confirmation bias

47
Confirmation Bias

Upload: halona

Post on 25-Feb-2016

47 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Confirmation Bias. Critical Thinking. Among our critical thinking questions were: Does the evidence really support the claim? Is there other evidence that I should consider?. Sufficient Conditions. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Confirmation Bias

Confirmation Bias

Page 2: Confirmation Bias

Critical Thinking

Among our critical thinking questions were:

Does the evidence really support the claim?

Is there other evidence that I should consider?

Page 3: Confirmation Bias

Sufficient Conditions

Consider the following claim: “you can get to CUHK from Lingnan using public transportation.”The claim is true if the MTR goes from Lingnan to CUHK.The claim is also true if there is a bus from Lingnan to CUHK.In fact, the claim is true if there is any way to get from Lingnan to CUHK.

Page 4: Confirmation Bias

Sufficient Conditions

A claim X is a sufficient condition for the claim “you can get to CUHK from Lingnan” when if X is true, “you can get to CUHK from Lingnan” is true. It’s true that if “the MTR goes from Lingnan to CUHK” is true, then “you can get to CUHK from Lingnan” is true. Therefore, “the MTR goes from Lingnan to CUHK” is a sufficient condition for “you can get to CUHK from Lingnan.”

Page 5: Confirmation Bias

Sufficient Conditions

A helpful way of thinking about this:

Whenever “If A then B” is true:

A is a sufficient condition for B.

Page 6: Confirmation Bias

Examples

“If today is Thursday, then we have class” is true.So, today’s being Thursday is a sufficient condition for our having class.“If you are convicted of murder, you will go to jail” is true.So, being convicted of murder is a sufficient condition for going to jail.

Page 7: Confirmation Bias

Examples

But the following are not true:

“If we have class today, then today is Thursday.”(we also have class on Monday)

“If you go to jail, then you were convicted of murder”(Some people in jail were convicted of other crimes)

Page 8: Confirmation Bias

Necessary Conditions

Suppose that “if A, then B” is true. We know that this means that A is a sufficient condition for B.

It also means that B is a necessary condition for A.

Page 9: Confirmation Bias

Requirements for Office

Consider the requirements for Chief Executive in Hong Kong:• Must be at least 40 years old.• Must be a Hong Kong permanent resident.• Must not have right of abode in a foreign

country.• Must have resided in Hong Kong for 20

consecutive years.

Page 10: Confirmation Bias

Necessary Conditions

Requirements for office are things that are necessary for office– things that must be true for you to hold office.So we know that if someone is the Chief Executive, then that person is at least 40 years old.In other words, being at least 40 (being a permanent resident, etc.) is a necessary condition for being Chief executive

Page 11: Confirmation Bias

“I know horoscopes can predict the future, because I’ve seen it happen.”

“Positive thinking can cure cancer, because I know someone who used it, and got better.”

“Everyone knows you do worse in your second year in college, you see it all the time.”

Page 12: Confirmation Bias

Necessary and Sufficient Evidence

If claims like these are true, for example, if it’s true that horoscopes predict the future, then the evidence in question is necessary.

If horoscopes predict the future, then there must be cases where a horoscope predicted something, and then it happened.

Page 13: Confirmation Bias

Necessary and Sufficient Evidence

But such evidence is not sufficient for establishing the truth of these claims.

When a horoscope predicts that X will happen, and then X happens, that doesn’t prove anything. Were there times horoscopes predicted things that didn’t happen? Were there things that horoscopes should have predicted, but never happened?

Page 14: Confirmation Bias

Contingency Tables

Page 15: Confirmation Bias

Contingency Tables

A contingency table is used to plot predictions of the form “If A happens, then B will happen.”

In the upper left corner of the table (Prediction = Yes, Observation = Yes) are cases where A happens and B happens. These are “true positives” and they confirm the prediction.

Page 16: Confirmation Bias

Contingency Tables

A contingency table is used to plot predictions of the form “If A happens, then B will happen.”

In the lower right corner (Prediction = No, Observation = No) are cases where A does not happen, and B does not happen. These are “true negatives” and also confirm the claim in question.

Page 17: Confirmation Bias

Contingency Tables

A contingency table is used to plot predictions of the form “If A happens, then B will happen.”

Two sorts of cases disconfirm the prediction. First there are false positives in the upper right corner, where the predicted outcome (Prediction = Yes) does not match the observed outcome (Observation = No).

Page 18: Confirmation Bias

Contingency Tables

A contingency table is used to plot predictions of the form “If A happens, then B will happen.”

Second, there are “false negative” cases. These are also outcomes where the prediction (Prediction = No) fails to match the observation (Observation = Yes).

Page 19: Confirmation Bias

Perfect Correlation Claims

For “absolute” claims (If A happens, B will always happen, A and B are perfectly positively correlated), all cases must fall in the upper left or lower right corners.

The prediction must always match the outcome.

Page 20: Confirmation Bias

Imperfect Correlation Claims

For probabilistic claims (A and B are imperfectly positively correlated), you must compare the proportion of true positives to predicted positives to the proportion of false positives to predicted negatives.

(How you should compare them depends on the base rates…)

Page 21: Confirmation Bias

For example…

Suppose I claim that students are more likely to get an A on the final if they take notes in class than if they don’t take notes.

I point out 5 students who took notes and got an A, and 18 students who didn’t take notes and didn’t get an A as evidence for this claim. But whether the claim is true depends on more than just these true positives and true negatives…

Page 22: Confirmation Bias

I’m RightGet an A Don’t get an

ATotals

Take notes 5 10 15

Don’t take notes

2 18 20

Totals 7 28 35

Page 23: Confirmation Bias

I’m Right

Here, it looks like taking notes matters. 5 out of 15 note-takers get A’s (33%) and only 2 out of 20 students who don’t take notes get A’s (10%).

However, with the same number of true positives, I could also be very wrong. Let’s add 10 students to the “false positive” and “false negative” squares…

Page 24: Confirmation Bias

I’m WrongGet an A Don’t get an

ATotals

Take notes 5 20 25

Don’t take notes

12 18 30

Totals 17 38 55

Page 25: Confirmation Bias

I’m Wrong

Even though the number of true positives and true negatives stayed the same, we now see that a measly 5 out of 25 note-takers got A’s (down to 20% from 33%), but a full 12 out of 30 students who didn’t take notes (40% up from 10%) got A’s. Students who didn’t take notes are more likely to get A’s, in this scenario.

Page 26: Confirmation Bias

Main Idea

The basic point is that you cannot use examples that agree with a claim to show that that claim is true.

You must also look at examples that disagree with the claim. If there are enough of these, then the claim might be false, even if there are lots of examples that support it.

Page 27: Confirmation Bias

CONFIRMATION BIAS

Page 28: Confirmation Bias

Confirmation Bias

Even though evaluating predictions requires looking at both the rates of true positives among predicted positives, and the rates of false positives among predicted negatives, human beings have a tendency to only consider true positives (and to a lesser extent, true negatives) when evaluating predictions or other claims of imperfect correlation.

Page 29: Confirmation Bias

Wason Selection Task

Page 30: Confirmation Bias

Around ½ of people studied say “D” and “5”.

About 1/3 say just “D”.

Only about 1/20 get the right answer: “D” and “2”!

Page 31: Confirmation Bias

Searching for Confirmation

People have a preference for positive answers that confirm their theories, even though negative answers that disconfirm their theories might give the same amount of information.

Page 32: Confirmation Bias

For example, suppose A picks a number between one and ten, and you’re supposed to guess what it is. I suggest that the number is 3.

The psychological research shows that you’d be more likely to ask “is the number odd?” than “is the number even?”– even though both answers are equally informative.

Page 33: Confirmation Bias

In this case, the preference for confirmation does not matter:

Asking the positive question and the negative question give you the same information. If people prefer the positive question, that doesn’t harm them at all. But the preference can harm them if the positive question gives less info.

Page 34: Confirmation Bias

A Strange Example

Americans were asked:

Which of these pairs of countries are more similar to one another?

1. West Germany, East Germany2. Sri Lanka, Nepal

Page 35: Confirmation Bias

They said (1), West Germany and East Germany. Others (Americans) were also asked:

Which of these pairs of countries are more different from one another?

1. West Germany, East Germany2. Sri Lanka, Nepal

Page 36: Confirmation Bias

They also said (1).

Americans thought that West Germany and East Germany were both more similar to each other than Sri Lanka and Nepal and less similar to each other than Sri Lanka and Nepal.

How is that possible?

Page 37: Confirmation Bias

First, when considering the question ‘which are more similar?’ the subjects looked for all the positive evidence that West Germany and East Germany were similar, and all the positive evidence that Sri Lanka and Nepal were similar.

Since Americans know nothing about Asian countries, they had no positive reason to think Sri Lanka and Nepal were similar.

Page 38: Confirmation Bias

Similarly, when asked ‘which are more different?’ the subjects considered the positive evidence that West Germany and East Germany were different and the positive evidence that Sri Lanka and Nepal were different.

Again, having no knowledge of Sri Lanka or Nepal, Americans chose (1), because of all the positive evidence in its favor.

Page 39: Confirmation Bias

But it cannot be true that East Germany and West Germany are both more similar and more different than Sri Lanka and Nepal.

What the subjects did not do is consider the relevant negative evidence that would disconfirm their hypotheses.

Page 40: Confirmation Bias

The Problem of Absent Data

Sometimes it’s not just that we only look for or evaluate the positive evidence, but that there is no negative evidence. This can lead us to think we have very well-confirmed beliefs when we do not.

Page 41: Confirmation Bias

Hiring Job Applicants

Suppose you’re hiring job applicants for your shoe company. You think people who haven’t studied a musical instrument would not be good employees.

Who do you hire? The people who have studied music, of course! And if they’re successful at your company, do you have good reason to believe that you were right?

Page 42: Confirmation Bias

No! You have positive evidence– people you predicted would be successful, who are successful– but you have no negative evidence.

What about all the people you didn’t hire, the ones who didn’t study music? They might have been successful too. They could’ve been more successful. You don’t know.

Page 43: Confirmation Bias

Absent evidence is all around us.

Suppose you decide to major in accounting instead of philosophy. You find that you are very happy studying accounting. Did you make the right choice? You can’t know. You could have been more happy studying philosophy. There’s just no evidence.

Page 44: Confirmation Bias

Self-Fulfilling Prophecies

Page 45: Confirmation Bias

The Prisoner’s Dilemma

There are two general strategies to playing the prisoner’s dilemma. You can view the game as one where the goal is for everyone to do well, and thus play “cooperatively” or you can view the game as one where the goal is for you to do better than your opponent, and thus play “competitively”.

Page 46: Confirmation Bias

The Prisoner’s Dilemma

Believing that the goal is selfish, to win more for yourself, is a self-fulfilling prophecy.

If you play against other selfish players, they will of course play competitively.

But even if you play against cooperators, they will have to play competitively, or get 0 every round. So it will seem as if there are no cooperators.

Page 47: Confirmation Bias

Another Example

Suppose you think I’m not a very nice person, so you avoid me.

If you avoid me, then you’ll never have a chance to correct your initial impression.

So if I’m a nice person, you’ll never find out if you start out thinking I’m not.