competitive advantage in international context william barnett daniel byrd stanford university...

13
Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Upload: rolf-nichols

Post on 17-Jan-2016

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Competitive Advantage in International Context

William Barnett

Daniel Byrd

Stanford University

Graduate School of Business

Page 2: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Barnett and Byrd, Stanford GSB

Comparative Advantage

Gains from trade are due to relative efficiency of different countries in producing different goods, not to absolute differences in efficiency. A country will export (import) a good to the

extent that its production of that good is efficient (inefficient) relative to the production of other goods within that country.

Page 3: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Barnett and Byrd, Stanford GSB

Comparative Advantage

1 unitin shoes

Nu/asu

Nu/amu

Nv/amv

Nv/asv

US VietnamShoes Shoes

Gain in microprocessor production from shifting 1 unit of shoe production

A

A*

P= pm/ps

BB*

T

T*

P

Page 4: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Barnett and Byrd, Stanford GSB

Gains from Trade

•Without trade, consume somewhere in shaded area

•With trade, consume somewhere on dotted line

Shoes Shoes VietnamU.S.

Chips Chips

Page 5: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Barnett and Byrd, Stanford GSB

Gains from Trade

Trade expands national income

Trade allows the country to consume outside the range of what it can produce for itself.

- (by producing what it has a comparative advantage in, and trading for other goods)

This is the fundamental argument for trade.

Page 6: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Barnett and Byrd, Stanford GSB

Distributional Effects of Trade

Overall gains do not mean gains for all. An increase in trade helps some (those in the

exporting and non-tradable sectors) and harms others (those in the import-competing sectors).

Hence political tensions: e.g. more trade with China helps US computer

industry, hurts US steel industry.

Page 7: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Barnett and Byrd, Stanford GSB

Labor as Source of Comparative Advantage

At the national level, there is roughly a constant wage/productivity ratio:

Page 8: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

The fruits of growthWages and productivity, 1991, South Korea=100, log scales

Wages** 500

Japan

Britain United States

Singapore

100 South Korea

Turkey

50Hungary

Philippines

EgyptIndia

10

55 10 50 100 500

Productivity*

*Labour costs per worker per year in manufacturing **Value added per worker per year in manufacturing

Source: Dani Rodrik; reprinted in The Economist, Sept 20, 1997, p.38

Page 9: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Barnett and Byrd, Stanford GSB

Low-Cost Labor as a Source of Comparative Advantage

Low home-country labor costs, especially in labor-intensive industries, can be an initial basis for international competitive advantage. "Low" here means relative to costs

elsewhere --- theory of comparative advantage.

Page 10: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Barnett and Byrd, Stanford GSB

Low-Cost Labor as Source of Comparative Advantage

However, low-cost labor will rarely be a basis for sustainable advantage

Success (at least on a sufficient scale) will drive up wages. Example: When Nike opened factories in Japan,

wages were $4/day.

Strategy and management are central in leveraging advantages and in overcoming the liabilities of the home environment.

Page 11: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Barnett and Byrd, Stanford GSB

Low Cost Labor as Advantage in New Economy

If high-skilled labor becomes more important, then need a well-developed education infrastructure

telecommunication infrastructure

legal/financial infrastructure

Page 12: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Barnett and Byrd, Stanford GSB

Comparative vs. Competitive Advantage

Distinguish comparative advantage (nations) from competitive advantage (firms).

A nation must, by definition, have a comparative advantage in producing something-(It can’t go out of business, though it may be poor; exchange-rate movements equilibrate).

A firm need not (by definition) have a competitive advantage in anything.

Page 13: Competitive Advantage in International Context William Barnett Daniel Byrd Stanford University Graduate School of Business

Barnett and Byrd, Stanford GSB

Your Challenge in Global Management

In contrast to the comparative advantages of nations, which exist by definition, firms need not (by definition) have a competitive advantage in anything!

This is especially a concern in situations where comparative advantages shift over time. Sustained competitive advantage then requires that a firm develop capabilities and position that are not dependent on their home countries’ initial comparative advantages.