do capital markets punish managerial myopia?

35
1 Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia? Jamie Y. Tong [email protected] University of Western Australia Feida (Frank) Zhang [email protected] Murdoch University 2015 April

Upload: others

Post on 11-Nov-2021

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

1

Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

Jamie Y. Tong

[email protected]

University of Western Australia

Feida (Frank) Zhang

[email protected]

Murdoch University

2015 April

Page 2: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

2

Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

Abstract

The extant literature provides conflicting arguments and mixed results on whether capital

markets punish managerial myopia. Using managers’ cutting R&D to meet short-term

earnings goals as a research setting, this study reveals that capital markets actually penalize

managerial myopia, especially for firms with high investor sophistication. Our results are

consistent with Jensen’s (1988) contention that the security market is not shortsighted.

Additionally, we document that compensation, especially cash compensation, could be one of

the reasons why managers behave myopically.

JEL classifications: G32; M41

Keywords: Managerial Myopia; Capital Market; Investor Sophistication; CEO Compensation.

Data availability: The data are available from the public sources identified in the paper.

Page 3: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

3

I. Introduction

Defined as managers’ desire to achieve a high current stock price by inflating current

earnings at the expense of long-term cash flows or earnings (Stein 1989; Bhojraj and Libby

2005), managerial myopia is believed to be a first-order problem faced by modern firms

(Edmans 2009). Graham, Harvey, and Rajgopal (2005) survey and interview more than 400

executives, and document that 78% of executives would forgo a project with positive net

present value if the project would cause them to miss short-term earnings targets. Empirical

studies of managerial myopic behavior have focused mainly on R&D expenditure and the

evidence is consistent with managers myopically cutting investment in R&D to achieve

various income objectives (Dechow and Sloan 1991; Baber et al. 1991; Bange and De Bondt

1998; Roychowdhury 2006; Cooper and Selto 1991; Bens et al. 2002; Jacobs 1991; Asker et

al. 2011).

The origins of managerial myopia have been debated, and central to the debate is the

view that U.S. equity markets induce corporate managers to behave myopically (Jacobs 1991;

Porter 1992). The view arises from the belief that investors cannot see beyond current

earnings and will depress stock prices when there is any reduction in short-term earnings.

Because R&D investments are expensed under current Generally Accepted Accounting

Principles (GAAP), managers have incentives to avoid such investments in spite of the long-

term payoffs1. Essentially, managers underinvest in R&D to create the impression that the

firm’s current and future profitability is greater than it actually is, hoping this will boost

today’s share price (Stein 1989). Hence, managers are pressured into trading long-term

performance for short-term performance in order to meet stock market expectation, and

especially in order to secure impatient capital.

1 We acknowledge that managers might not always give up R&D projects for short-term benefits. On the one hand, capital

market rewards firms that meet/beat the earnings target. On the other hand, capital market also values R&D investment.

Hence, managers might have to make a trade-off between investing in long-term projects while missing earnings target and

forgoing long-term valuable projects to meet/beat earnings target.

Page 4: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

4

Prominent CEOs have expressed their concerns about the pressure from capital markets.

For example, Anne Mulcahy, former Chairperson and CEO of Xerox, stated that fixating on

short-term performance is one of “the most dysfunctional things” in the marketplace, and it

may hurt U.S. firms in the long run2. During Google’s IPO offering in 2004, management of

Google said it did not want to lose focus on its long-term goals and therefore declined to

provide frequent earnings guidance (Gigler et al. 2009). Such concerns are also shared by

regulators. An independent commission established by the U.S. chamber of Commerce

recommends discontinuing quarterly earnings guidance and believes reducing the pressures to

meet precise quarterly earnings target is an important first step in shifting the focus of the U.S.

capital markets away from quarterly results and toward the long-term performance of U.S.

companies (Cheng et al. 2007). Recent empirical studies on earnings guidance, analyst

coverage and takeover protection are supportive of the concerns from the industry and the

regulator (Hu et al. 2014; He and Tian 2013; Zhao et al. 2012).

However, whether capital markets are myopic has never been conclusively established

(Houston et al. 2010). If capital markets are shortsighted so that managers are pressured to

behave myopically, we would expect a positive stock price reaction to managers’ myopic

behaviors3. Managerial myopia is sacrificing long-term growth for the purpose of meeting

short-term goals (Porter 1992). This concept has three aspects: (1) there should be

underinvestment in long-term value creation projects; (2) the underinvestment should occur

with the objective of meeting short-term goals; and (3) such underinvestment must be sub-

optimal in the sense of impairing long-term growth and value creation. Based on different

measures/settings, prior empirical studies provide mixed results. Some scholars find that the

stock market reacts positively to announcements of R&D increases (Jarrell and Lehn 1985;

Woolridge 1988) even when such announcements occur in the face of an earnings

2 Information source: http://knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/index.cfm?fa=viewArticle&id=1318&specialId=41. 3 In the long run, even shortsighted investors are likely to realize the unfavorable effects of managerial myopia.

Page 5: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

5

disappointment (Chan et al. 1990), suggesting that capital markets do reward R&D

investment immediately. While these studies document interesting and insightful results, they

only examine market response to R&D increase. We are still not clear about the stock market

reaction to myopia – cutting long-term projects (e.g., R&D) for short-term benefits. Using

U.K. data from 1989 to 2002, Osma and Young (2009) find that the sensitivity between one-

year return and earnings increases is lower if earnings increases are likely to come from

myopic R&D cut. What they focus is how managerial myopia influences earnings response

coefficients rather than how market reacts to managerial myopia. A more related paper is

Bhojraj, Hribar, Picconi, & McInnis (2009), in which the sample is divided into two groups.

The first group consists of firms that beat earnings target but have low earnings quality and

the second group consists of firms that miss earnings target but have high earnings quality.

Their results show that the first group of firms exhibits higher short-term stock price benefits

(measured by five-day returns surrounding the earnings announcement date) than the second

group. Further, such trend reverses over a three-year horizon, suggesting that managerial

myopia is punished by capital markets in the long term but not in the short run. Bhojraj et al.

(2009) use “low earnings quality but beat earnings target” to capture myopic behavior.

Particularly, firms are considered to be low in earnings quality if: (1) directional accruals are

above the median level of all firms in year t; and (2) change in R&D is below the median

level of all firms in year t; and (3) change in advertising is below the median level of all firms

in year t. However, the below-median change in R&D is not necessarily underinvestment4,

nor does it necessarily occur with the objective of meeting short-term earnings target because

the “meeting or beating” may come from discretional accruals or advertising decrease. Hence,

managerial myopia is not well captured in Bhojraj et al. (2009). Overall, prior studies provide

4 Because of the high variation across different industries, the median level of R&D change of all firms is

unlikely to be the optimal level of R&D change for each firm. Therefore, it’s questionable to use the median

level of all firms as the benchmark to judge whether one firm’s R&D change is underinvestment. For example,

if the median level of R&D change is 10%, then a firm will be classified as myopic even if it increases its R&D

investment by 8%.

Page 6: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

6

mixed findings.

In this paper we first sample firms for which earnings before R&D and taxes have

declined relative to the prior year, but have declined by an amount that can be reversed by a

reduction in R&D. By definition, all these firms are suspected of having myopic problems

because they have the incentive, as well as the ability, to cut R&D in order to meet earnings

targets. However, not all firms that have myopic problems will be involved in myopic

behaviors. Managers of these firms have two options – to cut or not to cut R&D. If they

choose to cut R&D, they are very likely to beat the target. If they choose not to cut R&D,

they have to miss the earnings target. Hence, if these firms do decrease R&D, then most

likely such cutting is for the objective of meeting earnings targets and therefore could be

regarded as myopic. We then focus on two subgroups of firms: (1) firms that cut R&D and

meet the previous year’s earnings (hereafter, myopic cutters) and (2) firms that do not cut

R&D, and thus miss the previous year’s earnings (hereafter, non-cutters). By the

classification, non-cutters are those who would have been able to meet/beat the earnings

target should they choose to decrease R&D. Myopic cutters, however, are those who would

have missed the earnings target should they maintain their prior R&D investment level. If the

market does not punish myopic R&D cutting, we should observe a better short-term stock

price performance for myopic cutters because these firms exhibit systematically higher

earnings surprises. If it turns out that myopic cutters show worse performance, then it

suggests that capital markets do punish myopic behavior because the only reason that myopic

cutters have higher earnings surprises than non-cutters is managerial myopia - cutting R&D

to meet earnings targets.5 We believe that our setting provides a cleaner setting to capture

managers’ myopic behavior.

5 This testing strategy makes it impossible to use zero as the earnings benchmark because earnings surprises (i.e., earnings

changes) will be incomparable for different firms. Although analyst forecast is also a popular benchmark, analysts may

change their forecasts from month to month. As a result, it is difficult for managers to make R&D cut decisions according to

analysts’ forecasts. Moreover, many analysts do not provide their forecasted R&D expenditure and thus make unavailable

the forecasted earnings before R&D. Therefore, we use earnings of the prior year rather than zero or analyst forecast as the

benchmark in this study.

Page 7: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

7

Applying an event study, we find that myopic cutters systematically underperform in a

five-day window surrounding the release of the earnings announcement. This indicates that

investors are able to see through the earnings manipulation by R&D cut and penalize such

myopic behavior. We also estimate ordinary least squares (OLS) regression to control the

factors that could influence five-day returns. The results show that myopic cutters still have

significantly lower five-day returns after controlling variables identified in prior studies.

If capital markets are efficient and do discount managerial myopia, we expect the

discount to be higher for firms with more sophisticated investors because these investors are

better able to “see through” managers’ myopic R&D cutting behavior and less likely to fixate

on earnings. Therefore, we further examine whether investor sophistication affects the market

reaction to the managerial myopia. We expect that managers in firms with more sophisticated

investors are more likely to be punished by the market for cutting R&D to meet/beat short-

term earnings targets. Consistent with our prediction, we find that the phenomenon of capital

markets punishing managerial myopic behavior exists only in the sub-sample of firms with

high investor sophistication. This finding further supports that capital markets with

sophisticated investors would punish manager’s myopic R&D cutting.

A question remained unsolved, however, is why managers still choose to behave

myopically. We further explore the incentives of managerial myopia by examining CEO

compensation. We find that CEOs who cut R&D to meet the previous year’s earnings receive

significantly higher cash pay (the sum of salary and annual bonus) and total pay (the sum of

cash pay and noncash pay) after controlling other important determinants of CEO

compensation. Our results provide another piece of evidence supporting the theory of

incomplete contract6 (Hart and Moore 1988). Particularly, when drawing up a contract, it is

6 A complete contract is one where each party could specify their respective rights and duties for every possible

future state of the world. However, complete contract does not exist in reality either because the state of the

world is not observable by all parties or because the cost of processing and using the information is too high.

Page 8: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

8

impracticable for each party to specify all relevant contingencies due to the costly

information and contracting. Regarding compensation contracts, some situations (e.g.,

whether firms will have a small earnings decline) are unpredictable before incentive plans are

made. Hence, the parties are likely to end up with an incomplete compensation contract,

which becomes one of the reasons why CEO behaves myopically.

Our paper contributes to the literature in a number of ways. First, it has long been argued

that the market pressure causes managers to behave myopically. If this argument holds, we

should observe a positive market reaction to managers’ myopic behavior. However, previous

empirical literature provides mixed results. On the one hand, some studies (Jarrell and Lehn

1985; Woolridge 1988) find that stock market rewards R&D increase but they did not address

how the market reacts to R&D decrease. Osma and Young (2009) did examine myopic R&D

cutting but they only focus on earnings response coefficients and did not provide direct

evidence on how market responds to managerial myopia. On the other hand, Bhojraj et al.

(2009) find that capital market punishes managerial myopia only in the long term, suggesting

that market does pressure managers to be involved in myopic behavior. However the way

they measure myopic behavior is not able to well capture myopia7. Our study is expected to

contribute to this line of research by reconciling previous mixed findings because our setting

enables us to better capture managers’ myopic behaviors. Specifically, our results show

significantly lower mean and median values of five-day returns for myopic cutters,

suggesting that capital markets do penalize the myopic behavior of managers (e.g., cutting

R&D to meet the previous year’s earnings). Additionally, by constructing a specific setting

where managers’ cutting R&D investment is most likely for meeting earnings target, we

provide a better measure for managers’ myopic behaviors.

Second, manipulating real operations such as R&D investment is a popular way of

7 Please refer to page 5 for detailed analysis on prior studies.

Page 9: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

9

earnings management (Bhagat and Bolton 2008), but there are few studies examining the

economic consequences of real earnings management8. Our study extends this stream of

research by showing that the market attaches a lower value to firms engaging in myopic R&D

cutting in the short run.

Finally, our results suggest that CEO compensation might be one of the possible reasons

why CEOs behave myopically. In this aspect, our study provides a new explanation on

managerial myopia and could contribute to the literature on both managerial myopia and

CEO compensation.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section reviews literature

and develops hypothesis. Section III describes the empirical analysis and reports the results.

Section IV examines the effects of investment sophistication. Section V extends the analysis

to explore why managers act myopically. Section VI examines the effect of managerial

myopia on future performance. Section VI concludes.

II. Literature and Hypothesis

A large amount of literature provides evidence of managerial myopia with respect to

R&D spending. It is documented that R&D spending is significantly lower when the

spending jeopardizes managerial ability to report positive/increased earnings in the current

period (Baber et al. 1991; Roychowdhury 2006), or when CEOs are in the final years of their

administrative tenure (Dechow and Sloan 1991). Further, Bens et al. (2002) find that firms

experiencing employee stock option exercises divert resources away from real investment

projects to finance share repurchases resulting from the exercises.

Among all the factors that have been linked to managerial myopia, the transient nature

of capital market has received the most attention. It is argued that the pressure from the

capital market motivates managers to meet the Wall Street expectations even if doing so

8 One exception is Gunny (2010), who finds that firms use real earnings management to attain current-period

benefits that allow them to perform better in the future or signal to outsiders.

Page 10: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

10

would require costly changes in real activities, such as myopically cutting R&D or capital

expenditures.

Prior empirical studies generally find that managers engage in more/less myopic

behaviors in response to increased/decreased capital market pressure. Specifically, managers

are more likely to cut R&D investment to avoid an earnings decline when they foresee a

stock issuance (Cohen and Zarowin 2010; Bhojraj and Libby 2005), when institutional

investors have high portfolio turnover and engage in momentum trading (Bushee 1998) or

when there exists a threat from the takeover market. Similarly, He and Tian (2013) show that

firms with greater analyst coverage generate fewer patents and patents with lower impact,

suggesting that financial analysts as one key ingredient of the public equity market exert

pressure on managers to meet short-term goals and therefore impede firms’ investment in

long-term innovative projects. Recently, Hu et al. (2014) find that after earnings guidance

cessation, managers have less pressure to manage reported earnings to meet guidance

numbers and accordingly can focus on actions that secure long-term values.

Another stream of research investigates the capital market reaction to managers’ R&D

investment decision. The results from this stream are mixed. Several prior studies

documented that returns are positively associated with the announcement of R&D projects

(Jarrell & Lehn 1985; Woolridge 1988; Chan et al. 1990), which suggests that the markets do

reward management decisions that are consistent with long-term value creation. If capital

markets are not short-sighted, we should also observe a significant negative returns following

myopic R&D cut. Nevertheless, Bhojraj et al. (2009) find that stock market reaction is

positive to beaters even though they exhibit low earnings quality (measured by below-median

change in R&D, below-median change in advertising and above-median change in directional

accrual), indicating that capital markets do not punish managers’ myopic behaviors

immediately. However, the below-median change in R&D does not necessarily represent

Page 11: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

11

underinvestment. More importantly, because Bhojraj et al. (2009) combines R&D,

advertising and discretional accruals in their measurement, the below-median change in R&D

is not necessarily a sacrifice to achieve a short-term earnings target and therefore might not

reflect managerial myopia. Taken together, although prior studies examined the market

reaction to change in R&D investments, they did not directly investigate market response to

managerial myopia (i.e. sacrificing long-term growth for the purpose of meeting short-term

goals).

We argue that capital markets could see through managerial myopia and thus penalize it

accordingly. Despite widespread allegations of stock market “short termism,” research

persuasively supports a view that capital markets consider R&D investments as significant

value-increasing activities (Cheng 2004). Further, market participants would search for

methods to mitigate potential wasteful reduction of long-term profitable investment

(Chhaochharia and Grinstein 2007). For example, managers are less likely to cut R&D to

reverse an earnings decline when institutional ownership is high. Specifically, institutional

ownership serves to reduce pressures on managers for myopic investment behavior if

institutional investors have low turnover and momentum trading (Bushee 1998). Osma (2008)

provides evidence suggesting that independent directors have sufficient technical knowledge

to identify opportunistic reductions in R&D, and to efficiently constrain myopic R&D

spending. In addition, the presence of auditors and other experts who estimate R&D project

values could lessen the information asymmetry that generates mispricing and therefore

suppress managerial myopia (Chhaochharia and Grinstein 2007). Managers could also

credibly reveal their belief that the firm is undervalued by initiating stock repurchases or by

accepting compensation contingent on project outcome (Meulbroek et al. 1990). In line with

this logic, we expect that:

H1: Capital markets react negatively to the behavior of cutting R&D to meet

Page 12: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

12

earnings target.

The discussion leading up to H1 assumes that the investors are capable of searching for

and analyzing information. However, as prior studies indicate, investor sophistication varies

across firms (Callen et al. 2005; Bartov et al. 2000). Although the threshold of investor

sophistication for an efficient capital market is unknown, we could empirically test whether

the extent of investor sophistication matters. Sophisticated investors are more likely to see

through the myopic R&D cut behavior than unsophisticated investors. Therefore, it is more

likely that myopic R&D cut is punished when investors are sophisticated. If the investors’

reactions to managerial myopia vary across firms in a manner consistent with the effects of

investor sophistication, it will increase the reliability of our empirical results. Following prior

studies, we construct the second hypothesis as follows:

H2. The phenomena that capital markets react negatively to the behavior of cutting

R&D to meet earnings target exists mainly in firms with sophisticated investors.

III. Empirical Analysis

A. Sample and Measures

Our sample consists of firm-year observations drawn from the Compustat Database from

1972 to 2014. The earliest year is set at 1972 because prior to that year relatively few firms

on Compustat reported information on R&D outlays (Kothari et al. 2002). All price and

returns data are from the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP). To ensure that

micro-cap or penny stocks did not bias our results, we dropped firms with assets less than $10

million or the share price less than $1. Utilities and banks are also omitted from our sample,

because their financial statements tend to be different from those of other types of firms. As

mentioned, we include in our sample only firms that have both incentive and ability to cut

R&D to meet short-term earnings. Thus, firms are excluded unless their earnings before R&D

and taxes have declined relative to the prior year, but by an amount that can be reversed by a

Page 13: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

13

20%9 reduction in R&D. Specifically, we compute EBTRD (Earnings before Tax and R&D)

and exclude firms that do not satisfy the inequality “–0.2*(RDt-1)<=(EBTRDt-EBTRD t-1)<0”.

Furthermore, we exclude firms that cut R&D and missed the previous year’s earnings10

.

Finally, observations were deleted if either: (1) Compustat reports missing values for sales,

total assets, book value of equity, or market value of equity; or (2) data needed to compute

the variables are missing. The sample-selection criteria yield a total of 3,061 observations,

with 939 myopic cutters and 2,122 non-cutters. To assuage the effects of outliers, we

winsorize all variables except dummy variables at the 1st and 99th percentile values.

We classify firms into categories based on whether they cut R&D and meet the previous

year’s earnings. We construct a dummy variable CutRD, which is 1 if managers cut R&D at

year t (i.e., R&D expenditure is lower relative to the prior year) and earnings at year t are not

less than that of year t-1. CutRD equals 0 if managers do not cut R&D at year t. Thus, CutRD

in this paper is the measure of managerial myopia.

Testing our hypotheses also requires the measure of market reaction. To increase the

robustness of our study, we use three different measures to capture market reaction: raw

return, market-adjusted abnormal return, and size-adjusted abnormal return. All the returns

are calculated using a five-day window that begins two days before the earnings

announcement and ends two days after the earnings announcement. Five-day (adjusted)

returns are calculated as the (adjusted) cumulative return in the five-day window. The market-

adjusted (size-adjusted) return is calculated using daily CRSP returns, and is adjusted by

subtracting the cumulative market return (market return of firms in the same CRSP size

decile) over the same period.

B. Descriptive Statistics

9 When the ratio of the distance from the earnings goal relative to the prior year’s R&D ((EBTRDt-1-EBTRD t)/RDt-1) is

higher than 20%, the probability of R&D cut is low (13.47%). This indicates that, if the ratio is high, it will be difficult for

managers to cut R&D to meet earnings targets. To ensure that managers have both the incentive and the ability to cut R&D

to meet the previous year’s earnings, we require the ratio to be less than or equal to 20%. We also apply 10%, 15%, or 25%

as the thresholds and get qualitatively similar results. 10 If we include these firms in the sample and treat them as myopic cutters, the results remain unchanged.

Page 14: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

14

Panel A of Table I provides descriptive statistics separately for myopic cutters and non-

cutters. For the mean values, the myopic cutters have significantly lower R&D change (△

RD), firm size (SIZE), earnings (Earnings), previous year’s earnings (Lag_Earnings), and

distance (Distance) as well as significantly higher earnings surprises (Surprise), book-to-

market ratio (BM), and Momentum. For the median values, all the variables (except book-to-

market ratio) show significant difference between myopic cutters and non-cutters.

Panel B of Table I provides distribution of observations for myopic cutters and non-

cutters across industries (two-digit SIC code). Most observations (around 70% of myopic

cutters and 72% of non-cutters) clustered on five industries: Chemical and Allied Products

(SIC: 26), Industrial Machinery & Equipment (SIC: 35), Electronic & Other Electronic (SIC:

36), Instruments & Related Products (SIC: 38), and Business Service (SIC: 73).

C. Research Design

We first examine how investors react to myopic R&D cut by comparing abnormal

returns of myopic cutters and non-cutters. Because myopic cutters have significantly higher

earnings surprise than non-cutters (See Table I: p-values of mean/median difference for

Surprise is lower than 0.000), the market reaction of myopic cutters should be more positive

than that of non-cutters. Therefore, if we find that the market reaction to myopic cutters is

more negative than that towards non-cutters, then it indicates that the investors punish the

behavior of myopic R&D cut. Our research design provides a conservative way to detect the

punishment of managerial myopia by investors.

To mitigate the concern that there might be many other factors affecting the abnormal

returns, we further apply the regression method to examine the influences of R&D cut on the

market reaction. Following Larker, Ormazabal, and Taylor (2011), we test our research

question by estimating the following regression.

RETi,t=α0+ α1CutRDi,t+ α2ERDSurprisei,t+ α3ΔRDi,t+ α4SIZEi,t + α5BMi,t

Page 15: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

15

+α6Momentumi,t+ Firm and Year Fixed Effects+ ε (1)

where:

i = Index of firm i;

t Index of year t;

RET = Five-day (adjusted) returns are calculated as the (adjusted)

cumulative return beginning two days before the earnings

announcement and ending two days after the earnings

announcement. The market-adjusted (size-adjusted) abnormal

return is calculated using daily CRSP returns, and is adjusted by

subtracting the cumulative market return (market return of firms in

the same CRSP size decile) over the same period;

CutRD = A dummy variable that equals 1 if firms cut R&D and meet the

previous year’s earnings, and 0 if firms do not cut R&D and fail to

meet the previous year’s earnings;

ERDSurprise = Earnings before R&D of year t minus earnings before R&D of year

t-1;

ΔRD = R&D of year t minus R&D of year t-1;

SIZE = The natural logarithm of market value at the end of year t;

BM = Book value divided by market value;

Momentum = Market-adjusted return over the prior six months.

D. Empirical Results

Empirical results on Hypothesis 1 are reported in Table II. Panel A of Table II presents

both the mean and median values of five-day returns11

surrounding the release of earnings

announcement for myopic cutters and non-cutters, respectively. It shows that the mean and

median values of raw return, size-adjusted return, and market-adjusted return are all

significantly negative for myopic cutters. In contrast, for non-cutters, only the mean and

median of size-adjusted return are significantly negative. More importantly, column (5) of

Panel A reveals significantly lower mean values of five-day returns for myopic cutters (t-

statistics of -3.917, -3.787, and -3.684). The values of the mean differences of the five-day

returns between the two subgroups are around 1%, which is economically significant.

Similarly, the median values of five-day returns are also significantly lower for myopic

cutters (z-statistics of -6.883, -11.271, and -9.080). Because both the mean and median values

of earnings surprises of myopic cutters are significantly higher (0.269 vs. -0.321 for mean

11 We also try three-day stock returns, and the (untabulated) results are qualitatively similar.

Page 16: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

16

values and 0.120 vs. -0.200 for median values, shown in Table I), our results indicate that

capital markets do penalize the myopic behavior of managers (e.g., cutting R&D to meet the

previous year’s earnings).

The more informative results are shown in Panel B of Table II, which presents the

coefficient estimates for equation (1). In all three columns, the coefficients on CutRD are

significantly negative (The coefficients on CutRD are -0.009, -0.009 and -0.008 respectively,

all significant at 5% level), indicating that myopic cutters generally have lower abnormal

returns than non-cutters. Our results further support the view that capital markets punish

managerial myopia.

The results for the control variables are generally consistent with prior literature. The

positive coefficients on ERDSuprise are consistent with prior studies on earnings response

coefficients (ERCs). The coefficients on △RD are significant and positive in Column (1) and

(2). The positive coefficients on SIZE and BM are consistent with Larker et al. (2011).

IV. Effects of Investor Sophistication on Market Reaction to Managerial Myopia

Prior studies find that the investor sophistication is not homogenous in capital markets. If

investors of a firm are naive, they would be less likely to see through managers’ myopic

behavior and to punish accordingly. Following previous literature, we use the percentage of

shares held by institutions12

(Inst_Percent) to proxy for investor sophistication (e.g., Bartov et

al. 2000; Callen et al. 2005). Consistent with the extant literature, institutional investors

comprise banks, insurance companies, and investment companies, including their managers,

independent advisors, and others. The institutional holding data are from 13-f filings to the

SEC, provided by CDA Spectrum database. Our sample for testing hypothesis 2 consists of

2,146 firm-year observations covering the years from 1972 to 2014.

12 We use the number of institutions holdings shares as an alternative proxy for investor sophistication, and the empirical

results remain qualitatively unchanged (untabulated). Moreover, we also use total asset size and analyst following as proxies

for investor sophistication. The alternative measures of investor sophistication do not change our empirical results

qualitatively (untabulated).

Page 17: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

17

Table III reports descriptive statistics for variables used in the investor sophistication

tests. It shows that myopic cutters have significantly lower raw return, market-adjusted

return, and size-adjusted return, which is consistent with our hypothesis. Myopic cutters also

have lower mean values of change in R&D, firm size, earnings, previous year’s earnings

(Lag_Earnings), and distance (Distance) while significantly higher earnings surprises

(Surprise), book-to-market ratio (BM), and momentum. For the median values, all the

variables (except book-to-market ratio) show significant difference between myopic cutters

and non-cutters.

We conduct sub-sample regressions to examine the effects of investor sophistication on

the market reaction to managerial myopia. Specifically, we divide our sample into high-IS

and low-IS sub-samples. The high-IS (low-IS) sub-sample consists of firm-years for which

Inst_Percent is higher (lower) than the median in year t, thus representing the observations

for which investors are more (less) sophisticated. By estimating the equation (1) in the

strong/weak investor sophistication subgroups, respectively, we expect that our results hold in

the high-IS sample. Because the threshold of investor sophistication ensuring the ability to

see through the managerial behavior is unknown, we make no prediction on the results in

low-IS sample.

The sub-sample regression results are presented in Table IV. It shows that the

coefficients on CutRD are all significantly negative in high-IS sub-sample (t-statistics of -

3.166, -3.438, and -2.748, respectively), while insignificant in low-IS sub-sample (t-statistics

of -0.151, -0.342, and 0.174, respectively). The differences of coefficients on CutRD are

statistically significant (all at the 5% level or better), suggesting that the negative impact of

myopic behavior on stock returns is pronounced only when investors are sophisticated. Our

second hypothesis is supported.

V. Extension: Managerial Incentive to Behave Myopically

Page 18: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

18

The above findings suggest that the market is efficient, and thus might not pressure

managers to cut R&D in a way that is myopic. A question that has remained unanswered,

however, is what causes managers to act myopically. In this section we further examine the

possible reasons for managerial myopic R&D cut.

Earnings is an important determinant of top executive compensation, because earnings-

based performance measures help to shield executives from fluctuations that are beyond their

control (Donaldson and Preston 1995). Missing an earnings benchmark may become a signal

of poor performance that induces the compensation committee to penalize managers.

Consistent with this argument, Matsunaga and Park (2001) find that CEOs’ annual bonuses

are positively related to the likelihood of meeting a quarterly earnings benchmark. Further,

meeting the earnings benchmark could constitute a public signal that allows the compensation

committee to justify higher compensation levels to shareholders and, thereby, to overcome

political constraints on CEO compensation (Porter and Kramer 2006). Thus, by meeting

earnings targets, managers are able to increase their personal wealth in the form of cash pay.

In view of this, we expect compensation to be a potential reason of managerial myopia13

.

In addition to cash pay, we also examine whether managerial myopia affects managers’

total pay and noncash pay. Total pay is the sum of cash pay and noncash pay, and thus is a

more comprehensive measure of CEO compensation. Noncash pay is the sum of the value of

equity grants during the year, the fringe benefits, and other long-term incentive plans, with

stock options valued at the end of the fiscal year using the Black-Scholes 1973 model

adjusted for dividends. Previous literature indicates that noncash pay is an important

component of CEO incentives (Murphy 1999).

We test our prediction by estimating the following model:

ΔPayi,t=β0+ β1CutRDi,t+ β2ΔROAi,t+ β3ΔRDi,t + β4RETi,t+ β5SIZEi,t-1+ β6Qi,t-1

13 We are not suggesting that corporate boards are myopic or they support managerial myopia. There are always some

contingencies that are not predictable and thus could not be factored into the compensation contract. The incompleteness of

the contract therefore becomes one reason why some managers eventually choose to behave myopically.

Page 19: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

19

+ β7LEVi,t-1 + β8Ownershipi,t-1+ β9Tenurei,t + β10Eindexi,t-1 + β11Board Sizei,t-1

+ β12Board Indpendencei,t-1+ β13CEO Duality,t-1 + Firm and Year Fixed Effects

+ ε (2)

where:

i = Index of firm i;

j = Index of year t;

ΔPay = The change of CEO’s total pay, the change of CEO’s cash

pay, or the change of CEO’s noncash pay. The change of

CEO pay (total pay, cash pay, or noncash pay) is calculated as

the logarithm of pay (total pay, cash pay, or noncash pay) in

year t minus the logarithm of CEO pay (total pay, cash pay,

or noncash pay) in year t-1;

Cash Pay = CEO cash pay, including salary and annual bonuses;

Noncash Pay = CEO noncash pay, including value of equity grants during the

year, fringe benefits, and other long-term incentive plans;

Total Pay = The sum of cash pay and noncash pay;

ΔROA = ROAi,t -ROAi,t-1;

ΔRD = R&Di,t –R&Di,t-1;

ROA = Net income divided by total assets;

RET = Annual stock return;

SIZE = Logarithm of total assets;

Q = The book value of assets minus the book value of equity, plus

the market value of equity, scaled by the book value of assets;

LEV = Total debts divided by total assets;

Ownership = CEO ownership as a percentage of shares outstanding;

Tenure = Number of years as the CEO of the firm.

Eindex = an index based on six antitakeover provisions: staggered

board, poison pills, the supermajority requirement for

mergers, limits to the shareholder bylaw amendments, limits

to the charter amendments, and golden parachutes;

Board Size = the natural log of number of directors on board;

Board Independence = percentage of independent directors on board;

CEO Duality = a dummy variable which equals 1 if CEO and Chairman of

the board are the same person, 0 otherwise

The model and control variables in (2) are based on previous literature (Sloan 1993;

Cheng 2004; Cheng and Indjejikian 2009). The dependent variable Δpayi,t could be the

change of CEO cash pay, the change of CEO total pay, or the change of noncash pay. We use

Page 20: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

20

a natural logarithmic transformation to control for skewness in CEO compensation14

. If

managers who cut R&D to meet the previous year’s earnings receive more compensation,

then β1 would be significantly positive.

We control ΔROA and Return because accounting and stock performance measures have

positive effects on CEO compensation (Baber et al. 1996; Lambert and Larcker 1987). We

also control other variables that have been identified by previous literature as being

associated with CEO compensation (Murphy 1999; Hartzell and Starks 2003; Cheng and

Indjejikian 2009). These include firm-level characteristics such as ΔRD, size, Tobin’s Q,

leverage, market-to-book ratio, CEO characteristics such as equity ownership and CEO

tenure, and corporate governance variables such as Eindex, board size, board independence,

and CEO duality.

We test our prediction on a sample of 324 firm years from 1993–200815

that have both

incentive and ability to cut R&D in order to meet the previous year’s earnings. We obtain the

annual compensation information from the Execucomp database. Since we are analyzing the

change in compensation, we require that a firm has two consecutive years of compensation

data. For this reason, as well, we restrict our sample to those executives who have been CEOs

for both of the consecutive years. The other sample selection criteria are the same as above.

The results are shown in Table VI. Columns (1), (2), and (3) report the results of total

pay, cash pay and noncash pay, respectively. In Columns (1) and (2), the coefficients on

CutRD are positive and significant (p-value less than 0.05), indicating that managers

generally receive benefits by acting myopically. In Column (3), the coefficient on CutRD is

positive but insignificant. Overall, our results indicate that compensation, especially cash

compensation, might be one of the possible reasons for managerial myopia.

14 The results remain unchanged when this transformation is not applied. 15 The earliest year is 1993 because Execucomp provides executive compensation data since 1992 and we need

to calculate the change of compensation using one-year-lag data. The ending year is 2008 due to the data

availability of Eindex (downloaded from Lucian Bebchuk's home page:

http://www.law.harvard.edu/faculty/bebchuk/data.shtml).

Page 21: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

21

VI. Additional Analysis: Managerial Myopia and Future Performance

Managers’ myopic behavior is expected to do harm to firm performance in a long run.

Therefore, we further test whether myopic cutters experience lower future performance than

non-cutters. In particular, we rerun model (1) by replacing dependent variables with future

performance, which is captured by future stock market performance (measured by one-year

stock return after earnings announcement) and future financial performance (measured by

return on assets and return on equity at the end of next fiscal year).

The results are shown in Table VII. In all three columns, the coefficients on CutRD are

significantly negative (-0.173, -0.054 and -0.159 respectively, all significant at 5% level),

indicating that myopic cutters generally have lower future performance than non-cutters. Our

results further support the view that cutting R&D for short-term earnings target is

unfavorable to firms’ future performance.

VII. Conclusions

Many academics and practitioners believe that myopia is a first-order problem faced by

the modern firm (Edmans 2009), and it is concern for the stock price that leads to myopia.

Using managers’ R&D cutting to meet short-term earnings targets as a setting, our study

examines whether the market actually discounts managerial myopia.

The study is based on a sample of U.S. firms with declined pre-tax, pre-R&D earnings

relative to the prior year—but earnings that have declined by an amount that can be reversed

by cutting 20% of the previous year’s R&D. We investigate whether the market reacts

negatively to managerial myopia around the earnings announcement date, and whether it

attaches a lower value to firms that cut R&D myopically. Using five-day returns surrounding

the announcement of earnings as an indicator of market reaction, we provide empirical

evidence suggesting that the market is not myopic, and that it does penalize firms if managers

engage in myopic R&D cutting for the purpose of short-term goals. Our further tests indicate

Page 22: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

22

that the negative market reaction to managerial myopia only exists in firms where investors

are more sophisticated.

Given that capital markets could “see through” managerial myopia, we further explore

why managers still choose to behave myopically. We conduct regressions to examine the

effects of managerial myopia on CEO cash pay, noncash pay, and total pay. Our results

suggest that CEOs who cut R&D myopically receive significantly higher total pay and cash

pay, indicating that the incomplete compensation contract is one of the reasons for managerial

myopia.

Although researchers argue that it cannot be true that the market is myopic, empirical

evidences are limited. Our study helps to reconcile previous findings and contributes to the

literature on managerial myopia. Further, this study extends the literature on the economic

consequences of real earnings management by indicating that the market discounts real

earnings management behaviors.

Page 23: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

23

References:

Asker, J., J. Farre-Mensa, and A. Ljungqvist. 2011. Comparing the investment behavior of

public and private firms: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Baber, W. R., P. M. Fairfield, and J. A. Haggard. 1991. The effect of concern about reported

income on discretionary spending decisions: the case of research and development.

The Accounting Review 66 (4):818-829.

Baber, W. R., S. N. Janakiraman, and S. H. Kang. 1996. Investment opportunities and the

structure of executive compensation. Journal of Accounting and Economics 21

(3):297-318.

Bange, M. M., and W. F. M. De Bondt. 1998. R&D budgets and corporate earnings targets.

Journal of Corporate Finance 4 (2):153-184.

Bartov, E., S. Radhakrishnan, and I. Krinsky. 2000. Investor sophistication and patterns in

stock returns after earnings announcements. The Accounting Review 75 (1):43-63.

Bens, D. A., V. Nagar, and M. Wong. 2002. Real investment implications of employee stock

option exercises. Journal of Accounting Research 40 (2):359-393.

Bhagat, S., and B. Bolton. 2008. Corporate governance and firm performance. Journal of

Corporate Finance 14 (3):257-273.

Bhojraj, S., P. Hribar, M. Picconi, and J. McInnis. 2009. Making sense of cents: An

examination of firms that marginally miss or beat analyst forecasts. The Journal of

Finance 64 (5):2361-2388.

Bhojraj, S., and R. Libby. 2005. Capital market pressure, disclosure frequency-induced

earnings/cash flow conflict, and managerial myopia. The Accounting Review 80 (1):1-

20.

Bushee, B. J. 1998. The Influence of Institutional Investors on Myopic R&D Investment

Behavior. The Accounting Review 73 (3):305-333.

Callen, J. L., O.-K. Hope, and D. Segal. 2005. Domestic and foreign earnings, stock return

variability, and the impact of investor sophistication. Journal of Accounting Research

43 (3):377-412.

Chan, S. H., J. Martin, and J. Kensinger. 1990. Corporate research and development

expenditures and share value. Journal of Financial Economics 26:255-276.

Cheng, M., K. R. Subramanyam, and Y. Zhang. 2007. Earnings Guidance and Managerial

Myopia. Working Paper.

Cheng, S. 2004. R&D expenditures and CEO compensation. Accounting Review 79 (2):305-

328.

Cheng, S., and R. J. Indjejikian. 2009. The Market for Corporate Control and CEO

Compensation: Complements or Substitutes? Contemporary Accounting Research 26

(3):701-728.

Chhaochharia, V., and Y. Grinstein. 2007. Corporate governance and firm value: The impact

of the 2002 governance rules. The Journal of Finance 62 (4):1789-1825.

Cohen, D. A., and P. Zarowin. 2010. Accrual-based and real earnings management activities

around seasoned equity offerings. Journal of Accounting and Economics 50 (1):2-19.

Cooper, J. C., and F. H. Selto. 1991. An experimental examination of the effects of SFAS No.

2 on R&D investment decisions. Accounting, Organizations and Society 16 (3):227-

242.

Dechow, P., and R. Sloan. 1991. Executive incentives and the horizon problem: an empirical

investigation. Journal of Accounting and Economics 14 (1):51-89.

Donaldson, T., and L. E. Preston. 1995. The stakeholder theory of the corporation: Concepts,

evidence, and implications. Academy of management review:65-91.

Edmans, A. 2009. Blockholder trading, market efficiency, and managerial myopia. The

Page 24: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

24

Journal of Finance 64 (6):2481-2513.

Gigler, F., C. Kanodia, H. Sapra, and R. Venugopalan. 2009. Increasing the frequency of

financial reporting: an equilibrium analysis of costs and benefits: Working paper,

University of Minnesota.

Graham, J. R., C. R. Harvey, and S. Rajgopal. 2005. The economic implications of corporate

financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 40 (1-3):3-73.

Gunny, K. A. 2010. The Relation Between Earnings Management Using Real Activities

Manipulation and Future Performance: Evidence from Meeting Earnings

Benchmarks. Contemporary Accounting Research 27 (3):855-888.

Hart, O., and J. Moore. 1988. Incomplete contracts and renegotiation. Econometrica: Journal

of the econometric society:755-785.

Hartzell, J. C., and L. T. Starks. 2003. Institutional investors and executive compensation.

The Journal of Finance 58 (6):2351-2374.

He, J. J., and X. Tian. 2013. The dark side of analyst coverage: The case of innovation.

Journal of Financial Economics 109 (3):856-878.

Houston, J. F., B. Lev, and J. W. Tucker. 2010. To guide or not to guide? causes and

consequences of stopping quarterly earnings guidance. Contemporary Accounting

Research 27 (1):143-185.

Hu, B., J. H. Hwang, and C. Jiang. 2014. The impact of earnings guidance cessation on

information asymmetry. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 41 (1-2):73-99.

Jacobs, M. 1991. Short-term America: The causes and cures of our business myopia. Boston,

MA: Havard Business School Press.

Jarrell, G., and K. Lehn. 1985. Institutional ownership, tender offers and long-term

investment: Securities Exchange Commission.

Kothari, S. P., T. E. Laguerre, and A. J. Leone. 2002. Capitalization versus expensing:

evidence on the uncertainty of future earnings from capital expenditures versus R&D

outlays. Review of Accounting Studies 7 (4):355-382.

Lambert, R. A., and D. F. Larcker. 1987. An analysis of the use of accounting and market

measures of performance in executive compensation contracts. Journal of Accounting

Research:85-125.

Larcker, D. F., G. Ormazabal, and D. J. Taylor. 2011. The market reaction to corporate

governance regulation. Journal of Financial Economics 101 (2):431-448.

Matsunaga, S. R., and C. W. Park. 2001. The effect of missing a quarterly earnings

benchmark on the CEO's annual bonus. The Accounting Review 76 (3):313-332.

Meulbroek, L. K., M. L. Mitchell, J. H. Mulherin, J. M. Netter, and A. B. Poulsen. 1990.

Shark repellents and managerial myopia: an empirical test. The Journal of Political

Economy 98 (5):1108-1117.

Murphy, K. J. 1999. Executive compensation. Handbook of labor economics 3:2485-2563.

Osma, B. G. 2008. Board independence and real earnings management: The case of R&D

expenditure. Corporate Governance: An International Review 16 (2):116-131.

Osma, B. G., and S. Young. 2009. R&D expenditure and earnings targets. European

Accounting Review 18 (1):7-32.

Porter, M. 1992. "Capital Choices: The Causes and Cures of Business Myopia." Research

Report to the U.S. Governament's Councial on Competitiveness. Washington D.C.,.

Porter, M. E., and M. R. Kramer. 2006. The link between competitive advantage and

corporate social responsibility. Harvard Business Review 84 (12):78-92.

Roychowdhury, S. 2006. Earnings management through real activities manipulation. Journal

of Accounting and Economics 42 (3):335-370.

Sloan, R. G. 1993. Accounting earnings and top executive compensation. Journal of

Accounting and Economics 16 (1):55-100.

Page 25: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

25

Stein, J. C. 1989. Efficient capital markets, inefficient firms: A model of myopic corporate

behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (4):655-669.

Woolridge, J. R. 1988. Competitive decline and corporate restructuring: is a myopic stock

market to blame? Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 1 (1):26-36.

Zhao, Y., K. H. Chen, Y. Zhang, and M. Davis. 2012. Takeover protection and managerial

myopia: Evidence from real earnings management. Journal of Accounting and Public

Policy 31 (1):109-135.

Page 26: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

26

Appendix 1: Variables Definitions

Variables Definitions

Raw Return calculated as the cumulative return beginning two days before the earnings announcement

and ending two days after the earnings announcement

Market-adjusted

Return

calculated as the cumulative market-adjusted abnormal return beginning two days before

the earnings announcement and ending two days after the earnings announcement. The

market-adjusted abnormal return is calculated using daily CRSP returns and adjusted by

subtracting the cumulative market return over the same period

Size-adjusted Return calculated as the cumulative size-adjusted abnormal return beginning two days before the

earnings announcement and ending two days after the earnings announcement. The size-

adjusted abnormal return is calculated using daily CRSP returns and adjusted by

subtracting the cumulative average return of firms in the same CRSP size decile over the

same period

Surprise measured as Earnings minus Lag_Earnings

△RD R&D of year t minus R&D of year t-1

SIZE the natural logarithm of market value at the end of fiscal year

BM book value divided by market value at the end of fiscal year

Momentum the market-adjusted return over the prior six months

Earnings earnings per share before extraordinary item of a given fiscal year

Lag_Earnings earnings per share before extraordinary item of the prior fiscal year

Distance change of earnings before R&D divided by R&D at the beginning of the fiscal year

CutRD a dummy variable that equals 1 if firms cut R&D to meet the previous year’s earnings, and

0 if firms do not cut R&D and fail to meet the previous year’s earnings.

ERDSurprise earnings before R&D of a given year minus earnings before R&D of the prior fiscal year

Inst_Percent percentage of ownership by institutional investors

Total Pay the sum of cash pay and noncash pay

Cash Pay the sum of salary and annual bonus

Noncash Pay the sum of the value of equity grants during the year, fringe benefits, and other long-term

incentive plans, with stock options valued at the end of the fiscal year using Black-Scholes

1973 model adjusted for dividends

ROA net income divided by total assets

RET annual stock return for the fiscal year

Q the book value of assets minus the book value of equity, plus the market value of equity,

scaled by the book value of assets at the end of fiscal year.

LEV total debts divided by total assets

Ownership the CEO ownership as a percentage of shares outstanding

Tenure the number of years as CEO of the firm

Eindex an index based on six antitakeover provisions: staggered board, poison pills, the

supermajority requirement for mergers, limits to the shareholder bylaw amendments, limits

to the charter amendments, and golden parachutes

Board Size the natural log of number of directors on board

Board Independence percentage of independent directors on board

CEO Duality a dummy variable which equals 1 if CEO and Chairman of the board are the same person,

0 otherwise.

Future Return the one-year stock return from the earnings announcement date

Future ROA return on assets of next fiscal year end

Future ROE return on equity of next fiscal year end

Page 27: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

27

Table I Descriptive Statistics for Myopic Cutters and Non-Cutters

Panel A of this table presents the summary statistics for the two subgroups: firms that cut R&D to meet the previous year’s earnings (myopic

cutters), and firms that do not cut R&D and fail to meet the previous year’s earnings (non-cutters). The sample includes firm-years for which

earnings before R&D and taxes have declined relative to the prior year, but by an amount that can be reversed by a 20% reduction in R&D. The t-

statistics (z-statistics) of the mean (median) differences are provided. Surprise is earnings surprise, measured as Earnings minus Lag_Earnings. △RD is R&D of year t minus R&D of year t-1. RD is research and development expenditure divided by total asset. SIZE is the natural logarithm of

market value at the end of fiscal year. BM is book value divided by market value at the end of fiscal year. Momentum is the market-adjusted return

over the prior six months. Earnings (Lag_Earnings) is earnings per share before extraordinary item of a given fiscal year (the prior fiscal year).

Distance is change of earnings before R&D divided by R&D at the beginning of the fiscal year. Panel B of this table presents the distribution of

observations for myopic cutters and non-cutters across industries labeled by two-digit SIC codes. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%,

and 1% level, respectively, two-tailed.

Panel A: Summary Statistics of Myopic Cutters and Non-Cutters

Myopic Cutters (N=939) Non-Cutters (N=2,122) Difference

Variable

(1)

Mean

(2)

Median

(3)

Std Dev.

(4)

Mean

(5)

Median

(6)

Std Dev.

(1)-(4)

p-value

(2)-(5)

p-value

Surprise 0.269 0.120 0.446 -0.321 -0.200 0.494 <0.000*** <0.000***

△RD -0.142 -0.025 0.367 0.143 0.023 0.421 <0.000*** <0.000***

SIZE 5.126 4.849 2.083 5.623 5.403 1.995 <0.000*** <0.000***

BM 0.672 0.504 0.589 0.606 0.486 0.482 0.001*** 0.498

Momemtum 0.019 -0.047 0.411 -0.058 -0.092 0.328 <0.000*** <0.000***

Earnings 0.338 0.030 1.655 0.612 0.310 1.686 <0.000*** <0.000***

Lag_Earnings 0.069 -0.080 1.785 0.922 0.590 1.812 <0.000*** <0.000***

Distance 0.083 0.076 0.056 0.095 0.092 0.058 <0.000*** <0.000***

Page 28: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

28

Panel B: Distribution of Observations across Industries

SIC Industry N(Myopic cutters) N(Non-Cutters)

1 Agricultural Production 2 9 7 Agricultural Services 1 1

12 Coal Mining 0 1

13 Oil and Gas Extraction 2 7

14 Nonmetallic Minerals, Ex. Fules 0 2

16 Heavy Construction, Ex. Building 3 2

20 Food and Kindred Products 6 21

22 Textile Mill Products 1 10

23 Apparel & Other Textile Products 0 2

24 Lumber and Wood Products 1 0

25 Furniture and Fixtures 2 12

26 Paper and Allied Products 8 17

27 Printing and Publishing 1 1

28 Chemical and Allied Products 239 535

29 Petroleum and Coal Products 4 12

30 Rubber & Misc. Plastics Products 7 17

31 Leather and Leather Products 0 2

32 Stone, Clay, and Glass Products 2 5

33 Primary Metal Industries 4 8

34 Fabricated Metal Products 9 19

35 Industrial Machinery & Equipment 102 297

36 Electronic & Other Electronic Equipment 152 372

37 Transportation Equipment 39 73

38 Instruments & Related Products 160 320

39 Misc. Manufacturing Industries 14 24

44 Water Transportation 1 0

45 Transportation by Air 0 1

47 Transportation Services 0 1

48 Communications 9 21

49 Electrics, Gas, and Sanitary Services 1 2

50 Wholesale Trade – Durable Goods 6 5

51 Wholesale Trade – Nondurable Goods 4 1

54 Food Stores 1 0

59 Miscellaneous Retail 4 3

73 Business Services 120 286

78 Motion Pictures 2 0

79 Amusement & Recreation Services 0 1

80 Health Services 7 6

82 Educational Services 0 3

87 Engineering & Management Services 15 15

99 Nonclassifiable Establishments 10 8

Total 939 2,122

Page 29: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

29

Table II Market Reaction to Managerial Myopia

Panel A presents the five-day returns surrounding the earnings announcement for myopic cutters and non-cutters. The raw return is calculated using

daily CRSP returns. The market-adjusted (size-adjusted) abnormal return is calculated using daily CRSP returns and adjusted by subtracting the

cumulative market return (market return of firms in the same CRSP size decile) over the same period. Five-day (adjusted) returns are calculated as

the (adjusted) cumulative return beginning two days before the earnings announcement and ending two days after the earnings announcement. T-

statistics or z-statistics are presented in the brackets.

Panel B presents results of regression five-day returns surrounding the earnings announcement on myopic R&D cut and control variables. CutRD is

a dummy variable that equals 1 if firms cut R&D and meet the previous year’s earnings, and 0 if firms do not cut R&D and fail to meet the previous

year’s earnings. ERDSurprise is earnings before R&D of a given year minus earnings before R&D of the prior fiscal year. △RD is R&D of year t

minus R&D of year t-1. SIZE is the natural logarithm of market value. BM is book value divided by market value. Momentum is the market-adjusted

return over the prior six months. All variables except dummy variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentile values. Heteroskedastic-robust

and cluster-adjusted t-statistics appear in brackets. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively, two-tailed.

Panel A. Event Day Returns

Types of Return

Myopic Cutters

N=939

Non-Cutters

N=2,122 Difference

(1)

Mean

(2)

Median

(3)

Mean

(4)

Median

(5)=(1)-(3)

(t-statistics)

(6)=(2)-(4)

(z-statistics)

Raw Return -0.012*** -0.006*** 0.002 -0.000 -0.013*** -0.006***

[-4.023] [-3.280] [0.943] [-0.834] [-3.917] [-6.833]

Market-adjusted Abnormal Return -0.014*** -0.011*** -0.002 -0.004 -0.012*** -0.007***

[-5.104] [-3.892] [-1.011] [-1.102] [-3.787] [-11.271]

Size-adjusted Abnormal Return -0.016*** -0.012*** -0.004** -0.005** -0.012*** -0.007***

[-5.738] [-4.518] [-2.240] [-2.325] [-3.684] [-9.080]

Page 30: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

30

Panel B. Cross-Sectional Variation in Event Day Returns

(1) (2) (3)

Variable Raw Return Market-adjusted Abnormal Return Size-adjusted Abnormal Return

CutRD -0.009** -0.009** -0.008**

[-2.314] [-2.400] [-2.138] ERDSurprise 0.012*** 0.009*** 0.009***

[3.200] [2.645] [2.588]

△RD 0.006** 0.005* 0.004

[2.294] [1.671] [1.420] SIZE 0.005*** 0.005*** 0.005***

[4.806] [5.084] [5.484] BM 0.012*** 0.011** 0.010**

[2.851] [2.430] [2.373] Momentum 0.005 0.005 0.006

[0.889] [1.009] [1.132] Constant -0.050*** -0.054*** -0.053***

[-3.036] [-3.679] [-3.731] Firm Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Observations 3,061 3,061 3,061

Adjusted R2 0.021 0.018 0.015

Page 31: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

31

Table III Summary Statistics for Investor Sophistication Test

This table presents the descriptive statistics of the variables used in investor sophistication test. The sample consists of 2,146 firm-year

observations covering the years from 1972 to 2014. All variables are defined in Appendix 1. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%,

and 1% level, respectively, two-tailed.

Myopic Cutters (N=644) Non-Cutters (N=1,502) Difference

Variable

(1)

Mean

(2)

Median

(3)

Std Dev.

(4)

Mean

(5)

Median

(6)

Std Dev.

(1)-(4)

p-value

(2)-(5)

p-value

Raw Return -0.002 -0.006 0.091 0.009 0.000 0.094 0.024** 0.032**

Market-adjusted Return -0.005 -0.009 0.090 0.006 -0.001 0.089 0.014** 0.025**

Size-adjusted Return -0.007 -0.009 0.089 0.004 -0.002 0.088 0.038** 0.024**

Surprise 0.377 0.110 1.484 -0.316 -0.200 0.823 <0.000*** <0.000***

△RD -0.234 -0.027 0.638 0.163 0.024 0.494 <0.000*** <0.000***

SIZE 5.374 5.045 2.142 5.734 5.502 2.003 <0.000*** <0.000***

BM 0.612 0.486 0.468 0.560 0.478 0.397 0.009*** 0.222

Momemtum 0.026 -0.026 0.374 -0.056 -0.090 0.314 <0.000*** <0.000***

Earnings 0.351 0.100 1.786 0.560 0.360 1.733 <0.011** <0.000***

Lag_Earnings -0.027 0.000 2.444 0.876 0.610 1.981 <0.000*** <0.000***

Distance 0.080 0.071 0.055 0.095 0.091 0.058 <0.000*** <0.000***

Page 32: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

32

Table IV Effects of Investor Sophistication on Market Reaction to Managerial Myopia

This table presents the results of investor sophistication test. The dependent variables are Raw Return, Market-adjusted Abnormal Return and Size-

adjusted Abnormal Return in column (1), (2) and (3), respectively. We divide the full sample into High-IS sub-sample (firms with high investor

sophistication) and Low-IS subsample (firms with low investor sophistication). A firm is identified as being with high (low) investor sophistication

if its Inst_Percent is higher (lower) than the sample median. Inst_Percent is the percentage of ownership by institutional investors. All variables are

defined in Appendix 1. All variables except dummy variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentile values. Heteroskedastic-robust and

cluster-adjusted t-statistics appear in brackets. *, **, *** denote two-tailed statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

(1)

Raw Return

(2)

Market-adjusted Abnormal Return

(2)

Size-adjusted Abnormal Return

High IS Low IS High IS Low IS High IS Low IS

CutRD -0.021*** -0.001 -0.022*** -0.002 -0.018*** 0.001

[-3.166] [-0.151] [-3.438] [-0.342] [-2.748] [0.174]

ERDSurprise 0.011* 0.000 0.009 -0.003 0.010* -0.003

[1.918] [0.031] [1.571] [-0.700] [1.698] [-0.763]

△RD -0.005 -0.001 -0.006 -0.002 -0.006 -0.001

[-0.818] [-0.454] [-0.985] [-0.735] [-1.062] [-0.525]

SIZE 0.001 0.004* 0.002 0.003 0.003 0.002

[0.545] [1.953] [0.888] [1.473] [1.179] [1.211]

BM 0.014* 0.027** 0.014* 0.027** 0.014* 0.022*

[1.730] [2.016] [1.660] [2.253] [1.666] [1.784]

Momentum 0.014 0.004 0.013 0.006 0.013 0.005

[1.327] [0.338] [1.221] [0.604] [1.255] [0.510]

Constant -0.015 -0.020 -0.021 -0.016 -0.028 -0.012

[-0.794] [-0.491] [-1.077] [-0.396] [-1.444] [-0.314]

Firm Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Observations 1,073 1,073 1,073 1,073 1,073 1,073

Adjusted R2 0.002 0.019 0.006 0.015 0.004 0.007

Difference of coefficients

on CutRD

High IS – Low IS

p=0.028**

High IS – Low IS

p=0.025**

High IS – Low IS

p=0.026**

Page 33: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

33

Table V Summary Statistics for CEO Compensation Test This table presents the descriptive statistics of the variables used in CEO compensation test. The sample consists of 324 firm-year observations. △Total pay, △Cash Pay, and △Noncash Pay are the change of CEO’s total pay, cash pay, and noncash pay. Cash pay is the sum of salary and annual bonus. Noncash pay is the

sum of the value of equity grants during the year, fringe benefits, and other long-term incentive plans, with stock options valued at the end of the fiscal year using

Black-Scholes 1973 model adjusted for dividends. Total pay is the sum of cash pay and noncash pay. △ROA is change of ROA. ROA is calculated as net income

divided by total assets. △RD is R&D of a given year minus R&D of the prior fiscal year. RET is annual stock return. SIZE is the logarithm of total assets. Q is

calculated as the book value of assets minus the book value of equity, plus the market value of equity, scaled by the book value of assets at year t. LEV is total

debts divided by total assets. Ownership is the CEO ownership as a percentage of shares outstanding. Tenure is the number of years as CEO of the firm. Eindex is

an index based on six antitakeover provisions: staggered board, poison pills, the supermajority requirement for mergers, limits to the shareholder bylaw

amendments, limits to the charter amendments, and golden parachutes. Board size is the natural log of number of directors on board. Board independence is

percentage of independent directors on board. CEO duality is a dummy variable which equals 1 if CEO and Chairman of the board are the same person, 0

otherwise. *, **, and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively, two-tailed. Myopic Cutters (N=87) Non-Cutters (N=237) Difference

Variable

(1)

Mean

(2)

Median

(3)

Std Dev.

(4)

Mean

(5)

Median

(6)

Std Dev.

(1)-(4)

p-value

(2)-(5)

p-value

△Total Pay 0.223 0.032 0.526 -0.094 -0.056 0.594 <0.000*** <0.000***

△Cash Pay 0.149 0.090 0.382 -0.125 0.000 0.388 <0.000*** <0.000***

△Noncash Pay 0.074 -0.026 0.638 0.031 0.002 0.653 <0.000*** <0.000***

△ROA 0.000 0.003 0.079 -0.041 -0.027 0.060 <0.000*** <0.000***

△RD -0.171 -0.018 0.565 0.068 0.006 0.433 <0.000*** <0.000***

RET 0.144 0.039 0.521 0.102 0.032 0.468 0.342 0.265

SIZE 7.150 6.658 1.701 7.161 7.021 1.520 0.959 0.449

Q 2.079 1.831 0.914 2.248 1.893 1.157 0.263 0.162

LEV 0.176 0.151 0.166 0.170 0.168 0.152 0.772 0.449

Ownership 0.016 0.003 0.047 0.018 0.003 0.043 0.802 0.893

Tenure 8.185 6.000 6.602 8.804 6.000 7.375 0.526 0.745

Eindex 2.569 3.000 1.299 2.442 3.000 1.303 0.466 0.836

Board Size 1.955 2.079 0.367 1.932 1.946 0.371 0.647 0.211

Board Independence 0.725 0.769 0.164 0.705 0.750 0.170 0.382 0.253

CEO Duality 0.554 1.000 0.501 0.659 1.000 0.475 0.102 0.920

Page 34: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

34

Table VI CEO Compensation and Managerial Myopia

This table presents the results of CEO compensation test. The dependent variables are the change

of CEO’s total pay, cash pay, and noncash pay for column (1), column (2) and column (3),

respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix 1. All variables except dummy variables are

winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentile values. Heteroskedastic-robust and cluster-adjusted t-

statistics appear in brackets. *, **, *** denote two-tailed statistical significance at the 10%, 5%,

and 1% levels, respectively.

(1) (2) (3)

Variable △Total Pay △Cash Pay △Noncash Pay

CutRD 0.631** 0.370** 0.261

[2.122] [2.086] [0.728]

△ROAi,t -0.188 -0.135 -0.053

[-0.137] [-0.198] [-0.033]

△RDi,t 0.000 -0.000 0.000

[1.089] [-0.576] [0.985]

RETi,t 0.200 0.062 0.138

[0.729] [0.397] [0.446]

SIZEi,t-1 -0.025 -0.154 0.130

[-0.059] [-0.742] [0.279]

Qi,t-1 0.178 -0.052 0.230

[1.165] [-0.706] [1.286]

LEVi,t-1 0.447 0.261 0.186

[0.351] [0.558] [0.147]

Ownershipi,t-1 -5.990 -8.038 2.048

[-0.643] [-1.318] [0.195]

Tenurei,t -0.022 0.004 -0.026

[-0.883] [0.278] [-1.134]

Eindexi,t-1 -0.129 0.083 -0.211

[-0.882] [0.864] [-1.189]

Board Sizei,t-1 0.122 -0.011 0.133

[0.125] [-0.026] [0.134]

Board Independencei,t-1 0.428 0.284 0.144

[0.226] [0.363] [0.075]

CEO Dualityi,t-1 0.300 -0.032 0.332

[0.686] [-0.162] [0.727]

Constant -0.614 0.750 -1.364

[-0.203] [0.566] [-0.422]

Firm Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Observations 324 324 324

Adjusted R2 0.097 0.331 0.088

Page 35: Do Capital Markets Punish Managerial Myopia?

35

Table VII Future Performance and Managerial Myopia

This table presents results on regressing future stock market and financial performance on myopic

R&D cut and control variables. Future Return is the one-year stock return from the earnings

announcement date. Future ROA is return on assets of next fiscal year end. Future ROE is return on

equity of next fiscal year end. All variables are defined in Appendix 1. All variables except dummy

variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentile values. Heteroskedastic-robust and cluster-

adjusted t-statistics appear in brackets. *, **, *** denote two-tailed statistical significance at the

10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

(1) (2) (3)

Variable Future Return Future ROA Future ROE

CutRD -0.173** -0.054*** -0.159**

[-2.530] [-2.586] [-2.015]

ERDSurprise 0.000 -0.000 0.000

[0.074] [-0.055] [0.225]

△RD -0.001 -0.000* -0.000

[-1.427] [-1.925] [-1.437]

SIZE -0.212*** 0.038** 0.088

[-3.335] [2.309] [1.579]

BM 0.105 -0.001 0.054

[0.747] [-0.043] [0.647]

Momentum -0.015 0.069** 0.205**

[-0.139] [2.286] [2.088]

Constant -0.122 -0.192** -0.557**

[-0.302] [-2.511] [-2.274]

Firm Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Observations 2,896 2,896 2,896

Adjusted R2 0.170 0.609 0.405