do earnings targets and managerial incentives affect sticky ......prior studies (abj, balakrishnan,...

24
DOI: 10.1111/j.1475-679X.2012.00471.x Journal of Accounting Research Vol. 00 No. 0 2012 Printed in U.S.A. Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky Costs? ITAY KAMA AND DAN WEISS Received 25 January 2010; accepted 11 September 2012 ABSTRACT This study explores motivations underlying managers’ resource adjustments. We focus on the impact of incentives to meet earnings targets on resource ad- justments and the ensuing cost structures. We find that, when managers face incentives to avoid losses or earnings decreases, or to meet financial analysts’ earnings forecasts, they expedite downward adjustment of slack resources for sales decreases. These deliberate decisions lessen the degree of cost stickiness rather than induce cost stickiness. The results suggest that efforts to under- stand determinants of firms’ cost structures should be made in light of the managers’ motivations, particularly agency-driven incentives underlying re- source adjustment decisions. 1. Introduction This study is part of a recently emerging stream of research aiming to ex- pand our understanding of how managerial choices in adjusting resources Faculty of Management, Tel Aviv University. Accepted by Abbie Smith. The authors are grateful for constructive suggestions and help- ful comments from an anonymous reviewer, Yakov Amihud, Eli Amir, Itay Ater, Rajiv Banker, Avraham Beja, Jeffrey Callen, Gavin Cassar, Mustafa Ciftci, Bart Dierynck, Surya Janakiraman, Michael Maher, Raj Mashruwala, Robert Pindyck, K. Sivaramakrishnan, Avi Wohl, participants of the American Accounting Association (AAA) Annual Meetings, and the Management Ac- counting Section Midyear Meeting. We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Henry Crown Institute of Business Research in Israel. Part of this research was performed dur- ing a visit to London Business School. An earlier version of this study was titled “Do Managers’ Deliberate Decisions Induce Sticky Costs?” 1 Copyright C , University of Chicago on behalf of the Accounting Research Center, 2012

Upload: others

Post on 21-Feb-2021

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

DOI: 10.1111/j.1475-679X.2012.00471.xJournal of Accounting Research

Vol. 00 No. 0 2012Printed in U.S.A.

Do Earnings Targets and ManagerialIncentives Affect Sticky Costs?

I T A Y K A M A ∗ A N D D A N W E I S S ∗

Received 25 January 2010; accepted 11 September 2012

ABSTRACT

This study explores motivations underlying managers’ resource adjustments.We focus on the impact of incentives to meet earnings targets on resource ad-justments and the ensuing cost structures. We find that, when managers faceincentives to avoid losses or earnings decreases, or to meet financial analysts’earnings forecasts, they expedite downward adjustment of slack resources forsales decreases. These deliberate decisions lessen the degree of cost stickinessrather than induce cost stickiness. The results suggest that efforts to under-stand determinants of firms’ cost structures should be made in light of themanagers’ motivations, particularly agency-driven incentives underlying re-source adjustment decisions.

1. Introduction

This study is part of a recently emerging stream of research aiming to ex-pand our understanding of how managerial choices in adjusting resources

∗Faculty of Management, Tel Aviv University.Accepted by Abbie Smith. The authors are grateful for constructive suggestions and help-

ful comments from an anonymous reviewer, Yakov Amihud, Eli Amir, Itay Ater, Rajiv Banker,Avraham Beja, Jeffrey Callen, Gavin Cassar, Mustafa Ciftci, Bart Dierynck, Surya Janakiraman,Michael Maher, Raj Mashruwala, Robert Pindyck, K. Sivaramakrishnan, Avi Wohl, participantsof the American Accounting Association (AAA) Annual Meetings, and the Management Ac-counting Section Midyear Meeting. We gratefully acknowledge financial support from theHenry Crown Institute of Business Research in Israel. Part of this research was performed dur-ing a visit to London Business School. An earlier version of this study was titled “Do Managers’Deliberate Decisions Induce Sticky Costs?”

1

Copyright C©, University of Chicago on behalf of the Accounting Research Center, 2012

Page 2: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

2 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

influence firms’ cost structures (Kallapur and Eldenburg [2005], Banker,Ciftci, and Mashruwala [2011], Banker, Huang, and Natarajan [2011],Chen, Lu, and Sougiannis [2012]). It follows Anderson, Banker, and Janaki-raman [2003, p. 47], hereafter ABJ, who termed costs as sticky if they de-crease less when sales fall than they increase when sales rise by an equivalentamount, arguing that sticky costs occur “because managers deliberately adjustthe resources committed to activities.” Focusing on deliberate decisions madeby self-interested managers, we investigate how resource adjustments madeintentionally to meet earnings targets affect the degree of cost stickiness.

When sales fall, some unutilized resources are retained unless managersmake the intentional decision to remove them. ABJ argue that managershesitate to remove slack resources when they expect a sales drop to betemporary. In this case, refraining from resource cuts when sales fall maxi-mizes firm value because of the high costs of adjusting resources downward(e.g., costs of firing employees) and of restoring resources when demandbounces back (Abel and Eberly [1994]). Self-interested managers, however,consider their personal utility when they adjust resources committed to ac-tivities, not only the value of the firm (Roychowdhury [2006], Cohen, Dey,and Lys [2008]).

Facing incentives to meet earnings targets, self-interested managers arelikely to accelerate cuts of slack resources in response to a sales drop evenif the drop is expected to be temporary. These accelerated cuts of slackresources result in greater cost decreases in the presence of incentives tomeet earnings targets than in the absence of such incentives. Therefore,based on the ABJ concept of sticky costs, incentives to meet earnings targetsare likely to lessen the degree of cost stickiness. Specifically, we hypothesizethat: (i) resource adjustments made intentionally to meet earnings targetsdiminish the degree of cost stickiness, and (ii) for a given decrease in sales,managers cut costs more aggressively in the presence of incentives to meetearnings targets than absent these incentives.

The empirical findings, based on a sample of 97,547 firm-year observa-tions from 1979 to 2006, indicate that, when sales fall, managers cut costsmore aggressively in the presence of incentives to avoid losses, to avoidearnings decreases, and to meet financial analysts’ earnings forecasts. Re-source adjustments made to meet these earnings targets significantly mod-erate the degree of cost stickiness. Furthermore, in some contexts, coststickiness is washed away in the presence of these incentives. Several anal-yses and robustness checks corroborate this evidence. Overall, the resultssuggest that the incentives to meet earnings targets lead to deliberate re-source adjustments that diminish cost stickiness.

We also utilize the framework presented by Banker, Ciftci, andMashruwala [2011], hereafter BCM, for testing the relationship betweenincentives to meet earnings targets and the degree of cost stickiness condi-tional on managers’ demand expectations. Facing incentives to meet earn-ings targets, managers are predicted to cut slack resources even if theyhave optimistic demand expectations and these resources are likely to berequired for supplying future demand growth. The findings support the

Page 3: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

EARNINGS TARGETS AND MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 3

prediction, showing that incentives to meet earnings targets significantly di-minish the degree of cost stickiness after controlling for managers’ demandexpectations. Taken as a whole, the empirical evidence suggests that man-agers intentionally adjust resources to meet earnings targets, which lessensthe degree of cost stickiness.

The findings contribute by expanding our understanding of how delib-erate decisions influence asymmetric cost behavior. They demonstrate thatincentives to meet earnings targets lead managers to accelerate resourcecuts when sales fall. That is, agency-driven incentives influence deliberatechoices, which, in turn, affect the degree of cost stickiness. The results em-phasize the role of deliberate decisions in shaping the asymmetry of firms’cost structures.

Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004],Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how managerial choicesmade to maximize firm value induce cost stickiness. Chen, Lu, andSougiannis [2012] show that agency-driven incentives to build empires alsoinduce sticky cost behavior. Our findings, however, suggest that agency-driven incentives to meet earnings targets diminish the degree of cost stick-iness, rather than induce cost stickiness. We conclude that some deliberatedecisions induce sticky costs while others diminish sticky costs, dependingon the underlying motivations.

We note that any effort to infer the sources of sticky costs should be madein light of the motivations underlying managers’ resource adjustments. Ig-noring the impact of agency considerations on documentations of stickycost behavior may bias the inferences due to an omitted correlated variableproblem.

The findings also extend the real earnings management literature bydocumenting how managers adjust resources to meet earnings targets.Therefore, the implications are likely to expand the audience of the coststructure literature beyond management accounting scholars and attractthe attention of financial accountants. In sum, the paper integrates atypical management accounting research topic, cost structures, with animportant financial accounting topic, real earnings management. Theimportance of integrating these two streams of research has long beenrecognized (Weiss [2010]).

The paper proceeds as follows. The hypotheses are developed in the nextsection. Sections 3 and 4 discuss the sample selection and research design,respectively. Sections 5 and 6 present the empirical results, and section 7summarizes.

2. Hypothesis Development

Understanding how incentives to meet earnings targets shape firms’ coststructures is of primary interest to accounting researchers. In particular,choices to cut resources made by self-interested managers have recentlydrawn much attention. Banker, Huang, and Natarajan [2011] show a posi-tive association between grants of equity incentives and increases in input

Page 4: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

4 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

resource spending when input resource expenditures create high futurevalue. Their findings suggest that equity incentives influence managers’ de-cisions to adjust resources, but they do not explore the potential impactof equity incentives on the extent of cost asymmetry. Focusing on agencyaspects, Chen, Lu, and Sougiannis [2012] document how empire-buildingincentives affect managers’ cost decisions made in response to exogenousdemand shocks. They show that empire-building managers increase selling,general, and administrative (SG&A) costs rapidly when sales rise and de-crease these costs slowly when sales fall. That is, empire-building incentivesgenerate cost asymmetry, implying a positive relation between an agencyproblem and the degree of SG&A cost asymmetry.1

A vast body of evidence indicates that agency considerations lead man-agers to reduce costs to meet various benchmarks (Dechow and Sloan[1991], Baber, Fairfield, and Haggard [1991], Bushee [1998]). In particu-lar, Graham, Harvey, and Rajgopal [2005], Roychowdhury [2006], Cohen,Dey, and Lys [2008], and Keung, Lin, and Shia [2010] report that managersreduce costs to avoid losses and earnings decreases, or to meet analysts’forecasts. However, the influence of cost reductions made intentionally tomeet earnings targets on the degree of cost asymmetry has not yet beeninvestigated.

When sales fall, unutilized resources are not eliminated unless managersmake a deliberate decision to remove them. Since future demand is stochas-tic, managers evaluate the likelihood that a drop in sales is temporary whendeciding whether to cut resources. Cutting slack resources when sales fallis likely to result in the incurring of extra costs to adjust resources down-ward (e.g., costs of firing employees) and to replace those resources if salesare restored in the future (e.g., costs of rehiring new employees). There-fore, value-maximizing considerations based on the future sales expecta-tions lead managers to maintain unutilized resources when they expect asales drop to be temporary. Retaining unutilized resources when sales de-cline results in costs that decrease less when sales fall than they increasewhen sales rise by an equivalent amount; that is, sticky costs (ABJ).

In this paper, we investigate the relationship between resource adjust-ments made intentionally to meet earnings targets and the degree of coststickiness. ABJ argue that, in addition to value-maximizing considerations,managers’ choices to maintain unutilized resources may also be caused bypersonal interests. These choices result in the form of agency costs, which,in turn, contribute to cost stickiness. Focusing on resources adjustments,we assert that incentives to meet earnings targets lead managers to accel-erate resource cuts to achieve cost savings. These accelerated cuts of slackresources when sales fall lead to greater cost decreases in the presence ofincentives to meet earnings targets than absent these incentives. For thisreason, we hypothesize that cost stickiness is lessened in the presence ofincentives to meet earnings targets.

1Dierynck, Landsman, and Renders [2012] use a sample of Belgian private companies andfind more asymmetric cost behavior for firms that report small profits.

Page 5: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

EARNINGS TARGETS AND MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 5

Facing earnings targets, the degree of cost stickiness is diminished be-cause managers expedite cost cuts when sales fall. This managerial behaviorexpresses a form of agency costs, which are incurred because self-interestedmanagers, motivated to meet earnings targets, make decisions to maximizetheir personal utility, not firm value. Managers are likely to eliminate slackresources when facing incentives to meet earnings targets and sales fall,even if they expect the sales drop to be temporary. Eliminating slack re-sources results in immediate cost savings, which are imperative for meetingearnings targets. In other words, incentives to meet earnings targets, thatis, agency considerations, lead managers to cut resources more when salesfall than would be optimal from the perspective of maximizing firm value.

When sales rise, however, incentives to meet earnings targets are ex-pected to encourage managers to restrain the hiring of new resources andslow down growth in costs. Yet, we note two reasons that reduce the impactof these incentives in the case of a rise in sales compared with a drop insales.

First, bad news on missing earnings targets is more acute in the pres-ence of additional bad news on sales decrease (Rees and Sivaramakrishnan[2007]). Managers are likely to be under more pressure to avoid reportingbad news on missing earnings targets when it is accompanied by bad newson sales decrease (Graham, Harvey, and Rajgopal [2005]). Therefore, in-centives to meet earnings targets create more pressure, and hence havemore of an impact when they are accompanied by a drop in sales than by arise in sales.

Second, suppose a manager faces incentives to avoid losses, which is oneof the earnings targets frequently used in the literature (e.g., Burgstahlerand Dichev [1997]). If a firm has small positive earnings and a sales risein the current year, it likely experienced losses in the prior year since salesin the prior year were lower. Therefore, the manager has probably alreadycut slack resources in the prior year to reduce the losses. In this case, thereis less slack left to cut in the current year. On the other hand, if a firmhas small positive earnings and a sales drop in the current year, it likelyexperienced larger positive earnings in the prior year, since sales in theprior year were higher. In this case, the manager was under less pressureto cut slack resources in the prior year. Therefore, there is more slack leftto cut in the current year in the presence of a drop in sales than in thepresence of a rise in sales. Overall, the relative impact of incentives to meetearnings targets when sales fall is likely to be greater than when sales rise.

The following hypotheses summarize our arguments:

H1: Resource adjustments made intentionally to meet earnings targets di-minish cost stickiness.

H2: For a given decrease in sales, managers cut costs more aggressively inthe presence of incentives to meet earnings targets than absent theseincentives.

In the next section, we extend ABJ to allow for testing the impact ofdeliberate resource adjustments made to meet earnings targets, in bothfavorable and unfavorable scenarios, on the degree of cost stickiness.

Page 6: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

6 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

3. Research Design

Investigating the impact of managerial discretion motivated by incentivesto meet earnings targets on the degree of cost stickiness, we expand theABJ framework by a battery of additional analyses to test the hypotheses.We focus on operating costs (OC) to capture managerial choices affect-ing the costs of manufacturing goods, the costs of providing services, andthe costs of marketing and distribution. Our approach is consistent withBalakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca[2008], and Weiss [2010]. We employ OC , annual sales revenue minusincome from operations, for estimating the regression models. For theABJ framework, the independent variables are log change of sales revenue(REV ), and log change of REV multiplied by a dummy variable that equals1 if REVit < REVi ,t−1 and 0 otherwise (REVDECit). The estimated regressionmodel is:

�lnOCit = β0 + β1� ln REV it + β2 REVDECit � ln REV it + εit . (1)

In estimating all models, we employ pooled cross-sectional regressions,include year effects, and cluster observations by firm to provide standarderrors that are robust to autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity as suggestedby Petersen [2009]. As a sensitivity check, we also estimate the regressionmodels as in Fama and MacBeth [1973].

In the ABJ framework, the coefficient β1 measures the percentagechange in costs for a 1% increase in sales, indicating the variation of oper-ating costs with sales revenue. Similarly, β1 + β2 measures the percentagechange in operating costs resulting from a 1% decrease in sales. ABJ anda series of subsequent studies report a significantly positive coefficient β1,and a significantly negative coefficient β2 using various samples and con-texts. ABJ claim that a significantly negative coefficient β2 conditional on apositive coefficient β1 indicates sticky costs.

3.1 SUBSAMPLE ANALYSES

Focusing on resource adjustments made intentionally to meet earningstargets, we follow Burgstahler and Dichev [1997], Roychowdhury [2006],and Cohen, Dey, and Lys [2008] in identifying the presence of such incen-tives. These studies argue that firms in the interval just right of zero tend toreduce their costs to meet earnings targets.

Gaining initial insights on the impact of deliberate resource adjustmentsmade to meet earnings targets, we group firm-years into intervals based onnet income before extraordinary items scaled by market capitalization atthe beginning of the year. To increase the power of our tests, we concen-trate on firm-year observations in the interval to the immediate right ofzero; that is, have net income scaled by market capitalization that is greaterthan or equal to zero but less than or equal to 0.01. Following prior studies,observations in this interval are assumed to have incentives to meet earn-ings targets. Similarly, we identify incentives to avoid earnings decreases by

Page 7: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

EARNINGS TARGETS AND MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 7

grouping firm-years into intervals based on changes in net income scaled bymarket capitalization at the beginning of the year. Again, the interval widthis 0.01 and we concentrate on firm-years in the interval to the immediateright of zero.

We estimate model (1) for subsamples of observations with and withoutincentives to avoid losses. The estimated coefficients β2 support the first hy-pothesis if β2 is significant and negative absent incentives to meet earningstargets and significantly higher (i.e., less negative or positive) in the pres-ence of these incentives. The estimated coefficients β1 and β2 support thesecond hypothesis if the slope for sales decreases, β1 + β2, is significantlyhigher in the presence of incentives to meet earnings targets than the slopeabsent these incentives. We repeat these procedures for subsamples of ob-servations with and without incentives to avoid earnings decreases.

3.2 COMPREHENSIVE REGRESSION MODELS

In developing the concept of cost stickiness, ABJ focus on managerialdiscretion only in the case of sales decreases, and assume mechanistic costresponse in the case of sales increases. By contrast, we explore how incen-tives to meet earnings targets influence intentional resource adjustmentswhen sales decrease as well as when sales increase. We extend the ABJ ap-proach to gain insights on resource adjustments made intentionally to meetearnings targets when sales either fall or rise. Specifically, we extend model(1) by adding interaction terms that enable estimation of the relative im-pact of incentives to meet earnings targets on decisions to adjust resourceswhen sales either fall or rise.

We also add control variables employed in ABJ and subsequent studies.First, ABJ report less sticky costs in periods where revenue also declinedin the preceding period. The reason for this is that managers are likelyto consider a revenue decline to be more permanent when it occurs in asecond consecutive period of revenue declines, providing a motivation toscale down resources. Thus, we control for successive revenue decreases.Second, adjustment costs tend to be higher when the firm relies more onself-owned assets and employees than on materials and services purchasedfrom external suppliers. Following prior studies, we control for asset inten-sity and employee intensity.

We estimate the following regression model to test the impact of (1) in-centives to avoid losses, (2) incentives to avoid earnings decreases, and (3)incentives to avoid losses or to avoid earnings decreases (termed “alternateincentives”) on the degree of cost stickiness:

� ln OCit = β0 + γ0 TARGET it + { β1 + γ1 TARG E Tit } � ln R E Vit

+ {β2 + γ2 TARG E Tit + δ1SU C DE Cit + δ2ASI N Tit

+ δ3 E MPI N Tit } × R E V DE Cit � ln R E Vit + εit , (2)

whereTARGETit = {LOSSit , EDECit , LOSSit∪EDECit}, such that:

Page 8: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

8 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

LOSSit is a dummy variable that equals 1 if annual earnings deflated bymarket capitalization of shareholders’ equity at prior year end is in the in-terval (0, 0.01), and 0 otherwise.

EDECit is a dummy variable that equals 1 if the change in annual earningsdeflated by market capitalization of shareholders’ equity at prior year endis in the interval (0, 0.01), and 0 otherwise.

LOSSit∪EDECit is a dummy variable, termed “alternate targets,” thatequals 1 if LOSSit = 1 or EDECit = 1, and 0 otherwise.

Control variables are as follows: SUC DECit is a dummy variable thatequals 1 if revenue in year t−1 is less than in year t−2, and 0 otherwise.ASINTit is the log of the ratio of total assets to sales revenues, and EMPINTit

is the log of the ratio of the number of employees to sales revenue.We extend ABJ for testing whether incentives to meet earnings targets

affect the degree of cost stickiness. In model (2), the slope for sales in-creases in the presence of incentives to meet earnings targets is β1 + γ 1,and the slope for sales decreases in the presence of incentives to meet earn-ings targets is β1 + γ 1 + β2+γ 2 + δ1SUC DEC + δ2ASINT + δ3EMPINT .We note that β1 + γ 1 enters the slope for both increases and decreases.Accordingly, the stickiness measure in the presence of incentives to meetearnings targets is the difference between the two slopes, which equalsβ2 + γ 2 + δ1SUC DEC + δ2ASINT + δ3EMPINT , whereas the stickinessmeasure absent incentives to meet earnings targets is β2 + δ1SUC DEC +δ2ASINT + δ3EMPINT . Therefore, testing the first hypothesis, resource ad-justments made intentionally to meet earnings targets diminish cost sticki-ness if γ 2>0.

Model (2) also provides the means for testing the second hypoth-esis, that is, when managers face incentives to meet earnings targets(i.e., TARGET = 1), they cut costs more aggressively for the same de-crease in sales than absent these incentives. A more aggressive cut incosts in the presence of incentives to meet earnings targets means thatthe slope for sales decreases, β1 + γ 1 + β2 + γ 2 + δ1SUC DEC +δ2ASINT + δ3EMPINT , is greater than the slope absent these incentives,β1 + β2 + δ1SUC DEC + δ2ASINT + δ3EMPINT . That is, the second hy-pothesis holds if γ 1 + γ 2 > 0.

We perform sensitivity analyses to reconfirm that the findings with re-spect to both hypotheses are not affected by technical estimation prob-lems. Specifically, we check whether firm size affects the results by splittingthe sample observations into small and large firms (below and above themedian) and estimating regression model (2) separately for each of thetwo groups. Additionally, to assure that findings are not driven by industry-specific characteristics, we control for potential industry-specific effects us-ing the Fama-French industry classification.2

2http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data˙library.html.

Page 9: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

EARNINGS TARGETS AND MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 9

3.3 INCENTIVE TO MEET FINANCIAL ANALYSTS’ EARNINGS FORECASTS

We expand the span of incentives to meet earnings targets by utilizing fi-nancial analysts’ earnings forecasts. Testing the hypotheses using earningstargets set by financial analysts is important despite the sample size limita-tion imposed by requiring the availability of at least two financial analysts’earnings forecasts. Specifically, we estimate the comprehensive regressionmodel (2), where TARGET is a dummy variable that equals 1 if the analystforecast error (actual minus forecast earnings per share) is between zeroand one cent. As before, the first hypothesis is supported if γ 2 >0 and thesecond hypothesis holds if γ 1 + γ 2 > 0.

3.4 EARNINGS TARGETS IN CONSECUTIVE PERIODS

We also test the impact of prior incentives on current cost stickiness. Thistest is of interest because prior and current incentives are likely to haveopposing effects on current cost stickiness. If managers faced incentives tomeet an earnings target in the prior period and, therefore, already cut theslack resources, then there is less slack left to cut in the current period.Therefore, lagged incentives are likely to increase current stock stickiness,whereas current incentives are likely to reduce current cost stickiness. Weadd lagged TARGET to the estimation model:

� ln OCit = β0 + γ0 TARGET it + ψ0TARGET i,t−1

+ {β1 + γ1 TARGET it + ψ1TARGET i,t−1

}� ln REV it

+ {β2 + γ2 TARGET it + ψ2TARGET i,t−1 + δ1SU C DE Cit

+ δ2ASINT it + δ3EMPINT it} REVDECit � ln REV it + εit .(3)

If managers’ current incentives diminish the degree of current cost stick-iness, regardless of whether or not managers faced the same incentives inthe prior period, then γ 2 > 0. If managers’ prior incentives increase thedegree of current cost stickiness, regardless of whether or not managersface the same incentives in the current period, then ψ2 < 0. In the caseof incentives in two consecutive periods, the degree of current cost stick-iness diminishes if γ 2 + ψ2 > 0. Findings from estimating model (3) canpotentially extend our understanding of the rationale underlying the rela-tionship between incentives to meet earnings targets and the degree of coststickiness.

3.5 THE BCM FRAMEWORK

The recently developed framework by Banker, Ciftci, and Mashruwala[2011], hereafter BCM, provides alternative means for going beyond theABJ assumption that cost behavior remains mechanistic when sales in-crease. BCM explore the role of managers’ optimism with respect to fu-ture demand in shaping decisions to adjust resources in both favorable andunfavorable scenarios. They find that managers’ intentional choices affectcosts in both directions, that is, when sales rise as well as when sales fall.

Page 10: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

10 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

T A B L E 1Sample Selection

Observations Observations DifferentSample Deleted Remaining Firms

Initial sample: Firm-year observations with validdata on Compustat, 1979–2006

135,594 16,149

Excluding observations with share price below $1 14,078 121,516 15,158Excluding observations with missing data on two

preceding years (t−1, t−2)22,565 98,951 11,844

Excluding observations that exhibit extreme valuesfor the regression variables (i.e., in the top andbottom 0.5% of the distribution)

1,404 97,547 11,758

The initial sample includes all firms with complete financial data available on Compustat on sales rev-enue (Compustat #12), operating income (Compustat #178), net earnings (Compustat #172), total assets(Compustat #6), book value (Compustat #60) and market value (Compustat #25 Compustat #199). Weexclude financial institutions (one-digit SIC = 6) and public utilities (two-digit SIC = 49).

Section 6 elaborates upon this new framework and utilizes it for testing ourhypotheses.

4. Sample Selection and Descriptive Statistics

The sample includes all public firms covered by Compustat during1979–2006. We use annual data for our tests and our sample choices followBurgstahler and Dichev [1997], ABJ, Roychowdhury [2006], and Banker,Byzalov, and Plehn-Dujowich [2011]. We exclude financial institutions andpublic utilities (four-digit SIC codes 6000–6999 and 4900–4999) becausethe structure of their financial statements is incompatible with those ofother companies. The sample includes firm-year observations with positivevalues for sales revenue, total assets, book value, and market value. We alsorequire share price at fiscal year end to be greater than $1 and delete firm-year observations with missing data on two preceding years (t−1, t−2).

To limit the effect of extreme observations, each year we rank the sam-ple according to the variables in the regression models and remove theextreme 0.5% of the observations on each side. We adjust dollar amountsfor inflation as in Konchitchki [2010]. The sample includes 97,547 firm-year observations for 11,758 different firms. Table 1 provides details on thesample selection.

Comparing the descriptive statistics of our sample reported in table 2with the ABJ sample, the firms in our sample are larger due to differencesin sampling criteria (mean sales of $1,809 million compared to $1,277 mil-lion in ABJ). However, our sample shows similar frequency of sales declines(27.4% vs. 27.0% in ABJ). Table 2 also presents descriptive statistics of theincentive dummy variables. There are 3,216 firm-year observations (3.3% ofthe sample) with incentives to avoid losses and 9,409 firm-year observations(9.7% of the sample) with incentives to avoid earnings decreases.

We also utilize a sample of 30,442 observations with available financialanalysts’ earnings forecasts. Of the sample, 6,423 observations (21.1%) are

Page 11: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

EARNINGS TARGETS AND MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 11

T A B L E 2Descriptive Statistics

Variable N Mean Std. Dev. 25th Pctl Median 75th Pctl

REV 97,547 1,809.36 8,386.62 39.74 159.56 717.95OC 97,547 1,635.93 7,660.57 39.44 147.44 653.85MV 97,547 2,041.80 12,678.29 28.95 121.08 632.11REVDEC 97,547 0.2744 0.4462 0 0 1LOSS 97,547 0.0330 0.1786 0 0 0EDEC 97,547 0.0965 0.2952 0 0 0MBE 30,442 0.2110 0.4080 0 0 0

1. Definitions of variables:REVit : annual sales revenue (Compustat #12) of firm i in year t,OCit : operating costs of firm i in year t—annual sales revenue minus income from operations (Compus-

tat #12 minus Compustat #178),MVit : market capitalization of shareholders’ equity at year t end (Compustat #199 × Compustat #25),REVDECit : a dummy variable that equals 1 if REVit<REV i,t−1 and 0 otherwise,LOSSit : a dummy variable that equals 1 if annual earnings deflated by market capitalization of sharehold-

ers’ equity at prior year end (Compustat #172t /MVt −1) is in the interval [0, 0.01], and 0 otherwise,EDECit : a dummy variable that equals 1 if the change in annual earnings deflated by market capitalization

of shareholders’ equity at prior year end is in the interval [0, 0.01], and 0 otherwise,MBEit : a dummy variable that equals 1 if the difference between actual earnings per share and consensus

analysts’ forecast is in the interval [0, 0.01], and 0 otherwise.2. See table 1 for sample selection.

suspect firm-years with incentives to avoid missing analysts’ earnings con-sensus forecasts (in line with Bartov and Cohen [2009]).

5. Empirical Results

5.1 SUBSAMPLE ANALYSES

The first hypothesis predicts that cost stickiness should be lower whenmanagers are facing incentives to meet earnings targets. Testing the firsthypothesis in the ABJ setting, results from estimating model (1) in subsam-ples of observations with and without incentives to meet earnings targetsare reported in table 3.3 Given no incentives to avoid losses, the estimateof β2 is −0.0929, significant at the 0.01 level (see panel A). That is, costsare sticky when managers are not motivated to avoid losses, consistent withABJ’s findings. However, the estimate of β2 in the presence of incentives toavoid losses is 0.0252, insignificantly different from zero (see panel A). Incontrast with ABJ’s findings, costs exhibit a symmetric, nonsticky pattern,when managers are motivated to avoid losses. The difference between thevalues of β2 in the two subsamples is positive and significant at the 0.02level.4 That is, cost stickiness is washed away in the presence of incentivesto avoid losses, consistent with the first hypothesis.

3The estimated coefficients β1 across the regression models are different from those re-ported by ABJ because we use operating costs, whereas ABJ use SG&A costs.

4We test the significance level using the full sample and a dummy variable to distinguishbetween the two subsamples.

Page 12: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

12 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

T A B L E 3The Impact of Incentives to Meet Earnings Targets on the Degree of Cost Stickiness

Panel A: Avoid Lossesβ0 β1 β2 β1 + β2

Avoid lossesLOSS = 1 0.0391∗∗ 0.7878∗∗∗ 0.0252 0.8130∗∗∗

N = 3,216 (2.26) (34.96) (0.54) (15.94)LOSS = 0 0.0356∗∗∗ 0.6815∗∗∗ −0.0929∗∗∗ 0.5886∗∗∗

N = 94,331 (11.27) (77.80) (−6.55) (36.50)The difference between LOSS = 1 0.0035 0.1063∗∗∗ 0.1181∗∗ 0.2244∗∗∗

and LOSS = 0 subsamples (0.21) (4.43) (2.28) (5.02)

Panel B: Avoid Earnings Decreases

Avoid earnings decreasesEDEC = 1 0.0460∗∗∗ 0.6504∗∗∗ 0.0525 0.7029∗∗∗

N = 9,409 (6.78) (16.41) (0.79) (9.69)EDEC = 0 0.0345∗∗∗ 0.6871∗∗∗ −0.0979∗∗∗ 0.5892∗∗∗

N = 88,138 (9.90) (80.43) (−6.81) (36.54)The difference between EDEC = 1 0.0115 −0.0367 0.1504∗∗ 0.1137∗∗

and EDEC = 0 subsamples (1.50) (−1.00) (2.22) (1.99)

1. The table presents regression results for subsamples of observations with and without incentives tomeet earnings targets. We split the sample into observations with and without incentives to avoid losses(panel A) and with and without incentives to avoid earnings decreases (panel B). Then we estimate model(1) separately in each of the subsamples.

2. The table presents values of coefficients β2 and the associated t-statistics (in parentheses) for eachsubsample.

�lnOCit = β0 + β1� ln R E Vit + β2REVDECit� ln R E Vit + εit . (1)

3. See table 2 for definitions of variables.4. ∗, ∗∗, ∗∗∗Significance at the 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively.

The second hypothesis predicts that, when managers face incentives tomeet earnings targets they cut costs more aggressively for the same de-crease in sales than absent these incentives. Given no incentives to avoidlosses, the estimate of β1 + β2 is 0.6815 − 0.0929 = 0.5886. The esti-mate of β1 + β2 in the presence of incentives to avoid losses is 0.7878+ 0.0252 = 0.8130. The slope for sales decreases, β1 + β2, is higher inthe presence of incentives to meet earnings targets than the slope absentthese incentives. The difference between the values of β1 + β2 in thetwo subsamples is significant at the 0.01 level, consistent with the secondhypothesis.

Similarly, given no incentives to avoid earnings decreases, the estimateof β2 is − 0.0979, significant at the 0.01 level (see panel B). Again, thisresult is consistent with ABJ’s findings. However, the estimate of β2 inthe presence of incentives to avoid earnings decreases is 0.0525 (insignif-icantly different from zero). The difference between the values of β2 inthe two subsamples is positive and significant at the 0.03 level. Once more,cost stickiness is washed away in the presence of incentives to avoid earn-ings decreases, consistent with the first hypothesis. As for the second hy-pothesis, given no incentives to avoid earnings decreases, the estimate of

Page 13: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

EARNINGS TARGETS AND MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 13

β1 + β2 is 0.6871 − 0.0979 = 0.5892. The estimate of β1 + β2 in thepresence of incentives to avoid earnings decreases is 0.6504 + 0.0525 =0.7029. The value of β1 + β2 differs between the two subsamples. The differ-ence is positive and significant at the 0.05 level, consistent with the secondhypothesis.

The findings indicate that the introduction of incentives to meet earn-ings targets washes away cost stickiness, resulting in symmetric costs. Over-all, the findings are consistent with less sticky costs caused by resource ad-justments made intentionally to meet earnings targets, and suggest thatmanagers cut costs more aggressively in the presence of incentives to meetearnings targets than absent these incentives.

5.2 COMPREHENSIVE REGRESSION ANALYSES

We start by estimating the ABJ model as a benchmark (third column oftable 4). Next, we estimate regression model (2) to test the effect of in-centives to avoid losses, incentives to avoid earnings decreases, and alter-nate incentives (i.e., incentives to either avoid losses or avoid earnings de-creases) on the degree of cost stickiness. Considering incentives to avoidlosses (fourth column of table 4), the estimate of γ 2 is 0.1176, positive andsignificant at the 0.03 level, supporting the first hypothesis. That is, resourceadjustments made intentionally to avoid losses diminish the degree of coststickiness. Testing the second hypothesis, γ 1 + γ 2 = −0.0103 + 0.1176= 0.1073, positive and significant at the 0.05 level. The findings suggestthat incentives to avoid losses result in more aggressive cost cuts when salesdecrease than absent these incentives. This evidence supports the secondhypothesis.

Considering incentives to avoid earnings decreases (fifth column oftable 4), the estimate of γ 2 is 0.1633, positive and significant at the 0.01level, in support of the first hypothesis. Testing the second hypothesis, γ 1

+ γ 2 = 0.0759 + 0.1633 = 0.2392, positive and significant at the 0.01 level.The result is consistent with the second hypothesis.

We also estimate model (2) with alternate incentives to either avoid lossesor avoid earnings decreases (sixth column of table 4). TARGET equals 1 if{LOSS = 1 or EDEC = 1}, and 0 otherwise. The estimate of γ 2 is 0.1157, sig-nificant at the 0.01 level. Again, γ 1 + γ 2 = 0.0557 + 0.1157 = 0.1714, posi-tive and significant at the 0.01 level. The findings support both hypotheses.

Overall, the findings from estimating the comprehensive regressionmodels suggest that managers’ resource adjustments made intentionallyto meet earnings targets diminish cost stickiness, in line with the firsthypothesis. The evidence is also consistent with the second hypothe-sis, suggesting that managers cut costs more aggressively in the pres-ence of incentives to meet earnings targets than absent these incentives.The results provide evidence that the degree of cost stickiness is influ-enced by managers’ deliberate resource adjustments motivated by agencyconsiderations.

Page 14: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

14 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

TA

BL

E4

Com

preh

ensi

veR

egre

ssio

nA

naly

ses

Avo

idA

lter

nat

eA

void

Ear

nin

gsE

arn

ings

Smal

lL

arge

Coe

ffici

ent

Vari

able

AB

JL

osse

sD

ecre

ases

Targ

ets

Firm

sFi

rms

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Inte

rcep

tsβ

00.

0214

∗∗∗

0.02

11∗∗

∗0.

0219

∗∗∗

0.02

13∗∗

∗0.

0319

∗∗∗

0.00

92∗∗

(10.

04)

(9.8

7)(1

0.04

)(9.8

0)(8.6

6)(4.0

7)γ

0A

void

loss

0.00

96∗∗

(3.1

6)γ

0A

void

earn

ings

decr

ease

−0.0

047∗∗

(−2.

71)

γ0

Avo

idlo

ssor

earn

ings

decr

ease

−0.0

012

−0.0

018

−0.0

003

(−0.

81)

(−0.

68)

(−0.

20)

Dir

ecte

ffec

10.

8257

∗∗∗

0.82

60∗∗

∗0.

8195

∗∗∗

0.82

01∗∗

∗0.

7551

∗∗∗

0.89

36∗∗

(107.7

7)(1

05.8

7)(1

02.1

8)(1

00.6

5)(6

1.53

)(9

6.02

1A

void

loss

−0.0

103

(−0.

44)

Avo

idea

rnin

gsde

crea

se0.

0759

∗∗∗

(3.7

6)A

void

loss

orea

rnin

gsde

crea

se0.

0557

∗∗∗

0.03

640.

0612

∗∗∗

(3.3

3)(1.3

1)(3.4

9)St

icky

mea

sure

2A

BJ

stic

kin

ess

mea

sure

−0.2

283∗∗

∗−0.2

316∗∗

∗−0.2

243∗∗

∗−0.2

290∗∗

∗−0.2

033∗∗

∗−0.1

727∗∗

(−10.7

8)(−

10.8

3)(−

10.5

7)(−

10.6

9)(−

7.77

)(−

3.95

)

(Con

tinue

d)

Page 15: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

EARNINGS TARGETS AND MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 15

TA

BL

E4

—C

ontin

ued

Avo

idA

lter

nat

eA

void

Ear

nin

gsE

arn

ings

Smal

lL

arge

Coe

ffici

ent

Vari

able

AB

JL

osse

sD

ecre

ases

Targ

ets

Firm

sFi

rms

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

γ2

Avo

idlo

ss0.

1176

∗∗

(2.1

9)A

void

earn

ings

decr

ease

0.16

33∗∗

(2.8

9)A

void

loss

orea

rnin

gsde

crea

se0.

1157

∗∗∗

0.12

94∗∗

0.10

24∗∗

(3.0

3)(2.3

7)(1.9

5)C

ontr

olva

riab

les

δ1

Succ

essi

vede

crea

se0.

1570

∗∗∗

0.15

77∗∗

∗0.

1572

∗∗∗

0.15

88∗∗

∗0.

1767

∗∗∗

0.13

27∗∗

(7.9

3)(7.9

7)(7.9

7)(8.0

7)(7.8

1)(3.1

2)δ

2A

sset

inte

nsi

ty−0.3

241∗∗

∗−0.3

236∗∗

∗−0.3

284∗∗

∗−0.3

262∗∗

∗−0.3

136∗∗

∗−0.3

731∗∗

(−27.4

1)(−

27.3

9)(−

27.9

2)(2

7.77

)(−

21.9

0)(−

17.9

6)δ

3E

mpl

oyee

inte

nsi

ty−0.0

696∗∗

∗−0.0

692∗∗

∗−0.0

669∗∗

∗−0.0

659∗∗

∗−0.0

764∗∗

∗−0.0

326

(−6.

28)

(−6.

28)

(−6.

03)

(−6.

01)

(−5.

91)

(−1.

40)

Adj

.-R2

0.62

290.

6231

0.62

400.

6239

0.56

600.

7113

N82

,697

82,6

9782

,697

82,6

9741

,348

41,3

49

1.T

he

tabl

epr

esen

tsco

effi

cien

tsan

dth

eas

soci

ated

t-st

atis

tics

(in

pare

nth

eses

)fo

rth

efo

llow

ing

regr

essi

onm

odel

:

�ln

OC

it=β

0+γ

0T

AR

GE

Tit

+{β

1+γ

1T

AR

GE

Tit}�

lnR

EV i

t

+{ β

2+γ

2T

AR

GE

Tit

+δ 1

SUC

DE

Cit

+δ 2

ASI

NT

it+δ 3

EM

PIN

Tit}

RE

VD

EC

it�

lnR

EV i

t+ε

it.

(2)

2.T

AR

GE

Tit

={L

OSS

it,E

DEC

it,L

OSS

it∪E

DEC

it},

such

that

LO

SSit∪E

DEC

itis

adu

mm

yva

riab

le,t

erm

ed“

alte

rnat

eta

rget

s,”

that

equa

ls1

ifL

OSS

it=

1or

EDEC

it=

1,an

d0

oth

erw

ise.

Con

trol

vari

able

sar

eas

follo

ws:

SUC

DEC

itis

adu

mm

yva

riab

leth

ateq

uals

1if

reve

nue

inye

art−

1is

less

than

inye

art−

2,an

d0

oth

erw

ise.

ASI

NT

itis

the

log

ofth

era

tio

ofto

tala

sset

sto

sale

sre

ven

ues,

and

EMPI

NT

itis

the

log

ofth

era

tio

ofth

en

umbe

rof

empl

oyee

sto

sale

sre

ven

ue.

See

tabl

e2

for

defi

nit

ion

sof

oth

erva

riab

les.

3.T

he

num

ber

ofob

serv

atio

ns

for

alls

ixre

gres

sion

sis

dete

rmin

edby

data

avai

labi

lity

for

allv

aria

bles

.4.

∗,∗∗,

∗∗∗ S

ign

ifica

nce

ofdi

ffer

ence

from

zero

atth

e0.

10,0

.05,

and

0.01

leve

ls,r

espe

ctiv

ely.

Page 16: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

16 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

We note that the lower degree of cost stickiness is induced primarily bydownward adjustments of resources made to meet earnings targets whensales fall. For incentives to avoid losses, the estimate of γ 1 is −0.0103, neg-ative and insignificant. That is, managers do not significantly restrain theirresource adjustments when sales rise in response to incentives to avoidlosses. For incentives to avoid earnings decreases, the estimate of γ 1 is0.0759, positive and significant at the 0.01 level. This result suggests thatincentives to avoid earnings decreases result in a cost increase at a fasterrate (higher slope) for the same sales increase. The findings suggest thatincentives to meet earnings targets encourage managers to expedite costcuts when sales fall, but do not lead them to restrain cost increases whensales rise.

One possible explanation for the positive γ 1 is that managers are ableto avoid losses or earnings decreases by increasing advertising expenses,which, in turn, increase sales. To test this explanation, we re-estimate model(2) and replace OC as the dependent variable with operating costs mi-nus advertising expenses. When advertising expenses are missing in thedatabase we assume that they equal zero. When advertising expenses are ex-cluded, the results (not reported for brevity) indicate that managers do notexpedite cost increases when facing earnings targets (γ 1 is not significantlydifferent from zero). This implies that advertising expenses contribute tocost increases in the presence of incentives to meet earnings targets andsales increases.

Results with respect to the control variables are in line with ABJ. The es-timated coefficients on successive decreases in sales, SUC DEC , are positiveand significant. The estimated coefficients for asset intensity, ASINT , andemployee intensity, EMPINT , are negative and significant. These results arein line with prior studies and demonstrate that the effects of incentives tomeet earnings targets on sticky costs hold when controlled for determinantsof sticky costs reported in the literature.

Several robustness checks are performed to reconfirm the evidence.First, we check the sensitivity of the findings to firm size. We split the sam-ple observations into small and large firms (below and above the medianof market value) and repeated the estimation of regression model (2) sep-arately for small (below median) and large (above median) observations(the seventh and eighth columns of table 4). The estimates are γ 2 = 0.1294(significant at the 0.02 level) for the small-firm subsample, and γ 2 = 0.1024(significant at the 0.05 level) for the large-firm subsample. Also, γ 1 + γ 2 =0.0364 + 0.1294 = 0.1658 (significant at the 0.01 level) for the small-firmsubsample and γ 1 + γ 2 = 0.0612 + 0.1024 = 0.1636 (significant at the 0.01level) for the large-firm subsample. The findings support both hypothesesfor both small and large firms. We conclude that firm size does not affectthe predicted phenomenon.

Second, we repeat the analyses (not tabulated for brevity) using theFama-MacBeth estimation procedure for estimating regression model (2)instead of the clustering suggested by Petersen [2009]. The findings are

Page 17: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

EARNINGS TARGETS AND MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 17

essentially the same. Third, to assure that findings are not driven byindustry-specific characteristics, we control for potential industry-specificeffects using the Fama-French industry classification. The results aresimilar.

Fourth, we check the robustness of the findings to employing an alter-native earnings deflator. Durtschi and Easton [2005, 2009] investigate dis-tributions of scaled earnings and report differences between the shape ofthe distribution of earnings scaled by total assets and the shape of the dis-tribution of earnings scaled by market capitalization. Therefore, we com-puted intervals of firm-years with incentives to meet earnings targets usingearnings scaled by total assets (rather than market capitalization) and usedthem to repeat the above analyses. The findings (not tabulated for brevity)are similar. Finally, we also repeated the analyses using different intervalsizes, of (0, 0.005] and (0, 0.02]. The results remain essentially the same.

Taken as a whole, the evidence shows that incentives to meet earningstargets encourage managers to moderate the degree of cost stickiness, andto expedite resource cutting in response to sales fall. These effects areeconomically meaningful and statistically significant. The findings extendthe literature by showing how decisions to adjust resources made by self-interested managers in the presence of incentives to avoid losses and earn-ing decreases diminish cost stickiness. In sum, the evidence suggests thatdeliberate decisions to meet earnings targets diminish the degree of coststickiness.

5.3. INCENTIVE TO MEET FINANCIAL ANALYSTS’ EARNINGS FORECASTS

Results from estimating the ABJ model (1) in subsamples of observationswith and without incentives to meet financial analysts’ consensus earningsforecasts are reported in panel A of table 5. Given no incentives to meetfinancial analysts’ earnings forecasts, the estimate of β2 is −0.2007, signif-icant at the 0.01 level. That is, costs are sticky when managers are not mo-tivated to meet financial analysts’ earnings forecasts. However, the estimateof β2 in the presence of incentives to avoid losses is −0.0962, insignificantlydifferent from zero. That is, costs express a symmetric pattern, not a stickyone, when managers are motivated to meet financial analysts’ earnings fore-casts. The value of β2 differs between the two subsamples. The difference ispositive and significant at the 0.10 level. That is, cost stickiness is washedaway in the presence of incentives to meet financial analysts’ consensusearnings forecasts, consistent with the first hypothesis.

Results from estimating model (2), where TARGET expresses incentivesto meet financial analysts’ consensus earnings forecasts, are reported inpanel B of table 5. The estimate of γ 2 is 0.0894, positive and significantat the 0.08 level. That is, incentives to meet financial analysts’ consen-sus earnings forecasts diminish the degree of cost stickiness, supportingthe first hypothesis. Testing the second hypothesis, γ 1 + γ 2 = 0.0348 +0.0894 = 0.1242, significant at the 0.05 level. That is, incentives to meet fi-nancial analysts’ consensus earnings forecasts lead managers to cut costs

Page 18: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

18 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

T A B L E 5Incentives to Meet Financial Analysts Earnings Forecasts

Panel A: The Degree of Cost Stickiness in Categories with and Without Targetsβ0 β1 β2 β1 + β2

Meet or beat analysts’ earningsforecastsMBE = 1 0.0231∗∗ 0.7882∗∗∗ −0.0962 0.6920∗∗∗

N = 6,423 (2.50) (26.29) (−1.24) (9.51)MBE = 0 0.0386∗∗∗ 0.6711∗∗∗ −0.2007∗∗∗ 0.4704N = 24,019 (10.09) (40.69) (−6.13) (13.83)∗∗∗

The difference between MBE = 1 −0.0155 0.1171∗∗∗ 0.1045∗ 0.2216∗∗∗

and MBE = 0 subsamples (−1.63) (3.57) (1.70) (2.59)

Panel B: Regression AnalysisCoefficient Variable Model

Interceptsβ0 0.0232∗∗∗

(8.93)η0 −0.0067

(−3.07)Direct effectβ1 0.8272∗∗∗

(52.65)γ 1 MBE 0.0348∗

(1.86)Sticky measuresβ2 ABJ Stickiness measure −0.2535∗∗∗

(−6.14)γ 2 MBE 0.0894∗

(1.75)Control variablesδ1 Successive decrease 0.1033∗∗

(2.39)δ2 Asset intensity −0.3399∗∗∗

(−17.16)δ3 Employee intensity −0.0908∗∗∗

(−3.89)Adj.-R2 0.6119N 25,994

1. The table presents coefficients and the associated t-statistics (in parentheses) for the following regres-sion models:

� ln OCit = β0 + γ0TARG E Tit + {β1 + γ1TARG E Tit }� ln R E Vit + {β2 + γ2TARG E Tit

+ δ1SU C DE Cit + δ2ASI N Tit + δ3 E MPI N Tit } R E V DE Cit� ln R E Vit + εit , (2)

2. TARGETit is a dummy variable that equals 1 if the analyst forecast error (actual minus forecast earningsper share) is between zero and one cent, and 0 otherwise. Control variables are as follows: SUC DECit is adummy variable that equals 1 if revenue in year t−1 is less than in year t−2, and 0 otherwise. ASINTit isthe log of the ratio of total assets to sales revenues, and EMPINTit is the log of the ratio of the number ofemployees to sales revenue.

See table 2 for definitions of other variables.3. The number of observations in each panel is determined by data availability for all variables.4. ∗, ∗∗, ∗∗∗Significance of difference from zero at the 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively.

Page 19: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

EARNINGS TARGETS AND MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 19

more aggressively in the presence of incentives to meet earnings tar-gets than absent these incentives, which is consistent with the secondhypothesis.

5.4 EARNINGS TARGETS IN CONSECUTIVE PERIODS

Results from estimating model (3) reported in table 6 shed light on theeffect of incentives to meet earnings targets in the prior period on the de-gree of cost stickiness in the current period. The estimate of γ 2 is 0.0595,significant at the 0.06 level. That is, managers’ current incentives diminishthe degree of current cost stickiness, regardless of whether or not man-agers faced the same incentives in the prior period. The estimate of ψ2 is−0.0515, significant at the 0.10 level. That is, managers’ incentives in theprior period increase the degree of cost stickiness in the current period, re-gardless of whether or not managers face the same incentives in the currentperiod.

Furthermore, in the case of incentives to meet earnings targets on twoconsecutive periods, we find that γ 2 + ψ2 = 0.0595 – 0.0515 = 0.0080, in-significantly different from zero. The result suggests that, if managers faceincentives to meet an earnings target in two consecutive periods, then thedegree of cost stickiness is not diminished, even though current incentivesreduce stickiness.

6. The BCM Framework:Managerial Optimism

BCM recently offered a new framework for gaining further insights onsources of asymmetric cost behavior. While ABJ assume that managerialintervention only affects changes in costs when sales decrease, BCM furtherexpand our understanding of asymmetric cost behavior by showing howmanagerial intervention affects cost changes in both directions. Theyfind that managers’ optimistic demand expectations are a key source ofasymmetric cost behavior. Their results indicate that, when managers areoptimistic with respect to future demand, the stickiness in SG&A costsis stronger than that reported in ABJ. In contrast with ABJ’s findings, ifmanagers are pessimistic, then costs decrease more when sales fall thanthey increase when sales rise by an equivalent amount, because pessimismmagnifies the downward adjustment to costs, which results in a reversal ofstickiness.

The BCM framework is essential for gaining additional insights on therelationship between incentives to meet earnings targets and the degree ofcost stickiness. Pessimistic demand expectations are likely to aggravate thepressure managers face due to incentives to meet earnings targets, motivat-ing them to cut costs to a greater extent. By contrast, optimistic demand ex-pectations stand at odds with cutting resources, as these resources are likelyto be required for supplying future demand. Therefore, when managersface incentives to meet earnings targets, they are more likely to acceleratecost cuts in the pessimistic case than in the optimistic case. Consequently,

Page 20: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

20 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

T A B L E 6Earnings Targets in Consecutive Periods

Coefficient Variable Model

Interceptsβ0 0.0150∗∗∗

(7.41)γ 0 TARGET = Avoid losses or earnings decreases −0.0027∗∗

(−2.10)ψ 0 Lagged TARGET 0.0068∗∗∗

(4.82)Direct effectβ1 0.8401∗∗∗

(107.32)γ 1 TARGET = Avoid losses or earnings decreases 0.0697∗∗∗

(4.28)ψ 1 Lagged TARGET 0.0158

(1.21)Sticky measuresβ2 ABJ stickiness measure −0.2281∗∗∗

(−7.62)γ 2 TARGET = Avoid losses or earnings decreases 0.0595∗

(1.86)ψ 2 Lagged TARGET −0.0515∗

(−1.63)Control variablesδ1 Successive decrease 0.1664∗∗∗

(10.55)δ2 Asset intensity −0.3387∗∗∗

(−25.23)δ3 Employee intensity −0.0007

(−0.10)Adj.-R2 0.6726N 71,849

1. The table presents coefficients and the associated t-statistics (in parentheses) for the following regres-sion model:

� ln OCit = β0 + γ0TARG E Tit + ψ0TARG E Ti,t−1 + {β1 + γ1TARG E Tit + ψ1TARG E Ti,t−1}× � ln R E Vit + {

β2 + γ2TARG E Tit + ψ2TARG E Ti,t−1 + δ1SU C DE Cit

+ δ2ASI N Tit + δ3 E MPI N Tit } REVDECit� ln R E Vit + εit , (3)

2. TARGETit is a dummy variable, termed “alternate targets,” that equals 1 if LOSSit = 1 or EDECit =1, and 0 otherwise. Control variables are as follows: SUC DECit is a dummy variable that equals 1 if revenuein year t−1 is less than in year t−2, and 0 otherwise. ASINTit is the log of the ratio of total assets to salesrevenues, and EMPINTit is the log of the ratio of the number of employees to sales revenue.

See table 2 for definitions of other variables.3.∗, ∗∗, ∗∗∗Significance of difference from zero at the 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively.

the impact of managers’ incentives on the degree of cost stickiness is likelyto be stronger in the pessimistic case than in the optimistic case. The BCMframework provides the means for testing the relationship between incen-tives to meet earnings targets and the degree of cost stickiness, conditionalon the optimism or pessimism of managers’ demand expectations.

BCM used directions of sales changes in consecutive periods as a proxyfor optimism or pessimism in demand expectations. They find that the

Page 21: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

EARNINGS TARGETS AND MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 21

direction of sales change in the prior period influences the degree of coststickiness. Specifically, they find significant stickiness after a prior sales in-crease, and significant anti-stickiness after a prior sales decrease. The in-centives variables LOSS and EDEC may be systematically correlated with thedirection of sales change in the prior period. Therefore, we build on themodel suggested by BCM and control for the direction of sales change inthe prior period to avoid omitted variable bias in the estimates of the impactof LOSS and EDEC on cost stickiness. Also, as discussed above, the impactof LOSS and EDEC is likely to be stronger in the pessimistic case than in theoptimistic case, and, therefore, we allow the coefficients on LOSS and EDECto vary depending on the direction of sales change in the prior period.

Examining a two-period setting, two consecutive periods of sales increase(decrease) signal managerial optimism (pessimism) about future demand.This model is similar to the model used in ABJ, except that BCM includefour cases based on the sales change in current and previous periods, in-stead of the two cases used in the ABJ model, which is based on saleschanges only in the current period. To estimate the impact of incentiveson resource adjustments, we follow Model A in BCM and add interactionswith the incentive variable, TARGET , as follows:

� ln OCit = β0 + ϕ0 TARGET it + β1� ln REV it REVINCit

× REVINCi,t−1 + β2� ln REV it REVINCit REVDECi,t−1

+β3� ln R E Vit R E V DE Cit REVINCi,t−1 + β4� ln R E Vit

× R E V DE Cit R E V DE Ci,t−1 + ϕ1TARG E Tit� ln R E Vit

× REVINCit REVINCi,t−1 + ϕ2TARG E Tit� ln R E Vit

× REVINCit R E V DE Ci,t−1 + ϕ3TARG E Tit� ln R E Vit

× R E V DE Cit REVINCi,t−1 + ϕ4TARG E Tit� ln R E Vit

× R E V DE Cit R E V DE Ci,t−1 + ηit , (4)

where �lnOCit is the log change in operating costs for firm i in year t (be-tween year t and year t−1) and�lnREVit is the log change in sales revenue.We include four dummy variables to distinguish the situations in terms ofthe direction of change in sales in current and prior periods for firm i. TheREVINCit dummy takes the value of 1 if sales revenue increases in the cur-rent period (between t−1 and t), and 0 otherwise. The REVDECit dummytakes the value of 1 when sales revenue decreases in the current period,and 0 otherwise. REVINC i,t−1 and REVDECi ,t−1 dummies are defined simi-larly for period t−1. TARGETit is LOSSit∪EDECit , which is a dummy variable,termed “alternate targets,” that equals 1 if LOSSit = 1 or EDECit = 1 and 0otherwise.

We employ pooled cross-sectional regressions, include year effects, andcluster observations by firm to provide standard errors that are robust toautocorrelation and heteroscedasticity, as suggested by Petersen [2009].

Page 22: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

22 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

T A B L E 7Earnings Targets and Managerial Optimism

Variable BCM Earnings Targets(1) (2) (3)

β0 Intercept 0.0316∗∗∗ 0.0311∗∗∗

(10.12) (9.84)φ0 TARGETit 0.0038

(1.37)β1 �lnREVit REVINCit REVINCi ,t−1 0.7670∗∗∗ 0.7660∗∗∗

(93.98) (91.15)β2 �lnREVit REVINCit REVDECi,t−1 0.4908∗∗∗ 0.4942∗∗∗

(34.75) (34.41)β3 �lnREVit REVDECit REVINCi,t −1 0.5684∗∗∗ 0.5595∗∗∗

(39.63) (37.31)β4 �lnREVit REVDECit REVDECi ,t−1 0.6231∗∗∗ 0.6131∗∗∗

(34.50) (32.78)φ1 TARGETit �lnREVit REVINCit REVINCi ,t−1 0.0120

(0.47)φ2 TARGETit �lnREVit REVINCit REVDECi ,t−1 −0.0484

(−0.79)φ3 TARGETit �lnREVit REVDECit REVINCi ,t−1 0.1372∗∗∗

(3.11)φ4 TARGETit �lnREVit REVDECit REVDECi ,t−1 0.1785∗∗∗

(3.76)Adj. R2 0.6451 0.6458N 94,255 94,255

1. The table presents coefficients and the associated t-statistics (in parentheses) for the following regres-sion model:

� ln OCit = β0 + φ0TARG E Tit + β1� ln R E Vit R E V I N Ci,t REVINCi,t−1

+β2� ln R E Vit R E V I N Cit R E V DE Ci,t−1 + β3� ln R E Vit R E V DE Cit R E V I N Ci,t−1

+β4� ln R E Vit R E V DE Cit R E V DE Ci,t−1 + φ1TARG E Tit� ln R E Vit R E V I N Cit R E V I N Ci,t−1

+φ2TARG E Tit� ln R E Vit R E V I N Cit R E V DE Ci,t−1 + φ3TARG E Tit� ln R E Vit R E V DE Cit

× R E V I N Ci,t−1 + φ4TARG E Tit� ln R E Vit R E V DE Cit R E V DE Ci,t−1 + ηit .

(4)

2. Following Banker, Ciftci, and Mashruwala [2011], �lnOCit is the log change in operating costs forfirm i in year t (between year t and year t−1); �lnRevit is the log change in sales revenue. REVINCitREVINCi ,t−1 is a dummy variable that equals 1 if sales revenue increases in both the current (between t−1and t) and previous periods (between t−2 and t−1), and 0 otherwise; REVINCit REVDECi,t −1 is a dummyvariable that equals 1 if sales revenue increases in the current period but decreases in the previous period,and 0 otherwise; REVDECit REVINCi ,t−1 is a dummy variable that equals 1 if sales revenue decreases in thecurrent period and increases in the previous period, and 0 otherwise; REVDECit REVDECi ,t−1 is a dummyvariable that equals 1 if sales revenue decreases for two consecutive periods, and 0 otherwise.

TARGETit is a dummy, termed “alternate targets,” that equals 1 if LOSSit = 1 or EDECit = 1, and 0otherwise.

3. ∗, ∗∗, ∗∗∗Significance of difference from zero at the 0.10, 0.05, and 0.01 levels, respectively.

In the second column of table 7, we report coefficient estimates for theBCM model, showing consistent results. The estimates for model (4) (thirdcolumn of table 7) indicate that the general pattern reported by BCM re-mains unchanged absent incentives to meet earnings targets. The estimatesof φ1 and φ2 are insignificantly different from zero, suggesting that thepresence of earnings targets does not encourage managers to restrain costincreases when current sales increase.

Page 23: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

EARNINGS TARGETS AND MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 23

We follow BCM’s approach in testing the hypothesis on the relationshipbetween incentives to meet earnings targets and the degree of cost sticki-ness in the optimistic and pessimistic cases. In the optimistic case, the de-gree of stickiness in the presence of incentives to meet earnings targets is(β3 + φ3) – (β1 + φ1) = (0.5595 + 0.1372) – (0.7660 + 0.0120) = −0.0813,versus β3 – β1 = 0.5595 – 0.7660 = −0.2065 in the absence of such incen-tives (the difference is equal to 0.1252, significant at the 0.01 level). In thepessimistic case, the degree of anti-stickiness in the presence of incentivesto meet earnings targets is (β4 + φ4) – (β2 + φ2) = (0.6131 + 0.1785) –(0.4942 – 0.0484) = 0.3458, versus β4 – β2 = 0.6131 – 0.4942 = 0.1189 ab-sent incentives to meet earnings targets (the difference is equal to 0.2269,significant at the 0.01 level). These findings suggest that incentives to meetearnings targets diminish the degree of cost stickiness (or, equivalently, in-crease the degree of anti-stickiness in the pessimistic case) even after con-trolling for managers’ demand expectations, lending further support to thefirst hypothesis. As expected, the impact of incentives to meet earnings tar-gets on the degree of cost stickiness is stronger in the pessimistic case thanin the optimistic case (0.2269 vs. 0.1252, respectively, as computed earlier).Consistent with the second hypothesis, incentives to meet earnings targetsencourage managers to cut costs more aggressively for concurrent sales de-creases, both in the optimistic case and in the pessimistic case (φ3 = 0.1372and φ4 = 0.1785, respectively, both significant at the 0.01 level). Overall,results for the BCM framework suggest that managers intentionally adjustresources to meet earnings targets, thereby lessening the degree of coststickiness.

7. Summary

In this study, we examine how deliberate choices, motivated by agency-driven incentives, influence asymmetric cost behavior. We show that delib-erate managerial choices made to meet earnings targets diminish, ratherthan induce, cost stickiness. Our findings suggest that any effort to infersources of sticky costs should be made in light of motivations underlyingmanagers’ resource adjustments. Overall, our results provide useful insightsfor the management and financial accounting literature, and encouragefurther research to enhance our understanding of the role of motivationsunderlying managers’ decisions in shaping firms’ cost structures.

REFERENCES

ABEL, A., AND J. EBERLY. “A Unified Model of Investment Under Uncertainty.” American Eco-nomic Review 84 (1994): 1369–84.

ANDERSON, M.; R. BANKER; AND S. JANAKIRAMAN. “Are Selling, General, and AdministrativeCosts ‘Sticky’?” Journal of Accounting Research 41 (2003): 47–63.

BABER, W.; P. FAIRFIELD; AND J. HAGGARD. “The Effect of Concern About Reported Income onDiscretionary Spending Decisions: The Case of Research and Development.” The AccountingReview 66 (1991): 818–29.

Page 24: Do Earnings Targets and Managerial Incentives Affect Sticky ......Prior studies (ABJ, Balakrishnan, Petersen, and Soderstrom [2004], Balakrishnan and Gruca [2008], BCM) document how

24 I. KAMA AND D. WEISS

BALAKRISHNAN, R., AND T. S. GRUCA. “Cost Stickiness and Core Competency: A Note.” Contem-porary Accounting Research 25 (2008): 993–1006.

BALAKRISHNAN, R.; M. J. PETERSEN; AND N. S. SODERSTROM. “Does Capacity Utilization Affectthe ‘Stickiness’ of Costs?” Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Finance 19 (2004): 283–99.

BANKER, R. D.; D. BYZALOV; AND J. M. PLEHN-DUJOWICH. “Sticky Cost Behavior: Theory andEvidence.” Working paper, Temple University, 2011.

BANKER, R.; M. CIFTCI; AND R. MASHRUWALA. “Managerial Optimism and Cost Behavior.” Work-ing Paper, Temple University, 2011.

BANKER, R.; R. HUANG; AND R. NATARAJAN. “Equity Incentives and Long-Term Value Createdby SG&A Expenditure.” Contemporary Accounting Research 28 (2011): 794-830.

BARTOV, E., AND D. COHEN. “The ‘Numbers Game’ in the Pre- and Post-Sarbanes-Oxley Eras.”Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance 24 (2009): 505–34.

BURGSTAHLER, D., AND I. DICHEV. “Earnings Management to Avoid Earnings Decreases andLosses.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 24 (1997): 99–136.

BUSHEE, B. T. “The Influence of Institutional Investors on Myopic R&D Investment Behavior.”The Accounting Review 73 (1998): 305–33.

CHEN, C. L.; H. LU; AND T. SOUGIANNIS. “The Agency Problem, Corporate Governance, andthe Asymmetrical Behavior of Selling, General, and Administrative Costs.” Contemporary Ac-counting Research 29 (2012): 252–82.

COHEN, D. A.; A. DEY; AND T. Z. LYS. “Real and Accrual-Based Earnings Management in thePre- and Post-Sarbanes-Oxley Periods.” The Accounting Review 83 (2008): 757–87.

DECHOW, P., AND R. G. SLOAN. “Executive Incentives and the Horizon Problem: An EmpiricalInvestigation.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 14 (1991): 51–89.

DIERYNCK, B.; W.R. LANDSMAN; AND A. RENDERS. “Do Managerial Incentives Drive Cost Behav-ior? Evidence About the Role of the Zero Earnings Benchmark for Labor Cost Behavior inBelgian Private Firms.” The Accounting Review 87 (2012): 121-46.

DURTSCHI, C., AND P. EASTON. “Earnings Management? The Shapes of the Frequency Distri-butions of Earnings Metrics Are Not Evidence Ipso Facto.” Journal of Accounting Research 43(2005): 557–92.

DURTSCHI, C., AND P. EASTON. “Earnings Management? Erroneous Inferences Based on Earn-ings Frequency Distributions.” Journal of Accounting Research 47 (2009): 1249–81.

FAMA, E. F., AND J. MACBETH. “Risk, Return, and Equilibrium: Empirical Tests.” Journal of Polit-ical Economy 81 (1973): 607–36.

GRAHAM, J. R.; C. R. HARVEY; AND S. RAJGOPAL. “The Economic Implications of CorporateFinancial Reporting.” Journal of Accounting & Economics 40 (2005): 3–73.

KALLAPUR, S., AND L. ELDENBURG. “Uncertainty, Real Options, and Cost Behavior: Evidencefrom Washington State Hospitals.” Journal of Accounting Research 43 (2005): 735–52.

KEUNG, E.; Z. LIN; AND M. SHIA. “Does the Stock Market See a Zero or Small Positive EarningsSurprise as a Red Flag?” Journal of Accounting Research 48 (2010): 91–121.

KONCHITCHKI, Y. “Inflation and Nominal Financial Reporting: Implications for Performanceand Stock Prices.” The Accounting Review 86 (2010): 1045–85.

PETERSEN, M. “Estimating Standard Errors in Finance Panel Data Sets: ComparingApproaches.” The Review of Financial Studies 22 (2009): 435–80.

REES, L., AND K. SIVARAMAKRISHNAN. “The Effect of Meeting or Beating Revenue Forecastson the Association Between Quarterly Returns and Earnings Forecast Errors.” ContemporaryAccounting Research 24 (2007): 259–90.

ROYCHOWDHURY, S. “Earnings Management Through Real Activities Manipulation.” Journal ofAccounting and Economics 42 (2006): 335–70.

WEISS, D. “Cost Behavior and Analysts’ Earnings Forecasts.” The Accounting Review 85 (2010):1441–71.