coercive vs. cooperative enforcement: the effect of ... effect of enforcement approach on...

45
Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two different approaches to the enforcement of environmental law: the coercive approach, which emphasizes the deterrence of non- compliance through imposed sanctions, and the cooperative approach, which emphasizes the inducement of compliance through more flexibility and assistance. For all the debate, relatively little empirical research directly compares the two approaches. This study empirically analyzes the effects of these two approaches on the extent of compliance with wastewater discharge limits imposed on U.S. chemical manufacturing facilities. For this analysis, we discern between cooperation versus coercion using a subjective measure of the degree of “fair treatment” offered by the environmental regulator to regulated facilities, as reported by facilities in response to an original survey. The empirical results robustly reveal that a more coercive enforcement approach leads to better environmental performance, i.e., greater compliance. Keywords: environmental performance, compliance, enforcement approach, wastewater 1

Upload: nguyenliem

Post on 06-Apr-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement:

The Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance

Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two different approaches to the

enforcement of environmental law: the coercive approach, which emphasizes the deterrence of non-

compliance through imposed sanctions, and the cooperative approach, which emphasizes the

inducement of compliance through more flexibility and assistance. For all the debate, relatively little

empirical research directly compares the two approaches. This study empirically analyzes the effects

of these two approaches on the extent of compliance with wastewater discharge limits imposed on

U.S. chemical manufacturing facilities. For this analysis, we discern between cooperation versus

coercion using a subjective measure of the degree of “fair treatment” offered by the environmental

regulator to regulated facilities, as reported by facilities in response to an original survey. The

empirical results robustly reveal that a more coercive enforcement approach leads to better

environmental performance, i.e., greater compliance.

Keywords: environmental performance, compliance, enforcement approach, wastewater

1

Page 2: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

1. Introduction

For years, scholars and environmental policymakers have conducted a spirited debate about

the best means of ensuring compliance with environmental laws through enforcement. This debate

over enforcement is greatly warranted since compliance assurance represents one of the most

contentious issues in the post-2000 EPA policy agenda (Glicksman and Earnhart, 2007). The debate

focuses on the comparative merits of two different approaches to enforcement of the nation’s

environmental laws – the coercive (or deterrence-based) approach and the cooperative approach.

In general, when employing a coercive approach, a government regulator deters facilities from non-

compliance by imposing enforcement sanctions. In contrast, generally when employing a

cooperative approach, a government regulator provides more flexibility to regulated facilities,

inducing them to address non-compliance pro-actively.

Supporters of the coercive model regard the deterrence of violations as the fundamental

purpose of environmental enforcement (Markell, 2000; Markell, 2005; Mintz, 1995). These

supporters also regard the imposition of enforcement sanctions, which make it more costly for

regulated entities to avoid complying with their regulatory responsibilities, as the most effective way

for inducing regulated entities to comply with their regulatory obligations. Supporters of the

cooperative approach to environmental enforcement focus more on compliance than deterrence

(Stoughton et al., 2001; Andreen, 2006). The cooperative approach operates on the premise that

regulated entities react to a variety of motives that supply sufficient incentives to comply with

regulatory obligations even without an overly punitive approach to enforcement. They contend that

a coercive approach to enforcement may even be counterproductive if it engenders intransigence and

ill will on the part of regulated entities.

Since the initial implementation of environmental protection laws in the United States,

2

Page 3: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

environmental enforcement has shifted away from exclusive reliance on traditional, deterrence-based

enforcement and towards a more partnership-based, less adversarial approach that uses multiple tools

for inducing compliance (Stoughton et al., 2001). In particular, during the 1990s, EPA improved

cooperation between the agency and regulated entities by adopting enforcement policies that were

designed to provide a more flexible approach to inducing compliance with regulatory obligations by

offering “compliance incentives” and “compliance assistance” to regulated facilities (Andreen,

2006). This shift most likely was prompted by a “broad agreement at the federal and state levels that

the traditional, exclusive reliance on penalty-based enforcement approaches to compliance assurance

is inadequate” (Stoughton et al., 2001). Accordingly to Stahl (1995), the EPA concluded that a

penalty-based approach is reactive rather than proactive and is incomplete because it fails to reward

voluntary compliance. Similarly, many states to some extent have replaced traditional enforcement

with some form of cooperation (Andreen, 2006). However, this shift and replacement has been

incomplete, leaving variation between (1) more coercive enforcement approaches in some EPA

regions and states and (2) more cooperative enforcement approaches in other regions and states.

For all the debate about enforcement approaches, relatively little empirical research directly

compares the coercive and cooperative enforcement approaches. Specifically, few studies

empirically test these competing theories about how better to induce environmental compliance.

This study attempts to address this paucity of evidence by empirically examining the effects

of the two enforcement approaches on the environmental performance generated by chemical

manufacturing facilities that are regulated under the National Pollutant Discharge Elimination

System Permit (NPDES) program, which represents the EPA’s implementation of the Clean Water

Act (CWA) as it relates to point sources of wastewater pollutant discharges. Specifically, we

examine the extent of compliance with wastewater discharge limits as measured by the ratio of actual

3

Page 4: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

discharges to permitted discharges, i.e., discharge ratio (Earnhart, 2004a,b; Earnhart, 2009; Earnhart

and Segerson, 2012; Shimshack and Ward, 2005). By examining the extent of compliance, our study

is able to examine both improvement toward compliance and improvement beyond compliance, as

well as degradation away from compliance. This ability is very important for two reasons.

Cooperation may generate so much goodwill that regulated facilities feel compelled to overcomply.

Conversely, coercion may generate so much ill will that regulated facilities choose to increase their1

extent of non-compliance, i.e., undercompliance. Exploration of both aspects represents a strong2

contribution to the thin empirical literature.

For our empirical examination, we conducted an original survey of all chemical

manufacturing facilities that were regulated under the federal Clean Water Act (CWA) between 1999

and 2001. One survey question seeks to capture the type of enforcement approach by instructing the

surveyed facilities to describe the treatment that they had received from their wastewater regulators

as “always fair”, “sometimes fair and sometimes unfair”, or “always unfair”. We use the degree of

fairness to discern between cooperation and coercion: “always fair” versus “less than always fair”.

Our empirical analysis exploits this survey question in order to estimate the link from

enforcement approach to the extent of compliance. Our base empirical results indicate that a more

coercive approach in general appears to induce better environmental performance, i.e., greater

compliance with wastewater discharge limits. These results are robust to the type of wastewater

pollutant examined, regardless of the regressor set used to establish the functional relationship

involving environmental performance. These empirical results imply that environmental regulators

In contrast, coercion is not generally expected to induce overcompliance since facilities do not1

lower the likelihood or severity of a sanction by pushing pollution levels below imposed limits. However,in a context of uncertain pollution outcomes, regulated facilities may choose to overcomply in order to reducethe likelihood of facing a sanction even under a coercive enforcement regime.

Of course, cooperation may also lead to undercompliance.2

4

Page 5: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

seeking to induce better compliance should employ a more coercive approach in general. Based on

our particular measure of coercion versus cooperation, our results imply that environmental

regulators should not be overly fair otherwise the regulators may lose their leverage with regulated

facilities. However, based on our extended empirical results, the influence of the enforcement

approach depends on the presence of local community pressure. Specifically, the effectiveness of

coercion grows as local community pressure builds, implying that coercion and local community

pressure are complements. By construction, these same results imply that cooperation and local

community pressure are substitutes. As important, our extended results reveal that coercion

dominates cooperation only when local community pressure is sufficiently meaningful. When local

community pressure is weak, cooperation dominates coercion. Thus, the policy implications are

stark. Before selecting an enforcement approach, environmental regulators should assess the

strength of local community pressure.

Our empirical research may contribute more generally given the broad regulatory interest in

the contrast between coercion and cooperation. Beyond the real of environmental protection,

scholarly and policymaking communities are interested in the topic of enforcement approach in the

realms of finance, tax compliance, occupational safety, food and drug safety, and consumer product

safety (Ayers and Braithwaite, 1992).

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 summarizes the previous literature

on the theoretical frameworks underlying the coercive and cooperative enforcement approaches and

the few empirical studies that directly compare the two approaches in the environmental realm.

Section 3 describes regulatory efforts to control water pollutant discharges. Section 4 constructs the

analytical framework by describing the functional relationship between environmental performance

and the enforcement approach to be estimated. Section 5 describes the data. Section 6 describes the

5

Page 6: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

statistical analysis, while Section 7 presents the estimation results. Section 8 briefly discusses the

policy and research implications.

2. Literature Review

This section reviews the previous literature on the theoretical frameworks underlying the

coercive and cooperative enforcement approaches and the few empirical studies that directly

compare the two approaches in the environmental realm.

2.1. Coercive and Cooperative Approaches to Enforcement: Theory

A review of the legal, political science, and economics literature on environmental

enforcement reveals a debate about the comparative efficacy of two different models of

environmental enforcement: the coercive/deterrence model and the cooperative model.

2.1.1. Coercive Approach to Environmental Enforcement and Compliance: Theory

The coercive/deterrence model is premised on the idea that regulated entities are rational

economic actors whose principal motivations revolve around the maximization of expected profits

or more generally maximization of expected benefits net of costs (Malloy, 2003; Spence, 2001). The

coercive/deterrence model postulates that decisions regarding compliance are based on self-interest;

businesses comply when the costs of noncompliance outweigh the benefits of noncompliance

(Vandenburgh, 2003). The benefits of noncompliance with environmental regulations consist of

money saved by not purchasing, installing, and operating pollution control equipment; organizing

and training workers; and other environmental management activities. The costs of noncompliance

include any additional costs of coming into compliance once a violation is detected as compared to

coming into compliance earlier, plus any penalties imposed for being found in violation, discounted

by the probability that the violations will be detected. These costs can also include damage to the

business’s reputation, potential tort liability, and legal system expenses (Karpoff et al., 2005;

6

Page 7: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

Vandenburgh, 2005; Rechtschaffen and Markell, 2003).

The coercive/deterrence model proceeds on the premise that regulated entities comply with

their legal obligations only when they are convinced that the government might detect and penalize

noncompliance great enough that it becomes economically irrational for regulated entities to violate

the law (Becker, 1968); Cohen, 2000). Thus, a facility’s compliance status depends on the likelihood

that violations will be detected by those entitled to enforce regulatory obligations and the severity

of the sanctions that noncompliance may trigger (Kagan et al., 2003). Consequently, the essential

task for enforcement agencies is to make penalties high enough and the probability of detection,

along with the likelihood that the government brings enforcement action upon detection, great

enough to deter noncompliance (Cohen, 2000).

In sum, the coercive/deterrence model emphasizes the importance of policing and deterring

violations as the essential core of environmental agencies’ activities. Consistent with this emphasis,

the EPA traditionally has attempted to identify violators and then pursue the identified violators

through formal enforcement actions that seek to impose sanctions that exceed the economic benefit

the violators gained from non-compliance (Markell, 2005).

2.1.2. Cooperative Approach to Environmental Enforcement and Compliance: Theory

The cooperative model is premised on the assumption that corporations are not merely

economic actors solely interested in maximizing expected profits. Instead, corporations represent

institutions that are influenced by a mix of civic and societal motives. This model postulates that

corporations are generally inclined to comply with the law (Rechtschaffen and Markell, 2003).

Correspondingly, the cooperative model emphasizes compliance rather than the deterrence of

noncompliance.

This emphasis alters the use of both inspections and enforcement actions. Within the

7

Page 8: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

cooperative model, an inspection serves a special purpose: it helps to resolve problems by providing

advice to regulated entities as a means of facilitating compliance (Rechtschaffen and Markell, 2003).

In contrast, within the coercive model, an inspection is primarily conducted in an effort to detect

violations and collect evidence for subsequent enforcement actions. Under both the coercive and

cooperative models, facility inspections serve as threats of future enforcement action.

Similar to the use of inspections, the cooperative model’s emphasis on compliance also alters

the use of enforcement actions. Under the cooperative model, regulated facilities may be afforded

more opportunities to avoid sanctions by resolving noncompliance before a penalty is assessed or

other enforcement action pursued than under the coercive model. A cooperative regulator might even

withdraw a pending sanction for past noncompliance once compliance has been achieved. Such a

regulator may choose to refrain from sanctioning a facility that has violated its environmental permit

due to the presence of a cooperative history between the regulator and the facility. As a result, the

cooperative approach “emphasizes flexible or selective enforcement that takes into consideration the

particular circumstances of an observed violation” (Scholz, 1984). Indeed, imposing penalties is

viewed as a sign of the cooperative system’s failure to obtain compliance (Rechtschaffen, 1998).

As important extension of this logic, if businesses are generally committed to compliance

with their regulatory obligations even without a coercive enforcement presence, the imposition of

sanctions in the event that noncompliance occurs is not only unnecessary, but may even be

counterproductive. A sanction-oriented response to noncompliance may make regulated entities

resentful and less likely to cooperate with regulators in the future (Burby and Patterson, 1993; Kagan

et al., 2003). In many environmental contexts, random variations in facility operations or unexpected

events may occasionally push a facility into noncompliance. A coercive response to these

noncompliance events may breed especially strong resentment or ill will.

8

Page 9: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

In essence, the cooperative model tends to treat regulated entities as “partners.” These

“partnerships” should involve the use of flexible guidelines rather than uniform rules, an emphasis

on ex ante prevention of violations rather than ex post sanctions for noncompliance, and compliance

assistance from regulators (Burby, 1995). In the end, regulated entities afforded status as a partner

should tend to respond more positively to suggestions offered by regulators on how to achieve

compliance than those regulated entities facing coercion (Rechtschaffen and Markell, 2003).

2.2. Coercive v. Cooperative Enforcement: Empirical Studies

In contrast to the vast theoretical literature on the enforcement approach, relatively few

empirical studies analyze the use of cooperative enforcement strategies. Harrison (1995) states that

“past studies that have hailed the merits of cooperative enforcement have offered surprisingly little

by way of empirical support.” There seems to be even less research that directly compares coercive

and cooperative strategies. According to Rechtschaffen (1998), “[t]he argument that cooperation

works better than deterrence to achieve compliance with environmental law ... is largely untested”.

Consistent with this assessment, only four empirical studies directly analyze the efficacy of

overall enforcement strategies. First, Harrison (1995) analyzes the use of the cooperative approach

in regulation of water pollution in Canada. Her research relies on the fact that rates of compliance

with water pollution controls are significantly lower in the pulp and paper industry in Canada, where

the cooperative approach to enforcement is generally followed, than in the United States. She finds

that the cooperative Canadian approach to enforcement has delivered disappointing results compared

to the more adversarial U.S. approach.

Second, Burby (1995) examines states’ programs to reduce erosion and sedimentation

pollution in urban areas. Based on his empirical analysis, he concludes that “[t]he best performing

state programs [for nonpoint sources of water pollution] tend to be those that use a highly coercive

9

Page 10: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

approach”.

Third, Burby and Patterson (1993) empirically examine whether the impact of the

government’s choice of enforcement strategies on compliance with regulatory obligations depends

on the kind of regulatory standard at issue and whether, in particular, the cooperative approach is

better suited to inducing compliance with performance standards than with specification standards. 3

Their empirical results show that “a cooperative approach to enforcement has much more impact on

the degree of compliance attained for performance standards than for specification standards.”

Fourth, Andreen (2006) empirically examines compliance rates for major dischargers under

the CWA. His analysis reveals that compliance rates remained stubbornly static during the period

in which many states were replacing traditional enforcement with some type of cooperative

enforcement. He concludes that “[t]he new, more flexible approach has not improved rates of

compliance”.

While these empirical studies help to inform our understanding of enforcement strategies and

their relative efficacy, none of these empirical studies (1) employ multivariate statistical analysis of

facility-specific data to explore the effect of the overall enforcement approach, (2) explore this effect

on the extent of environmental compliance, which permits an assessment of both overcompliance

and the degree of non-compliance, (3) assess the influence of other forms of external pressure on the

effectiveness of the enforcement approach, or (4) use regulated facilities’ perceptions of their

interactions with regulators to assess the enforcement approach. Our study contributes these four

features.

Specification standards (also known as design standards) typically specify a goal that takes the3

form of a mandatory cap on discharges (this cap is often expressed numerically) and then agencies definethe method by which regulated entities are required to achieve the goal. In contrast, performance standardsdo not constrain the regulated entities’ choice of method for achieving a similarly articulated goal, i.e., capon discharges.

10

Page 11: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

Our empirical study also contributes to a broader literature that explores certain features of

a cooperative enforcement approach. As recently prominent studies in this literature, certain studies

explore environmental policies granting leniency in some form, such as immunity from prosecution,

to regulated facilities that self-disclose violations identified using internal audit programs. Short and

Toffel (2008) examine the influence of audit-related leniency policies on regulated facilities’

decisions to self-disclose. Short and Toffel (2010) examine the effect of facilities’ decisions to self-

disclose violations or not on facilities’ subsequent environmental compliance status regarding the

Clean Air Act. Toffel and Short (2011) examine the effect of facilities’ decisions to self-disclose

violations or not on facilities’ subsequent environmental compliance and environmental performance

as measured by abnormal releases of toxic chemicals. [This same study explores whether self-

disclosing facilities experience fewer regulatory inspections following disclosure.] Khanna and

Widyawati (2011) examine the effect of audit-related leniency policies on firms’ decisions to

conduct self-audits and environmental compliance with the Clean Air Act.

Outside of audit-related leniency policies, other studies explore certain features of

cooperation. For example, Helland (1998) empirically explores the use of self-reporting by regulated

facilities to demonstrate their willingness to cooperate with their Clean Water Act regulators.4

Examination of cooperative features fits into an even broader literature that explores

environmental compliance and management and the role of regulatory pressure without assessing

the contrast between a coercive enforcement strategy and a cooperative enforcement strategy and

their effects on environmental compliance (e.g., Earnhart, 2004a,b; Earnhart, 2009; Earnhart and

Segerson, 2012; Laplante and Rilstone, 1996; Shimshack and Ward, 2005; Magat and Viscusi,

1990). Various studies in this even broader literature explore the effect of local community pressure

While studies of cooperative features certainly contribute to a better understanding of a cooperative4

approach, none of these studies compare the cooperative approach to a coercive approach.

11

Page 12: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

on environmental compliance or management decisions (Earnhart, 2004c; Earnhart, 2009; Earnhart

and Segerson, 2012; Pargal and Wheeler, 1996). None of these studies assesses whether or how

local community pressure influences the effect of regulatory pressure on regulated facilities’

environmental or management decisions.

3. Regulatory Context

Our empirical analysis examines environmental performance relating to the U.S. Clean Water

Act. We focus on wastewater discharges controlled by the Clean Water Act because, unlike other

media, regulators systematically record wastewater discharge limits and actual discharges so that we

are able to measure the extent of compliance rather than merely the status of compliance, which

masks overcompliance and the degree of non-compliance. The Clean Water Act seeks to protect

water quality mostly by controlling discharges from point sources of pollution. Based on the

authority granted by this act, the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) constructed the

National Pollutant Discharge Elimination System (NPDES), which is designed to control wastewater

discharges from point sources. As the primary form of control within the NPDES system,

government efforts begin with the issuance of facility-specific permits to facilities regulated as point

sources. These permits specify the pollutant-specific discharge limits imposed on facilities.

Although the EPA possesses the authority to issue permits, this authority has been delegated to states

that meet federal criteria. Permits are issued by the EPA or authorized state regulatory agencies

through the efforts of permit writers. Regardless of the issuing agency, NPDES permits are issued

generally on a five-year cycle.

When establishing the facility-specific discharge limits embedded within facility-specific

permits, permit writers consider two standards: (1) the Effluent Limitation Guideline standard, and

(2) the state water quality-based standard. Effluent Limitation Guideline standards are designed to

12

Page 13: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

require a minimum level of wastewater treatment for a given industry (i.e., they establish a uniform

upper bound on limits across the entire United States for a given industry). These standards are

derived from available pollution control technologies. The state water quality-based standard is5

designed to ensure that the ambient water quality of the receiving water body meets state-based

ambient quality standards. In other words, the discharge limit is set so that the facility's discharges

do not cause the water body's ambient concentration of the relevant pollutant to exceed the

acceptable level, which is designed to assure that the receiving waterbody can sustain designated use,

e.g., fishable, swimmable. Discharge limits identified by state water quality-based standards differ

across facilities and time since ambient water quality standards differ across states and water bodies’

capacities to assimilate discharges differ across time and space even in the same state.

After a limit is determined under each standard, the more stringent limit is written into the

permit. Since the state water quality-based standards may trump the Effluent Limitation Guideline

Standards, effluent limits differ across facilities and time even within the same industry at the same

moment in time. Thus, our consideration of discharges relative to limits seems strongly meaningful.

To ensure compliance with the issued permit limits, the EPA and state agencies periodically

inspect facilities and take enforcement actions as needed. While the EPA retains authority to

monitor and sanction facilities, state agencies are primarily responsible for monitoring and

enforcement. Inspections represent the backbone of environmental agencies’ efforts to monitor

compliance and collect evidence for enforcement (Wasserman, 1984); inspections also maintain a

regulatory presence (EPA, 1990). As for enforcement, agencies use a mixture of informal

If no industry-specific Effluent Limitation Guideline applies to the particular facility, the permit5

writer uses his/her Best Professional Judgment, which draws upon all reasonably available and relevant data. In particular, the permit writer evaluates the effect of a permitted discharge limit on the environment. In thestudied sample, the role for professional judgement is highly limited since nearly all of the facilities operatein sub-sectors with effluent limitation guidelines. Thus, the scope for negotiation over effluent limit levels,including any reflection of compliance history, is severely restricted in the sample.

13

Page 14: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

enforcement actions (e.g., warning letters) and formal enforcement actions, which include both

penalties (i.e., fines) and formal enforcement actions that do not represent penalties, e.g.,

administrative orders. EPA regional offices may initiate an administrative proceeding in order to

impose an administrative sanction or may request the Department of Justice (DOJ) to initiate a civil

court proceeding in order to impose a civil sanction.

Point sources generally divide into two categories: municipal wastewater treatment facilities

and industrial sources. Our study focuses on a single sector within the category of industrial sources:

chemical manufacturing facilities. This focus on a single sector is consistent with other empirical

studies of industrial pollution (e.g., Laplante and Rilstone, 1996; Shimshack and Ward, 2005;

Earnhart, 2009).

The sector of chemical and allied products serves as an excellent vehicle for examining the

influence of corporate environmental behavior, audits in particular, on environmental performance.

First, the EPA has demonstrated a strong interest in this sector as evidenced by its study, jointly

authored with the Chemical Manufacturing Association (CMA), on the root causes of noncompliance

in this sector (EPA, 1999) and its study on the compliance history for this sector (EPA, 1997b).

Consistent with this interest, two sub-sectors in the industry, industrial organics and chemical

preparations (SIC-codes 2869, 2899), were regarded by the EPA as priority sectors during a portion

of the study period. Second, the CMA, which is now known as the American Chemistry Council

(ACC), has demonstrated a strong interest in promoting pollution reduction and prevention with its

Responsible Care initiative. Third, this sector is expected to display a wide variety of environmental

performance, involving noncompliance and overcompliance. Fourth, this sector permits the analysis

to exploit similarities and differences across sub-sectors. Fifth, this sector is responsible for a

significant portion of the nation’s industrial output and a meaningful portion of all wastewater

14

Page 15: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

discharges by facilities subject to Clean Water Act regulation.6

Lastly, as noted above, effluent limits are pollutant-specific. Thus, our analysis must focus

on certain pollutants in order to assess the extent of compliance. Our study focuses on the two

pollutants most common to the sampled facilities – total suspended solids (TSS) and biological

oxygen demand (BOD). TSS is the most prevalent in our sample and BOD is the second most

prevalent. As important, these pollutants represent two of the five EPA conventional pollutants,

which are the focus of EPA efforts. As further support, all previous studies of wastewater discharges

examine only BOD, only TSS, or both BOD and TSS (e.g., Earnhart, 2004a,b; Earnhart, 2009;

Laplante and Rilstone, 1996).

4. Analytical Framework

To assess the relative efficacy of the two enforcement approaches – coercive versus

cooperative, this section structures the statistical analysis that estimates a functional relationship

between environmental performance and the overall enforcement approach employed against the

sampled facilities. This estimation controls for other influential factors especially government

interventions – inspections and enforcement actions.

The chemical industry is not necessarily representative of all industrial sectors. Indeed, its unique6

attributes contribute to our interest in studying it.

15

Page 16: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

4.1. Effect of Enforcement Approach

In each relevant year of the sample, a facility chooses its level of environmental performance

as reflected in the extent of compliance with the facility’s wastewater discharge limit, which is

represented by the ratio of actual discharges to permitted discharges, i.e., discharge ratio. The

facility’s chosen discharge ratio represents the dependent variable in our statistical analysis. The

chosen discharge ratio depends on the overall enforcement approach, along with other explanatory

variables, which collectively represent the regressors in our statistical analysis.

Given the strongly empirical thrust of this study, we do not attempt to model formally the

relationship between environmental performance and overall enforcement approach. Instead, we rely

upon the review of previous theoretical studies provided in sub-section 2.1.1 for generating the basic

hypotheses being tested in the present study.

For our statistical analysis, we capture the enforcement approach using the prevalence of fair

treatment of the facility by the regulator: (1) always fair, (2) sometimes fair and sometimes unfair,

or (3) always unfair. We interpret “always fair” treatment as reflective of a more cooperative

enforcement approach and less than “always fair” treatment as reflective of a more coercive

enforcement approach. The treatment of regulated facilities affects environmental performance

differently under the two theoretical models. Under the coercive model, greater fairness dulls the

incentive to comply, leading to worse environmental management. Under the cooperative model,

greater fairness engenders good will, which induces better environmental performance. Conversely,

less fairness engenders intransigence and ill will on the part of regulated facilities, which induces

worse environmental performance.

Our empirical analysis tests these two competing hypotheses in two steps. First, we estimate

a functional relationship between environmental performance and a set of regressors. The primary

16

Page 17: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

regressor takes a value of one when the enforcement approach is cooperative and a value of zero

when the enforcement approach is coercive. Then we assess the estimated effect of overall

enforcement approach on environmental performance, i.e., test whether the coefficient associated

with the cooperative enforcement regressor differs positively or negatively from zero.

4.2. Effects of Other Factors on Environmental Performance

In order to isolate the effect of the overall enforcement approach on environmental

management for proper testing, our statistical analysis controls for the influence of other explanatory

factors particularly government interventions – inspections and enforcement actions (hereafter

“control factors”). Within a simple conceptual framework, these control factors relate to either the

costs of compliance or the costs of non-compliance. We identify the control factors according to

these two categories. As we identify these control variables, we also describe the a priori

expectations regarding the relationship between each control factor and the dependent variable of

discharge ratio.

The first set of control factors relate to the costs of compliance. First, compliance costs

depend on abatement methods, which we measure as the presence or absence of an end-of-pipe

treatment technology, and self-audits. The presence of end-of-pipe treatment is expected to lower

the chosen discharge ratio. Moreover, audits conducted by the facilities should improve the

effectiveness of the existing abatement methods, which lowers the marginal costs of abatement.

Given a lower marginal abatement cost, facilities should choose to abate more, implying that an

increase in audits should decrease the chosen discharge ratio. Second, facility and firm

characteristics influence compliance costs. The age of a facility represents a proxy for the vintage

of production capital. Older facilities are expected to discharge more due to higher compliance

costs. In addition, the type of production process as proxied by broad sectoral classification –

17

Page 18: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

“organic chemicals” versus “inorganic chemicals” versus “other chemicals” – influences compliance

costs but without a priori expectations regarding the effect of production process on the chosen

discharge ratio. Compliance costs also depend on ownership structure, which we measure by

contrasting publicly held structures from all other ownership structure. Facilities owned by publicly

held firms are expected to discharge less (i.e., lower discharge ratio) because publicly held firms

enjoy greater access to external financing. Compliance costs additionally depend on the firm-level

ratio of environmental employees to total employees, which we interpret as a proxy for firm-level

commitment to environmental protection or at least the quantity of resources available from

corporate staff. Facilities owned by firms with more environmental employees are expected to

discharge less (i.e., lower discharge ratio).

The second set of control factors relate to the costs of non-compliance. These factors

primarily reflect regulatory pressure, which we divide into monitoring and regulatory enforcement.7

We measure regulatory monitoring based on the prevalence of inspections. Consistent with the

standard deterrence model (Becker, 1968), we construct a factor that measures the ex ante likelihood

or threat of an inspection, which arguably approximates the likelihood of a sanction. To construct

an exogenous measure of this ex ante threat, we assess inspections conducted at other similar

facilities, specifically other regulated chemical manufacturing facilities operating in the same

relevant jurisdiction (i.e., state or EPA region) in the current calendar year. Given the discrete nature

of monitoring, we simply count the inspections conducted at other similar facilities, while dividing

by the number of “other similar facilities” in the jurisdiction in the current year for comparability

The use of a cooperative enforcement approach is vulnerable to the criticism that its use is merely7

cover for decreasing the regulatory pressure applied on polluting facilities through monitoring andenforcement (Webster, 2006). Since our analysis controls for the use of monitoring inspections andenforcement actions, our analysis is better able to isolate the effect of a cooperative enforcement approachin general, independent of any possible reduction in monitoring and enforcement.

18

Page 19: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

across space and time. Based on work by Earnhart (2004a), we derive two separate measures for

state inspections and federal inspections. These measures serve collectively as a proxy of the

perceived threat of inspections based on others’ experiences (Sah, 1991). Obviously, greater

monitoring is expected to lower the chosen discharge ratio.

We measure regulatory enforcement based on the strength of enforcement. Specifically, we

construct three variables that collectively measure the ex ante strength of enforcement. To construct

exogenous measures, we assess enforcement actions taken against other similar facilities. In the

case of penalties, we measure the inflation-adjusted dollar value of penalties levied on other similar

facilities, while dividing by the number of regulated facilities. In the case of non-penalty

enforcement, we count the enforcement actions taken against other similar facilities, while dividing

by the number of regulated facilities. We derive two separate measures for informal enforcement

and formal non-penalty enforcement. These measures collectively serve as a proxy of the perceived

strength of enforcement based on others’ experiences (Sah, 1991). Similar to monitoring, greater

enforcement is expected to lower the chosen discharge ratio.

As other regulatory control factors, we incorporate individual EPA region indicators and

individual calendar year indicators, which contain no obvious a priori expectations.

More important, our statistical analysis controls for two additional forms of external pressure.

Specifically, we control for local community pressure, as measured by the facility’s perceived need

to respond to local community pressure, which is expressed in response to a question in our original

survey of the sampled facilities. Based on these responses, we distinguish between a “strong need

to respond” and a less than “strong need to respond”. Facilities facing a greater need to respond to

local community pressure are expected to discharge less (i.e., lower discharge ratio). Regarding the

second form of external pressure, we allow ownership structure to control for both variation in

19

Page 20: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

compliance costs, as discussed above, and variation in investor pressure. Facilities owned by

publicly held firms are expected to discharge less because publicly held firms face greater pressure

from investors for good environmental performance.

As the last control factor, we include the lagged discharge ratio. In practice, enforcement

authorities consider a facility’s compliance history – both current and lagged discharge ratios – when

exploring sanctions for non-compliance, consistent with EPA guidelines. Thus, the higher was the

discharge ratio in the past, the greater is the impact of an increased current discharge ratio on the

threat of sanction. Given this connection, a higher lagged discharge ratio leads to a greater marginal

cost of non-compliance, prompting the facility to lower its currently chosen discharge ratio; the

converse also holds.

Previous empirical studies of environmental compliance and management employ control

factors similar to ours: treatment technology (Earnhart, 2004a,b,c), audits (Evans et al., 2011;

Khanna and Widyawati, 2011), facility age (Wang, 2002; Anton et al., 2004; Arimura et al., 2008;

Khanna et al., 2009; Harrington et al., 2008), sectoral classification (Khanna et al., 2007; Ervin et

al., 2012; Henriques and Sadorsky, 1996; Earnhart, 2009), ownership structure (Arimura et al., 2008;

Dasgupta et al., 2000; Khanna et al., 2007; Earnhart, 2009), government monitoring (Earnhart,

2004a,b,c; Earnhart, 2009; Earnhart and Segerson, 2012; Anton et al., 2004; Evans et al., 2011),

enforcement actions (Khanna et al., 2009; Harrington et al., 2008; Earnhart, 2004a,b,c), EPA

regional indicators (Earnhart, 2009; Earnhart and Segerson, 2012), local community pressure

(Earnhart, 2004c; Earnhart, 2009; Earnhart and Segerson, 2012; Pargal and Wheeler, 1996), investor

pressure (Ervin et al., 2012; Khanna et al., 2007), lagged discharge ratio (Magat and Viscusi, 1990;

Harrington, 2012; Earnhart, 2004a,b,c).

4.3. Influence of Local Community Pressure on the Effect of Enforcement Approach

20

Page 21: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

As noted above, regulatory pressure represents only one form of pressure applied by external

entities (i.e., external pressure) on facilities efforts to comply with environmental regulations. Our

empirical analysis also includes local community pressure as a second form of external pressure

(along with investor pressure).

Conceptually, regulatory pressure and local community pressure may serve as complements

or substitutes for inducing better environmental compliance. If these two forms of pressure generate

signals that resonate, thus, producing synergistic effects on facilities’ compliance decisions, then

these two external pressure forms represent complements. In this case, the marginal effect of

regulatory enforcement pressure grows as local community pressure builds. In contrast, if the two

forms of external pressure generate signals that drown out each other, thus, weakening both forms’

effectiveness at inducing better compliance, then regulatory pressure and local community pressure

represent substitutes. In this case, the marginal effect of regulatory enforcement pressure declines

as local community pressure grows. Most interesting, whether the two external pressure forms are

complements or substitutes depends on the type of enforcement approach since cooperation and

coercion clearly send different types of regulatory signals that may amplify or dampen the signal of

local community pressure.

We assess whether regulatory enforcement pressure and local community pressure are

complements or substitutes by generating an interaction between these two explanatory factors and

incorporating this interaction term into our regressor set for estimating the extent of compliance.

5. Data

In order to explore the influence of the overall enforcement approach on Clean Water Act-

regulated facilities’ wastewater discharge ratios, we explore data drawn from a survey of regulated

facilities and an EPA database.

21

Page 22: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

5.1. Survey of Regulated Entities

This first sub-section describes the set of facilities sampled by the survey and the information

extracted by the survey. Our survey was administered to a sample of U.S. chemical manufacturing

facilities whose wastewater discharges were regulated by effluent limits imposed within permits

issued as part of the National Pollutant Discharge Elimination System (NPDES) in 2001. The

population of CWA-regulated facilities in the chemical manufacturing industry as of September,

2001, was extracted from the EPA’s Permit Compliance System (PCS) database, which records

information on facilities permitted within the NPDES system. This extract included 2,596 chemical

facilities. The population held both “minor facilities” and “major facilities” as classified by the EPA

for the NPDES system; in general, minor facilities are smaller and major facilities are larger. To8

remain in the survey population, facilities needed to meet the following criteria: (1) possessed a

NPDES permit; (2) faced restrictions on their wastewater discharges, (3) discharged regulated

pollutants into surface water bodies, (4) were operating as of 2002, and (5) contact information was

available from either the EPA or alternative sources, e.g., phone books. Application of these criteria

identified 1,003 facilities to contact. Of those facilities contacted between April of 2002 and March

of 2003, 736 refused to participate in the survey, while 267 facilities completed at least 90 percent

of the survey, implying a 27 % response rate. This rate is comparable to previous large-scale surveys

of industrial sectors (e.g., Arimura et al., 2008) and lies above the average response rate of 21 % as

identified by a review of 183 studies based on business surveys published in academic journals

(Paxson, 1992). [The appendix addresses the possible concern of sample selection bias.]

When administering the survey, we first contacted those individuals responsible for signing

For the classification of each regulated facility, the EPA calculates a major rating with points8

assigned on the basis of toxic pollution potential, flow type, conventional pollutant load, public healthimpact, and water quality impact; the EPA classifies any discharger with a point total of 80 or more as a“major facility”.

22

Page 23: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

their respective facilities’ wastewater discharge monitoring reports, which facilities are required to

submit to the EPA on a regular basis, generally monthly. This selection of survey participants allows

our survey to exploit the insight of those individuals most knowledgeable about their facilities’

wastewater operations.

The survey gathered various data elements. Mostly the survey gathered annual data for the

years 1999, 2000, and 2001. The survey gathered data on environmental management (e.g., audits,

end-of-pipe treatment), characteristics of the facilities (e.g., facility age), and characteristics of the

firms that own these facilities (e.g., ownership structure, number of firm-level environmental

employees and total employees). Most important, the survey gathered data on the enforcement9

approach employed by a wastewater regulator against a specific facility by asking each respondent

to characterize the prevalence of its regulator’s fair treatment: always unfair, sometimes fair and

sometimes unfair, or always fair. Another survey question asked respondents to assess their

perceived need to respond to local community pressure.

5.2. Publicly Available Data on Regulated Entities

To complement the data gathered by our survey, we also collected information from the EPA

Permit Compliance System (PCS) database. This database provides information on each facility’s

(1) location, (2) NPDES major or minor classification, (3) four-digit standard industrial classification

[SIC] code, (4) monthly limit levels of permitted discharges, and (5) monthly levels of actual

discharges. From these data, we calculate the monthly discharge ratio. We focus exclusively on10 11

To validate the self-reported data on firm ownership structure, our study draws upon publicly9

available data. The EPA Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) database provides annual information on a facility’sparent company. The Business and Company Resource Center database and Compustat / Research Insightdatabase provide annual data on a parent company’s ownership structure.

The analysis aggregates the four-digit SIC codes into three broader sectoral categories: organic10

chemicals, inorganic chemicals, and “other” chemicals. The broad category of organic chemicals includesthe following four-digit SIC codes: 2821, 2823, 2824, 2843, 2865, 2869, 2891, and 2899. The broad category

23

Page 24: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

the two most prominent wastewater pollutants in the sample: total suspended solids (TSS) and

biological oxygen demand (BOD). The PCS database also provides data on government

interventions: inspections performed by federal and state regulators, formal enforcement orders

imposed by federal administrative and civil courts, and informal enforcement actions issued by

federal enforcement agencies.

The PCS database systematically records wastewater discharges and discharge limits only

for major facilities. Not surprisingly, the PCS database contains no information on discharge limits

and wastewater discharges for any of the 164 survey respondent minor facilities. Of the 103 survey

respondent major facilities, the PCS database contains records that potentially provide data on

discharge limits and wastewater discharges for 97 major facilities. For all of our analysis, we focus

exclusively on these 97 facilities for which we possess both survey data on environmental

management practices and EPA data on limits and discharges.

Our exclusive focus on major facilities clearly limits the generalizability of our results.

Nevertheless, our analysis remains policy relevant since the EPA focuses its regulatory efforts on

major facilities (Earnhart, 2004a; Earnhart, 2004b; Earnhart, 2009; Earnhart and Segerson, 2012).

Moreover, major facilities represented 21 % of the 2,481 chemical manufacturing facilities in the

NPDES system in 2001. Given their size, we suspect that major facilities were responsible for the

bulk of wastewater discharges from this sector during the sample period.

To match the annual data provided by the survey for the years 1999 to 2001, we aggregate

the monthly data on discharge ratios to an annual basis by identifying the year-specific median ratio

of inorganic chemicals includes the following four-digit SIC codes: 2812, 2813, 2816, 2819, 2873, and 2874.

Discharge limits constrain wastewater measured as a quantity, e.g., pounds per day, or as a11

concentration, e.g., milligrams per liter of wastewater. By calculating discharge ratios, we avoid thecomplication of combining these two disparate forms of measurement.

24

Page 25: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

among the 12 monthly ratios. (Use of the year-specific mean ratio generates highly similar

estimation results.)

Prior to this aggregation, we assess the reporting of discharges. Of the monthly observations

relevant to TSS discharge limits, 99.5 % also provide data on actual TSS discharges. Of the monthly

observations relevant to BOD discharge limits, 99.7 % also provide data on actual BOD discharges.

This nearly universal reporting of wastewater discharges is quite reassuring and practically

eliminates the need to consider strategic non-reporting of discharges.

In sum, the sample represents a panel of 97 facilities with annual data for the years 1999,

2000, and 2001. Thus, the unit of observation is an individual facility discharging in a given year.

However, not all 97 facilities discharge TSS or BOD in all three years so the regression sample is

smaller. Further, by first-differencing our variables, which is required by our chosen estimation

procedure (as described in the next section), we effectively use only two years of data. In the end,

the TSS regression sample includes 144 observations, while the BOD regression sample includes

123 observations.

5.3. Summary Statistics

Table 1 statistically summarizes the dependent variables and the various independent

variables. Information on the dependent variables is most interesting. Based on the average TSS

discharge ratio of 0.232, the average facility discharges TSS at levels 77 % below its limits [(1-

0.232)×100 = 76.8 %]. Based on the average BOD discharge ratio of 0.230, the average facility

discharges BOD at levels 77 % below its limits. Clearly, many facilities are choosing to overcomply.

Table 1 also describes the prevalence of the two types of enforcement approaches –

cooperative versus coercive – within the sample of regulated facilities. As shown, 84 % to 90 % of

the sampled facilities, depending on the pollutant-specific regression sample, report that their

25

Page 26: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

regulatory treatment is “always fair”, while 10 % to 16 % report that their regulatory treatment is

“sometimes fair and sometimes unfair”. (No sampled facility reports that its treatment is “always

unfair”.)

6. Statistical Analysis

This next section describes the statistical analysis used to explore the gathered data.

Most important, our statistical analysis addresses two key issues. First, it addresses the

inclusion of the lagged dependent variable as a regressor in a panel data framework. In the presence

of a lagged dependent variable, a fixed effects estimator generates inconsistent estimates because the

differenced lagged dependent variable is correlated with the error term (Anderson and Hsiao,

1982). To address this complication, we employ the two-stage Anderson-Hsiao estimator12

(Anderson and Hsiao, 1982) as applied by Jaffe and Stavins (1995) and Harrington (2012). In the

first stage, we first-difference all of the variables and estimate the first-differenced model in order

to generate coefficients for the time-variant regressors. In the second stage, we recover coefficients

for the time-invariant regressors.13

Given the concern over the correlation between the lagged dependent variable and the error

term, we assess whether the lagged dependent variable is endogenous using both a Wu-Hausman

Exogeneity Test and a Durbin-Wu-Hausman Exogeneity Test. The test statistics reject the null

hypothesis of exogeneity, given p-values of 0.002 and 0.002, respectively, for the TSS sample. For

We do not employ a random effects estimator since Hausman Test of Random Effects statistics12

do not indicate that the random effects estimates are consistent.

We recover the coefficients in three steps. As the first step, we multiply each coefficient derived13

in the first stage with the facility mean of that same variable and then sum these products. As the secondstep, we subtract the sum from the mean of the dependent variable measured in levels rather than differences,generating the necessary “residuals”. As the final step, we use ordinary least squares regression to estimatea functional relationship between the residuals and the time-invariant factors in order to generate the relevantcoefficients.

26

Page 27: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

the BOD sample, however, the test statistics fail to reject the null hypothesis of exogeneity, given

p-values of 0.42 and 0.40, respectively. Hence, for the estimation of the TSS discharge ratio, we

instrument for the first-differenced one-year-lagged dependent variable using a two-year-lagged level

of the dependent variable, as suggested by Anderson and Hsiao (1982) and employed by Jaffe and

Stavins (1995) and Harrington (2012). For the sake of comparability between the two dependent

variables and out of a sense of precaution, we employ the same procedure for the estimation of the

BOD discharge ratio.

As the second statistical issue, our analysis addresses the potential endogeneity of the

enforcement approach regressor. We address this potential concern by employing an instrumental

variable (IV) estimator, for which we must identify at least one instrument for this potentially

endogenous regressor. An effective instrument is both relevant, i.e., helps to explain the type of

enforcement approach chosen by a regulator, and valid, i.e., does not influence the facility’s choice

of discharge ratio. To assess instrument validity, we must identify multiple instruments. Consistent

with Anton et al. (2004), we lag key time-variant regulatory factors in order to generate instruments.

In particular, we construct lagged measures of government intervention-related regressors, along

with lagged measures of state-level audit-related immunity and privilege policies (Short and Toffel,

2008, 2010; Toffel and Short, 2011; Khanna and Widyawati, 2012). By granting immunity from

prosecution for violations self-disclosed by facilities generated from an internal audit program and/or

granting privilege to evidence of violations generated from these audits, these policies represent a

more cooperative approach to environmental regulation (Short and Toffel, 2008). We argue that

states adopting these audit policies are more likely to use a cooperative enforcement approach.

However, we argue that these audit policies should not influence the extent of compliance directly.

Instead, these policies should prompt more audits, as documented by Short and Toffel (2008), which

27

Page 28: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

then influence compliance outcomes, as documented by Short and Toffel (2010) and Toffel and

Short (2011); thus, the audit policies only indirectly affect compliance. While contemporaneous

measures of these policies – only immunity, only privilege, both immunity and privilege – may be

sufficient, we lag these factors in order to increase the validity of these instruments.

Based on an assessment of the calculated statistics of standard tests, the instruments appear

both relevant and not invalid. Therefore, we test whether the potentially endogenous regressor of14

enforcement approach is exogenous using both a Wu-Hausman Exogeneity Test and a Durbin-Wu-

Hausman Exogeneity Test. For the TSS regression sample, these two test statistics fail to reject the

null hypothesis of exogeneity given p-values of 0.266 and 0.221, respectively. For the BOD

regression sample, these two test statistics also fail to reject the null hypothesis of exogeneity given

p-values of 0.886 and 0.841, respectively. These statistics indicate that the enforcement approach

regressor does not appear endogenous. Performing IV estimation when a regressor is not

endogenous (i.e., uncorrelated with the error process) involves an important cost: unnecessarily large

standard errors (Wooldridge, 2002). Therefore, our econometric analysis proceeds by addressing

exclusively the problematic lagged dependent regressor.15

In order to assess the robustness of our empirical results linking overall enforcement

To assess the relevance of our instruments, we test under-identification in the first stage of14

estimation. Based on both the Angrist-Pischke ÷ Test statistics and the Anderson Canonical Correlation2

Lagrange Multiplier Test statistics, we reject the null hypothesis of under-identification given p-values of0.068 and 0.088, respectively, for the TSS regression sample and p-values of 0.0004 and 0.007, respectively,for the BOD regression sample. To assess the validity of our instruments, we primarily employ the Sargan-Hansen Test of Overidentifying Restrictions. For both the TSS and BOD regression samples, the Sargan-Hansen Test statistics fail to reject the null hypothesis of valid orthogonality conditions given p-values of0.124 and 0.765, respectively. As further evidence, we employ weak instrument robust inference tests:Anderson-Rubin Wald Test and the Stock-Wright Lagrange Multiplier Test. For both regression samples,regardless of the test, the statistics fail to reject the null hypothesis of valid orthogonality conditions with p-values of 0.201 and 0.124, respectively, for the TSS sample and p-values of 0.884 and 0.686, respectively,for the BOD sample.

The audit-related regressor may be endogenous. However, exogeneity test statistics fail to reject15

the null hypothesis of exogeneity. Details are available upon request.

28

Page 29: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

approach to the chosen discharge ratio, we consider a variety of regressor sets, i.e., models. Model

1 includes only the enforcement approach indicator and the lagged dependent variable, which

represents the most parsimonious regressor set feasible when implementing the Anderson-Hsiao

estimator. Model 2 adds the year indicator and EPA regional indicators. Model 3 includes all of the

regressors excepting the interaction between the enforcement approach indicator and local

community pressure. Model 4 includes all regressors.

For the sake of improving our estimation’s fit of the data, we take logs of certain regressors:

informal enforcement, formal non-penalty enforcement, penalty enforcement, state inspections,

federal inspections, and the firm-level ratio of environmental employees to total employees.

By using the Anderson-Hsiao estimator, which requires first-differences, we lose

observations from the year of 1999 because we do not possess survey data for 1998. Thus, we must

restrict our sample period to the years of 2000 and 2001. The TSS regression sample includes 144

observations and the BOD regression sample includes 123 observations.

7. Estimation Results

This section reports and interprets the estimation results. Table 2 displays the estimates

based on the TSS sample. Table 3 displays the estimates based on the BOD sample. For reasons

explained below, Table 3 does not include Model 4 estimates for the BOD sample. As noted in both

tables, the reported estimates reflect robust standard errors.

7.1. Base Empirics

For our base set of empirical results, we focus on Models 1, 2, and 3, while ignoring the

model that includes the interaction between enforcement approach and local community pressure.

In this way, we allow the estimates from Models 1, 2, and 3 to reveal the general effect of

enforcement approach. In sub-section 7.2, we explore the results from Model 4.

29

Page 30: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

7.1.1. TSS Discharge Ratio

We first interpret the results generated by the estimation of TSS discharge ratios. As shown

in Table 2, estimates from Models 1, 2, and 3 reveal that a cooperative enforcement approach,

relative to a coercive enforcement approach, positively influences the discharge ratio. This positive

coefficient implies that “less fair treatment” leads to better environmental performance. Thus, a

coercive approach dominates a cooperative approach at inducing greater compliance with wastewater

discharge limits. This conclusion is robust across the three relevant models. This conclusion is also

robust to estimation of models that exclude either all of the cost of compliance factors or all of the

cost of noncompliance factors; details are available upon request.

Perhaps consistent with the dominance of a coercive approach, the estimation results reveal

that enforcement actions influence environmental performance. Most interesting, the estimates

indicate that formal non-penalty enforcement negatively influences the discharge ratio. This negative

coefficient indicates that increased enforcement lowers the discharge ratio. Since the coefficient

associated with informal enforcement is statistically insignificant, we conclude that enforcement

must be formal in nature to prove effective. In contrast to formal non-penalty enforcement, formal

penalty enforcement proves statistically insignificant, similar to informal enforcement. We discount

this contrast and similarity based on the statistical insignificance of penalties since this form of

enforcement is utilized so infrequently. Moreover, the estimates demonstrate that enforcement, but

not monitoring in the form of inspections, proves effective.

As our key form of external pressure, the significantly negative coefficient on the community

pressure regressor indicates that a greater need to respond to local community pressure appears to

lower discharge ratios.

Estimates also reveal the following links. First, the firm-level ratio of environmental

30

Page 31: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

employees to total employees negatively influences the discharge ratio. This link implies that a firm-

level commitment to environmental management resources appears to improve environmental

performance at the facility level. Second, estimates reveal that the type of production process, as

proxied by sectoral classification, influences the discharge ratio. Facilities manufacturing organic

chemicals generate a higher discharge ratio than facilities manufacturing “other chemicals”. Third,

the effect of audits on discharge ratios is negative and statistically significant regardless of the

regressor set. The negative coefficient indicates that an increase in the count of audits lowers the

discharge ratio, indicating that audits effectively control wastewater pollution.

7.1.2. BOD Discharge Ratio

We next interpret the results generated by the estimation of BOD discharge ratios as shown

in Table 3. Similar to the TSS results, BOD estimates reveal that a cooperative enforcement

approach, relative to a coercive approach, positively influences the discharge ratio. Again, this

positive coefficient implies that “less fair treatment” leads to better environmental performance.

As with the TSS results, this conclusion is robust across the models. Thus, our conclusion is also

robust to the type of wastewater pollutant explored.

Contrary to the TSS results, the BOD estimates reveal that the lagged dependent variable

negatively and significantly influences the current BOD discharge ratio. This result is robust across

the models. This set of results indicates that those facilities who complied better in the past (i.e.,

lower lagged discharge ratio) are expected to comply worse in the present (i.e., higher current

discharge ratio).

Collectively, these BOD results appear to reveal that BOD discharge ratios are not influenced

by many factors other than the enforcement approach and lagged dependent variables. (For example,

contrary to the TSS estimates, the effect of audits proves statistically insignificant, indicating that

31

Page 32: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

audits prove ineffective for controlling BOD discharges.) Given the strength of the relationship

between lagged and current discharge ratios, we wonder whether this connection eats up the

explanatory power available in the overall relationship connecting the current discharge ratio to a

set of factors; however, we can provide no evidence to support this point.

7.2. Extended Empirics

We next extend our empirics by exploring the interaction between enforcement approach and

local community pressure. As shown in Tables 2 and 3, local community pressure significantly

affects TSS discharge ratios but not BOD discharge ratios. We argue that exploration of an

interaction involving local community pressure is not warranted when local community pressure

does not independently affect discharge ratios. Therefore, we proceed by focusing exclusively on

TSS discharge ratios.

To explore the interaction between enforcement approach and local community pressure, we

assess the estimation results of Model 4 shown in Table 2. In particular, we assess the coefficients

associated with the enforcement approach, local community pressure, and the interaction term. To

start, the interaction term proves statistically significant, revealing that local community pressure

influences the effect of enforcement approach on the extent of compliance. Further interpretation

of these coefficients is challenging because the two key underlying regressors are binary and a lower

discharge ratio reflects better environmental compliance. To facilitate understanding, Table 4 reports

the marginal effects of the enforcement approach factor, conditional on the strength of local

community pressure, while evaluating each enforcement approach type separately. As shown in

Table 4, the marginal effect of coercion equals +0.484 when local community pressure is weak

(“little/some”) but equals - 0.131 when local community pressure is strong (“quite bit / great deal”).

Since a negative marginal effect indicates that coercion effectively lowers discharge ratios, the

32

Page 33: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

effectiveness of coercion grows as local community pressure builds, implying that coercion and local

community pressure are complements. Thus, the two external pressure signals appear to resonate.

In contrast (and by construction), the marginal effect of cooperation equals - 0.484 when local

community pressure is weak (“little/some”) but equals + 0.131 when local community pressure is

strong (“quite bit / great deal”). Since a positive marginal effect indicates that cooperation

counterproductively raises discharge ratios, the effectiveness of coercion falls as local community

pressure grows, imply that cooperation and local community pressure are substitutes. Most

interesting, these results reveal that coercion dominates cooperation only when local community

pressure is sufficiently meaningful, which is true for 93 % of the sample. When local community

pressure is weak, cooperation dominates coercion. Based on the sample average strength of local

community pressure, coercion dominates cooperation.

7.3. Legal Importance

Lastly, we assess the legal importance of the influence of the overall enforcement approach.

For this assessment, we consider each pollutant separately. Consequently, we first identify the

pollutant-specific mean discharge ratio; each value is shown in Table 1. Based on the base empiris,

we next identify the most representative enforcement approach coefficient, which we believe stems

from estimation of the most comprehensive regressor set: Model 3. (Use of the other models’

coefficients generates a highly similar result.) Then we compare the coefficient to the mean

discharge ratio. The switch from a coercive approach to a cooperative approach prompts the TSS

discharge ratio to rise by 0.101; relative to a mean TSS discharge ratio of 0.232, this rise represents

a 44 % increase. More dramatically, the switch from a coercive approach to a cooperative approach

prompts the BOD discharge ratio to rise by 0.537; relative to a mean BOD discharge ratio of 0.230,

this rise reflects a 233 % increase. These base empirical calculations clearly demonstrate that the

33

Page 34: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

influence of the overall enforcement approach is legally important. We finally assess the legal

importance based on the extended empirics, which consider the influence of local community

pressure on the effect of enforcement approach. When local community pressure is weak

(“little/some”), the switch from a coercive approach to a cooperative approach prompts the TSS

discharge ratio to fall by 0.484; relative to a mean TSS discharge ratio of 0.232, this drop represents

a 209 % decline. When local community pressure is strong (“quite bit / great deal”), the switch from

a coercive approach to a cooperative approach prompts the TSS discharge ratio to rise by 0.131;

relative to a mean TSS discharge ratio of 0.232, this rise represents a 56 % increase. Again, these

calculations reveal that the influence of overall enforcement approach is legally important.

9. Conclusions, Policy Implications, and Future Research

In this last section, we draw an overall conclusion, discuss policy implications of our research

results, and provide guidance on future research. Based on our base empirical results, we draw the

following conclusion: a more coercive approach appears in general to induce better environmental

performance, i.e., greater compliance with wastewater discharge limits. Our results are robust to the

type of wastewater pollutant examined, regardless of the regressor set used to establish the functional

relationship involving environmental performance. However, based on our extended empirical

results, the influence of the enforcement approach depends on the presence of local community

pressure. Specifically, the effectiveness of coercion grows as local community pressure builds,

implying that coercion and local community pressure are complements. By construction, these same

results imply that cooperation and local community pressure are substitutes. As important, our

extended results reveal that coercion dominates cooperation only when local community pressure

is sufficiently meaningful. When local community pressure is weak, cooperation dominates

coercion.

34

Page 35: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

These conclusions possesses policy implications. Environmental regulators seeking to induce

better compliance should employ a more coercive approach in general. Based on our measure of

coercion versus cooperation, the base results imply that environmental regulators should not be

overly fair otherwise the regulators may lose their leverage with regulated facilities. However, the

extended results imply more policy consideration. Before selecting an enforcement approach,

environmental regulators should assess the strength of local community pressure.

These policy implications aside, we acknowledge that our conclusion need not generalize to

other sectors regulated under the Clean Water Act or compliance with other environmental

protection laws. Future research should expand the coverage of analysis. Specifically, we encourage

future research to explore additional sectors beyond the chemical manufacturing sector, to explore

a broader set of wastewater pollutants beyond TSS and BOD, and to explore pollution in other

media, such as air pollution and toxic and hazardous waste generation. As important, we encourage

future research – both empirical and theoretical – to explore more deeply the interaction between

regulatory enforcement pressure and local community pressure.

35

Page 36: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

Appendix: Incomplete Response to Survey of Chemical Manufacturing Facilities

This appendix assesses the incomplete response to our original survey of chemical

manufacturing facilities. Given the survey’s non-response rate of 73 %, the potential for sample

selection bias is a valid concern. As the initial assessment of this concern, we compare the original

sample of 1,003 potentially eligible facilities to the 267 facilities that actually completed the survey.

Based on this comparison, we find no systematic state or regional bias in survey participation. For

example, only the Midwest region is slightly over-represented in the response group, and only the

Northeast region is slightly under-represented. These differences, however, are small. In addition,

across most of the states, the difference between representation in the original sample and

representation in the response group averages less than two percent. In contrast, our initial

assessment reveals some difference in the participation of major facilities versus minor facilities.

In the original sample, 69 percent of facilities are minor facilities and 31 percent are major facilities.

In the group of survey respondents, major facilities are slightly over-represented at 39 percent. This

difference proves statistically significant.

As a stronger assessment, we test for sample selection bias by assessing whether any relevant

factors appear to affect a facility’s decision to complete our survey once it is contacted. For this

assessment, we use a probit model to estimate a functional relationship between the binary decision

to complete or not our survey and a set of relevant factors, including major versus minor status,

inspections, enforcement actions, and EPA region. This assessment reveals a bias in a single

dimension: major facilities were more likely to respond to the survey than were minor facilities. Put

differently, the analysis indicates that only the distinction between minor and major facilities proves

important for explaining whether or not a contacted facility completed the administered survey. The

analysis demonstrates that neither the preceding history of inspections nor the preceding enforcement

36

Page 37: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

actions against a particular facility explains whether or not a contacted facility responded to the

survey. Moreover, the analysis demonstrates that the decision to respond is not explained by the

EPA region in which a particular facility resides. Thus, even if the threat of inspections and

enforcement actions varies across EPA regions, this variation does not explain whether or not a

contacted facility responds to the survey.

Thus, based on our analysis, it appears that a sample selection bias exists in only a single

dimension: the distinction between a “major facility” and a “minor facility”. This single distinction

proves irrelevant for our final sample of analysis. Therefore, in the end, our study does not correct

for any potential sample selection bias. This lack of correction is consistent with prominently

published studies of environmental management practices (Anton et al., 2004; Arimura et al., 2008).

37

Page 38: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

References

Anderson, T.W. and Cheng Hsiao (1982), “Formulation and Estimation of Dynamic Models using Panel

Data,” Journal of Econometrics, 18 (1), pg. 47-82.

Andreen, William (2007), “Motivating Enforcement: Institutional Culture and the Clean Water Act,”

Pace Environmental Law Review, 24, 67-98.

Anton, Willma Rose, George Deltas, and Madhu Khanna (2004), “Incentives for Environmental Self-

Regulation and Implications for Environmental Performance,” Journal of Environmental

Economics and Management, 48, pg. 632-654.

Arimura, Toshi, Akira Hibiki, and Hajime Katayama (2008), "Is a Voluntary Approach an Effective

Environmental Policy Instrument? A Case for Environmental Management Systems," Journal of

Environmental Economics and Management, 55 (3), pg. 281-295.

Becker, Gary (1968), “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” Journal of Political Economy,

76, pg. 169-217.

Burby, Raymond and Robert Paterson (1993), “Improving Compliance with State Environmental

Regulations,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 12, pg. 753-756.

Burby, Raymond (1995), “Coercive v. Cooperative Pollution Control: Comparative Study of State

Programs to Reduce Erosion and Sedimentation Pollution in Urban Areas,” Environmental

Management, 19, pg. 359-361.

Cohen, Mark (2000), “Empirical Research on the Deterrent Effect of Environmental Monitoring and

Enforcement,” Environmental Law Reporter, 30, pg. 10245-10252.

Earnhart, Dietrich (2004a), “Panel Data Analysis of Regulatory Factors Shaping Environmental

Performance,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 86 (1), pg. 391-401.

Earnhart, Dietrich (2004b), “Regulatory Factors Shaping Environmental Performance at Publicly-Owned

38

Page 39: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

Treatment Plants,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 48 (1), pg. 655-681.

Earnhart, Dietrich (2009), “The Influence of Facility Characteristics and Permit Conditions on the Effects

of Environmental Regulatory Deterrence,” Journal of Regulatory Economics, 36 (3), pg. 247-273.

Earnhart, Dietrich and Kathleen Segerson (2012), “The Influence of Financial Status on the Effectiveness

of Environmental Enforcement,” Journal of Public Economics, 96, pg. 670-684.

EPA (1990), “A Primer on the Office of Water Enforcement and Permits and Its Programs,” Office of

Water, Environmental Protection Agency, Washington, DC, March 1990.

EPA (1997a), EPA Strategic Plan, EPA/190-R-97-002.

EPA (1997b), Chemical Industry National Environmental Baseline Report 1990-1994, Office of

Enforcement and Compliance Assurance, Environmental Protection Agency, EPA 305-R-96-002,

October 1997.

EPA (1999), EPA/CMA Root Cause Analysis Pilot Project: An Industry Survey, Environmental

Protection Agency, EPA-305-R-99-001, May 1999.

EPA (2000), U.S. EPA Strategic Plan 2000, Washington, DC: Environmental Protection Agency.

Glicksman, R. and Dietrich Earnhart (2007), “The Comparative Effectiveness of Government

Interventions on Environmental Performance in the Chemical Industry,” Stanford Environmental

Law Journal, 26, p. 112-139.

Harrington, Donna R. (2012), “Effectiveness of State Pollution Prevention Programs and Policies,”

Contemporary Economic Policy, forthcoming.

Harrison, Kathryn (1995), “Is Cooperation the Answer? Canadian Environmental Enforcement in

Comparative Context,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 14, pg. 221-223.

Heckman, James (1979), “Sample Selection Bias as Specification Error,” Econometrica, 47, pg. 153-161.

Jaffe, Adam B. and Robert N. Stavins (1995), “Dynamic Incentives of Environmental Regulation: The

39

Page 40: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

Effects of Alternative Policy Instruments on Technology Diffusion,” Journal of Environmental

Economics and Management, 29 (3), pg. S43-63.

Kagan, Robert, Neil Gunningham, and Dorothy Thornton (2005), “Explaining Corporate Environmental

Performance: How Does Regulation Matter?” Law and Society Review, 37, pg. 51-61.

Karpoff, Jonathan, John R. Lott, Jr. and Eric W. Wehrly (2005), “The Reputational Penalties for

Environmental Violations: Empirical Evidence,” Journal of Law and Economics, 48, pg. 653-

675.

Malloy, Timothy (2003), “Regulation, Compliance and the Firm”, Temple Law Review, 76, pg. 451-454.

Markel, David (2000), “The Role of Deterrence-Based Enforcement in a ‘Reinvented’ State / Federal

Relationship: The Divide Between Theory and Reality,” Harvard Environmental Law Review,

24, pg. 1-5.

Markel, David (2005), “‘Slack’ in the Administrative State and its Implications for Governance: The

Issue of Accountability,” Oregon Law Review, 84, pg. 1-22.

Mintz, Joel (1995), Enforcement at the EPA: High Stakes and Hard Choices, Austin: University of Texas

Press.

Paxson, M.C. (1992), “Response Rates for 183 Studies,” Working Paper Washington State University,

Washington State University.

Polinsky, A. Mitchell and Steven Shavell (2000), “The Economic Theory of Public Enforcement of

Law,” Journal of Economic Literature, 38 (March), p. 45-76.

Rechtschaffen, Clifford (1998), “Deterrence vs. Cooperation and the Evolving Theory of Environmental

Enforcement,” Southern California Law Review, 71, pg. 1181-1188.

Rechtschaffen, Clifford (2004), “Promoting Pragmatic Risk Regulation: Is Enforcement Discretion the

Answer?” University of Kansas Law Review, 52, pg. 1327-1361.

40

Page 41: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

Rechtschaffen, Clifford and David Markell (2003), Reinventing Environmental Enforcement and the

State/Federal Relationship, Washington, DC: Environmental Law Institute.

Sah, Raaj (1991), “Social Osmosis and Patterns of Crime,” Journal of Political Economy, 99 (6), pg.

1272-1295.

Scholz, John (1984), “Cooperation, Deterrence, and the Ecology of Regulatory Enforcement,” Law and

Society Review, 18, pg. 179-180.

Shimshack, Jay P. and Michael B. Ward (2005), "Regulator Reputation, Enforcement, and Environmental

Compliance," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 50, pg. 519-540.

Spence, David (2001), “Can the Second Generation Learn from the First? Understanding the Politics of

Regulatory Reform,” Capitol University Law Review, 29, pg. 205-207.

Stahl, Michael M. (1995), “Enforcement in Transition,” The Environmental Forum, 12, pg. 19-25.

Stoughton, Mark, Jeanne Herb, Jennifer Sullivan, and Michael Crow (2001), “Toward Integrated

Approaches to Compliance Assurance,” Environmental Law Report, 31, pg. 11266-11283.

Vandenbergh, Michael (2003), “Beyond Elegance: A Testable Typology of Social Norms in Corporate

Environmental Compliance,” Stanford Environmental Law Journal, 22, pg. 63-64.

Wasserman, Cheryl (1984), “Improving the Efficiency and Effectiveness of Compliance Monitoring and

Enforcement of Environmental Policies, United States: A National Review,” OECD.

Webster, Richard (2007), “Federal Environmental Enforcement: Is Less More?” Fordham Environmental

Law Review, 18, pg. 303-333.

Wooldridge, Jeffrey (2003), Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, 2 edition, South-nd

Western.

41

Page 42: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

Table 1Descriptive Statistics of Variables: Means, Standard Deviations (in parentheses)

Variable Variable Description [Units]TSS

SampleBOD

SampleDependent Variable

Discharge Ratio Ratio of measured discharges to permitted discharges [ratio]0.232 0.230

(0.183) (0.396)Primary Regressor

CooperativeEnforcementApproach

Facility’s perceived fairness of regulator’s treatment: =1 ifalways fair;= 0 if sometimes fair / unfair [dummy indicator]

0.838(0.370)

0.901(0.300)

Control FactorsFirm EnvironmentalEmployees

Ratio of firm-level environmental employees to all firm-level employees [ratio]

(0.370) 0.023(0.140) (0.028)

Organic ChemicalSub-sector

= 1 if facility in organic chemical sub-sector; = 0 otherwise(benchmark: “other chemical”) [dummy indicator]

0.625 0.683(0.486) (0.467)

Inorganic ChemicalSub-sector

= 1 if facility in inorganic chemical sub-sector; = 0otherwise (benchmark:“other chemical”) [dummy indicator]

0.222 0.146(0.417) (0.355)

TreatmentTechnology

Treatment technology presence (vs absence): Averagebetween TSS and BOD technology [dummy indicator avg]

0.920 0.935(0.202) (0.212)

Audits Number of audits conducted per year [count per year]2.764

(8.936)3.195

(9.651)Firm OwnershipStructure

= 1 if firm is publicly held, = 0 otherwise [dummyindicator]

0.917 0.935(0.277) (0.248)

InformalEnforcement Threat

Ratio of informal enforcement actions against other similarfacilities and number of others [count per facility]

0.110 0.100(0.156) (0.151)

Formal Non-PenaltyEnforcement Threat

Ratio of formal non-penalties against other similar facilitiesand number of others [count per facility]

0.043 0.039(0.057) (0.056)

PenaltyEnforcement Threat

Ratio of penalties against other similar facilities andnumber of others [$ per facility]

1.235 1.446(5.944) (6.411)

State InspectionsThreat

Ratio of state inspections at other similar facilities andnumber of others [count per facility]

1.419 1.525(1.319) (1.404)

Federal InspectionsThreat

Ratio of federal inspections at other similar facilities andnumber of others [count per facility]

0.051(0.070)

0.051(0.074)

EPA Region 2= 1 if facility in EPA Region 2; = 0 otherwise (benchmark:Regions 1, 8, 9, 10) [dummy indicator]

0.083 0.098(0.277) (0.298)

EPA Region 3= 1 if facility in EPA Region 3; = 0 otherwise(benchmark: Regions 1, 8, 9, 10) [dummy indicator]

0.111 0.163(0.315) (0.371)

EPA Region 4= 1 if facility in EPA Region 4; = 0 otherwise(benchmark: Regions 1, 8, 9, 10) [dummy indicator]

0.347 0.309(0.478) (0.464)

EPA Region 5= 1 if facility in EPA Region 5; = 0 otherwise (benchmark:Regions 1, 8, 9, 10) [dummy indicator]

0.083 0.098(0.277) (0.298)

EPA Region 6= 1 if facility in EPA Region 6; = 0 otherwise(benchmark: Regions 1, 8, 9, 10) [dummy indicator]

0.347 0.317(0.478) (0.467)

EPA Region 7= 1 if facility in EPA Region 7; = 0 otherwise(benchmark: Regions 1, 8, 9, 10) [dummy indicator]

0.014 0.000(0.117) 0.000

Year 2001 = 1 if year is 2001; = 0 if year is 2000 [dummy indicator]0.507 0.504

(0.502) (0.502)

Local CommunityPressure

Facility’s perceived need to respond to local communityconcerns: = 1 if quite bit/great deal, = 0 if little/some[dummy indicator]

0.929 0.966

(0.258) (0.181)

Number of Observations 144 123

42

Page 43: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

Table 2

Anderson-Hsiao Estimation of TSS Discharge Ratios

Variable Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

Cooperative Approach0.066

(0.014)** 0.074

(0.009)*** 0.090

(0.003)*** - 0.484

(0.000)***

Local Community Pressure- 0.152(0.008)

*** - 0.515(0.000)

***

Cooperative Approach × Local Community Pressure0.615

(0.000)***

Organic Chemical Sub-sector0.072

(0.090)* 0.052

(0.191)

Inorganic Chemical Sub-sector0.020

(0.671)0.045

(0.306)

Treatment Technology0.115

(0.097)* 0.270

(0.000)***

Audits- 0.003(0.015)

** - 0.003(0.015)

**

Firm Ownership Structure0.031

(0.445)- 0.026(0.512)

Firm Environmental Employees- 0.547(0.001)

- 0.165(0.314)

Informal Enforcement Threat a0.052

(0.842)0.052

(0.842)

Formal Non-Penalty Enforcement Threat a- 1.206(0.094)

* - 1.206(0.094)

*

Penalty Enforcement Threat a0.006

(0.478)0.006

(0.478)

State Inspections Threat a- 0.147(0.140)

- 0.147(0.140)

Federal Inspections Threat a0.018

(0.953)0.018

(0.953)

Lagged TSS Discharge Ratio0.086

(0.644)0.085

(0.647)0.078

(0.668)0.078

(0.668)

Year 2001- 0.002(0.917)

0.007(0.809)

0.007(0.809)

F-test: EPA Regions 2.44 ** 3.13 *** 5.31 ***

F-test: Cooperative Approach, Community Pressure 6.57 *** 5.01 ***

# of Observations 144 144 144 144

Robust p-values shown in parentheses.Asterisks indicate level of statistical significance: * 10%; ** 5%; *** 1%. EPA regions are included in the models but individual coefficients are not reported.Regression also includes a constant term.Regressors enter the estimation in log form.a

43

Page 44: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

Table 3Anderson-Hsiao Estimation of BOD Discharge Ratios

Variable Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Cooperative Approach0.163

(0.354)0.251

(0.166)0.533

(0.041)**

Local Community Pressure0.127

(0.821)

Organic Chemical Sub-sector0.138

(0.590)

Inorganic Chemical Sub-sector0.143

(0.676)

Treatment Technology0.219

(0.671)

Audits- 0.001(0.520)

Firm Ownership Structure0.421

(0.274)

Firm Environmental Employees1.141

(0.713)

Informal Enforcement Threat a - 0.031(0.839)

Formal Non-Penalty Enforcement Threat a- 0.033(0.950)

Penalty Enforcement Threat a - 0.002(0.797)

State Inspections Threat a- 0.047(0.241)

Federal Inspections Threat a - 0.181(0.542)

Lagged TSS Discharge Ratio- 0.060(0.000)

*** - 0.059(0.000)

*** - 0.060(0.000)

***

Year 20010.007

(0.668)0.008

(0.733)

F-test: EPA Regions 1.410 2.14 *

F-test: Cooperative Approach, Community Pressure 2.13

# of Observations 123 123 123

Robust p-values shown in parentheses.Asterisks indicate level of statistical significance: * 10%; ** 5%; *** 1%. EPA regions are included in the models but individual coefficients are not reported.Regression also includes a constant term.Regressors enter the estimation in log form.a

44

Page 45: Coercive vs. Cooperative Enforcement: The Effect of ... Effect of Enforcement Approach on Environmental Performance Abstract: A spirited debate explores the comparative merits of two

Table 4

Marginal Effect of Enforcement Approach on TSS Discharge Ratios:Conditional on Local Community Pressure

Type ofEnforcement

Approach

Strength of LocalCommunity Pressure

Marginal Effect

Magnitude 0H : Effect = 0Test Statistic

0H : Effect = 0p-value

Coercive

Little / Some 0.484 0.000

Quite Bit / Great Deal - 0.131 0.13 0.000

Average - 0.087 0.002

Cooperative

Little / Some - 0.484 0.000

Quite Bit / Great Deal 0.131 0.13 0.000

Average 0.087 0.002

45