delhi seminar

Upload: sumeet-saini

Post on 02-Jun-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    1/26

    Friedman-Ball Hypothesis for Inflation Revisited:

    Evidence from some OECD Countries

    Kushal Banik Chowdhury

    Economic Research Unit

    Indian Statistical Institute, Kolkata

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    2/26

    In his key note address, Friedman (1977) blames bad economic

    policies for large and inefficient fluctuations. He argues that when

    inflation is low, policymakers try to keep it low. To the extent they

    are successful, inflation remains low and stable. However, when it is

    high, policymakers are more likely to adopt disinflationary policies.

    These policies suffer from some serious problems such as the

    problem of choosing the inside lag (i.e., the time gap between a

    shock to the economy and the policy action responding to that

    shock) and outside lag (indicating the time between a policy action

    and its influence on the economy) and as a result, uncertainty about

    future inflation rises, and consequently the economy gets affected

    more.

    FRIEDMANS HYPOTHESIS

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    3/26

    Ball (1992) has formalised Friedmans hypothesis by

    introducing a game theoretic framework between public and

    policy makers about their response to high inflationary situation.

    There exists a positive relationship between inflation and inflation

    uncertainty, i.e., when inflation increases, inflation uncertainty

    also increases.

    This hypothesis has given rise to many empirical studies examining

    the link between inflation and inflation uncertainty.

    Outcome of Friedman-Ball hypothesis

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    4/26

    After the introduction of autoregressive conditional

    heteroskedasticty (ARCH) and generalised ARCH (GARCH)

    model by Engle (1982) and Bollerslev (1986), respectively

    several studies use it as a measure of inflation uncertainty thatunderpin the dynamic nexus between inflation and inflation

    uncertainty.

    ,

    where stands for the rate of inflation and for its

    conditional variance.

    Measure of uncertainty

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    5/26

    With an ARCH process, Engle (1982) found a weak evidence to

    support Friedmans hypothesis. Bollerslev (1986) who has

    generalised the ARCH, called the GARCH process, also found

    that his analysis does not support the Friedman-Ball hypothesis.

    This evidence is also same in Cosimano and Jansen (1988) study.

    Important empirical results

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    6/26

    In their study, Evans and Watchtel (1993) have emphasized on

    the consequences of regime switching behaviour of inflation in

    dealing with inflation uncertainty. They also claimed that the

    resultant model will seriously underestimate both the degree ofuncertainty and its impact if one neglects this regime switching

    feature of inflation. One serious limitation with the (symmetric)

    GARCH model is that it does not incorporate the possibility of

    structural instability due to regime changes.

    Criticism of the above studies

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    7/26

    Further, Brunner and Hess (1993) have pointed out a reason

    behind the failure of finding any support to the above

    hypothesis. According to them, for testing Friedman-Balls

    hypothesis directly, conditional variance should be a function of

    lagged inflation.

    Subsequently, with the advancement of exponential GARCH

    (EGARCH) model of Nelson (1991), threshold GARCH

    (TGARCH) model of Glosten et al. (1993), recent studies have

    used these variants of GARCH model to allow asymmetries in

    the conditional variance.

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    8/26

    Following Brunner and Hess (1993) and Fountas et al. (2000), the

    conditional variance specification of inflation is assumed to explicitly

    include a lag inflation term. With the conditional mean specification being

    an AR(k) model, the model, designated as AR(k)-GARCH(1,1) L(1) for

    describing inflation, consists of the following specifications for the

    conditional mean and conditional variance.

    ,

    where stands for the (rate of) inflation at time t, the conditional

    variance at t and k the optimal lag order in the conditional mean

    specification. Here the coefficient depicts the link between inflation

    uncertainty and inflation.

    Econometr ic models

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    9/26

    AR(k)-TGARCH(1,1) L(1)

    A Threshold GARCH (TGARCH) model where the lag inflation is

    included in the conditional variance equation can be written as

    follows.

    whereI[.] is an indicator function.

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    10/26

    1.

    Now, we raise a question, namely that, if a regime switching

    behaviour or asymmetry is allowed in the conditional variance

    specification, then why should it be only reflected in the

    coefficient of lag squared error term (as in the case of EGARCH

    and TGARCH model), and why not in the other parameters,

    especially the coefficient which captures the link between

    inflation and uncertainty. As argued by Friedman (1977), Ball

    (1992), Ungar and Zilberfarb (1993), Brunner and Hess (1993)

    and Baillie et al. (1996) that for the high inflationary period

    there is a significant positive link between inflation and its

    uncertainty, whereas it does not exist for the low inflationary

    SOME IMPORTANT QUESTIONS

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    11/26

    period. Keeping this in mind, it is quite obvious to attach regime

    specific behaviour to the coefficients which captures the link.

    2.Subsequently, another question arises, how high (low) is a high

    (low) inflation rate? In other words, does a threshold level of

    inflation exist? Thus from the policy perspective, it is quite

    important for the policymakers to know the threshold level of

    inflation rate above which significant increase in uncertainty

    may occur.

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    12/26

    To address these two questions in our framework of analysis we have adoptedasymmetric nonlinear smooth transition ARCH (ANSTARCH) model, as

    proposed by Anderson et al. (1999) and Nam et al. (2002). We have extended it

    to allow for the inclusion of lag inflation as an exogenous regressor in the

    conditional variance equation.

    ,

    PROPOSED MODELS

    AR(k)-ANSTGARCH(1,1)-L(1)

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    13/26

    ,

    Here comprises the coefficients of both

    conditional mean and conditional variance specifications for the th regime

    where stands for , denoting the low and high inflation regimes,

    respectively. Apart from the usual GARCH coefficients, and describe the

    link between inflation uncertainty and inflation in the two regimes, respectively.

    STAR(k)-ANSTGARCH(1,1)-L(1)

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    14/26

    The regimes are governed by the transition function .

    A popular choice for the transition function is the logistic

    function which is defined as

    where is a threshold variable corresponding to a threshold

    value.

    We have used a lag inflation term, , as our thresholdvariable, and accordingly the regimes are defined as the lag

    inflation is greater or smaller than an unknown threshold level

    of inflation. Thus, in the transition equation we replace by

    as a probable candidate for the threshold variable.

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    15/26

    In this empirical study, we have considered monthly time series on

    consumer price index from January 1960 to December 2009 for 13

    different OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and

    Development) countries viz., Canada, France, Germany, I taly, Japan,

    the U.K., the U.S.A., Austr ia, Belgium, F in land, Greece, Luxembourg

    and Spain. All the time series have been downloaded from the official

    website of Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The time series of

    inflation, denoted as , has been obtained as

    where is the seasonally adjusted consumer price index of a particular

    country.

    Empirical analysis

    Data

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    16/26

    Country

    Estimate

    Canada France Germany Italy Japan The U.K. The U.S.A.

    Conditional variance parameters

    0.014* 0.033* 0.015* 0.000*** 0.005 0.005** 0.001

    0.191* 0.172* 0.458* 0.150* 0.104** 0.405* 0.102*

    0.665* 0.000 0.324* 0.848* 0.867* 0.647* 0.897*

    0.016 -0.001 0.026*** 0.000 -0.004 0.002 0.001

    Autocorrelation in standardized residuals

    Q(1) 0.781 0.137 0.040 0.486 0.013 1.124 0.047

    Q(10) 1.836 3.355 1.071 1.894 1.607 8.732 4.119

    Autocorrelation in squared standardized residualsQ (1) 0.060 1.425 0.379 1.802 0.323 0.013 3.450

    Q2(5) 1.206 2.173 2.442 2.159 2.303 3.037 6.333

    Q2(10) 3.228 2.780 4.797 7.203 3.020 5.021 9.879

    [*, ** and *** indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels of significance, respectively.]

    Parameter estimate and results of residual diagnostic tests for the AR(k)-

    GARCH(1,1)L(1) model

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    17/26

    Country

    Austria Belgium Finland Greece Luxembourg Spain

    Conditional variance parameters

    0.004* 0.007* 0.008* 0.002 0.005* 0.018*

    0.197* 0.045 0.224* 0.089** 0.151* 0.764*

    0.766* 0.845* 0.750* 0.910* 0.807* 0.381*

    0.005 0.021* 0.012 0.003 0.002 0.044*

    Autocorrelation in standardized residuals

    Q(1) 2.012 0.057 0.000 0.005 0.010 0.097

    Q(5) 2.692 1.594 1.840 0.640 0.812 3.418

    Q(10) 6.044 2.698 3.324 1.587 2.139 4.992

    Autocorrelation in squared standardized residuals

    Q2(1) 6.285** 0.179 0.719 3.360 1.990 0.019

    Q (5) 8.618 1.922 3.294 4.355 6.904 1.879

    Q2(10) 12.252 11.187 15.601 7.679 11.841** 3.279

    [*, ** and *** indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels of significance, respectively.]

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    18/26

    The finding of no such significant relationship between inflation uncertainty and

    inflation for the remaining ten countries may be due to the consideration of

    single regime in the modelling of inflation and inflation uncertainty which may

    mask potentially different realizations due to the regime shift of inflation,

    especially because the span of the data set is quite large.

    Comment

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    19/26

    We first test for our assumption of nonlinearity based on own

    transition effect as captured by . To that end, we use Lagrange

    multiplier (LM) test statistic as developed by Luukkonen et al. (1988),

    to test linearity against nonlinearity as represented by STAR model.

    Test for nonlinearity (AR Vs STAR)

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    20/26

    LM test statistic values

    Country Test statistic value

    Canada 48.27***

    France 84.82*

    Germany 50.11**

    Italy 133.23*

    Japan 91.66*

    The U.K. 70.28*

    The U.S.A. 90.03*

    Austria 227.67*

    Belgium 62.34*

    Finland 28.04***

    Greece 97.86*

    Luxembourg 69.60***

    Spain 147.83*

    [*, ** and *** indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels of significance, respectively.]

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    21/26

    Country

    Estimate

    Canada France Germany Italy Japan The U.K. The U.S.A.

    Conditional variance parameters in the first regime

    0.037** 0.027* 0.011* 0.000 0.010 0.002 0.000

    0.559* 0.778* 0.636* 0.000 0.063 0.545* 0.050***

    0.221 0.000 0.380* 0.973* 0.459* 0.677* 0.914*

    0.047 0.070* 0.020 -0.002 -0.185** -0.005 -0.012**

    Conditional variance parameters in the second regime

    0.005 0.034 0.000 0.005 0.000 0.000 0.022**

    0.000 0.303** 0.000 0.491* 0.142 0.000 0.000

    0.657* 0.000 0.000 0.215 1.035* 0.873* 1.145*

    0.099** -0.082 0.211* 0.029 -0.010 0.048*** -0.046

    Smooth transition parameters

    3.3410 16.38 6.5310 3.84 29.75 62.13 8.99

    0.015 0.216* 0.185** 0.533* 0.056** 0.077* 0.273*

    [*, ** and *** indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels of significance, respectively.]

    Parameter estimate and results of residual diagnostic tests for the STAR(k)-

    GARCH(1,1)L(1) model

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    22/26

    Country Austria Belgium Finland Greece Luxembourg Spain

    Conditional variance parameters in the first regime

    0.010* 0.036* 0.010 0.000 0.028* 0.011*

    0.630* 0.584* 0.283** 0.046 0.122 0.841*

    0.472* 0.000 0.786* 0.898* 0.035 0.409*

    0.030 0.067** 0.030 -0.064*** -0.231* 0.025**

    Conditional variance parameters in the second regime

    0.000 0.087* 0.000 0.005 0.056* 0.000

    0.245* 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.059

    0.561** 0.000 0.654* 0.884* 0.000 0.000

    0.027 0.007 0.149* 0.115** 0.115** 0.311*

    Smooth transition parameters

    8.77105 2.2410

    17 1.0710

    6 3.34 5.8710

    18 29.61

    0.255* 0.098 0.012*** 0.000 0.057*** 0.541*

    [*, ** and *** indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels of significance, respectively.]

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    23/26

    Lastly, we make a statistical comparison between AR(k)-GARCH(1,1)-L(1)

    model which may be taken as a benchmark model and the proposed STAR( k)-ANSTGARCH(1,1)L(1) model by means of likelihood ratio (LR) test.

    Country Model I

    versusModel II

    Canada 31.32**France 63.62*Germany 45.4*

    Italy 38.9*Japan 20.52

    The U.K. 56.58*

    The U.S.A. 48.98*Austria 51.14*Belgium 25.56Finland 15.24

    Greece 24.98Luxembourg 24.36***

    Spain 85.54*[Model I: AR(k)-GARCH(1,1)L(1) and Model II: STAR(k)-ANSTGARCH(1,1)L(1). *, ** and *** indicate

    significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels of significance, respectively.]

    Likelihood Ratio test (AR(k)-GARCH(1,1)-L(1) Vs STAR(k)-

    ANSTGARCH(1,1)L(1)STAR))

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    24/26

    The paper has revisited this hypothesis by proposing a new

    model, called STAR(k)-ANSTGARCH(1,1)L(1) where the

    conditional mean as well as the conditional variance for

    inflation are based on consideration of two regimes for inflation

    below and above a certain level of inflation- and which is

    determined endogenously.

    There exists a threshold level of inflation in case of 10 out of 13

    countries considered. This means that the control of inflation

    would crucially depend on this threshold level of inflation which

    is estimated endogenously.

    Concluding Remarks

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    25/26

    The parameter capturing the effect of inflation on inflation

    uncertainty in the specification of conditional variance clearly

    shows that this coefficient is different in the two inflation

    regimes. It is observed from the results that the Friedman-Ball

    hypothesis holds for six countries viz., Canada, Germany, the

    U.K., Finland, Greece and Luxembourg in the high-inflation

    regime, two countries (France and Belgium) in the low-inflation

    regime and one country (Spain) in both the regimes.

    The improvement in terms of maximized log likelihood value is

    significant for the proposed model as compared to the

    benchmark AR(k)-GARCH(1,1)L(1) model for 9 out of 13

    countries.

  • 8/11/2019 Delhi Seminar

    26/26

    THANK YOU