

4

Percent

50

40

30

20

10

o

Chart 1Resource Share of Total Gross State Product

EconomicReview / Fall 1989

Page 6: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 5

Page 7: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

The information in Table 1 does not account for dif­ferences in the sizes of states' economies. Such a com­parison is presented in Chart 1. Resource industry shares oftotal state asp are calculated using averages from the1964-86 period. As can be seen by comparing the chart,which has shares of state output, with Table 1, whichreports shares of national output, differences in nationalnatural resource production shares have been translatedinto differences in concentration in resource production.The uneven dispersion of resources across states has re­sulted in differences in reliance on natural resource indus­tries. Resource dependence, as measured by the share ofreal asp accounted for by the resource industries, varieswidely across states and across resources. As shown inChart 1, the average share of real asp contributed byresource industries (agriculture, forestry and fisheries,mining, and fuel mining) over the period 1964-86 rangedfrom virtually zero in Rhode Island to nearly 50 percent inWyoming.

The composition of resource endowments varies signifi­cantly across states as well. As shown in charts 2 through5, the states with the largest shares of asp in each resourceare different across resources, with little overlap betweenagricultural states and mining states.

The magnitude of dependence on resources variesacross resources as well as across states. Among theresource-dependent states, energy stands out as the mostdominant single source of resource output. The top six

energy-dependent states have between 20 and 40 percent oftheir gross state product originating in the energy sector.Agriculture also plays a major role in. the agriculture­dependent states, with five states reporting an average of10 to 20 percent of their asp from agricultural production.

Incontrast, mining and forestry play less dominant roleseven in the states with the highest concentrations of thoseactivities. Lumber and wood products account for less thanfive percent of output in all states except Oregon, whilemining accounts for less than four percent of total outputeven in the states with the highest concentrations of miningoutput. (Mining in this article refers to non-energy mining;coal, oil, and natural gas outputs are combined to form theenergy category.)

These figures, however, may understate the importanceof the natural resource industries to state economies,particularly in the short run. For example, according to the1977 California input-output model, agriculture has amultiplier of 3.2 in the economy, suggesting that a 10percent increase in agricultural output generates a 32percent increase in aggregate output through the associ­ated increase in demand for inputs, processing, marketing,transporting, and retailing (State of California, 1980.)Because such measures tend to assume that these factorscould not be shifted to other uses, however, the multipliereffects tend to overstate the importance of resource in­dustries."

Percent

20

15

Chart 2Agriculture Share of Total Gross State Product

6

10

5

o

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 8: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

II. Natural Resources and Production

These differences in resource endowments can be ex­pected to result in different economic orientations, andthereby to affect the level of activity and the rate of growthof regional economies. In this section, several strands ofthe literature are summarized to shed some light on theeffects that a natural resource orientation can have ondifferent regional economies.

Comparative Advantage

The most obvious effect of differential endowments ofnatural resources is that states with large shares of aparticular resource specialize in the production of thatresource. This result displays the basic concept of com­parative advantage laid out in the Heckser-Ohlin theoremin the international trade literature. Regions (or countries)with different factor proportions can generate higher totaloutput and consumption by specializing in the productionof commodities in which they havea relative abundance ofthe needed inputs. Totaloutput is maximized whenregionsspecialize in the production of commodities that bestreflect the area's relative resource mix (its comparativeadvantage) and then trade with areas that have a compara­tive advantage in producing other goods. Consequently,regions with abundant natural resources would be ex­pected to specialize in natural resource-intensive produc­tion, using resource outputs to trade for non-resourcecommodities from other regions.

In the regional economics literature, differences innatural resource endowments are important in explainingdifferent regional production processes. If all regions hadidentical resource endowments, there would be little rea­son to expect specialization across regions. In fact, dif­ferences in resource production and therefore, in industrymix across states, have led to different responses to tech­nology or price shocks. A recent study by Cox and Hill(1988), for example, predicts the differential incidence ofexchange-rate shocks at the state level by taking intoaccount industry-mix characteristics and the relative trade­sensitivity of those sectors. Similar research has examinedthe differential regional effect of oil price shocks. Thesestudies explicitly assume that differences in factor endow­ments promote different productive processes and outputs,and hence, expose regional economies to different externalforces.

Levels vs. Growth Rates

While the principle of comparative advantage predictsthat differences in resource endowments would affect thecomposition of output across regions, natural resourcesalso may be key factors determining both the level and rateof growth of regional economies.

In the case of natural resources, the answer to thequestion "is more better?" seems obvious at first glance.From the standpoint of an economy, being resource-rich

Chart 3Lumber Share of Total Gross State Product

Percent10

8

6

4

2

o

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 7

Page 9: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

increases productivity. Abundant natural resources lowerthe cost of certain inputs, enhancing the competitivenessof resource-intensive production.

Simpleproduction-function models of aneconomy sug­gest that the level of output is a direct function of theresource base. As long as some factor substitution ispossible, an abundance of a given resource boosts totaloutput.

Theeffect of theresource stock on the. rate of growth islessdear. Natural resources could.increase .the rate.ofgrowth of aneconomy if theresource stock grew overtime,or if the "effective stock" (that is, the actual stock ad­justedforchanges in thatstock'sproductivity) were toriseovertimebecause of technological efficiency gains. Con­versely, natural resources couldcausetherateofgrowth toslow, if increasing scarcity of the natural resources con­strained the growth of related sectors.

Consequently, theory suggests that a higher stock of anatural resource should raise the level of activity, but theeffecton therateofgrowth depends inpartonthedegree towhich natural resource production expands andspurs otherindustries to develop. As shown in the remainder of thissection, theoretical evidence on the extent to which re­sources spur growth is not conclusive.

Agglomeration Effects vs. Boom Towns

The classic model highlighting the role of natural re­sources as a stimulus for regional economic growth wasdeveloped by North (1955). In North's export-base model,

natural resources are viewed as a driving force for eco­nomic growth, modeled along thelinesofeconomic devel­opment in theUnited States. Earlysettlers to a regionoftenare attractedby theeconomic potential of thatarea, whichtypically includes its natural resources. Trappers wereattracted to thewestern areas by available wildlife popula­tions ..Farmers were attracted to the Midwest andWest byavailable low-cost land. Miners were attracted to thewestern states by discoveries of gold andsilver. Loggerswere attracted to thePacific North",estandupperMid\Vestby available supplies of timber. Discoveries of massive oilreserves brought an influx of people to Texas.

In many parts of .the country,therefore, economicgrowth was either initiated or boosted by the influx ofpeople seeking to use natural resources. Accordingly,exports of natural resource products to other regions andcountries became important in the early development ofregional economies.

In the export-base literature, thecreation of exportablecommodities shapes a region's economy and spurs furthergrowth. As production of the resource increases, risingwages and returns to capital encourage the migration ofproductive factors from otherregions (Borts [1960], Bortsand Stein [1964], and Schmidt [1985]). Population risesbecause of immigration, and export earnings and invest­mentallow the capital stockto grow.

In theearlystages, this investment is closely tiedto theresource sector. Processing and transportation facilitiesdevelop, along with services to support theresource indus­try's employees and production.

Percent4

3

Chart 4Mining Share of Total Gross State Product

8 Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 10: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

Over time, however, other industries not directly tied toresource production develop to take advantage of thegrowing economic and social infrastructures. Moreover,firms that initially support resource industries diversifyinto other products. For example, Texas Instruments beganas a company manufacturing seismic equipment for oildrilling. As the company grew, it expanded into otherelectronic instruments. Today, equipment for the oil indus­try is only a small part of the company's sales.

Natural resources, therefore, can be a primary source ofearly development, followed by diversification of the econ­omy into other fields not tied to an area's natural resources.But as evidenced by boom towns, natural resources are notalways a source of lasting growth. In the case of extractiveor nonrenewable natural resources, the extent to which aregion diversifies into non-resource production may deter­mine the sustainability of its economic growth. In manycases, natural resource booms have led to temporarygrowth, followed by decline. This idiosyncratic relation­ship between growth and natural resources has been de­scribed by economic historian Jonathan Hughes in thefollowing way:

Apart from agriculture, no doubt the best known cause ofincreased economic growth in the past came from thediscovery and exploitation of natural resources. The ghosttowns of the Rockies and the capped oil and gas wells of[the oil states] are witness to the fragile tenure of economicgrowth from such sources. Exploitation growth via nonre­producible natural resources usually involves only therelatively short-lived creation of fungible wealth that is

carried off, leaving a hole in the ground, a stumped-overwoodland, or an ocean stripped of one of its main species.In the past, there have been many examples of this purelyephemeral kind of growth. It was caricatured by historianChristopher Lasch once with these lines: 'American cap­italism's idea of economic development was to leave thecontinent a smoking ruin.' Sometimes one must agree withLasch on this point. Fortunately, the smoking ruin is theexception and not the rule. [Hughes 1985, p.5]

Natural resources, therefore, can be the impetus forsustained growth, but that is not always the case.

Information Effects

Dependence on natural resources also may affect re­gional economic growth because of the way naturalresource price movements and/or discoveries of newdeposits tend to change perceptions of the economic oppor­tunities in the affected region. As shown in Plaut and Pluta(1983), Miernyck (1985), Gruben, Martens, and Schmidt(1988), and Gruben and Schmidt (1989), energy priceshocks were instrumental in explaining shifts of labor andcapital among regions. Those regions that were energyexporters benefited markedly from rising oil prices relativeto non-energy producing states. The factor flows were notdirected solely to energy industries, but rather to thebroader economy. Although part of the expansion andcontraction in the energy states can be directly linked toenergy-supporting industries, the factor movements ap­peared to reflect investors' and migrants' expectations ofrapid growth in other sectors as well.

Percent40

30

20

10

Chart 5Energy Share of Total Gross State Product

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 9

Page 11: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

As hypothesized by Schmidt and Gruben (1988), thislarger effect reflects the imperfect information available tomigrants and investors regarding spatial opportunities.Because information is costly and known only with a lag,shocks that have easily recognized impacts convey anunusually large amount of information. The oil price risesin 1973-74 and 1979-80 highlighted investment oppor­tunities in the oil patch states, while the price collapse mayhave encouraged potential investors to spend their limitedresources acquiring information on other regions not likelyto be hurt by the collapse.

Because resource price movements often are dramaticand typically are expected to have differential geographicincidence, a state's characterization as natural resource­dependent may give strong signals-whether false ortrue-regarding the potential opportunities to outside fac­tors. Dramatic price movements tend to focus attention ona resource-rich region, thereby giving investment oppor­tunities a better chance of attracting the needed factors thanareas that are less well known.

"Dutch Disease"

The previous aspects of the relationship between naturalresources and economic growth have stressed the ways inwhich natural resource production can attract factors ofproduction from other regions. In this way, natural re­sources can be a source of non-resource industry growth.

The assumption in those cases is that the income orwealth effects from expanding natural resource productionwill spill over into non-resource production, thus diversify­ing the economy. In contrast, the literature in internationaleconomics points to the potential for an expanding naturalresource sector to crowd out non-resource industries,known in the literature as the "Dutch disease" (Laney[1982]).

This phenomenon has been applied to cases of oilexporting countries, in particular, although the same pro­cess affects other markets as well. In this framework, asudden price shock to a key export industry (such as the oilprice increases of 1973-74 and 1979-80) boosts the nomi­nal value of the country's exports, causing an increase inthe country's trade surplus. As a result, the country'sexchange rate appreciates.

The higher exchange rate then makes imports lessexpensive and non-petroleum exports more expensive.Consequently, domestic industries that export or competewith imports in the domestic market become less competi­tive. At the same time, productive factors may flow into thepetroleum sector away from other sectors, thus raisingfactor costs in other sectors as firms bid for potentiallyscarce labor and capital.

10

If the price shock persists, the negative effects on theother sectors of the economy are transitional as the econ­omyshifts toa new production mix that reflects theheightened comparative advantage of the natural resourceindustry. However, if the shock is expected to persist and,instead, proves to be temporary, the cost in terms ofmisallocated· factors, particularly irreversible investmentin plant and equipment, can offset the potential gains to theeconomyof the positive price shock. Moreover, suchtemporary losses ofcompetitiveness can result in the lossofmarket share in non-resource industries that may bedifficult to recapture. Finally, Dutch disease also canexpose a. country to greater risk by making its exportportfolio less diversified.

Similar forces are at work in a regional context, al­though there are important differences as well. Resourceprice shocks can lead to increased production of thoseresources, which can cause factors to be reallocated fromother industries. Moreover, factor prices can be bid up­ward, increasing the cost of other sectors' output relative toother areas of the country. Thus, even though there is acommon currency, a process akin to exchange rate appre­ciation can occur through a rising relative cost of living.

The most important difference between regions andnations, however, is the greater mobility of factors acrossregional boundaries. Constraints are not placed on inter­state movements of labor or capital, nor are constraintsplaced on shipments of products. Therefore, whereas theDutch disease can lead to sharply higher factor prices in theresource-dependent country, factor prices need not rise assharply in a region where factors can be drawn from otherregions relatively easily.

Special Characteristics of Natural Resources

The preceding discussion, while couched in terms ofresource industries, is not unique to natural resources.Many of the same relationships between resource indus­tries and regional economies can be found in states that arehighly dependent on non-resource-based industries, suchas autos and steel.

There are, however, several areas in which naturalresource industries differ from other industries. Naturalresources lend at least three primary advantages to adeveloping economy over and above simple comparativeadvantage: a developed market, low initial technologicalrequirements, and access to capital. First, natural re­sources often enjoy developed markets, both domestic andinternational. To an area that is sparsely developed, anatural resource can provide a readily exportable com­modity.Unlike many finished commodities, a resourcedoes-not require strong local demand during start-up

Economic Review I Fall 1989

Page 12: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

phases of the operation. As long as the region has access totransportation, trade is possible.

A •second, related advantage that accrues to naturalresource production concerns the relatively low level ofskill and capital that is required at initial stages of produc­tion. Typically, the existence of abundant resources andaccess to transportation make the cost of extracting the firstunits relatively 'low.> Mineral mining can be profitablewith a shovel and pan, logs can be obtained with a saw anda river, and oil can be extracted with little more than thetechnology to drill a water well. Thus, in initial phases,successful development requires risk-taking by the availa­ble-labor supply and only modest support operations.Production initially does not require a large collection ofhighly-trained technical and professional workers.

The third advantage of a natural resource is that itinitially can produce economic rents that allow the regionto import needed capital for other ventures. Becausenatural resources tend to be scarce worldwide, the price ofthe resource generally will be sustained above the marginalcost of producing it in areas where it is abundant. Tradingwith more developed countries allows the region to importcapital goods that cannot be developed locally with existingcapital. Ainatural resource, therefore, can serve as achannel through which raw materials are converted intoreproducible capital. 6

At the same time, however, dependence on naturalresource production has several disadvantages that canthreaten sustained economic growth of more developedeconomies. To begin with, access to world markets makesthe region highly susceptible to fluctuations in those mar­kets.Changes in terms of trade, embargoes, or tradebarriers can have a large impact on a resource-dependenteconomy. Moreover, changes in world supplies, such as thediscovery of new reserves elsewhere, or in demand, such asshifts in taste or technology, have immediate impacts on thelocal economy. Markets are less predictable and control­lable than when supply and demand are more insulatedgeographically.

The downside of resource price volatility clearly hasbeen evident in the oil-dependent states in the 1980s.While the rest of the nation has enjoyed a record peacetimeexpansion, the oil states have experienced the worst reces­sion in the post-depression era because of the sharp drop inoil prices.

The problem is exacerbated by the close linkage be­tween natural resource production and government policy.In most countries, natural resources are heavily controlledor owned by governments. Oil prices are determined inlarge part by OPEC's decisions about production. Agri­cultural production is highly subsidized in most countries.

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

Forestry sales are heavily dependent on decisions concern­ing.access to public stands of timber-decisions that oftenare influenced by environmental policy considerations.These government controls, therefore, further expose aresource-dependent economy to political uncertainty, aswell as to the uncertainty that would normally arise in themarket.

The low skill requirements needed in many of theextraction industries also can work to the detriment oflong-term regional growth. In many cases, boom periodslead to rapid increases in the wages of low-skilled workers,encouraging a migration of such workers from other areasofthe country. These low-skilled workers receive highwages because of temporary output surges and concomi­tant shortages oflabor, rather than as a result of a steady­state measure of their opportunity cost. In periods withslowing demand and production, these workers often be­come unemployed and typically are less able than skilledworkers to find other work at similar pay.

Moreover, the temporarily high returns to low-skilledlabor-which may not be perceived to be temporary by theworkers-can inhibit investment in human capital. Thevalue of boosting human capital through training andeducation is obscured by the temporary returns to rela­tively low levels of such human capital. Over the long run,a drop in the skilled labor pool can slow innovation andproductivity growth.

Finally, the theory of exhaustible resource productiontypically points to declining production after some stage.Optimal production behavior calls for spreading produc­tion over time, but even in cases where production capabil­ity first must expand, production is expected to declineeventually, both as a share of output and in absolute levels(Pindyck [1978]). Production tends to rise in early stages asdiscoveries are made and new reserves are developed, butfinding large new deposits to replace the reserves that wereused in previous periods becomes harder over time. Thecase of declining U.S. oil production in the face of risingprices during the 1970s offers dramatic evidence of thispotential problem.

Summary

Natural resources potentially can play an important roleina region's economy. First, a region heavily endowed withnatlIral resources can be expected to specialize in resourceproduction in conformity with the notion of comparativeadvantage. Second, other things equal, possession of moreresources boosts the potential output of the region.

With respect to the rate of growth, however, the resultsare mixed. Natural resources have at times been instru­mental in providing a catalyst for rapid and sustained

11

Page 13: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

growth. In other cases, a resource boom has crowded outother industries to the detriment of the region's longer-termprospects. Moreover, while natural resource industries

may provide strong growth at early stages of a region'sdevelopment, the advantages associated with those indus­tries are more questionable as the economy matures.

III. Relative Performance and the Role of Prices

As indicated in Section II, the relationship between nat­ural resources and differential regional economic growth iscomplex. In this section, evidence from the GSP data ispresented to address two aspects of this relationship. First,gross statistics on the relative economic performanceof resource-dependent and non-resource-dependent statesare presented. Second, simple regression results are pre­sented to determine whether resource price shocks orresource industries per se influence relative performancemore.

Relative Performance

For the purpose of this analysis, the 50 states are splitinto two groups foreach natural resource industry based ontheir resource dependence. Those identified as "resourcedependent" are listed in Table 2.7 As shown in Charts1-5 earlier, resource dependence is highly skewed acrossstates. In the case of agriculture and energy, the top 10states are selected as resource dependent. In contrast,because the number of states with significant mining orforestry activity is small, only the top five states arecategorized as resource dependent.

The performance of resource-dependent states has dif­fered from that of other states during the 1964-86 period.As shown in Table 3, resource-dependent states ("high")grew more rapidly than did other states ("low"). Over thewhole period, the top ten resource states grew at an averageannual rate of 3.35 percent, compared to 2.56 percentgrowth for the other 40 states. 8

This difference in growth rates was not constant over thewhole sample period. Resource industries, particularly theenergy sector, have faced significant changes over thisperiod. Accordingly, the sample period was split into threesub-periods-1964 to 1972, 1973 to 1981, and 1982 to1986-that are divided by the major oil price shocks in1973-74 and 1979-80.

Although these periods are selected to capture changesin energy industry activity, the shocks were sufficientlytraumatic to overall economic activity to make those datesimportant to the other resource industries. Economic slow­downs early in each of the last two sub-periods, while notnecessarily causally related to the oil price shocks, wereassociated with sharp changes in many of the industries.Higher interest rates dampened the demand for lumber by

12

slowing construction activity, and changes in inflationaffected mineral prices and had significant impacts onagricultural land values.

These periods also were characterized by sharp changesin natural resource price behavior. In the early period,natural resource prices were fairly stable. In the middleperiod, however, energy prices surged. Overall, mineral,lumber; and agricultural prices showed little trend growthover the period, but sharp increases in precious metals

EconomicReview / Fall 1989

Page 14: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

prices at the end of the 1970s and sharpagricultural spikesin 1973 and 1980 were important events shaping industryactivity.

As indicated in Table 3, resource industries have hadmajor changes in the pace of economic growth over thewhole period. In the 1973-81 period, resource statespostedgrowththatexceededother states' growthbynearly1.75 percentage points. Conversely, in the 1982-86 pe­riod, resource statesgrewmorethanfourpercentage pointsslower than the remaining 40 states.

The.more rapid growth in the resource states wasaccompanied by greater variance. The weighted averagerootmean square error around trend growth was 0.57percentage points higher for resource states than for non­resource. states. Comparing sub-periods, however, it isclear thatthis highervariance largelyis theresultofthelastperiod, <luring whichgrowth in resourceindustries slowed

dramatically. In the earlier periods, differences in vari­anceswere relatively small.

Considerable differences in the relationship betweenresources and growth are apparent across natural re­sources. Agricultural statesgenerallygrewat thesamerateas other states, with faster growth in the 1973-81 periodoffsetby slowergrowth in the other periods. The varianceingrowth·also was smaller for agricultural states duringmost-time periods.

In the case of forestry, growthrates werehigheroverall,althoughthe variance wasconsiderably higher in forestry­dependent economies. As in the case of agriculture, themiddleperiod stands outas theperiodofrelativegain, withslower-than-average growthregisteredin the otherperiods.

Mineral states have out-performed the rest of the nationin all sub-periods except the last period, and even there,theyperformed nearly as well. The variance washigher in

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 13

Page 15: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

the mineral-dependent economies, but the growth rateswere the highest registered by any resource-dependentcategory.

Energy-dependent states had the most dramatic varia­tions relative to the rest of the nation over the whole period.Growth during the pre-1982 period exceeded that in thenation, particularly in the 1973-81 period when oil pricesrose sharply. The collapse of oil prices in the 1982-86period caused growth to plunge to one-quarter of the rateof growth experienced in the rest of the country. Further­more, after enjoying lower-than-average variance in theearly periods, the variance rose to twice the nationalaverage in the later period. The volatility of the energystates during this period is not surprising given energy'srelatively large share of output in these states (see Table 2)and the large swings in prices observed in the period.9

The data in Table 3, therefore, suggest that the better­than-average performance of resource industries largelywas the result of gains made during the 1973-81 period.Mining and energy states were clear winners overall,while forestry and agriculture also registered some gains.

Separating Price and Share Effects

The results in Table 3 point to strong gains in resourceindustries during the period of sharp gains in naturalresource prices-particularly in the prices of oil andminerals. In this section, an attempt is made to disentanglerelative price effects from output effects associated withthe growth of resource industries apart from the priceshocks.

Ordinary least squares (OLS) and generalized leastsquares (GLS) regression results are presented in Table 4for a simple model relating prices and resource shares torelative output growth. The data are estimated in pooledcross-section time series form, using all 50 states and 23time periods. In the GLS case, the data are corrected forcross-sectional heteroskedasticity As indicated by the lowdegree of explanatory power, these estimations fail tocapture most of the differences across states in economicgrowth. The results are useful, however, in the sense thatthey provide partial correlation statistics for share andprice variables, which are better measures than those fromsimple bivariate correlations between relative growth andprices or shares separately!"

14 Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 16: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

The dependent variable is measured as the differencebetween the annual percentage changes in the levelof realGSP for each state from the national average percentagechange (formed using total·GSP summed across states).Thus, it represents the relative growth of a state's GSP.

Share variables are formed by taking the share of astate's GSP accounted for by the given resource industryand subtracting from it the nation's average resource share.For resource-dependent states, this variable is positiveand for those with below average shares, the variable isnegative.

Price variables are formed in two steps. First, the realannual percentage change in each resource price is calcu­lated.!' The price change for a given resource is thenmultiplied by the state's relative share of that resourcedescribed earlier. This specification is necessary becauseprice effects depend on a state's relative dependence on agiven resource. Clearly, oil price increases had a positiveeffect on energy-exporting states and a negative effecton energy-importing states. With this formulation, a posi­tive coefficient indicates that a positive price shock willboost the resource-intensive state and slow growth in non­resource-intensive states.

Finally, to account for the possibility that growth alsoresults from factor movements generated by differences inper capita income, the relative per capita income ofpersonsin each state in 1963 (the beginning of the period) isincluded. If faster growth simply is the result of a statestarting from a low base, this variable will proxy for thateffect.

Both OLS and GLS results are reported because to­gether, they convey some sense of the robustness of therelationships. Differences between the two estimates arisefrom the treatment of variances of state growth rates,which can differ because of a variety of factors, including

the size and diversity of the state's economy. The GLSmodel estimates the coefficients after standardizing thevariances of the state, while the OLS model makes no suchcorrection. Both methods yield unbiased coefficients, al­though the standard errors can be biased in the OLS case.

Results from the regressions differ in the size andsignificanceof the coefficients, but several broad charac­terizations can be made. First, share variables either do nothave a .significant influence on relative growth, or wheresignificant at the 95 percent confidence level, tend to haveanegative influence on growth. These results suggest that,other things equal, having more natural resource produc­tion will not stimulate relative economic growth.

Price variables, on the other hand, were positive in allcases. This result suggests that the sharp movementsin resource prices during the period did have an impor­tant, positive influence on the relative output growth ofresource-dependent economies.

The effect of the starting levelof the economy, per capitaincome in 1963, had a positive effect on relative growth inthe OLS case and an insignificant effect in the GLS model.To the limited extent that the starting level mattered,therefore, those states with the strongest economies at thebeginning grew faster, making the spread between stateincomes larger.

Results from the table, therefore, suggest that the supe­rior performance of the natural-resource dependent statesshown in Table 3 may be better interpreted as the result ofsharp positive price movements during the sample period,rather than advantages associated with resource produc­tion per se.12 To summarize, the results in Table 4 indicatethat having a large share of natural resources is detrimentalto relative growth prospects, unless the relative price ofnatural resources rises.

IV. Non-Resource Industries and the Dutch Disease

In the previous section the evidence indicated thatnatural-resource-based economies out-performed the restof the nation, although the gains appear to be the result ofprice effects rather than share effects. This finding allows adirect examination of the applicability of the "Dutchdisease" to regional economies. In this section, the dataare examined to determine whether the gains in resource­based regional economies led to greater concentration inresource industries-and possibly had detrimental effectson non-resource industries-as would be consistent withDutch disease.

Table 5 presents average changes in the natural resourceshare of state GSP over various sub-periods (weighted by

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

GSP) calculated for resource- and non-resource-dependentstates. Comparing columns, it can be seen that resource­dependent states had much larger changes in the shares ofGSP contributed by the various natural resource industriesthan did the non-resource-dependent states. This is notsurprising given the small shares that those industriescontribute in non-resource states.

Comparing resource industries in the resource-depend­entstates, the largest changes in output shares occurred inthe energy sector. Energy's share of output droppedin eachperiod, with declines of three and six percentage points inthe last two sub-periods in the energy-dependent states. Incontrast, mining had less than a 0.4 percentage-point

15

Page 17: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

change in share in the states that have the greatest out­put shares in that industry. Agriculture and forestry hadslightly larger changes, but those changes in shares wereless than two percentage points between any two sub­periods.

As shown in the table, agriculture, forestry, and miningshares dropped sharply during the 1973-81 period, despitepositive price shocks. Combined with the earlier informa­tion that showed those states doing far better than averageduring that period, this suggests that non-resource indus­tries in those states were the most important source ofgrowth-causing the resource share to fall because of thefaster growth of the other sectors.

A direct comparison of sectoral growth is given in Table6. Comparing the first two columns, it is clear that resourceindustries lagged in contributing to growth. In all cases­for both high- and low-resource-dependent states across allcategories of resources-the growth rate of the resourceindustries was below that of the total state economy.

Comparing the two groups of states, the growth rates ofresource industries were relatively similar. Only in the caseof forestry states was significantly faster growth registeredin the resource sector of the high resource-dependentstates.

Non-resource industries in resource-dependent statesregistered the fastest growth in all cases. Consequently, inan apparent refutation of the Dutch disease hypothesis, thenon-resource sectors were the prime beneficiary of theresource price shocks.

This conclusion is strengthened by comparing thegrowth of non-resource industries that are directly tied toresource production (resource processing industries suchas refining, pulp and paper, food processing, and stone,clay, and glass) with that of other industries with less directties. As shown in the last two columns of the table, non­processing industries ("other") had faster growth than allprocessing industries except in the case of forest products.

Results from the table, therefore, suggest that the Dutchdisease did not afflict regional economies. Price effectsboosted the economy, but those prices did not result inincreased specialization in resource production and declin­ing competitiveness of other industries.

Differences in relative factor mobility may help toexplain this difference between regional and national econ­omies with respect to susceptibility to Dutch disease. Inthe international case, factor flows are constrained byrestrictions on immigration and capital movements. Con­sequently, relative price shifts that encourage the move­ment of factors to support the resource industry take factorsaway from other domestic sectors.

In the regional case, few limits are imposed on factor

16

movements. Labor and capital can flow to areas withpotential opportunities. Consequently, increased output bythe resource sector does not need to reduce factors availableto other industries, since those factors can be importedfrom other regions. Costs of living can rise as labor isattracted, but the cost increases, in tum, will stimulateadditional factor movement, such as the inflow of buildingmaterials for additional housing.

Results in Table 6 also highlight the inelastic nature ofnatural resource production. Resource industries wereunable to expand significantly even when sharp positiveprice movements gave them incentive to do so. Energystates often could not increase output as prices rose be­cause of binding constraints on availability. In Texas, forexample, the sharp run-up in prices in 1979-80 slowed thesecular trend towards declining production and provenreserves, but production could not rise. As a result, oilwealth tended to be invested in other industries or regions.

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 18: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

V. ConclusionThe GSP data suggest several relationships between

natural resources and relative economic performance.Overall, the experience of the 1964-86 period indicatesthat resource states grew more rapidly than non-resourcestates. This faster growth was accompanied by highervolatility in growth, however.

The faster growth and higher volatility of resource­dependent states reflects, in part, the significant volatilityin natural resource prices observed during the period,particularly in the 1970s. Sharp price increases boostedresource-dependent economies by providing increased in­vestment in the economy.

Contrary to the Dutch disease, price increases in naturalresource industries boosted non-resource industries. Re­source industries showed little ability to expand outputin the wake of favorable price movements and increasesin wealth. These increases in wealth, instead, were in­vested in non-resource industries. Thus, in the states

Federal Reserve Bankof San Francisco

with large resource industries, these non-resource indus­tries expanded most when positive resource price shocksoccurred.

Having a large resource sector, therefore, can be benefi­cial to a region's growth when the industry experiencespositive price shocks. If prices fall or remain unchanged,the slow growth (or actual decline) in resource industryoutput can slow the relative growth of resource-dependentstates.

This observation suggests an important area for furtherstudy. Why does the additional wealth generated by re­source price shocks remain within a resource-dependentregion and boost local non-resource industries when in­vestment in such industries outside the region is possibleas well? Most theories would argue that non-resourceindustries in a resource-dependent economy would beharmed, as suggested by the Dutch disease, or at leastunaffected in a world of freely-flowing capital. The answer

17

Page 19: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

to this question may be associated with the informationcost arguments discussed earlier, but a full explanationremains to be uncovered.

Finally, differential effects across states may diminishover time. As noted in this study, resource industries have

become less dominant in nearly all states. Output shareshave fallen sharply, especially in the resource-depend­entstates, which-should-make future regional differ­encesin growth less attributable to natural resource pricemovements.

NOTES

1. For a discussion of the BEA GSP data, see .Giese(1989).

2. The data in the table correspond to shares of nationaloutput, rather than shares of national reserves of thoseresources. Output and reserves tend to be correlated, butparticularly inthe case of minerals and energy, there maybe some differences in themag nitude of the shares basedon the length oHime the resource has been extracted.3. The GSPdata do not break forestry separately from theindustry data. Instead, BEAreportsa total for forestry,fisheries, and agricultural services-an aggregation thatis not appropriate for this study. Because nearly all em­ployment in forestry is in the durable goods category"lumber and wood products," that category is used as aproxy for the contribution of forestry to output. Althoughthis procedure understates the role of forestry, it is repre­sentative of that impact.4. Often, characterizations of resource industry impor­tance magnify the effect of the industry by counting theemployment of all persons in some way connected toresource processing-some figures for agriculture rangeas high as 25 percent of the economy. Such a claim wouldbe valid only if (1) those services and production were notperformed if the state did not have resource production­including retail sales of food-and (2) those inputs tied upin the resource chain otherwise would be unemployed.

5. This low initial cost is not always the case, of course, asevidenced by the high cost of developing Alaska's oilfields.

6. This advantage is not limited to developing countries.The Soviet Union, for example, earns much of its hardcurrency to purchase machinery and supplies from salesof gold and oil to the Western countries.7. GSP statistics and information used in this article areexpressed in real terms unless otherwise noted.

18

8. Grovvth rates were.estimated by regressing the log oftotal real GSPon a constant and a time trend for eachstate. Coefficients on the time trend indicate the growthrate, While the root mean square error from the estimationis used to measure the variance. Averages for the highandJow groups .are weighted by size of GSP.9. Evidence on real oil prices is presented by Schmidt(1988). As shown in that article, real oil prices have beentrendless over the past 115 years, although prices havetended to be volatile. The price spikes in the 1970s,however, were clear outliers, with unusually large devia­tions from the historical average.10. The significance of the coefficients supports the inclu­sion of resource shares in models of regional perform­ance. See Sherwood-Call (1988) for related work thatincorporates farm and oil variables into models explainingdeviations of state growth from national performance.11. Prices for the resources were selected from severalsources. Lumber and oil prices are based on the whole­sale price indexes for lumber and crude oil, respectively.Agricultural prices are based on the series, "Prices Re­ceived," published by the U.S. Department of Agriculture.Mineral prices are the weighted average of iron, copper,lead, and zinc prices (using fixed consumption weightsderived from average consumption over the period). In allcases, the prices are deflated by the general wholesaleprice index.

12. This is particularly true in the case of energy. In theother resource industries, although no trend growth inprices was noted, price increases (the percentage in­crease) were larger in the positive direction than in thenegative direction-that is, price declines were moregradual. Since the price variables were formed usingannual percentage changes, the positive price move­ments helped to explain the better-than-average perform­ance of the resource states.

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 20: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

REFERENCESBorts, George H. "The Equalization of Returns and

Regional Economic Growth," American EconomicReview, 50, JuneJ9.60.

____ and Jerome L. Stein. Economic Growth in aFree Market. New York: Columbia University Press,19.64.

Cox, W. Michael and John K. Hill. "Effects of the LowerDollar on U.S. Manufacturing: Industry and StateComparisons," Economic Review, Federal ReserveBankofDallas, March 1988.

Giese,Alenka S. "A Window of Opportunity Opens forRegional Economic Analysis: BEA Releases GrossState ProductData," FRB Chicago Working PaperSeries, WP-1989-3, Federal Reserve BankofChicago,February 1989.

Gruben, William C., Joann E. Martens, and Ronald H.Schmidt. "Interstate Shifts in Nonresidential Con­struction," Economic Review, Federal Reserve BankofDallas, July1988.

Gruben William C. and Ronald H. Schmidt. "State andLocal Fiscal Policies, Shocks, and Interregional Mi­gration," Presented at theWestern Regional ScienceAssociation Meetings, February 1989.

Hughes, Jonathan. "Comments on Long-Run Growth andDevelopment," Energy and theSouthwest Economy,Proceedings of the 1985 Conference on Energy andthe Southwest Economy, Federal Reserve Bank ofDallas, 1985.

Laney, Leroy O. "How Contagious is 'Dutch Disease'?"Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas,March 1982.

Miernyk, William H. "Fossil Fuels and Regional EconomicDevelopment," Energy and theSouthwest Economy,Proceedings of the 1985 Conference on Energy andthe Southwest Economy, Federal Reserve Bank ofDallas, 1985.

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

North, Douglass C. "Location Theory and Regional Eco­nomic Growth," JournalofPolitical Economy, 63, June1955.

Pindyck, Robert S. "TheOptimal Exploration andProduc­tionof Nonrenewable Resources," Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 86, October 1978.

Plaut, Thomas R. andJoseph E. Pluta. "Business Climate,Taxes and Expenditures, and State Industrial GrowthintheUnited States," Southern Economic Journal, 51,July1983.

Schmidt, Ronald H. "Effects of Energy on Income Growthin theSouthwest," Energy .and the Southwest Econ­omy, Proceedings of the1985 Conference on Energyand the Southwest Economy, Federal Reserve Bankof Dallas, 1985.

____. "Hotelling's Rule Repealed? An Examinationof Exhaustible ResourcePrlclnq," Economic Review,Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Fall 1988.

____ and William C. Gruben. "Expectations andRegional Growth," Presented attheRegional ScienceAssociation Meetings, Toronto, Canada, November1988.

Sherwood-Call, Carolyn. "Exploring theRelationships be­tween National andRegional Economic Fluctuations,"Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank ofSan Fran­cisco, Summer 1988.

Smith, Donald M. "Regional Growth: Interstate and Inter­sectoral Factor Allocations," Review of Economicsand Statistics, 56, 1974.

State of California. Measuring Economic Impacts: TheApplication of Input-Output Analysis toCalifornia Wa­ter Resources Problems, Bulletin 210, Department ofWater Resources, March 1980.

19

Page 21: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

Unemployment-Rate Dynamics:Aggregate-Demand and -Supply Interactions

John P. Judd and Bharat Trehan

Vice President and Associate Director of Research, andSenior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of San Fran­cisco. Research assistance was provided by Conrad Gann.We wish to thank the members of the editorial committee,Fred Furlong, Adrian Throop, and Carl Walsh, for valuablecomments on earlier drafts of this paper.

The implications for monetary policy of movements inthe unemployment rate depend upon the nature of theunderlying disturbances that caused those movements.Positive aggregate-demand shocks cause the unemploy­ment rate to fall as inflationary pressures build, whereaspositive aggregate-supply shocks are likely to lead to afallin both the unemployment rate and inflation. In this paper,we employ a recently developed modeling technique todisentangle the effects of aggregate-demand and -supplyshocks on the unemployment rate. The technique is agnos­tic about alternative macroeconomic theories, derivingidentifying restrictions from relatively uncontroversiallong-run, or steady state, relationships.

20

The unemployment rate often plays an important role inmonetary-policy deliberations, not only because policymakers are concerned about unemployment itself, but alsobecause it is viewed as an important indicator of futureinflation. For example, when the unemployment rate de­clined rapidly to a relatively low level in recent years,a number of Federal Reserve officials became concernedthat the economy was developing dangerous inflationarypressures.'

One problem in evaluating the policy implications ofmovements in the unemployment rate (as well as those ofother macroeconomic variables) is that these implicationsoften depend on one's assumptions about the structure ofthe economy. Currently there is little agreement amongeconomists concerning the appropriate paradigm; theKeynesian (both the traditional and "new" versions), real­business-cycle, and monetary-misperceptions paradigmsall have significant followings among different groups ofmacroeconomists.?

These paradigms differ in the emphasis they placeon aggregate-demand versus aggregate-supply shocks ininfluencing economic activity and labor-market condi­tions. Real-business-cycle models ascribe a larger role toaggregate-supply shocks, whereas Keynesian and mone­tary-misperceptions models place greater weight on aggre­gate-demand shocks. This distinction between demandand supply factors is important because the appropriatemonetary-policy response (or lack thereof) to unemploy­ment rate movements depends on the nature of the underly­ing disturbance. Positive aggregate-demand shocks causethe unemployment rate to fall as inflationary pressuresbuild, and such developments could make a tightening ofmonetary policy appropriate. By contrast, positive aggre­gate-supply shocks are likely to lead to a fall in both theunemployment rate and the rate of inflation. Under thesecircumstances, a tighter monetary policy most likelywould be inappropriate.

In this paper, we employ a recently developed modelingtechnique to disentangle the effects of aggregate-demandand -supply shocks on the unemployment rate (as well ason other important macroeconomic variables.) The tech­nique is agnostic about alternative theories, derivingidentifying restrictions from relatively uncontroversial

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 22: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

assumptions about long-run, or steady-state, relationships.Given the current lack of agreement about macroeconomictheory, such models have the advantage that they eschewover-identifying restrictions, and choose not to go beyondthe minimum number of restrictions necessary to achieveidentification.

Our empirical results suggest that for very short hori­zons of a few quarters, shocks to aggregate demand ac­count for nearly all of the variance of unemployment rateforecast errors. However, at longer horizons of twelvequarters and more, aggregate-supply shocks playa signifi­cant role. Moreover, we find that movements in the unem­ployment rate that are caused by supply shocks (as definedby our model) are positively correlated with inflation,whereas those associated with demand shocks are nega­tively correlated with inflation. Thus, decomposing the

sources of unemployment rate movements into demandversus supply shocks can be important in designing effec­tive monetary policy.

The paper is organized as follows. Section I reviews therelevant literature on macroeconomic modeling and dis­cusses the rationale for the approach taken in this paper.Section II sets out the theoretical specification of themodel. In Section III, we discuss econometric issues thatarise .in estimating the model and the results of thisestimation, as well as their implications for the sources ofvariation in important macroeconomic variables, includ­ing the unemployment rate. Also in this section we analyzethe historical evolution of the unemployment rate and therelationship between inflation and the aggregate-demandand -supply components of the unemployment rate. Policyimplications and conclusions are discussed in Section IV.

I. Methodological Considerations andLiterature ReviewAdherents of the main alternative macroeconomic theo­

ries-Keynesian, real-business-cycle, and monetary mis­perceptions-have very different views about the structureof the economy. A major source of controversy concernsthe relative importance of demand and supply shocks. TheKeynesian and monetary-misperceptions theories stressthe role played by aggregate-demand shocks in inducingshort-run movements around long-run trends which areindependent of those shocks. In contrast, real-business­cycle theories emphasize the role played by technology andlabor-supply shocks in producing short-run fluctuations inoutput around changing equilibrium values which arethemselves determined by factors traditionally emphasizedin neo-classical growth models.

These alternative macroeconomic theories have dif­ferent implications for how monetary policy should beconducted. For example, since Keynesians believe thatunemployment rate movements mainly are induced byaggregate-demand factors, inflation will rise (fall) whenthe measured unemployment rate goes below (above) itsnatural rate. Assuming the monetary authority knows thenatural rate of unemployment, Keynesians suggest that theobserved rate of unemployment relative to its natural ratecan be a major source of information in setting policies tocontrol inflation.

In contrast, real-business-cycle theorists believe thataggregate-supply shocks are the predominant sources ofchange in macroeconomic variables. Under these circum­stances, policy mistakes would be made if the central bankinterpreted the unemployment rate as an indicator ofaggregate-demand pressures. Further, existing real-busi­ness-cycle models generally have modeled business cycles

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

as Pareto-optimal responses to exogenous shocks. Thus, inthese models, there is no role for any type of macro­economic policy aimed at stabilizing the economy.

Macroeconomists have not been able to agree on whichtheory (or combination of theories) most accurately de­scribes the economy. Each theory implies a different set ofidentifying restrictions. Thus, a certain degree of agnosti­cism is warranted in selecting identifying restrictions. Thisagnostic approach increasingly has shown up in macro­economic research in recent years. The use of vectorautoregressions appears to reflect this view. No identifyingrestrictions are needed to obtain macroeconomic forecasts.Of course, if these forecasts are to be interpreted in termsof economic theory, identifying restrictions must be added.In early applications, these took the form of assuming aspecific recursive structure for the contemporaneous cor­relations in the data.3,4

The Blanchard-Quah Model

Recently, Blanchard and Quah (1989) specified a smallvector autoregression of the macroeconomy that achievesidentification by imposing relatively uncontroversial con­straints on steady-state conditions, thereby avoiding therestrictions associated with alternative theories of thebusiness cycle. Moreover, their model is exactly identified,and thus avoids over-identifying restrictions that may raisetheoretical controversy. Blanchard and Quah (BQ) assumethat supply shocks (those emphasized in real businesscycle models) can have permanent effects on the level ofreal activity, while demand shocks (those emphasized by

21

Page 23: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

where (J~ is the (observed) variance of y, (J~ is thevarianceof u, (Jy" u, is the contemporaneous covariance of u andy,and the othervariances are defined similarly.

So far, there are five conditions from which we mustobtain six coefficients. One more restriction is needed toidentify the model. The traditional approach has been toimpose a recursive structure on the contemporaneouscorrelations in the data (Sims [1980]). For example, onemight assume thatthecoefficient a j = 0,. thatis, shocks tothe unemployment rate do not have a contemporaneous

effect ontherateofgrowth ofoutput. Suchanassumption,however, would be theoretically controversial.

BQ avoid having to assume contemporaneous causalorderings by relying on long-run, or steady-state, restric­tions. Specifically, they assume that v has no long-runeffect on output; that is,

b, + cj = O. (3f)

Thisrestriction, together with the conventional restric­tions onvariances andcovariances, is sufficient to identifythe unobserved shocks from observations ony and u. Therestriction also leads to a straightforward interpretation oftheunderlying structural disturbances: v canbeinterpretedas an aggregate-demand shock since it can have no long­runeffect ony, while e canbeinterpreted asa supply shocksince it is permitted permanently to affect y. In otherwords, the permanent level of real GNP is determined byrealfactors. Although aggregate-demand shocks cancausereal GNP to deviate from this level, it cannot affect thepermanent level itself. By construction, neither demandnorsupply shocks have a permanent impact on the unem­ployment rate.

Using thismethod, BQ found thatdemand disturbanceshada hump-shaped effect onthetimepathofoutput, whilesupply shocks had an effect that increased gradually overtime. They alsofound thatdemand disturbances accountedfor only 35% of the variance of unpredictable changes inreal output in the contemporaneous quarter, leaving 65%for supply disturbances, while demand accounted for 13%at a horizon of eight quarters.> In contrast, demand dis­turbances accounted for 100% of the variance of unpre­dieted changes in the unemployment rate in the currentquarter, and for 50% at an horizon of eight quarters.

The Shapiro-Watson Model

Oneproblem withBQ's analysis is thatit allows foronlytwo underlying disturbances to the economy. If, as seemsplausible, theeconomy isaffected by more than onekindofsupply (or demand) shock, their procedure will tend toconfound the effects of these different shocks. Based onthis reasoning, Shapiro and Watson (1988) useda systemthat comprised real GNP, total labor hours, inflation andtherealinterest rate." Thissetofvariables allowed them toaccount for four different disturbances: two to aggregatesupply, whieh they identified as shocks to laborsupply andtechnology, and two to aggregate demand, which theyreferred to as IS and LM shocks, but did not identifyseparately.

Shapiro andWatson (SW) found thataggregate-demandshocks had a smallerimpact on real output than BQ did.?

(1)

(2)

(3a)

(3b)

(3c)

(3d)

(3e)

Yt = a.e, + b», + CjVt_ j

Ut = a2et + b2vt + C2Vt-j

(J =cby, , u,_) j 2

(j =bcy,_) , u, l 2

the Keynesian and monetary-misperceptions models) canhave only temporary effects. These assumptions are con­sistent with each of the three main macro paradigms.Importantly, they are sufficient to identify certain typesof VARs incorporating important macroeconomic timeseries.

Since theBQ approach is usedin thispaper, albeit on alarger model, it is useful to see how theirmethod works.(A detailed discussion of theirmethod of identification isprovided in Appendix A.) BQ specify a VAR with twovariables: therateof growth of realGNP(Y), andthe levelof the unemployment rate (u). Two types of (unobserved)structural disturbances, v ande, areassumed toaffect thesevariables. (As discussed below, we follow BQ in iden­tifying these disturbances with aggregate-demand andaggregate-supply disturbances.) Equations (1) and (2) aremoving average representations ofy andu interms ofthesetwo disturbances. For simplicity here, we introduce dy­namics intotheBQmodel by including only onelagofv ineachequation, although thefullBQmodel contains severallags.

In order to study the dynamics of this system, it is firstnecessary to obtain estimates of thevarious coefficients inequations (1) and (2). This requires placing certain restric­tions on e and v. In traditional fashion, BQ assume that eand v are uncorrelated with each other and have unitvariance. Inaddition, e andv arealsoserially uncorrelated.Given therepresentations in (1)and(2), these assumptionsimply the following identifying restrictions:

(J~=a]+b]+c]

(J~=a~+~+c~

(Jy" u, = aja2 + bjb2 + CjC2

22 Economic Review / Fall1989

Page 24: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

Specifically, aggregate-demand shocks accounted for just28% of the variance of the output forecast error in thecontemporaneous quarter, and 20% at an eight-quarterhorizon. In addition, they found that labor supply shocksalone accounted for about 45% of the variance of unpre-

dieted changes in output in the contemporaneous quarter.Thesefindings, as wellas those of BQ, sharply contradictthe Keynesian and monetary-misperceptions views thattrend and cycle are neatly separable, with demand shocksplaying the dominant role over the business cycle.

II. Model Specification and Identification

wheres* is the logof the steady-state value of laborsupplyand e* represents (unobserved) technology. Thelaborsup­ply and technology shocks, !J.s and !J.e , are uncorrelated,and the lag polynomials f3s (L) and W(L) describe thetransitory movements in s* and e* as they move to newpermanent levels.

The Underlying Model

We begin by assuming that the production technologycan be described by a neo-classical growthmodel, so thatthe long-run level of output is determined by the capitalstock and labor supply? The capital stock term can beeliminated by assuming a Cobb-Douglas production func­tion and a constantsteady-state capital-output ratio. Thus,the steady-state level of output can be expressed as afunction of the steady-state levels of labor supply andtechnology.

The levels of labor supply and technology may bepermanently affected by labor-supply and technologyshocks, respectively. The evolution of these variables isdescribed by

below, the results obtained when population is used as ameasure of labor supply are much more plausible. Thus,given this paper's policy-driven focus on the unemploy­ment rate, we have opted for working-age population.

We also extend the BQ and SW models by explicitlyincorporating a foreign variable to identify the effects ofshocks originating abroad. Giventhe growing importanceof international trade and capital flows to the U.S. econ­omy, it is desirable to incorporate the independent effectsof shocks from abroad. While inclusion of the exchangerate appears to be an obvious choice, the move fromfixed­to floating-exchange rates in the early 1970s implies achange in the exchange-rate process that precludes sensi­ble estimation results over our 1954-88 period. Instead,we includeas a foreign variable the ratio of real exports toreal imports.

In this section,wepresentthe specification of themodelestimatedin this paper. We begin with a discussion of thevariables included in the model, followed by a discussionof the equations that constitute the model, and how weachieve identification.

The model includes five variables: the unemploymentrate, real GNP, a nominal rate of interest, a measure oflabor supply, and a variable that measures foreign trade.Thesevariables providebroadcoverage of important typesof activity in the economy, and thus should capture theeconomic relationships that are important in determiningthe behavior of the unemployment rate. Movements in theunemployment rate and the interest rate are likely to behighlycorrelated with two types of underlying aggregate­demand shocks, which can be thought of as being asso­ciated withthe IS and LM curves of textbook macroeco­nomic theory. The interest rate should captureshocks bothto inflation expectations and real interest rates, whilethe unemployment rate should reflect aggregate-demandshocks as theyaffectthe level of economic activity. Follow­ing previous research, we assume that movements in realGNP are correlated with technology shocks, once westandardize for aggregate-demand shocks. 8

Weuse working-age population as our measure of laborsupply. This variable is clearly exogenous, and thereforeguards against the possibility of confounding labor de­mand and supply. However, it has the disadvantage ofomitting the effects on labor supply of changes in par­ticipation rates and average hours worked. One obviousalternative would be to follow SW andusetotallaborhoursas the labor-supply variable. However, our empirical evi­dence suggests that using labor hours to measure supplycausesa seriousbias; weare unablecompletely to separatethe demand-induced changes in labor hours from thoseinduced by labor supply. Specifically, when we includelabor hours in our model, we find that a positive labor­supply shock leads to a large, sustained decline in theunemployment rate, an outcome that suggests a confusionbetween labor supply and demand. Such confusion couldhave a profound effect on conclusions concerning therelative importance of supplyand demand disturbances inmacroeconomic time series. By contrast, as discussed

s*= O'.s + s* + Qs (L) liSt t-1 I-' rrt

e*= O'.e + e* + Qe (L) liet t-1 I-' rrt

(4)

(5)

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 23

Page 25: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

Labor supply is not affected, either in the short or longrun, by any of the other variables in the system. Thisassumption follows from our choice of working-age popu­lation to represent the influences oflabor supply, and yieldsfour of the ten restrictions we need to identify the model. 10

Both labor-supply and technology shocks can causeshort-run movements in output as the level of outputadjusts to a new steady-state value. Short-run movementsin output also can be the result of aggregate-demandshocks. However, the two types of aggregate-demandshocks are permitted to have only temporary effects on thelevel of output. These assumptions yield two more identi­fying restrictions. Foreign shocks cause output to deviatetemporarily from its steady-state value, but are not per­mitted to have a long-run effect on output. 11This assump­tion yields one more identifying restriction.

These considerations suggest the following equationsfor the relationship between observed and equilibriumvalues:

St = si + XS (L) (I-Li) (6)

Yt = Y;+ XY (L) (l-1i, I-1T, f.1f, 1-1:1,1-1:') (7)

where XS(L) and XY(L) are vectors of lag polynomials (inthe indicated variables) that allow for temporary deviationsfrom steady-state levels. Thus, this specification allows theactual level of output to deviate from the level implied bythe Cobb-Douglas production function in the short run. Asdiscussed above, y* itself is a function of s* and e*. f.1fdenotes shocks originating abroad, while 1-1~1 and 1-L~2 arethe domestic demand shocks.

Statistical tests suggest that output and labor supply areboth nonstationary, and thus we take first differences ofequations (6) and (7) (see Appendix B). Substitutingequations (4) and (5) into the results yields:

St - St-I = {XS + W (L) (I-LO + (1-L)XS (L) (I-Li) (8)

Yt Yt-I = {XY + rY' (L) (l-1i, I-LT)+ (1- L)XY (L) (I-Li, I-LT, f.1f, 1-1:1, 1-1:2) (9)

Consider now the specification of the foreign variable.In addition to disturbances originating abroad, this vari­able is affected by all the domestic shocks. However, thetwo aggregate-demand shocks are permitted to affect theforeign variable only temporarily.'? These assumptionsyield two more identifying restrictions. Weassume that thelong-run evolution of the foreign variable can be describedin the same wayas output, so it is included in the model in aform similar to (8) and (9). Thus,

it - h-I = at + [3f (L) (1-1:, I-LT, f.1f)+ (1- L)x! (L)(I-1:, I-LT, f.1f, 1-L:1, 1-L:2)(10)

24

Given that the interest rate appears to be non-stationary(see Appendix B), we specify its equation in differencedform:

. - i-Xi (L) (s e .. f II d 1 II d 2) (11)It t r-L - , f.L t , f.Lt, t"'t' I""t ' I""t

Thus, all the disturbances in the model can have a perma­nent effect on the nominal interest rate.

There is some ambiguity about how the unemploymentrate should be included in the model. On the one hand,there. is a large body of theoretical work in macroeco­nomics to suggest that the unemployment rate is station­ary.13 Tests carried out over long sample periods tend toconfirm this. 14 On the other hand, as shown in AppendixB, unit root tests suggest that the unemployment rate isnon-stationary over shorter sample periods.

This inability to reject nonstationarity in the unemploy­ment rate over the post-war period poses a problem.Different researchers have dealt with this problem indifferent ways. BQ for instance, present results both for thecase where the unemployment rate is assumed to bestationary and where it contains a deterministic trend.Unfortunately, removal of a linear trend is not sufficient tomake the unemployment rate stationary. Evans (1989)allows for an increase in the mean of the unemploymentrate beginning in 1974. As indicated in Appendix B,allowing for this shift in the mean appears to make theunemployment rate stationary.

Acceptance of this "solution" to the nonstationarityproblem implicitly assumes the existence of some well­defined, exogenous change in the economy that is associ­ated with a change in the mean unemployment rate. Whilesome economists have pointed to the change in participa­tion rates of women and teenagers in the labor force overthis period, the issue is by no means resolved. 15 Accord­ingly, we estimated two alternative versions of the model,one that allows the mean unemployment rate to change in1974, and one that holds it fixed over the entire 1954-88period. The results in the two cases are similar, and sowe present only those from the specification that allows fora mean shift. (However, we do point out instances belowin which the results from the two specifications differmaterially.)

Thus, the complete model comprises equations (8)-(11),plus

f.Lt = {XU + XU (L) (f.L:, I-1T, 1JIr, 1-L:1, f.L:2) (12)

where {XU is allowed to shift in 1974Ql. Thus, the unem­ployment rate is affected by all the disturbances in themodel. However, because it is entered as a level, none ofthese disturbances has a permanent effect on it.

In summary, we have identified the model by restricting

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 26: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

certain long-run coefficients to equal zero, and by usingworking-age population, which is strictly exogenous, forour labor-supply variable. As discussed in Appendix A, werequire ten identifying restrictions to separate the influ­ences of each of the five shocks-two domestic demand,two domestic supply, and one foreign-on all the variablesin the system. The assumption that population is ex­ogenous yields four identifying restrictions. Four addi­tional restrictions come from the assumption that the two

aggregate-demand shocks do not have long-run effects onoutput and the foreign variable. One more restrictioncomes from the specification that the foreign shock has nolong-run effect on U.S. output. This gives us a total of ninerestrictions. Following SW, we choose not to identify thetwo aggregate-demand shocks separately. In this way, weare able to eliminate the need for a potentially controver­sial tenth restriction.

HI. Estimation and Empirical Results

In this section we describe the estimation technique andpresent our results. The impulse response functions andthe variance decompositions presented below provide in­formation about the structure of the economy as estimatedby the model. We use this information to analyze thefactors that have contributed to the changes in the unem­ployment rate that occurred over the period from 1955 to1988. Finally, at the end of this section, we show correla­tions between our measures of the aggregate-demand andaggregate-supply components of the unemployment rateand the rate of inflation.

Our model includes the log of the unemployment rateand the first differences of the logs of all other variables.Because population is exogenous, we use ordinary leastsquares to estimate a regression of population growth onsix of its own lags. (A lag-length of six is used in all theequations in the model.)

To illustrate the technique used to estimate the remain­ing equations, we use the real GNP equation. 16 Real GNPis regressed on lags of all the variables in the system pluscontemporaneous values of population, the interest rate,the unemployment rate, and the foreign trade variable. Weimpose the restriction that neither the aggregate-demandshocks nor the foreign shocks has a permanent impact onthe level of GNP by taking the difference of the relevantright-hand-side variables one more time and reducing thelag length by one. Thus the first difference of real GNP isregressed on first differences of population, the seconddifferences of the foreign variable and interest rates, andthe first difference of the unemployment rate (in addition tolags of first differences of real GNP). Two-stage least­squares is used to estimate the equation because it containscontemporaneous values of the three endogenous variables(that is, of interest rates, unemployment, and the foreignvariable). The contemporaneous value of population andlagged values of all variables in the model are used asinstruments.

The remaining equations are estimated in a similar man-

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

nero Following our discussion above, domestic aggregate­demand variables are restricted to have only a temporaryimpact on the foreign variable, while no such restriction isplaced on the domestic supply variables. No restrictionsare placed on the equations for the interest rate and theunemployment rate. As mentioned above, the inclusion ofthe level of the unemployment rate in the model impliesthat no shock to the system has a permanent impact on thatrate.

The Estimated Structure of the Model

Exhibit IA shows the impulse response functions fromthe model. The first two columns of the exhibit show theresponse of the model's four endogenous variables todomestic shocks, while the third column shows the effectsof shocks originating abroad. As discussed above, weidentify labor-supply and technology shocks separately,but we do not disentangle the two underlying demandshocks. Thus, the impulse response functions in the secondcolumn of the exhibit represent responses to a linearcombination of the demand shocks.

Positive aggregate-demand shocks reduce unemploy­ment and raise output and interest rates. By construction,the effects on the unemployment rate and GNP are tempo­rary. The effects of aggregate-demand shocks on the unem­ployment rate die out in about 12 quarters, while those onoutput last eight to 10 quarters. At first, the ratio of U.S.exports to imports reacts negatively to domestic demandshocks; that is, higher domestic demand leads to a rise inimports relative to exports. The impulse response functionthen cycles, becoming positive from five to twelve quar­ters, at which time the effect dampens out.

Positive shocks to technology reduce the unemploymentrate. This effect lasts for about 24 quarters before substan­tially dying out. I? Shocks to labor supply have insignifi­cant effects on the unemployment rate, causing it to cyclearound its original level. Positive shocks to labor supply

25

Page 27: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

ExhibitlA1mpul seRes.ponse.F unet ion s

Domestic Supply Shocks

Labor Supply

Responses of:

Unemployment Rate

31

-1

-3-5-7

-9

- 11 -i-t'''"T''''I""'''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''"T''''I""''''''-'''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''"T"'T'"14 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

Technology

Labor Supply

Real GNP

1.3

1.1

.9

.7

.5

.3

.1

-. 1 -i-t'''"T''''I""'''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''"T''''I""''''''-'''''''''''''''''''''''''''''I''''T''''I""T'"'I''"'14 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

Technology

Labor Supply

Interest Rate

191715131 1

97531

-1- 3 ....J.of..,..,..'I""'r"'I...,..,......,-,...,....,"T""I"~....,....,....,..,...,..,....I""T""I"""T""I"".,..,...,

4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

Technology

Labor Supply

4

3

2

1

o~-I-J.~::::============--

-1

- 2 -i-t'''"T''''I""'''''''''1''''''l''"I''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''0''T'''''''''''''''''''''Foreign Variable26

4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 28: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

ExhibitlA (conttnued)

Domestic Demand Foreign ShocksShocks

31

-1-3...5

-7 -7-9 -9

-11 -114 12 20 28 36 44 52 60 4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

1.3 1.31.1 1.1

.9 .9

.7 .7

.5 .5

.3 .3

. 1 .1-.1 -.1

4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60 4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

19 1917 1715 1513 131 1 1 1

9 97 75 53 31 1

-1 -1-3 -3

4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60 4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

4 4

3 3

2 2

1 1

0 0

-1 -1

-2 -24 12 20 28 36 44 52 60 4 12 20 28 36 44 52 60

FederalReserve Bank of San Francisco 27

Page 29: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

and technology permanently raiseoutput, withtheeffectoflabor-supply shocks buildingup somewhat moregraduallythan the effect of technology shocks. Positivi shocks tothese two variables also permanently raise the level ofinterest rates, and the ratio of exports to imports.

Positive foreign shocks temporarily raise output andlower the unemployment rate, although the latter effectsare relatively small. These shocks also permanently raisethe interest rate.

Exhibit IB presents the associatedvariance decomposi­tions, which show the relative importance of the variouskindsof shocksin explaining theerrors made in predictingthe model's variables. At forecast horizons of up tofour quarters, variation in the unemployment rate hasbeendominated by aggregate-demand shocks. Aggregate­supply shocks begin to playa larger role as the forecast ho­rizon lengthens, reaching 15 percent at eight quarters and25 percent at 60 quarters. These results suggest that

28 Economic Review ! Fall 1989

Page 30: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

unemployment has been substantially affected both byaggregate-demand-and -supply shocks duringthepost-warperiod.

Aggregate..demand shocks arethemostimportant factorin.explaining variation in real GNP in the short run(contemporaneously and at forecast horizons of one andtwo quarters), accounting for 50 to 55 percent of thevariation. Technology shocks also are quite important atthese shortlags, accounting for from 28 to 35 percent. Astheforecast horizonlengthens, technology shocks begintodominate, as theseshocks arepermanent, while aggregate­demand. shocks are transitory. By the time the lags reachtwo years, technology shocks dominate demand shocks,with the former factor accounting for 61 percent of thevariation and the latter accounting for only 18 percent.Labor-supply shocks beginto become important only aftertwo years. At the frequency of the average business cycle,ourresultsshow a largerrolefordemand shocks relative tosupply shocks than does earlier research.

Interest rate variation is dominated at all forecast hori­zons bydomestic demand shocks, although foreign shockshave a noticeable effect in the long run. Domestic supplyshocks play onlya small role, except at the very long lags.At a lag of 60 quarters, labor supply accounts for 22percent of the variation in the interest rate, while at shorterlags, the role of this variable is quite small (under fivepercent).

Theforeign variable largely isexogenous withrespect tothe otherfour variables in the model-that is, it is deter­mined mainly by its own past behavior-at forecast hori­zons of up to 12 quarters. At long lags, however, laborsupply plays a significant role in the error variance of theforeign variable, reaching 43 percent at 60quarters. Tech­nology and domestic aggregate demand play only smallroles at all forecast horizons.

Theeffects of the foreign variable on theU.S. economyare relatively modest, as would be expected from therelatively small, albeitgrowing, roleof foreign trade in theU.S. economy. Foreign shocks playa significant role inU.S. real GNP at short lags, accounting for 13 percent ofthe contemporaneous variation and then declining in im­portance as the lag lengthens. Foreign shocks also haveplayed a significant role in U.S. interestrate movements,accounting for 10 to 12 percent of the variation in thatvariable at forecast horizons in the range of two to 12quarters.

Federal Reserve Bank of SanFrancisco

Historical Analysis

We how use our estimated structure to carry out twodifferent exercises thatexamine the historical evolution ofthellllemployment rate. First,to understand thefactors thatbave'eaused movements in theunemployment rateoverthecourseofthebusiness cycle, we lookat the sources of ourmodel'sforecast errorsat a forecast horizon of threeyears.

The results of this exercise are shown in Exhibit II. Byconstruction, any error in predicting the unemploymentratehastobe theresultof theunpredicted demand, supply,and/orforeign shocks thattookplacewithin thethree-yearforecasthorizon. We obtain the contribution of each kindof disturbance to the forecast error for any particularquarter by multiplying the coefficients in the impulseresponse functions by the appropriate historical shocks asmeasured by the model.

The•. top panel of Exhibit II shows the total error inpredicting the unemployment rate twelve quarters aheadovertheperiodfrom 1955 to 1988. At thisforecast horizon,themajorerrorsareclosely associated withbusiness cycleswings. The four panels below show the contributions to

Exhibit IIHistorical Analysis: Decomposition

of 12-0uarter-Ahead Forecast Errorsfor Unemployment Rate

TotalErrors

0.0

LaborSupply

Foreign

52 56 60 64 68 72 76 80 84 88

29

Page 31: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

theseforecast errors made bytheindicated shocks. Shadedareasrepresent business cycledownturns.

Themost strikingJeature of this analysis is that aggre­ga.te-<iemand shocks have played by far the largest role inunemployment. rate•movements over the course of thebusiness cycle inthe postwar period. Although technologyshocks. areimportant for the average quarterly variabilityof the unemployment rate over the whole sample, aggre­gate-demand shocks appear to be more closely related tocyclicalswings in the unemployment rate.

TechnologyshocksdO, however, contribute significantlyto thelonger-run swings in the forecast errors. Forexam­pie, the well-known productivity surge in the 1960s ispicked. •up in•• ouranalysis as a succession of positivetieC~~ysbocks that.led to a lower-than-predicted unem­ployment rate over most of the decade. Similarly theslowdowninpr()ductivity growth in theearly to mid1970sis pickedupasa succession ofnegative technology shocks.

The 1980s have been marked by large shocks both toaggregate demand and to technology. Not surprisingly,the second panel of Exhibit II shows large, negativeaggregate-demand shocks (which pushed up the unem­ployment rate) during theperiod from 1980 to 1982, whenthe Federal Reserve oriented monetary policy around themonetary aggregates tocombat thesurge in inflation in thelate 1970s and early 1980s.

Aggregate-demand shocks then turned positive (thuspushing down theunemployment rate)in 1983 asmonetarypolicy became more accommodative in the face of a con­tinuing recession and falling inflation. In addition, fiscalpolicy became highly expansionary from 1983 through

1986, with the high-employment deficitjumping sharplyin 1983 and reaching a peak in mid 1986. From1986through 1988, aggregate demand shocks were relativelysmall, although on average were slightlynegative.

Technology shocks also have been important factors inunemployment rate movements in the1980s.1n fact,theywere about as important as aggregate-demand shocks inraising theunemployment rate. Thiseffectwas substantialby historical standards and lasted from early1980 throughmid 1984. Technology shocks also accounted for a goodpart of the unemployment rate decline-in 1986 and1987,when the unemployment rate moved into a range thatcontributed to the Federal Reserve's concern about futureinflation.

What might beresponsible forthispatternof technologyshocks? Any suggestions would be highly speculative.lfSeveral large studies on thesources of productivity changein the U.S., for example, have failed to come up withspecific explanations for a substantial portion of thatchange.'? Nonetheless, we note that the timing of thenegative technology shocks in theearly1970s andtheearly1980s is close to the two oil price shocks, suggesting thatthis factor may have been important. However, as notedelsewhere, inclusion of oil prices causes problems inexplaining developments after 1985 (see footnote 6).

Unemployment and Inflation

We tum now to the second exercise of our historicalanalysis, namely a decomposition of the unemploymentrate into its aggregate-demand and -supply components,and a comparison of these components with the inflation

Percent1 1

9

7

5

Exhibit IIIThe Unemployment Rate and its

Supply-Induced Component

UnemploymentRate

62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88

*Includes the estimatedmean level of the unemployment rate to allowfor comparisonwith the actual unemployment rate.

Economic Review t Fall1989

Page 32: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

rate. In Exhibit III, theactual unemployment rate isplottedagainst the mean unemployment rate plus thecontributionofaggregat~-supply factors. To obtain this rate, we sub­tractedfromthe unemployment rate both the effects ofaggr~gate-d~mand-induced changes and the effects ofshocks originating abroad.t? The difference between thetwo series plotted in Exhibit III represents the effects ofaggregate-demand. pressures and foreign shocks in thelabor market. (Of the two, the latter are not very impor­tant.)iDemandpressures apparently have reduced theunell1ploymentrate duringmostof the 1965-1981 period,implying the possibility of an inflationary bias in policy.After 1981, these pressures have been more balanced,sometimes positive and sometimes negative.

According to economic theory, there should be a nega­tivecorrelation between our measure of the aggregate­demand component of the unemployment rate and therateQfinflation relative to inflation expectations, if our rneas­ur~jsvalid. This correlation arises in both the KeynesianPhiUipsicurveand the Lucas-Barro, or monetary-misper­ceptions,.· Phillips curve." In the former, an aggregate­demandshockthat reduces theunemployment rate leads tohigh~r inflation. In the latter, a positive aggregate-demandshock that raises inflation above inflation expectations(thatis,createsan inflation surprise) willleadtoa decreaseintheun~mployment rate.

The expected negative correlation is shown in the toppanel.of Exhibit IV. (We have used annual averages in

Exhibit tVInflation and Unemployment

2

4

6

8

Percent

4

3

2

1

o-1

-2

-3

o .........--r-....-r-.,...,...,..,....,...,........,-.-r-r-,...,...,....,..,...,.-r"'l-.-....-r-.,...,.....-+- 4

Percent

10

62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88

Percent10

8

6

4

2

, Aggregate­SupplyComponent ______

Percent4

3

2

1

o

-1

o """"""""''''''''''''''''''''''''''-'-I'''"''I"".,....,..,...,.....,...,,...,........,....,-,....,...,-.-,....,...,....,.-!-- 262 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 31

Page 33: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

order to reduce the random fluctuations in the data.) Notethat we plot actual inflation rather than the differencebetween actual and expected inflation. In the followingdiscussion, we implicitly assume a positive correlationbetween actual and unexpected inflation. The top panel ofthe exhibit reveals that as the aggregate-demand compo­nent of the unemployment rate fell below zero in mid-1960through 1980, the inflation rate rose, reaching a peak in1981. Since then, the aggregate-demand component hasfluctuated around zero, and inflation has fallen.

The bottom panel of Exhibit IV plots the aggregate­supply component of the unemployment rate and the rateof inflation. As expected, these two series are positivelycorrelated. When there is a positive technology shock, forexample, inflation falls as prices adjust to a new level, andat the same time the unemployment rate falls as firms'demand for labor rises.

The correlations shown visually in Exhibit IV are pre­sented more rigorously in the first two columns of ExhibitV. The first column presents cross correlations betweenpast, present, and future values of inflation, on the onehand, and the aggregate-demand component of the unem­ployment rate, on the other. The correlations between theaggregate-demand component of the unemployment rateand inflation are strongly negative, suggesting that ourmeasure of aggregate-demand pressure is functioning asexpected.

The second column of the exhibit presents the correla­tions between our measure of the aggregate-supply com­ponent of the unemployment rate and past, present, andfuture rates of inflation. These correlations are uniformlypositive, which appears to validate our concept of theaggregate-supply component of unemployment.

In the third column, we show cross-correlations be­tween the unemployment rate minus its mean rate with pastand future values of the inflation rate. The correlationsbetween the aggregate-demand component of the unem­ployment rate and future inflation are noticeably strongerthan those between the (mean-adjusted) unemploymentrate and future inflation. Likewise, the positive relation­ship between past inflation and our measure of the supply­induced changes in the unemployment rate is noticeablystronger than that between past inflation and the unemploy­ment rate.

Notice also that the correlations between past values ofinflation and the unemployment rate are positive. Thus, theraw data tend to support the Keynesian Phillips curve,which has causation running from unemployment to futureinflation, and refutes the monetary-misperceptions Phil­lips curve. The latter relationship implies that there should

32

be a negative correlation between past inflation surprisesand unemployment rates, rather than the positive correla­tion shown in column three. However, the first column ofthe table shows that once the aggregate-supply shocks arestripped away, both directions of causation are supported.There is a negative correlation between past inflationand aggregate-demand-induced unemployment (monetarymisperceptions) and also between future inflation andunemployment (Keynesian).

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 34: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

IV. Policy Implications and Conclusions

The aim of this paper has been to estimate the relative unemployment rate in order to arrive at an estimate ofimportance of different kinds of disturbances in causing future inflation. Since movements in the unemploymentmovements in the unemployment rate. Towardthatend, we rate may be the result of either demand or supply factors,have attempted to keep our model as free as possible of the looking at the level of the unemployment rate alone (or atcontroversial identifying restrictions that are inherent in theunemployment rate relative to some fixed value)can bethe various competing paradigms of the macroeconomy. misleading in particular episodes; instead, it is necessaryWe find that on average both demand and supply shocks first-to determine the relative importance of aggregate-have been important in explaining unemployment rate demand and -supply forces.movements in the postwar period. While demand shocks With this in mind, we consider what the model tells usarerelatively more important in causing cyclical swings in about the conditions that prevailed in 1988 (the last year ofthe unemployment rate, supply shocks playa significant our sample period). As Exhibit III indicates, aggregaterole in inducing longer-term movements. Our finding that demand was mildly stimulatory. The unemployment ratepositive supply shocks are correlated with falling unem- averaged5.5 percent over the year. In the absence of anyployment in subsequent periods casts doubt on Phillips- demand shocks, it would have averaged 5.8 percent. Thecurve analyses, which assume that relative prices and the difference between these two numbers (0.3 percent) pro-unemployment rate move independently of each other. vides a measure of aggregate-demand pressures in the

Our historical analysis suggests that supply shockswere economy. A measure of the net impact of supply shocks isimportant in keeping the unemployment rate low in the obtained as the difference between what the unemploy-1960s, and relatively high in the early- and mid-1970s. Of ment rate would have been in the absence of demandparticular interest right now is the role played by supply shocks and what it would have been in the absence ofshocksin raising the unemployment rate in the firsthalf of shocks of any kind. Our model implies that in the absencethe 1980s, and then lowering it in the second half of the of any shocks to the economy the unemployment ratedecade. The relatively large role played by supply shocks would have settled at 6.0 percent. 22

in the decline in the unemployment rate over the last few Thus, this difference between the actual 5.5 percent rateyearscould be one reason the inflationrate has notacceler- in 1988 and the 6.0 percent mean rate is accounted forated as much as past estimates of the unemployment- about equally by demand and supply shocks. Althoughinflation relationship would have led us to expect. demand pressures do appear to have contributed to labor

The analysis is relevant for policy purposes to the extent market tightness in 1988, the degree of pressure probablythat policy makers take the unemployment rate into ac- is not as intense as would be suggested by comparing thecountin determining policy. Policy makers may lookat the prevailing rate with its 6.0 percent mean.

APPENDIX A

Identification

In this appendix we describe the identificationproblem Let the estimated VAR representation of the model bein terms of the moving average representation of a VAR. given byLet the vector X, = [x., x2t... xnt ] denote the variablescontained in the model, where all the elements are nonsta- B (L) Z, = Vt • (A2)tionary, but are not cointegrated. Assume that the struc- Multiplying both sides of (A2) by C(L) B(L) -lleads totural representation of the model can be written as the moving average representation

z, = A (L) et (AI)

where Z, = JlXt , A(L) = Ao + AlL + A2U + A3V . . . ,and the lag operator L is defined by Let = et- l . Further, itisassumedthat~At< 00, and that thestructuraldisturbanceterm e is serially uncorrelated.

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

z, = C (L) Vr (A3)

where E(v t) = 0, and E(vsv/) = n for t = s and is zerootherwise. (A3) is the reduced form representation of (AI),and we have

(A4)

33

Page 35: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

[ZIt]..ZZt .

Thisis satisfied foranyvt suchthatvt = S*et, andCtl.) =A(L)*S-I. Thus, to recover the structural representationfrom the estimated VAR, we need to obtain the matrix Swhich links the VAR residuals vt with the structuraldisturbances e;

Theexact form ofSwilldepend upon thestructure ofthemodel. Under the usual assumption that the structuraldisturbances areuncorrelated witheachotherandthattheyhave unit variance (that is, E(ete/) = I), the problem ofchoosing the appropriate S reduces to choosing the ele­mentsofS subject to thecondition thatS is a square rootofn (the variance-covariance matrix of the VAR residuals).Sincen has n(n+1)/2 unique elements and S is n*n, weneed n(n-1)/2 (that is, n2 [n(n +1)12]) additionalrestrictions in order to identify a unique S. If n = 2, forexample, n contains three unique elements while S con­tains four. Thus, we need one additional restriction toidentify S.

Sims(1980) suggested choosing S suchthat Sij = 0, forall j > i, which serves tomake thesystemexactly identified.Fora two-variable system, this restriction prevents shocksto the second variable from having any contemporaneouseffectonthe first variable. Sims' restrictions imply thattheunderlying structural model is a recursive, simultaneousequations model (with independent error terms), a repre­sentation thatmay sometimes bedifficult to reconcile witheconomic theory. Blanchard and Watson (1986) imposedrestrictions on contemporaneous correlations that wereexplicitly derived from economic theory, andvariations ofthis technique have beenimplemented byBemanke (1986)and Walsh (1987), among others.

The technique of identification used in this paper hasbeen suggested recently by Blanchard and Quah. In this

technique the restrictions used to identify S can be inter­pretedas restrictions on the long-run effects of the asso­ciatedshocks on certainvariables. Tosee how thisworks,assume that the vector Z, contains only two elements, sothat (A3) becomes

[Cd L) CdL)] [Vlt]

czI(L) cziL) VZt

or

or

rIl = [Cl1(L)Sn + c12(L)s21 cn(L)s12 + CdL)S22] PI]

Ed czlL)sn + cziL)sZI czlL)s12 + cziL)szz ~Zt

As discussed above, if eland e2 are assumed to beindependent of each other, only one more restriction isneeded to identify S. If it isassumed thate2 hasnolong-runeffect onxI (thefirst variable in the model), therestrictiontakes the form

Cll (1) Sl2 + Cl2 (1) S22 = 0

Here, CII (1) is just the sum of the coefficients in the lagpolynomial cll(L). Thus, in this case identification isachieved by choosing an S forwhich a particular weightedsumof theelements of thesecond column ofS is zero. Thecondition that these weights be the sumof thecoefficientsof the estimated lag polynomials for the first variable iswhat ensures that the level of x, is independent of e2 •

Shapiro and Watson (1988) show how this restrictioncan be imposed quite easily in the VAR representation.

Tests for Stationarity

We tested for stationarity using the Said-Dickey test,which is recommended by Schwert (1987). The test in­volves estimating an equation of the form

j

Yt = a + !3Yt-I + .I ~\~Yt-i + e;I=I

Totestwhether theYprocess contains aunitroot we haveto determine whether !3 = 1. However, under the nullhypothesis that the process generating Y contains a unitroot, the ratio of the estimated value of !3 to its standard

APPENDIXB

Data and Preliminary Tests

We use quarterly data over the period 1948Q1-1988Q4for our estimation.

Alldata have beenobtained from theCitibase datatape.For population, we use noninstitutional population, 16years and over, after subtracting armed forces. Theunem­ployment rate is the civilian unemployment rate. Tomakethe GNPdatacomparable, weuse real GNPnet of federaldefense expenditures. The interest rate we use is thesix-month commercial paper rate. Data for U.S. exportsand imports are from the National Income and ProductAccounts.

34 Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 36: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

error does not have the usual t-distribution. The criticalvalues to be used in this case are tabulated in Fuller (1976).

Schwert (1987) demonstrates that choosing a large valueof} (as recommended by Said and Dickey) avoids theproblem of falsely rejecting the hypothesis that y contains aunit root. In the table below we present the results for thecases where} = 8 and} = 12. The table shows that we areunable to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root forpopulation, real GNP, the interest rate, or the foreignvariable at the 10%level in either the eight-lag or the 12-lagcase.

the case of the unemployment rate, we present threedifferent sets of results. We are unable to reject the nullhypothesis of a unit root in the unemployment rate whetheror not we allow for a linear trend. The last column showsthe results for the case where we allow for a change in the

mean unemployment rate beginning in 1974Ql. For theeight-lag case, the computed test statistic is significant at5%, while for the 12-lagcase the computed value of - 2.80is justbelow the 5% critical value of - 2.89.

Note, however, that these critical values do not allow fora shift in the mean under the alternative hypothesis. It isuseful to compare these critical values to those reported inPerron (1988). Perron generalizes the null of a unit rootprocess to allow for a one-time change in the structure ofthe series, and compares this to the alternative of astationary series with a discrete change in its mean. (Thus,his null hypothesis is not strictly the same as ours.) It turnsoutthatthecritical values vary with the date at which thebreak occurs. For the case at hand, where the break occursabout two-thirds of the way into the sample, the 5% criticalvalue is - 3.33, while the 10% critical value is - 3.01.

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 35

Page 37: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

NOTES

1. See, for example, "Records of Policy Actions of theFederal Open Market Committee," FederalReserve PressRelease, for the eight Federal Open Market Committeemeetings in 1988.2. See, for example, Ball, Mankiw, and Romer (1988),Long and Plosser (1983), Lucas (1973), and Greenwaldand Stiglitz (1988).3. Later applications used restrictions derived from eco­nomic theory. See Blanchard and Watson (1986), Ber­nanke (1986), Sims (1986), and Walsh (1987).4. In another example of theoretical agnosticism, McCal­lum (1988) has investigated the robustness of nominal­income-targeting rules across different macroeconomictheories.5. These results refer to the case where no trend isremoved from the unemployment rate. Blanchard andQuah also present results for the case where they removea linear trend from the unemployment rate. Removal of alinear trend tends to increase the relative importance ofdemand shocks.6. They also included the price of oil as an exogenousvariable, on the grounds that the two recessions duringthe 1970s were the consequence of the oil price shocksduring this period. Inclusion of the oil price variable isproblematic, however, since oil prices fell dramatically in1985 without an obvious effect on real output. Shapiro andWatson estimate their model through the end of 1985only.7. SW also present two sets of results: one where there is adeterministic trend in labor hours and one where the trendin hours is stochastic. The results discussed in the textrefer to the latter case.

8. See, for example, Blanchard and Quah (1989), Longand Plosser (1983), and Shapiro and Watson (1988).

9. The model outlined here closely follows that in Shapiroand Watson.10. As described in Appendix A,once we assume that theunderlying shocks are uncorrelated and have unit vari­ance, we need n(n-1 )/2 additional restrictions to identify amodel that contains n variables. Since n = 5 here, weneed a total of 10 restrictions.

11. This assumption implies symmetric treatment of for­eign and domestic aggregate-demand shocks; that is,neither have permanent effects on output. However, theforeign shock also is designed to include the effects offoreign supply disturbances. One drawback of our modelis that we are treating foreign and domestic supply shocksasymmetrically; that is, domestic supply shocks can havepermanent effects, while foreign supply shocks cannot.

36

12. The assumption that an aggregate-demand shockinduced by monetary policy does not have a long-runeffect on the foreign variable is uncontroversial. The as­sumption that a fiscal-policy shock does not have a long­run effect on real exports and imports is less clear cut. SeeKrugman (1985) and Mussa (1985) for discussions ofthese issues and other references.13.See Phelps (1978). For a contrary view, see Summersand Blanchard (1986).14.See, for instance, Nelson and Plosser (1982).15. See, for instance, Gordon (1982) and CongressionalBudget Office (1987).16. The reader interested in more detail is referred toShapiro and Watson (1988).17. As noted earlier, we also estimated a model with nomean shift in the unemployment rate, even though underthis specification unit root tests suggest that the unem­ployment rate is non-stationary. The impulse responsefunctions and variance decompositions for this model arenearly identical with those presented in the text, with oneexception. The model without a mean shift in the unem­ployment rate ascribes a larger role to technology shocksand a smaller role to demand shocks in determining theerror variance of the unemployment rate. Moreover (con­sistent with our findings in the unit root tests), the effectsof different kinds of shocks on unemployment dissipatemore slowly in the model without a mean shift than in themodel discussed in the text.18. The list of real shocks considered by Boschen andMills (1988), for instance, contains changes in the price ofoil, marginal tax rates, real government purchases, work­ing-age population, and real exports.19. See Jorgenson, et aI., (1987).20. More specifically, to obtain the supply component ofthe unemployment rate for any given quarter, we subtractthe effect of all demand and foreign shocks that occurredas long as 40 quarters ago. The impulse response func­tions in Exhibit 1A show that this is more than long enoughfor the effects of these shocks to die out.21. See Gordon (1982), Barro (1977), and Lucas (1973).22. Prior to 1974,when we assume a mean shift, this rate isestimated to be 4.8 percent. Also, in the model where themean is not allowed to shift, the mean rate of unemploy­ment is estimated to be 5.0 percent.

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 38: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

REFERENCESBall, Laurence, N. Gregory Mankiw, and David Romer.

"The New Keynesian Economics and the Output­Inflation Trade-off," Brookings Papers on EconomicActivity, 1988:1.

Barra, Robert J. "Unanticipated Money, Output, and thePrice Level in the United States," Journal of PoliticalEconomy, Vol. 86, 1977.

Bernanke, BenS. "AlternativeExplanations for theMoney­Income Correlation," Carnegie-Rochester Confer­ence Serieson Public Policy, 25: 1986.

Blanchard, Olivier J. and Danny Quah. "The DynamicEffects of Aggregate Demand and Supply Disturb­ances," The American Economic Review, September1989.

Blanchard, OlivierJ. and MarkW Watson. "Are All CyclesAlike?", in RobertJ Gordon, ed., The American Busi­ness Cycle. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,1986.

Boardof Governors of the Federal Reserve System. "Rec­ords of Policy Actions of the Federal Open MarketCommittee," Federal Reserve Press Release, for theeight Federal Open Market Committee meetings in1988,

Boschen, John F, and Leonard O. Mills, "Tests of theRelation Between Moneyand Output in the Real Busi­ness Cycle Model," Journal of Monetary Economics,22,1988.

Congressional Budget Office. Congress of the UnitedStates, The Economic and Budget Outlook: An Up­date. August, 1987.

Evans, George W, "Output and Unemployment Dynam­ics in the UnitedStates: 1950-85," Journal ofAppliedEconometrics, Vol. 4, 1989,

Fuller, Wayne A. Introduction to Statistical Time Series.New York: John Wileyand Sons, 1976,

Gordon, Robert J. "Inflation, Flexible Exchange Rates,and the Natural Rate of Unemployment," in Martin N,Bailey, ed. Workers, Jobs, and Inflation. WashingtonD.C,: The Brookings Institution, 1982,

Greenwald, Bruce C. and Joseph E, Stiglitz. "ExaminingAlternative MacroeconomicTheories," Brookings Pa­pers on Economic Activity, 1988:1,

Jorgenson, Dale W, Frank M, Gollop, and Barbara M,Fraumeni. Productivity and US, Economic Growth.Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard UniversityPress: 1987.

King, Robert, Charles Plosser, James Stock, and MarkWatson, "Stochastic Trends and MacroeconomicFluctuations," unpublished paper, University of Roch­ester, 1987,

Federal Reserve Bankof San Francisco

Krugman, Paul R. "Is the Strong Dollar Sustainable?," inThe US. Dollar-RecentDevelopments, Outlook, andPolicy Options, Proceedings of a Symposium Spon­sored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 21-23,1985.

Long, John B. and Charles I. Plosser. "Real BusinessCycles," Journal of Political Economy, 91, 1983.

Lucas, RobertE. "SomeInternational Evidenceof Output­Inflation Tradeoffs," American Economic Review, 63,1973.

McCallum, BennettT "RobustnessProperties ofa RuleforMonetary Policy," Carnegie-Rochester ConferenceSerieson Public Policy, 29, 1988.

Mussa, Michael L. "Commentaryon "Is the Strong DollarSustainable?," in The US, Dollar-Recent Develop­ments, Outlook, and Policy Options, Proceedingsof aSymposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bankof Kansas City, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August21-23,1985.

Nelson, Charles R, and Charles I. Plosser. "Trends andRandom Walks in MacroeconomicTimeSeries: SomeEvidenceand Implications,"Journal of Monetary Eco­nomics, 10, 1982,

Perron, Pierre. "Testing for a Unit Root in a Time SeriesWith aChanging Mean," mimeo, Princeton University,1988.

Phelps, Edmund S. Microeconomic Foundations of Em­ploymentand Inflation. NewYork: W W Norton, 1970,

Schwert, G. William, "Effects of Model Specification onTests for UnitRoots in Macroeconomic Data,"Journalof Monetary Economics, 20, 1987.

Shapiro, Matthew D. and Mark W Watson. "Sources ofBusiness Cycle Fluctuations," NBER Macroeconom­ics Annual 1988, Cambridge, Massachusetts: M.l.TPress,

Sims, Christopher A. "Macroeconomics and Reality,"Econometrica, 1980.

____. "Are Policy Models Usable for Policy Analy­sis?,"Quarterly Review, FederalReserve Bankof Min­neapolis, 1986.

Summers, Lawrence and Olivier Blanchard. "Hysteresisand European Unemployment," NBER Macroeco­nomics Annual 1986, Cambridge, Massachusetts:M.I.T Press,

Walsh Carl E, "Monetary Targeting and Inflation: 1976­1984," Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank ofSan Francisco, Winter, 1987.

37

Page 39: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

38 Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 40: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

Liquidity Constraints on Consumption:The Real Effects of "Real" Lending Policies

James A. Wilcox

Visiting Scholar, Federal Reserve Bank of San Fran­cisco and Associate Professor, University of California,Berkeley. I would like to thankBrian Bray, John Duca, JoePeek, Charles Steindel, David Wilcox, andparticipants atthe Spring 1989 Federal Reserve System Conference onBusiness Conditions fortheirviews onanearlierversion ofthis article. Especially helpful were the thoughtful andconstructive comments of editorial committee members,Ramon Moreno, Bharat Trehan, and Carl Walsh.

This article argues thathouseholds are oftenpreventedfrom consuming as much as their permanent incomejustifies. The hypothesis is advanced thatlending criteriabased onpayment-to-income ratios often inappropriatelyconstrain borrowing and therefore consumption. The evi­dence indicates that the variables presumed to proxy forpayments andfor income, thenominal interest rate andtheunemployment rate, respectively, significantly affect con­sumption growth in the manner suggested by thishypothe­sis. In contrast, there is little evidence that real interestrates have important effects on consumption.

Federal ReserveBank of San Francisco

Personal consumption expenditures typically compriseabout two-thirds of total national spending. Not only isconsumption thesingle largest category ofspending, but itchanges by large amounts. In absolute terms, the vari­ability of consumption expenditures is as large as that ofbusiness investment. Moreover, the variabilities of thecomponents of consumption (services, nondurables, anddurables) are large. The variabilities ofnondurables andofservices individually are nearly as large as that of con­sumer durable expenditures and the variability of the sumof nondurables andservices is appreciably largerthan thatof durables.' An understanding of the movements in anddeterminants ofconsumption anditscomponents clearly isimportant for the conduct of monetary policy.

The widely accepted permanent income hypothesis pos­its that consumption is driven by households' wealth andtheir expectations of income over the long run. Althoughactual income may fluctuate, these fluctuations are hy­pothesized not to affect consumption unless they alterhouseholds' expectations of their longer-run average, orpermanent, income. Instead, when households are facedwithdeviations of actual from permanent income, they arepresumed to vary borrowing andlending inorderto steadyconsumption.

Considerable recent empirical research, however, basedon both macroeconomic and microeconomic data bases,suggests that movements in actual income have sizeableeffects on consumption apart from the effect of thosemovements on permanent income. Likewise, theory sug­gests that real, after-tax interest rates should affect con­sumption, but that nominal interest rates should not. Theevidence, however, indicates that exactly the opposite ismore likely to be true. Consistently, the data point tosignificant nominal interest rateeffects onexpenditures fordurables, nondurables, and services, and to insignificantreal-interest-rate effects.? This is surprising indeed.

This article suggests thata single factor helps toexplainthese two findings-that consumption expenditures arereduced both by higher nominal interest rates andby theshortfall of actual, current real income below its perma­nent level. These interest-rate and income effects bothresult from a borrowing constraint which prevents house­holds from obtaining sufficient credit to finance as much

39

Page 41: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

consumption as their permanent income justifies. In par­ticular, this borrowing, or liquidity, constraint is hypoth­esized to emanate from the prevailing lending practice ofgranting credit subject to virtually-never-changing pay­ment-to-income-ratio ceilings. 3

The first section presents a brief exposition of thepermanent income theory of consumption and its empiricalimplications. Then it is argued that current credit-grantingpractices lead to liquidity constraints that are associatedwith nominal interest rates and real income. Section IIreviews the evidence from microeconomic data bases re­garding liquidity constraints. It also suggests what these

constraints portend for macroeconomic data. Section IIIeconometrically assesses the extent to which nominalinterest rates and unemployment rates affect aggregateconsumption, apart from their effects on permanent in­come.The estimates suggest that each has powerful effectson consumption expenditures. The evidence points towardthe liquidity constraint that operates through the payment­to-income ratio as the source of these important effects onconsumer expenditure. The short- and longer-run implica­tions of these results for national spending and saving, foreconomic policy, and for financial institutions are dis­cussed in the concluding Section IV.

I. Permanent Income, Consumption, and Constraintswhich shows that today's forecast of future income differsfrom last period's forecast of income over the same futureperiod by an unforecastable amount, u. No informationavailable prior to the current period would help predict thechange in permanent (or forecasted) income. Otherwise, italready would have been incorporated in last period'sestimate of permanent income.

Taking first differences of (2) and using (3) generates

Liquidity-Constrained Consumption

One potential weakness of this permanent-income for­mulation is that it assumes perfect capital markets, inwhich households can borrow and invest in order tosmooth consumption across time periods. If capital mar­kets are not perfect, however, households' desired spend­ing patterns may be "liquidity constrained" in significantways." Thus, the presence of liquidity constraints couldmake the permanent income hypothesis an inferior explan­ation for aggregate consumption behavior, particularly

On the assumption that k is constant over time, the growthrate of consumption, ~log(C), should be random. Noinformation available prior to the current period shouldreliably predict changes in consumption growth.

This model, however, is correct only if expected, real,after-tax interest rates are constant. When they are notconstant, theory predicts that households defer more con­sumption when the reward for doing so is higher. Thismeans that, ceteris paribus, higher interest rates lastperiod reduce last-period's consumption relative to currentconsumption, thereby raising the growth rate of con­sumption:

(5)

(4)~log(C) = ~log(k) + j.L

~log(C) = 'Y + 8re_ 1 + j.L

(3)

Note that actual income does not appear. The permanentincome hypothesis states that actual income affects con­sumption only to the extent that if affects permanentincome. Consumers are presumed to have access to capitalmarkets, and therefore are not constrained by cash flow orcurrent income. Borrowing and lending are viewed asshock absorbers for temporary fluctuations in income,making it possible for households to maintain consump­tion in the face of changes in actual income that areperceived to be temporary or are anticipated. Access tocapital markets also permits consumption to change whenpermanent income changes in advance of actual income.

Permanent income represents a forecast, not a measuredquantity. When consumers use all the information that isavailable at a given time to form estimates of permanentincome, those estimates will change from period to periodonly as new information is received. Hence, changes inestimates of permanent income will be unpredictable. Thisis common to optimal forecasts; over time, the change inwhat is expected to happen over any given future period israndom." This is embodied in

The permanent income hypothesis posits that consumersbase desired consumption on permanent income. Thetheory can be summarized as

C = kYP (I)

where C is the level of real, per capita consumption, k is the(average and marginal) propensity to consume out ofpermanent income and y P is the level of real, per capitapermanent income. Permanent income, yP, is the average,discounted income a consumer expects to receive over therelevant horizon. In logs, (I) becomes

log(C) = log(k) + log(YP) (2)

40 Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 42: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

since changes in borrowing flows are an empirically impor­tant factor in consumption patterns. 6

The alternative hypothesis advanced here is that liquid­ity constraints are indeed binding for a significant portionof households and that the aggregate amount of liquidityconstraint is associated with unemployment and nominalinterest rates. As either rises, liquidity constraints bothbind more tightly on previously constrained householdsand begin to bind on more households. Each aspect drivesconsumption further below the unconstrained value thatthe permanent income hypothesis predicts.

Consumers subject to liquidity constraints are assumedto behave differently from those who are not. Their con­sumption generally will respond vigorously to changes incurrent income or other sources of cash flow, even if thosechanges are anticipated, since, by definition, constrainedhouseholds want to consume more but are prevented fromdoing so by restrictions on their ability to borrow. Consum­ers not subject to borrowing constraints, in contrast, wouldbe expected to react little to anticipated, or to past incomechanges since their estimates of permanent income andtheir consumption plans already have adjusted to thosedevelopments. Liquidity-constrained consumers alreadymay have changed their desired consumption, but actualconsumption may have to await increases in actual incomeand the increased cash flow and ability to borrow thatcomes with it.

The liquidity constraint impinging on an individual maybe relatively short-lived or very long-lived. Borrowingmay be constrained to less-than-optimal levels for house­holds with expected (average, discounted) lifetime earn­ings that are above their actual, current earnings forperiods extending into years. Given the typical upward tiltin the age-earnings profile, most young households wouldbe expected to be substantial net debtors for many years.Kotlikoff (1988) shows that in practice, however, there isvery little net borrowing by the young, whose consumptiontracks earnings very closely at least up to age 45. And itmay be that not only the young are liquidity constrained.Wilcox (1989) cites several studies that suggest that asubstantial portion of the elderly may be liquidity con­strained. 7

Liquidity constraints resulting from the combination oflending criteria based on current income and the usualupward slope of the age-earnings profile then may lead to avery important and relatively constant share of householdswhose spending is constrained. For an individual, this typeof liquidity constraint may become less binding as actualearnings approach potential earnings and as financialassets are accumulated." The number of households sub-

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

ject to this form of liquidity constraint may change as timepasses, probably slowly and in tandem with the ratio ofyoung to total households.

In addition to the households subject to this age-relatedconstraint, a changing fraction of households is likely toexperience varying degrees of liquidity constraint in re­sponse to variations in unemployment and nominal interestrates." One reason consumers may become liquidity con­strained is that lenders widely follow a practice of restrict­ing consumer borrowing so as to keep payment-to-incomeratios below some ceiling level. A recent American Bank­ers Association textbook on consumer lending suggeststhat a borrower's capacity to repay a loan can be measuredby the payment-to-income ratio. 10 This means that appli­cations for credit are likely to be disapproved if the ratio oftotal loan payments to income breaches a ceiling, forexample, of 40 percent. II Note that, in practice, this policyrefers to current payment-to-current income. One conse­quence of this policy is that lenders generally refuse toextend credit to the currently unemployed. 12

Using a payment-to-income rule means that movementsin current income relative to permanent income can lead toconsumers being liquidity constrained. This practice sug­gests a capital market imperfection that may explain whycurrent income and cash flow affect consumption when thepermanent income theory suggests they should not.

These credit practices also suggest that the extent towhich consumption is liquidity constrained will vary withnominal interest rates. Lending policies that predeterminea payment-to-income ratio ceiling reduce the real amountof credit that would be made available to a borrower as thenominal interest rate rises.

Consider a $10,000, 48-month fully-amortizing loan.Suppose that the real interest rate is six percent. 13 Ifthe expected inflation rate built into interest rates werezero percent, the resulting six percent loan would entailmonthly payments of $235. 14 Since the actual and ex­pected inflation rate is zero for this period, the actualpayments and their real, or inflation-adjusted, values areboth $235 per month for 48 months. The lower horizontalline in Figure 1 shows that payment, which is level indollar, or nominal, terms and in real terms.

Suppose now that the actual inflation rate and theexpected inflation rate incorporated into nominal interestrates rises from zero to five percent and that the realinterest rate remains at six percent. The resulting elevenpercent market interest rate means that the same loan nowcarries a $258 payment, an increase of 10 percent. Thishigher, nominal amount is shown as the upper horizontalline in Figure 1. This repayment pattern has the same six

41

Page 43: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

percent real return over the life of the contract. The realburden of those higher nominal payments is shown as thediagonal line in Figure 1. Note that relative to the constantreal payments in the zero-percent inflation case, the leveldollar payments in the five-percent inflation case, in realterms, are higher early on and lower later in the life ofthe loan.

Level nominal payments during a period of inflationimply falling payments in real terms over time. An increasein expected inflation leads to an immediate one-timeincrease to higher nominal payments. The problem is thatthe onset of inflation does not have the same effect onhousehold incomes. Incomes generally rise gradually asthe level of prices rises. They do not jump by the same 10percent in the first month that payments do. Thus, anincrease in nominal interest rates stemming from an in­crease in the inflation premium would raise the initial realburden of this loan by virtually 10 percent. Suppose that alender followed a payment-to-income rule and that theborrower would be permitted in either inflation scenario toborrow an amount that would imply a $235 payment. In thezero percent inflation case, a loan of $10,000 would begranted; in the five percent inflation case, a loan of only$9,087 would be granted.

This happens even though households and financialinstitutions both may think that they are adjusting forinflation. By basing their decisions on the ratio of two(nominal or real) flows, which often leads to an inflation­adjusted magnitude, they may be attempting to make a"real" decision. They are not. The reason is straightfor­ward: the dollar payment per dollar of credit extended riseswith the nominal interest rate. The only type of loanrepayment schedule currently available provides for level

dollar repayments. As time passes and inflation raises thelevel of wages and prices, those level payments constitutefalling real payments.'> Since later nominal repaymentswill be less in real terms, earlier ones must be greater topreserve the same average real payment and real rate ofinterest.

Over time, lenders might be expected to make lendingpolicy parameters "realistic" to maintain optimal realborrowing limits. In practice, adjustments in lending pol­icy take place so slowly that the aggregate amount ofconsumption that is liquidity constrained is likely to risewith the level of inflation. To the extent that nominal.interest rates respond to (expected) inflation, payment-to­income ceilings would have to rise and fall with inflation toavoid tightening of liquidity constraints. It does appearthat, on average, consumer credit parameters may havebecome somewhat looser in higher inflation periods. Itdoes not appear, however, that they became tighter asinflation fell over the past ten years. In any event, lendingparameters seem to be adjusted slowly enough, if ever, thatas nominal interest rates move in response to inflation,more households become subject to these interest-rate­related restrictions.

The extension of loan maturities may reflect an attemptto overcome the high, initial, real payments brought on byinflation-related increases in nominal interest rates. Theevidence does seem to be that loan maturities have consis­tently lengthened over the past four decades, but that seemsto have gone on apart from the rise and fall of inflation.Regardless, attempting to solve the real-payment-tilt prob­lem with longer maturities is indirect and inefficient sincelonger loans have lower, but still level, dollar payments.

Figure 1*Real Nominal and Real Loan Payments

Payment ($)

260

250

240

230

220

2 1 0 -h-..,...,...,...,...,...,...,...,...,...,..,...,..,........,..,...,...,.....,..,...,....,..,..,..,...,....,..,..,,..,..,....,..,..,,...,..,....,...,..................................12 24 36 48

42

*Basedon $10,000, 48-month, fully-amortizing loan with a 6% real interestrate.

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 44: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

II. Micro EvidenceOne potential way to measure the extent of aggregate

liquidity constraint is to look at data on loan applica­tions disapproved." However, the results of such a studywill almost certainly understate the degree of liquidityconstraint since borrowing constraints related to actualincome may not be imposed only by lenders but also (self­imposed) by households. To the extent they recognize thatlenders impose payment-to-income restrictions, house­holds are likely to adjust current borrowing behavior as ahedge against temporary declines in actual income in thefuture. This may explain why, for example, so manyhouseholds purchase lines of credit through credit cardfees. Such lines may provide access to the credit thatlenders otherwise would refuse to extend under circum­stances that would lead a borrower to seek it. By temperingtheir debt accumulation and by maintaining lines of credit,households effectively have credit-access insurance.

Likewise, households may not bother applying for creditwhen they (accurately) forecast that they do not fall underlenders' payment-to-income ceilings. Most households arelikely to believe (accurately) that their prospects for obtain­ing additional credit are dim when they are unemployed,for example, and therefore may not even apply. Finally,even though the constrained may end up obtaining credit,the amount they borrow will be less than if they were notconstrained. In the mortgage market, for example, it iscommon for potential borrowers to seek prior estimatesfrom lenders directly or indirectly of the maximum mort­gage they would qualify for and then to adjust homepurchases accordingly.

As an alternative approach to assessing the extent towhich consumers are liquidity constrained, a number ofempirical studies have investigated the consumption be­havior of individual households. The important questionfor our purposes is whether liquidity-constrained consum­ers are numerous enough or receive a large enough share ofaggregate income that aggregate consumption patterns areimportantly affected. Below, I briefly review the results ofstudies of the spending patterns of individuals with thatin mind.

Hall and Mishkin (1982) used data from the early 1970son income and consumption of food by individual fam­ilies. They conclude that 80 percent of these actual con­sumption expenditures appear to move in the mannerprescribed by the liquidity-unconstrained, permanent in­come hypothesis. Their results further suggest that muchof the deviation of actual from unconstrained consumptionis .due to the inability to borrow to overcome temporaryincome shortfalls. Hall and Mishkin conclude that "food

Federal Reserve Bankof San Francisco

consumption behaves as if constraints on borrowing wererelatively unimportant."

Hayashi (1985) analyzed consumption behavior of twogroups of consumers in the early 1960s: those who hadhigh savings and those who did not. The hypothesis wasthat consumers who had accumulated wealth were unlikelyto be constrained in their consumption behavior since theycould self-finance more consumption by saving less, oreven by dissaving. In contrast, those who did not have highsavings were more likely to find their consumption re­stricted if liquidity constraints did, in fact, exist.

When the empirical model that best tracked the con­sumption of the high savers was used to predict theconsumption of the low savers, Hayashi found that lowsavers tended to spend less (and save more) than the modelforecasted. The rationale given for that result is thatliquidity constraints prevented the group with low accumu­lated savings from consuming as much as they otherwisewould have chosen; their inability to borrow precludedspending. The group whose consumption seemed mostconstrained was young households. That result is consis­tent with the typical upward tilt in age-earnings and in age­wealth profiles.

Mariger (1986) also concluded "that liquidity con­straints are quite prevalent." Again employing the early1960sdata set, his estimates suggest that about twenty per­cent of families were liquidity constrained. These familiesaccounted for about one-sixth of aggregate consumption.

Zeldes (1988) uses food consumption data collectedfrom the late 1960s through the early 1980s to assesswhether binding liquidity constraints have been wide­spread. Like Hayashi, he splits the individual-family dataset in two. The specific criterion is whether the family has anon-negligible wealth-to-income ratio. He then estimateswhether either group seems to exhibit consumption be­havior that is consistent with the presence of borrowingconstraints. He finds that, as Fitzgerald and Hemingwayfirst conjectured, the rich are different.'? Their consump­tion displayed no indication of being constrained by aninability to borrow, whereas that of the group with the lowwealth-to-income ratio did.

These studies each find that a minority of households hasbeeninfluenced by either binding current, Or potentially­binding future, liquidity constraints. Taken together, thesestudies seem to make a compelling case for the practicalimportance of liquidity constraints. First, the fraction ofhouseholds deemed to be constrained was a substantialminority. Finding that about 20 percent of consumers hadbeen constrained implies serious deviation from the un-

43

Page 45: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

constrained model of aggregate consumption. Since theunconstrained consumers are able optimally to smooththeir consumption, it may be that the remaining consumersaccount for a very large fraction of total consumptionvariability. 18

Second, of all the items in the household budget, expen­diture for food would seem to be one of the least likely to

be liquidity constrained. Food consumption is usually con­sidered very income inelastic; it is the last purchase tobe sacrificed when income falls. Evidence that the foodexpenditures of twenty percent of all households are con­strained suggests that expenditures on the remaining cate­gories of expenditure may be vastly more affected. 19

III. Macro Evidence

Given the evidence from studies of the spending patternsof individual households, this section investigates whetherliquidity constraints have important effects on aggregateconsumption behavior. According to the liquidity-uncon­strained version of the permanent income hypothesis ofconsumption, no lagged values of any variable should helppredict the growth rate of consumption. Table I providesevidence to the contrary. It presents the results of regress­ing consumption on the first four lags of (personal dispos­able) income. Rows I, 2, and 3 present the results of usinglagged income to predict total consumption expenditures(C), the sum of consumer expenditures on nondurables andon services (CNS), and consumer expenditures on dura­bles (CD), respectively. All variables in Table I are ex­pressed as real, per capita, seasonally-adjusted percentagechanges at annual rates. Current growth rates are based oncurrent relative to prior-quarter levels.

The first two lagged income coefficients tend to besizeable and significant. Lags three and four tend to besmaller and negative. Not surprisingly, t;IE reaction ofdurable goods expenditures to lagged income is consider­ably different from that of nondurables and services. For

nondurables and services, it is reasonable to take both thesize and the timing of the consumption services that flowfrom them to be the same as expenditures on them. When itcomes to durables, such an assumption is patently unrea­sonable.s? A $20,000 expenditure this quarter for a newautomobile is almost entirely investment and little con­sumption. The continuing flow of consumption servicesfrom past durable goods purchases, therefore, suggests thata positive response of durable goods expenditures to in­come is likely to be followed by negative ones. That is whatRow 3 shows. After large and significant positive re­sponses to the first two lags of income, large, negativeresponses appear.

The F-statistics in each row test whether the laggedvalues of income significantly help predict consumption.Since each of the calculated F-statistics exceeds the .05significance level (critical value of 2.37), I conclude thateach of the measures of consumption is predicted bylagged, actual-income movements. 21 This predictabilityof consumption growth argues against the simplest versionof the permanent income theory as a sufficient explanationfor consumption.

44 Economic Review I Fall 1989

Page 46: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

The results in Table 1, however, do not point to thereasons the permanent income hypothesis might be vio­lated. The results presented in Table 2 suggest that laggedincome and lagged consumption appear to affect consump­tion to the extent that each serves as a proxy for currentincome. Table 2 shows the results of arbitrarily splitting thesample period into decades and testing whether laggedvalues of consumption and income help predict consump­tion and income. (Reported F-statistics above 2.65 in Table2 indicate statistical confidence above the.95 level.) Whencurrent income is predicted by its own lags, as in the 1950sand, to a lesser extent, the 1960s, lagged income serves asan effective proxy for current income. Those are also theperiods when consumption is predicted by lagged in­come.22 When income is not predicted by past income, asin the 1970s and 1980s, lagged income does not serve as aneffective proxy for current income. In those periods, con­sumption is not predicted by past income.

Similar findings pertain to lagged consumption. Whenactual income is predicted by, and therefore effectivelyproxied by, lagged consumption, as in the 1980s, con­sumption is significantly related to its own lags. Whenlagged consumption does not serve as an effective proxyfor current income, lagged consumption does not signifi­cantly predict current consumption. The exception to thispattern is that, in the 1970s, when income is not predictedby lags of consumption, lagged consumption still helpspredict consumption. 23 These results indicate that it is notlagged income or lagged consumption per se that affectsconsumption. Instead, what they suggest is that consump­tion reacts to current income to an extent greater than iswarranted by the permanent income hypothesis.

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

Testing for Liquidity Constraints

The finding that consumption does not correspond to thepredictions of the simplest version of the permanent in­come hypothesis does not necessarily invalidate it. Asnoted earlier, consumption growth also may be affected bychanges in the real interest rate and be completely inaccord with the permanent income hypothesis. The appar­ent violation reported above may reflect that effect. How­ever, as I argue, an alternative explanation for the resultsin Tables 1 and 2 is that consumption is importantly af­fected by liquidity constraints associated with payment-to­income ceilings on borrowing.

This hypothesis implies that changes in the nominal in­terest rate (0, as distinguished from changes in the realinterest rate, and changes in the unemployment rate (U),which proxy for changes in current income, affect thegrowth rate of aggregate consumption expenditures onnondurables and services, apart from their effects on per­manent income.24 Suppose that the propensity to consumeout of permanent income apart from the liquidity con­straints associated with i and U is k*, that the actual pro­pensity to consume is k, and that the two are related by:25

k = k*e(aU+[3i) (6)

On the assumption that (X and ~ are negative, equation (6)embodies the hypothesis that, as either the unemploymentrate or the nominal interest rate rises, consumption isreduced relative to the level implied by permanent income.The reason is that as either rises, liquidity constraintswill bind on more households and more consumption perhousehold. Taking logarithms of equation (6), then sub­stituting into equation (1), and allowing for the real interestrate effects discussed earlier produces:

D.log(C) = 'Y + 8r:"'1 + (XD.U + ~D.i + f.L (7)

Table 3 shows the results of estimating equation (7) andsome variations of it. To ensure consistent estimates andvalid statistical inference of the effect of each of theseright-hand-side variables on consumption growth, an in­strumental variables estimation technique was used. 26

This approach addresses two problems. First, the currentchanges in unemployment and interest rates (and presuma­bly in almost all other macroeconomic variables) are verylikely to be correlated with current revisions to permanentincome and are, therefore, correlated with the equation'serror term.

Second, even if households are continuously obeying thepermanent income hypothesis, quarterly-average meas­ures of consumption growth will be correlated with theprevious period's consumption growth, which is deter-

45

Page 47: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

mined by the previous period's new information. Thisapparent violation of the permanent income hypothesisemanates from time-averaging of data, not from a violationof the theory. The induced autocorrelation implies that,when time-averaged data are employed (as they are here),the consumption equation error term will be correlatedwith one-period-lagged variables, such as the one-period­lagged expected real interest rate that equation (7) suggestsis relevant. Thus, one-period-lagged variables are not validinstruments.

The variables used as instruments are a constant termand lags two through five of the first differences of theunemployment rate, the expected inflation rate, the autoloan rate, the Treasury bill rate, and the real, after-taxTreasury bill rate.?" Expected real interest rates werederived by subtracting the one-year expected inflation ratefrom the nominal interest rate.28

The top and bottom halves of Table 3 use as the

consumption measure the sum of expenditures on con­sumer nondurables and services (CNS) and expenditureson consumer durables (CD), respectively. Row 1 presentsresults from estimating equation (5), the modified (uncon­strained) permanent income hypothesis, using the real,after-tax Treasury bill interest rate as the measure of thelending rate that consumers face."? As can be seen fromthese results, the real interest rate does not have a signifi­cant effect on consumption. Row 2 adds the two presumeddeterminants of the degree of economy-wide liquidityconstraint: the unemployment rate and an interest rate atwhich consumers can borrow. The borrowing rate thathouseholds face is taken to be the nominal, before-tax,interest rate on auto loans. Row 3 includes both theborrowing and the lending interest rates households face.The lending rate is taken to be the Treasury bill rate. Theborrowing and lending rates that consumers face did notalways move closely over this period, in part due to

46 Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 48: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

regulations, in part due to maturity differences. The esti­mates.show that the borrowing rate clearly is the dominantfinancial force.>" That the entire interest-rate impact takesplace through the nominal borrowing rate is just what apayment-to-income constraint leads us to expect.

Consistently, the estimated effect of (lagged, expected)real interest rates on nondurables and services expenditureis negative, small, and statistically indistinguishable fromzero. This coincides with most earlier research and holdsregardless whether liquidity constraint proxies are in­cluded .. By contrast, the liquidity constraint proxies arelarge and significant. 31

Rows 5-8 use expenditures on durables as the depend­ent variable. These results are qualitatively similar to thosefor nondurables and services. The unemployment rate andinterest rate coefficients are large and clearly statisticallysignificant in each row. Again, the borrowing rate domi­nates the lending rate. The real-rate effects are positive andmuch larger than for nondurables and services, but neverapproach statistical significance.

The estimates in Table 3 also embody some equalitiesthat support the. payment-to-income-constraint hypothe­sis. Since the coefficients for durables are about five timesas large as those for nondurable and services spending andsince the level of the latter category is about five times aslarge as that of the former, the estimated reduction inspending due to a rise in either the unemployment rate orthe nominalinterest rate is about the same for both spend­ing categories.

Second, equality of the interest-rate- and unemploy­ment-rate-spending elasticities cannot be rejected. Tests ofthat hypothesis for expenditures on nondurables and serv­ices.and for expenditures on durables generate t-statisticsof -0.8 and 1.8, respectively, each of which is belowthe critical value for a .05 significance test. 32 These resultsare consistent with the hypothesis concerning payment-to­income constraints since equal percentage changes in theinterest rate and in the unemployment rate should have(approximately) the same effect on the payment-to-incomeratio and therefore on the degree of liquidity constraint.

Third, when Rows 4 and 8 of the table are re-estimatedusing the two individual components of the nominal inter­est rate, the expected real rate and the expected inflationrate, the estimated coefficients on the components areclose to that on their sum. Statistical tests of this equalitywithin each spending category do not call for rejection; therespective t-statistics were 0.6 and 1.7, considerablybelow the critical value for confidence at the .95 level.Thus, it seems that it is not the expected inflation rate northe real rate component of the nominal interest rate, but thenominal interest rate in toto, that affects consumer spend­ing. This finding is consistent with the hypothesis ad­vanced here that the nominal interest rate affects paymentsand through this channel, affects spending.

Equation (6) can be rewritten as

(8)

The heavy line in Figure 2 plots the constraint for nondur-

CombinedConstraint

UnemploymentRate Constraint

Figure 2Constraints on Consumptionof Nondurables and ServicesPercent of

UnconstrainedConsumption40

35

30

25

20

15

10

5

Q-+--.-r-l...............-..--.-.....,...,...,...,....,...,....,...,...,.."'1'""T"T"T-.-r-r-r--.-.""T""l....................,....,.-,-,...,...,...,

1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco 47

Page 49: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

Expected RealInterest-Rate

Constraint

NominalInterest-Rate

Constraint

ExpectedInflation-Rate

Constraint

Figure 3Decomposition of the

Nominal Interest Rate ConstraintPercent ofUnconstrainedConsumption

30

25

20

15

10

5

o-5

- 1 0 -f---,--.-........-,--.-.--.-.--.-.--.-........-,--.-.--.-......,.....,--.-.--.-.--.-.--.-......,.....,--.-.--.-.,...,....,....,...,,.....,1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985

abies and services spending implied by the estimates inRow 4 of Table 3. This constraint shows the joint effects onthe propensity to consume out of permanent income overtime due to changes in unemployment and interest rates. Inthe 1970s, this constraint rose and then declined brisklyafter 1980. Apparently, the effects of rising nominal inter­est rates have offset those of falling unemployment ratesover the last few years, stalling the decline in the con­straint.

The separate effects of unemployment and interest ratesare also plotted in Figure 2. The estimates suggest that theconstraint related to the nominal interest rate generally hashad a much larger effect on spending than that related tothe unemployment rate. The reason for this may be thatmany more households are affected by payment changesthan by income changes.

Equation (9) separates k, into its components, the effectsof changes in expected real rates, k., and of changes inexpected inflation, kp '

k, = e13; = e13(r + p) = e13re 13p=k k (9)1 r p

All three are plotted in Figure 3. Figure 3 reflects thedominant role of expected inflation in interest rate move­ments and consequently in changes in the constraint. Thesecular rise of expected inflation until the 1980s is esti­mated alone to have increased the constraint by about 15percentage points. Since the early 1980s, lower expectedinflation and lower real rates have combined to reduceliquidity constraints operating through nominal interestrates, thereby freeing consumers to spend more.

IV. Interpretations and Implications

The evidence presented here points to large and relia­ble responses of aggregate consumption expenditures tochanges in unemployment and in nominal interest rates.This is consistent with the view that large numbers ofhouseholds find themselves liquidity constrained. I arguethat this constraint emanates from households being con­strained in their ability to borrow as a result of lenders'payment-to-income restrictions.

These borrowing restrictions become more binding asnominal interest rates rise. Given that the major factordriving nominal rates has been expected inflation, house­holds become increasingly liquidity constrained as ex­pected inflation rate rises. This prevents households from

carrying out their utility-maximizing consumption. This isan example of a large, real cost of expected inflation, onethat may help account for households' generally inexplica­ble antipathy to expected inflation.

The presence of, and even the possibility of future,liquidity constraints means that aggregate spending willbehave very differently than is predicted by models thatignore such constraints. The impacts of fiscal and mone­tary policies, short-run or long-run, will depend upon theamount and nature of liquidity constraints faced by varioushouseholds. Since the degree of liquidity constraint islikely to differ systematically by group, assessment ofthese policies should allow for differential effects on the

48 EconomicReview / Fall 1989

Page 50: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

young and the old, the rich and the poor, the homeownerand the renter. Without allowance for these distributionalconsiderations, the workings of the economy and theeffects of policies are likely to be misunderstood.

In the absence of liquidity constraints, changes in fiscalpolicy that the public perceives to be temporary would notbe expected to affect consumption much, especially that ofthe young. In the presence of liquidity constraints, how­ever, the change in cash flows can greatly alter households'ability to achieve desired consumption, especially that ofthe young. A temporary income tax reduction, for exam­ple, might change permanent income very little, but mightraise consumption virtually dollar-for-dollar, as consumersfound themselves less bound by liquidity constraints. 33

The widespread presence of liquidity constraints alsoaffects the effectiveness of monetary policy, since nominalinterest rate changes have large effects on expenditures. Infact, in contrast to much recent theorizing, anticipated

monetary policy may have larger effects than unanticipatedpolicy, since it is the anticipated part of inflation thatprimarily affects nominal interest rates.

The substantial response of aggregate consumption tonominal-interest- and expected-inflation rates suggeststhat a large number of households are genuinely bound bythe cash-flow constraint associated with those factors. Thispaper has not addressed the reasons that such constraintspersist. To the extent they are associated with institutionaland psychological factors that can be overcome, the finan­cialservices industry can satisfy a heretofore-constrained,enormous household demand for credit. The easiest way totap this unmet demand is to introduce financial instrumentsthe payments of which are geared to the upward tilt inhousehold income associated with long-run aggregate pro­ductivity increases, long-run individual real income in­creases, and, especially, increases in the average level ofprices.

NOTES

1.The variabilities referred to are the standard errors of theestimate generated by separately regressing the ratio ofeach spending component (in real terms) to detrendedreal GNP on a linear trend with the 194702-198803quarterly data. Detrended real GNP consists of the expo­nentiated fitted values obtained by regressing the log ofreal GNP ona constant, a linear trend, and the square ofthe linear trend.2. For example, a nominal interest rate variable is signifi­cant when added to the FRBSF econometric model'scurrent equation for consumer expenditures on nondur­ables and services. The durables expenditure equationalready has a nominal rate variable included, in order tohandle credit rationing effects. For a typical example ofsignificant estimated nominal interest rate effects on ag­gregate consumption, see Blinder and Deaton (1985).3. Consumers and households are referred to inter­changeably, as are liquidity or borrowing or financingconstraints. I do not attempt to ascertain why lenders havechosen their lending criteria or why they so seldomchange them.

4. Of course, the optimal forecast may be that actualincome will change. During a period of perceived-to-be­temporary unemployment, the optimal forecast will be thatincome will rise on average over time. The optimal fore­cast of what average income will be over a fixed period willbe revised as new information arrives, but the directionand size of those revisions will not be predictable. Optimalforecasts have the property that no one, including theforecaster, can forecast how the forecast will change.

5. Liquidity constraints may affect not only households.Econometric estimates of business investment spendinglong have found substantial effects of various financialvariables which can be interpreted as indicating whether

Federal Reserve Bankof San Francisco

firms are likely to face liquidity constraints. Recent micro­economic evidence concurs with the earlier aggregateestimates that support the significant role played by theseconstraints on business borrowing. Given the size of theeconomic units involved and the relatively more collateri­zable nature of the assets being financed by businesses,it is easy to imagine that individual households also mightbe subject to financing constraints.

6. Household expenditures are financed with some com­bination of current income, changes in gross householddebt, and changes in gross household savings (assets).To illustrate the typical financing pattern, three regres­sions were performed. In each, the change in personalconsumption expenditures was regressed on the changein one of the methods of financing. The data were monthly,current-dollar, seasonally adjusted at an annual rate, andcovered the period 1975:03-1988:10. Each regressioncontained one regressor but no constant term. Incomewas calculated as the sum of the consumption and netsaving measures. Consumption was taken to be totalpersonal consumption expenditures. The flow of net sav­ingwas taken to be personal saving. The flow of debtwas taken to be the net (extensions minus repayments)change in consumer installment credit.

The results show that an additional dollar of consumptiontypically is financed with an estimated $0.62 of additionalincome, $0.13 of reduced (gross) saving, and $0.25 ofadditional debt. Although aggregate household assetsexceed household liabilities, the distribution of financialassets is very skewed, with most households owning veryfew. One consequence is that, per dollar change in con­sumer spending, the change in the flow of credit is abouttwice as large as that of (gross) saving. Thus, changingcredit flows are an integral part of changes in consump­tion. These estimates also hint that the borrowing, rather

49

Page 51: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

than the lending, rate that households face may be morerelevant for household spending.7. Applying lending criteria based on current income torecipients of social security income, which is tied to theCPI by statute, seems especially perplexing.8. Credit-granting processes that do not use age as adetermining factor then may inadvertently discriminateagainst the young.9. Tobin and Dolde (1971) discuss some types of liquidityconstraints and, through simulations, assess their effectson consumption. Walsh (1986) models the fraction ofconsumers whose consumption is liquidity constraineddue to an inability borrow against future income. Thefraction is affected by the level of wealth and also fluctu­ates with actual aggregate income. He concludes that it isinappropriate in such circumstances to treat aggregateconsumption as being the outcome of fixed shares ofconstrained and unconstrained households.

10. See Beares (1987). One example in Beares (1987)shows how the average maturity of a consumer's loanscan be lengthened in order to reduce the payment-to­income ratio and thereby enable the lender to extendcredit to a loan applicant that it would otherwise turndown. This does not mean that a payment-to-incomeceiling is the sole criterion. Various consumer lendingtextbooks refer to various criteria, e.g., the six "c's'' ofcredit. The literature and discussions with consumer lend­ing officials do suggest that lending policies set ceilingson payment-to-income ratios, and rely much less on debt­to-income ratios. In spite of that, it is apparently commonin this industry and its literature to refer to debt-to-incomeratios when meaning payment-to-income ratios.

11. Such rules may have developed from either house­holds' or financial institutions' fear of default. Households'recognition that they may be subject to future constraintsmay also influence their current behavior.12. The unemployed referred to here are those who wouldnot generally be deemed to be guaranteed re-employ­ment. We mean to exclude the seasonally unemployed~~d those on definitely temporary layoff, for example, butIt IS not apparent that much is made of this distinction inthe credit process.13. Suppose, for the sake of this example, that incometaxes are irrelevant.14. In this example all dollar amounts have been roundedto the nearest dollar. Calculations were based on un­rounded amounts.15.It is commonly, and mistakenly, thought that adjustablerate loans cure this problem. They do not. Such loansallow payments to vary with the interest rate, and therefore!ndir~ctly with the inflation rate. In a period of steadyinflation, they do not, however, imply constant real pay­ments over the repayment period. Similarly, graduatedpayment mortgages provide for payments that are lowerinitially and rise for a short period. The rate of increase ofthose payments is not tied to the inflation rate. After theinitial period, payments typically are constant in nominal

50

terms for the remainder of the term of the mortgage, andtheretore likewise fall in real terms if there is inflation.16. The American Bankers Association's annual RetailBank Credit Report for the years 1979, 1980, and 1981(only)does contain a table headed "Reasons why bor­rowers m~y fail to qualify for financing during (that year)."The candidate reasons were inadequate income, insuffi­cient equity, inadequate income management, and other.For large banks, the percentage judged to have "inade­quateincome" rose over those years from 31 to 43 to 47percent.17.F. Scott Fitzgerald: "You know, Ernest, the rich aredifferent from us."Ernest Hemingway: "Yes, they have money." (attributed)

l? Optirnatsmoothinq is not ~he same as total smoothing.Since permanent Income vanes, optimal consumption willtoo.19..Hall and Mishkin state that their results for food implynothing about the behavior of other expenditures.20. It is, however, reasonable to question how durablemuch of what is classified in the national income accountsas services and nondurables is.

21. Table 1 shows the ability of lagged income to predictconsumption. That contrasts with the results presented byHall (1978), whose sample period ended with 197701data. When my sample period is terminated at 197701, Iget results much like his (F-statistic = 2.19). Re-estimat­ing with a sample that is just one year longer, however,implies rejection of the unpredictability hypothesis. Bothlonger and shorter samples generally lead to rejection ofthe unpredictability hypothesis. Variables other than in­come also may lead to that result.22. From now on, unless otherwise noted, consumptionrefers to the sum of nondurables and services, expendi­tures on which correspond most closely to the flow ofconsumption services. Total consumption service flowwould also include the flow of services from the outstand­ing stock of consumer durables. Since our objective hereis to explain expenditures, we consider expenditures ononly these two consumption categories.

23. This. hints that there are factors other than changes incurrent Income that are associated with the violation of thepermanent income hypothesis.24. The unemployment rate is used here to proxy foraggregate income. Flavin (1985) concludes that the un­employment rate is superior empirically to a measure ofthe deviation of actual income from its permanent value inaccounting for consumption.25. Even if there were no interest- and unemployment­rate-related liquidity constraints, those arising from theage-earnings profile might exist. In what follows, I take k*to be equal to one.26. For a more complete discussion of these issues, seeHall (1988) and Campbell and Mankiw (1987).27. Specifically, I used the investment yield to maturity ona three-month Treasury bill. The finance rate on 48 month

Economic Review / Fall 1989

Page 52: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

automobile loans comes from DR!. Until 1984, I used theaverage marginal personal income tax rate on interestincome from Peek and Wilcox (1987). The rates for 1984,1985,and 1986 have been calculated in the same manner.The rates for 1987 and 1988 are assumed to be 27 and 25percent, respectively. For each quarter I used the corre­sponding annual rate. The tax rate for the upcomingquarter is applied to the interest rate for the currentquarter.28.The expected inflation data are taken from the Living­stan survey, which records expectations each June andDecember. I used those values for the second and fourthquarter Observations, respectively. First and third quarterobservations were obtained by interpolating betweensecond and fourth quarter observations.29. Using lags of the explanatory variables required short­ening the sample slightly. Starting the sample after theKorean War, omitting 1975(due to the one-time income taxrebate), and omitting 1980 (due to the imposition andremoval of credit controls) each seemed to make littledifference to the estimates.

30. To the extent that credit rationing effects stemmingfrom adverse selection become more severe as open­market nominal interest rates rose, I would have expectedthe Treasury bill yield better to have explained consump­tion. The reason is that if banks do not raise loan ratescommensurately with open market rates, the open marketrate would likely better capture the combined constrainteffects of bank rules (as already proxied by the borrowingrate) and of credit rationing (as captured by the differencebetween the lending and borrowing rates). In fact, theseestimates provide little evidence to support that effect.

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

31. An alternative functional form for k is one which islinear, as opposed to the linear-in-Iogarithms form in (6).Specifying k = k* + aU + 13i necessitates using anonlinear instrumental variables estimation technique.Doing so produces qualitatively similar results to thosepresented in Table 3. Estimates of the linear form werealso obtained while including the squares of the unem­ployment rate and of the interest rate. This allowed thedatatosuggest whether liquidity constraints bind more, orless, than proportionately as rates rise. Significantly nega­tivecoefficients estimated for the squared unemploymentand interest rate terms would imply that an accelerating­constraint hypothesis fit the data better. The squaredterms turned out to be negative, but insignificant. Thus nostrong conclusion about the appropriate functional formfor kemerged.32. Since these consumption equations do not deliverconstant elasticities, the test is for equality of the elas­ticities at the respective sample means of the unemploy­ment and interest rates.33. Even a permanent, anticipated, balanced-budget shiftin tax policy could affect aggregate spending. One way todo so would be to have some parameters of the tax codebe age-specific, perhaps by making average income taxrates rise with the age of the taxpayer. To the extent thatyoung-household cash flows were enhanced and bal­anced by reductions for older households, the averageamount of constraint would be loosened.

51

Page 53: Economic Review: Fall 1989, Number 4 - FRASER · 2018-11-07 · 10to 20 percentof their asp from agricultural production. Incontrast, miningand forestry play less dominantroles even

REFERENCES

Bearss, Paul. Consumer Lending. American Bankers As­sociation, Washington, D.C., 1987.

Blinder, AlanS.andAngusDeaton. "The Time SeriesConsumption Function Revisited,"BrookingsPaperson Economic Activity. Washington, D.C., 1985:2.

Campbell, John and N-. Gregory Mankiw. "PermanentIncome, Current Income, and Consumption," Ne­tionaCBureauofEconomic. ReSearch.Working PaperNo. 2436. November 1987.

Flavin; Marjorie. "Excess Sensitivity of Consumption toCurrent Income: Liquidity Constraints or Myopia?,"CanadianJournal ofEconomics, 18,February1985.

Hall, Robert E. "Intertemporal Substitution inConsurnp­tion, '.' Joumel.o;Political Economy, 86, April 1988.

____ and Frederick S. Mishkin. "The Sensitivityof Consumption to Transitory Income Estimatesfrom Panel Data on Households," Econometrica, 50,March 1982.

Hayashi, Fumio. "The Effect of Liquidity Constraints onConsumption: A Cross-Sectional Analysis," QuarterlyJournal of Economics, 100, February 1985.

52

KoUikoff, Laurence J. "Intergenerational Transfers andSavings," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2,Spring 1.988.

Mariger, Randall P.Consumption Behavior andtheEffectsof Government Fiscal Policies. Cambridge, Massa­chusetts: Harvard University Press,1986.

Peek,Joe andJames A. Wilcox. "Monetary Policy RegimeChanges andthe Reduced.Form fori nterestRates,"Journal ofMoney, Credit, and Banking, 19, August198?

Tobin,James and Walter Dolde."Wealth, Liquidity andConsumption.: Consumer. Spending and MonetaryPolicy: The Linkages." Federal Reserve Bankof Bos­ton Conference Series, No. 5, June1971.

Walsh, Carl.E. "Borrowing Restrictions and Wealth Con­straints:lmplications for Aggregate Consumption,"Working Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of San Fran­cisco, September 1986.

Wilcox, David W. "Social Security Benefits, Consumption,Expenditure, and the LifeCycleHypothesis," Journalof Political Economy, 97, April 1989.

Zeldes, Stephen P. "Consumption and Liquidity Con­straints: An Empirical Investigation," Journal of Politi­cal Economy, 97, April 1989.

Economic Review I Fall 1989