chapter six aig 1 chapter six aig in the crisis abstract ... · chapter six aig 2 stochastic...

31
Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract: The financial structure of the derivatives insured by AIG with credit default swaps (CDS) was ultimately related to the systemic risk from the inability of the mortgagors to service their debts. AIG made several serious mistakes. First: The estimate of the drift of the capital gain, which drove the bubble, was based upon the unsustainable growth of the housing price index 2004-06. A collapse would occur when the unsustainable capital gain declined below the interest rate. Second, risk was underestimated because AIG ignored the negative correlation between the capital gains and the liabilities/claims. The CDS claims grew when the value of the insured obligations declined. This set off collateral requirements, and the stability of AIG was undermined. The solution for the optimal insurance liabilities on the basis of SOC is derived. The SOC approach is a generalization of the contributions of the economics and actuarial literature. The chapter concludes with an evaluation of the government bailout. Introduction. At its peak, American International Group (AIG) was one of the largest and most successful companies in the world boasting a Triple-A credit rating, over $1 trillion in assets, and 76 million customers in more than 130 countries. Yet the sophistication of AIGs operations was not matched by an equally sophisticated risk-management structure. This poor management structure, combined with a lack of regulatory oversight, led AIG to accumulate staggering amounts of risk, especially in its subsidiary, AIG Financial Products (AIGFP). I draw upon the Congressional Oversight Panel Report (COP, 2010) that describes AIG’s role in the financial market crisis. Part 6.1 describes what happened to AIG in the 2007-08 crisis. Part 6.2 sketches the economics literature and the actuarial literature. The conclusions from the economics literature are that “Despite extensive researches about the determinants of corporate capital structure, the theories of capital structure remain one of the most controversial issues in modern corporate finance” (Shim, 2010). The actuarial literature on capital requirements and risk was discussed in chapter four. The stochastic optimal (SOC) approach in the following sections is a generalization of the contributions of the economics and actuarial literature. Its components are: the criterion function, the

Upload: others

Post on 01-Sep-2019

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 1

Chapter Six

AIG in the Crisis

Abstract: The financial structure of the derivatives insured by AIG with credit default swaps (CDS) was ultimately related to the systemic risk from the inability of the mortgagors to service their debts. AIG made several serious mistakes. First: The estimate of the drift of the capital gain, which drove the bubble, was based upon the unsustainable growth of the housing price index 2004-06. A collapse would occur when the unsustainable capital gain declined below the interest rate. Second, risk was underestimated because AIG ignored the negative correlation between the capital gains and the liabilities/claims. The CDS claims grew when the value of the insured obligations declined. This set off collateral requirements, and the stability of AIG was undermined. The solution for the optimal insurance liabilities on the basis of SOC is derived. The SOC approach is a generalization of the contributions of the economics and actuarial literature. The chapter concludes with an evaluation of the government bailout.

Introduction.

At its peak, American International Group (AIG) was one of the largest and most

successful companies in the world boasting a Triple-A credit rating, over $1 trillion in

assets, and 76 million customers in more than 130 countries. Yet the sophistication of

AIG’s operations was not matched by an equally sophisticated risk-management

structure. This poor management structure, combined with a lack of regulatory oversight,

led AIG to accumulate staggering amounts of risk, especially in its subsidiary, AIG

Financial Products (AIGFP). I draw upon the Congressional Oversight Panel Report

(COP, 2010) that describes AIG’s role in the financial market crisis.

Part 6.1 describes what happened to AIG in the 2007-08 crisis. Part 6.2 sketches

the economics literature and the actuarial literature. The conclusions from the economics

literature are that “Despite extensive researches about the determinants of corporate

capital structure, the theories of capital structure remain one of the most controversial

issues in modern corporate finance” (Shim, 2010). The actuarial literature on capital

requirements and risk was discussed in chapter four. The stochastic optimal (SOC)

approach in the following sections is a generalization of the contributions of the

economics and actuarial literature. Its components are: the criterion function, the

Page 2: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 2

stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the

optimal capital requirement on the basis of SOC is in part 6.5. Part 6.6 is an evaluation of

the government bailout.

6.1. AIG

AIG occupied an important role in the financial system. Of all the possible losers

in the financial crisis discussed in chapter five, AIG should have been the most concerned

with risk management. The AIG Financial Products AIGFP subsidiary sold credit default

swaps (CDSs) involving three parties. Party 1 the obligor sells the “reference securities”

to party 2. The latter are security houses, hedge funds that purchase protection from party

3, who are banks and insurance companies, which issue the protection. In many cases

municipalities are required to carry insurance in order to market their bonds, or to obtain

a high credit rating. The CDS are privately negotiated contracts that function in a similar

manner to insurance contacts, but their payoff structure is closer to a put option.

AIGFP’s obligations were guaranteed by AIG’s triple-A rating, which facilitated

borrowing at low interest rates. Ultimately, however, it made it difficult to isolate AIGFP

from its parent, with disastrous consequences. Bernanke characterized AIGFP as a hedge

fund attached to a large and stable insurance company. AIGFP entered the credit

derivatives market in 1998 when it underwrote its first CDS.

Over time AIGFP became a central player in the fast-growing CDS market.

AIGFP’s corporate arbitrage CDS portfolio was comprised of CDS contracts written on

corporate debt and collateralized loan obligations (CLOs). The collateral pools backing

the corporate debt portfolio included baskets of investment-grade corporate bonds and

loans of commercial and industrial loans of large banks. The collateral pools backing the

multi-sector CDOs included prime, Alt-A, and subprime residential mortgage-backed

securities (RMBS), commercial mortgage-backed securities (CMBS), other asset-backed

securities (ABS). CDS written on corporate debt, CLOs, and multi-sector CDOs serve as

protection against “credit events” of the issuer of the reference obligation, including

bankruptcy, failure to pay, acceleration of payments on the issuer’s obligations, default

on the issuer’s obligations, restructuring of the issuer’s debt, and similar events.

Page 3: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 3

AIGFP’s operating income grew from $131 million in 1994 to $949 million in

2006, 18% pa, paralleling the boom in the overall derivatives market, as well as the CDS

market. While the credit markets provided a source of steady profits for AIGFP, the

division’s operating income represented a relatively small percentage of AIG’s total

operating income, contributing just 7 percent to firm-wide net income in 2006. More

importantly, as events made clear, the risk involved in this business was dramatically

disproportionate to the revenue produced. For example, losses in 2007 totaled $11.5

billion, twice the aggregate net income produced by this division from 1994 to 2006.

AIG models showed that there would be no defaults on any of the bond payments

that AIG swaps had insured. AIGFP did not have its own model or otherwise try to value

the CDO portfolio that it guaranteed through CDS nor did it hedge its exposure. AIG

mistakenly believed that it would only have to pay counterparties if holders of the super-

senior tranches insured incurred actual losses. AIGFP relied on Gorton’s actuarial model

that did not provide a tool for monitoring the CDO’s market value. Gorton’s model had

determined with 99.85% confidence that the owners of super-senior tranches of the

CDO’s insured by AIGFP would never suffer real economic losses (FCIC, pp. 266-67).

The company’s auditor PWC apparently was also not aware of the collateral

requirements. PWC concluded that “..the risk of default on the [AIG] portfolio has been

effectively removed as a result of a risk management perspective…”.

The bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers was a cataclysmic event. Investors began to

compare the types of securities held by AIG and by Lehman. Goldman-Sachs was an

AIG counterparty, which was very much concerned with the value of AIG’s collateral.

The G-S executives concluded that the Gorton/AIG models were irrelevant because the

contracts required collateral to be posted if market values of the insured securities

declined, irrespective of only long term cash losses. G-S estimated that the average

decline in the market value of the bonds was 15%. With leverage this would translate into

very large declines in equity.

Until the dispute with G-S, AIG relied on Gorton’s model that did not estimate

the market value of the underlying securities. So G-S mark to market caught AIG by

surprise. By August 2007 AIG publicly disclosed, for the first time, the $79 billion in

Page 4: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 4

CDS’s on super-senior CDO tranches. Sixty four billion were backed by subprime and

nineteen billion were written on risky BBB collateral. By January 2008, AIG still did not

have a reliable way to determine the market price of the securities on which it had written

credit protection.

AIG valued its Alt-A and subprime mortgage backed securities at 1.7 – 2 times

the values used by Lehman. During the summer of 2008, AIG faced increasing demands

from their CDS customers for cash security – collateral calls – totaling tens of billions of

dollars. AIG was not able to provide the required additional collateral. This put AIG’s

credit rating under pressure, which in turn led to even greater collateral calls, creating

even greater pressure on AIG’s credit.

In September 2008, AIG suffered a liquidity crisis, because the firm lacked the

liquidity to meet collateral demands from its customers. In only a matter of months AIG’s

worldwide empire had collapsed, brought down by the company’s underestimation of

risk. The AIG liquidity crisis led to the largest government bailout of a private company

in US history, totaling $182 billion. Maurice Greenberg, the former CEO, characterized

the bailout as a nationalization of AIG, was bewildered by the situation and was at a loss

over how the entire situation got out of control as it did.

The resulting downgrades of AIG securities were, in the opinion of Charles

Prince, the precipitating event in the financial crisis. The Office of Thrift Supervision

(OTS) was the only regulator that had explicit authority to look at the entire company,

and the only regulator with any authority over AIGFP. Acting Director Polakoff

acknowledged that AIG did not foresee the extent of risk concentration and profound

systemic impact CDS caused within AIG. He stated that OTS should have directed AIG

to stop originating CDSs and begin reducing its CDS portfolio before December 2005.

Table 6.1 shows that the crisis of both AIG and of the financial sector was

unexpected by the market and pervasive. Column 1 is the spread TED between the

interest rate on interbank loans and the US Treasury bill rate. Column 2 is 3- month

LIBOR – OIS overnight index spread rate. It is a measure of how likely borrowing banks

will default. Column 3 is a measure of the cost of insurance, based upon CDS.

Page 5: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 5

Table 6.1 AIG and the Financial Crisis, fall 2008

Date 2008

(1) TED spread bps

(2) 3-month Libor – OIS spread bps

(3) AIG CDS spread bps

(4) AIG stock price ($)

(5) 3-month treasury bond yield (%)

(6) D-J industrial average

Aug. 15

96 77 300.7 459.8 1.85 11,659

Sept. 15

180 105 1527.6 95.2 1.02 10,917.5

Oct. 15

433 345 1816.9 48.6 0.22 8577.9

Nov. 7

198 176 2923.9 42.2 0.31 8943.8

Source: COP (2010, Figure 14). (1) Interest rate on interbank loans – US Treasury bill rate; (2) 3- month LIBOR – OIS overnight index spread rate; (3) A CDS rate of y basis points (bps) means that it costs $1000y to insure $10 million of debt for five years..

Page 6: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 6

In August 2008 markets were relatively tranquil. A crisis was not anticipated. One

month later the crisis appeared. The cost of CDS insurance (column 3) was five times

higher and the stock price of AIG fell by 80%. The financial crisis reached panic

proportions in October. Banks were reluctant to lend to each other, as seen in the drastic

rises in the TED spread and 3 month Libor – OIS spreads. In October, the CDS spread

was six times the August level. The price of AIG’s stock was 90% below its August

level. The market lost confidence in AIG’s ability to insure financial assets. The flight to

safety is seen in columns 5 and 6. Treasury bill interest rates fell as the D-J industrial

average fell and risk measures rose. The financial collapse was unexpected, sudden and

pervasive.

This example leads one to ask the following questions. [Q1]What is an optimal

liabilities/net worth or capital requirement for a large (non-life) insurer that balances the

expected growth against risk? [Q2]What is an optimal risk? [Q3] What are theoretically

founded early warning signals of a crisis? I explain why the application of stochastic

optimal control (SOC)/dynamic risk management is an effective approach to answer

these questions. The theoretically derived early warning signal of a crisis is the excess

liability ratio, equal to the difference between the actual and optimal ratio. This SOC

analysis should be used by those charged with surveillance of financial markets.

6.2. The economics and actuarial literature

Since the Modigliani-Miller irrelevance proposition, and despite extensive

research for decades, there is little consensus on how firms choose their capital structure

(Shim, 2010). Both the literature and regulations have departed greatly from the

irrelevance proposition. The banking studies use the ratio of risk weighted assets/total

assets as a measure of portfolio risk (Aggarwal-Jacques, 2001). It is based upon the view

that portfolio risk is mostly determined by how assets are allocated and the different risk

types. This is inadequate for an insurance industry, since the liability side of the portfolio

must also be taken into account. Hence an alternative measure of portfolio risk for an

insurer is the volatility of asset/liability ratio (Cummins and Sommer, 1996). This

measure takes into account the variance/covariance matrix between the vectors of assets

Page 7: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 7

and liabilities. The appropriate level of capital is determined mostly by the insurer’s risk

exposure.

There is a variety of theories. The tradeoff theory postulates that firms seek to

maintain a target/optimal debt ratio by balancing the tax advantages of debt financing

against the costs of financial distress (Meyers, 2001). The target ratios may vary from

firm to firm. The pecking order theory of capital structure states that firms prefer retained

earnings as the main source of financing new investment followed by debt financing

followed by new issues of equity. Thus more profitable firms have less need for leverage.

The financial theory suggests that capital structure is determined by firm specific

characteristics such as profitability, growth opportunities and size of firm.

Korteweg (2010) reviews the literature on net benefits to leverage and then

estimates the market’s valuation of the net benefits to leverage by using panel data from

1994 to 2004, identified from market values and betas of the company’s debt and equity.

The literature tests the trade off between debt versus equity financing by running cross

sectional regressions of leverage on a set of variables that proxy for the benefits and costs

of leverage. The problem with this regression approach is that it is not possible to detect

whether firms have too much or too little debt. The implicit assumption is that firms are

on average optimally leveraged. This assumption lacks cogency in light of the analysis

especially in chapter three above. High profits mechanically lower leverage debt/equity

so that cross section regressions show a negative relation between profitability and

leverage, even though optimal debt ratios are positively related to profitability.

The article by Volchan ( 2007) reflects the state of the art in actuarial risk science.

In chapter four, I focused upon Volchan’s excellent discussion of the Cramér-Lundberg

model, and I generalized the Classical gambler’s ruin problems. My conclusions in

chapter four were that the Cramér-Lundberg analysis is inadequate to evaluate the

risk/return in the AIG case. First, the asset side of the equation for the change in surplus

is ignored. The insurance company has assets against the liabilities that bring in income.

Second, the value of the claims against AIG are highly negatively correlated with the

value of the assets. When the market value of the insured assets decline, AIG must either

compensate the insurer for the difference or put up more collateral. Third, the assets that

Page 8: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 8

are insured by AIG are quite closely correlated with the assets in AIG’s portfolio.

6.3 Stochastic Optimal Control (SOC) approach to optimal liabilities of a large insurer

The message from the actuarial literature above is that a risk measure should reflect the

economic elements to measure risk, the economic situation, and that the problem is to

find the optimal “required capital”, liabilities/net worth, and risk to maximize expected

surplus. Neither the economics literature nor the Cramér-Lundberg literature surveyed

above answers questions [Q1]-[Q3] whereas the (SOC) approach is directly concerned

with these questions. As described above, the AIGFP followed policies that were far from

optimal, which led to the collapse of AIG. I derive a warning signal of financial difficulty

by focusing upon the difference between the actual liabilities and the optimal liabilities.

SOC is a dynamic optimization, where key variables are stochastic, that I apply to

the AIG case. Technical mathematical details are in the appendix to chapter four.

My criterion function is the maximization of the expected logarithm of surplus

(net worth) at a future date. Surplus X = A – L is assets A less L liabilities. This is: V(X)

= max ln X(T) at terminal date T. There are several advantages of this criterion. First, it is

a risk averse strategy because the logarithm is a concave function. Unexpected bad events

are weighted more heavily than unexpected good events. Second, the focus is upon the

surplus X, which is an objective measure of economic performance. This measure of

performance is relevant for stockholders, the parties that are insured by the firm and

regulators. The control variable of the insurance company is the ratio of insurance

liabilities/surplus. The ratio of assets/surplus = leverage is equal to one plus the ratio of

liabilities/surplus.

The dynamics of the surplus, equation (6.1) is the sum of several components.

Change in surplus = (premium rate) liabilities + (return + capital gain) assets

– (claims on the company related to liabilities) (6.1)

The first term in the change in surplus is the premiums, equal to the premium rate

times the insurance liabilities. The second term is the return on assets, which has two

components. The first is the productivity of assets, which is deterministic, and the second

Page 9: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 9

is the capital gain on the assets. The third term concerns claims on the company that

reduce the surplus. Claims may be losses to the insured parties and/or collateral calls by

the parties that have insured assets whose Mark-to-Market (M-t-M) prices have fallen, as

discussed above.

An increase in the liability ratio will increase expected growth of surplus if the

return on investment plus premiums exceeds the claims. There are two stochastic

variables in this model. First, the productivity of assets is observed, but the future capital

gains are unknown when the investment decision is made. Second, the future claims are

unknown when the insurance policies are sold. Third, there will be a correlation between

the capital gain on assets and the claims. Most certainly, the correlation is negative.

When asset prices, such as the index of housing prices fell, the claims against AIG

increased, either for defaults or for collateral calls. The latter is what led to AIG’s

downfall.

The SOC approach derives an optimal liability ratio conditional upon the

stochastic processes. The true stochastic process is unknown. Alternative stochastic

processes imply different optimal liability ratios or optimal leverages. I start with a

general model of the stochastic process and derive the optimal liability/surplus ratio,

optimal risk, and optimal expected growth. Then I consider several specifications of the

stochastic processes, as was done in chapters four and five. These are special cases of the

general model. In all cases, the capital gain and claims rate are negatively correlated.

When asset prices fall, insurance claims rise.

A standard of optimality must be based upon sustainable stochastic processes. By

contrast, the market optimized on the basis of unsustainable stochastic processes, which

led to the bubble and its subsequent collapse.

Given the stochastic process, an optimal liability ratio is derived using the method

explained in chapter four, making the appropriate changes. The expected growth of

surplus or net worth is a concave function of the liability ratio, figure 4.2. It is maximal

when the optimal ratio is chosen. As the liability ratio exceeds the derived optimal, the

expected growth declines and the risk (variance) rises, figures 4.1, 4.3. If the liability

ratio is less than the optimal, expected growth is unduly sacrificed to reduce risk.

Leverage is equal to one plus the liability ratio; and the capital requirement is the inverse

Page 10: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 10

of the leverage. I focus upon the liability ratio, and the optimal capital requirement and

optimal leverage follow.

The main theoretical results are as follows. (1) The optimal liability ratio is not a

number, but a function. It is proportional to: the drift of the capital gain less the drift of

the claims plus the current productivity of capital plus the insurance premium rate less a

risk premium. The factor of proportionality is the reciprocal of risk elements. Therefore

the optimal liability ratio or capital requirement will vary over time. (2) Define the excess

liability ratio as the actual liability ratio less the optimal ratio. For a sufficiently high

excess liability or debt, the expected growth is zero or negative and the variance is high.

See figures 4.1, 4.2. The probability of a decline in net worth or a debt crisis is directly

related to the excess liability or debt ratio. This is our Early Warning Signal (EWS) of a

crisis.

6.4. Mathematical Analysis

The expected logarithm of the surplus of the insurer is the growth variable that is

consistent with the insurance literature. Let V(X,T) be the expected logarithm of surplus

X(T) at time T relative to its initial value X(0). The stochastic optimal control problem is

to select ratios f(t) = L(t)/X(t) of liabilities L(t) to surplus X(t) during the period (0,T) that

will maximize V(X,T) in equation (6.2). The maximum value is V*(X,T). Ratio f*(t) is

the optimal leverage, or 1/f*(t) is the optimal capital requirement and will vary over time.

The stochastic optimal control tells us what is an optimal and what is an “excessive”

leverage.

V*(X,T) = maxf E ln [X(T)/X(0)] (6.2)

f = L/X = liabilities/surplus, A/X = 1 + f = leverage

As explained in chapter four, an advantage of the criterion function equation (6.2) is that

the model can be solved by using the Ito equation rather than dynamic programming, the role

of the key variables in deriving the optimal capital requirement is clearly seen, it corresponds

to an explicit economic objective and the model can be easily implemented for empirical

purposes.

Page 11: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 11

The change in surplus dX(t) in equation (6.3) is equal to the earnings of the insurer plus

the revaluation of assets – the capital gains or losses – less the claims paid out. The earnings

are : (i) the income from premiums π L(t) equal to the premium π per dollar of insurance

liabilities times L(t) the liabilities plus (ii) the earnings from the assets βA(t), where A(t) is the

value of assets and β is the deterministic rate of return. (iii) The revaluation of assets, the

capital gain or loss on assets, is [dP(t)/P(t)]A(t), where P(t) is the price index of the asset –

such as the house price index in the AIG case. The change in price dP(t) and claims C(t) are

stochastic. The first term in brackets is earnings and the second term in brackets is the capital

gains. The length of the period is dt.

dX(t) = [π L(t)dt + β A(t)dt ] + [dP(t)/P(t))A(t)] – C(t). (6.3)

The dynamics of the process to derive E[ln X(T)] is based upon equation (6.3). There are

several possibilities for modeling the stochastic processes for the claims C(t) and capital gains

dP(t)/P(t). I work with a general model, as I did in chapters four and five, and then consider

specifications as I did in chapter five.

Assume, for simplicity, that the premium rate π is given. At this premium rate there is

an elastic demand for insurance and the insurer decides how much insurance L(t) to offer at

that rate. L(t)/X(t)= f(t) is the control variable. Let the claims C(t) be described by stochastic

differential equation (6.4). They are proportional to L(t) the amount of insurance liabilities.

Claims are the required payments to the insured holders of CDS, due to either defaults of the

obligors or for collateral calls when the prices of the insured securities decline. The latter led

to the downfall of AIG. The mean of claims C(t) is cL(t)dt. The variance of the claims

is σc2L2(t) dt. Brownian Motion term dwc has independent and stationary increments, with zero

expectations, as assumed in the classical literature.

C(t) = [c dt + σcdwc]L(t). (6.4)

E(dwc) = 0, E(dwc)2 = dt. (6.4a)

Stochastic differential equation (6.5) concerns the capital gain/loss term dP(t)/P(t). The

time varying drift is a(t)dt and the diffusion is σpdwp. This is a general formulation. The

variance of the capital gain is σ2p dt. The dwp term has independent and stationary increments.

Page 12: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 12

dP(t)/P(t) = a(t) dt + σpdwp (6.5)

E(dwp) = 0, E(dwp)2 = dt. (6.5a)

The two Brownian Motion terms are expected to be negatively correlated, equation

(6.6). Correlation coefficient -1 < ρ < 0. When there is a period with capital losses dP(t)/P(t) <

0, then claims against AIG including collateral calls are most likely to be high. This condition

accurately described the period of the AIG crisis with CDS, part 6.1.

E(dwp dwc) = ρ dt. -1 < ρ < 0 (6.6)

Using equations (6.4) – (6.6 ) in (6.3), derive the stochastic differential equation (6.7) for the

change in surplus dX(t). The first set in brackets contains the deterministic part and the second

set contains the stochastic part: the randomness of the price of the assets less the randomness of

the claims.

dX(t) = [πL(t) + βA(t) – cL(t) + A(t)a(t)] dt + [A(t)σpdwp – L(t)σcdwc]. (6.7)

X = A-L = surplus, A = assets, L = liabilties, β = return on assets , π = premium rate, C =

claims, a(t) = drift capital gain, stochastic BM terms dwp, dwc. Correlation between them is ρ <

0. Leverage = A/X = (1+f)), debt ratio f = L/X.

I follow the analysis in chapters 4 and 5. The control variable is f(t) = L(t)/X(t) the ratio of

liabilties/surplus. Write (6.7) as (6.8) in terms of the liability, or debt, ratio f(t), which is the

control variable. Abbreviate it where terms M(f(t)) and N(f(t)) correspond respectively to the

two terms in brackets in equation (6.8). Term M(f(t)) is deterministic and N(t) is stochastic

with an expectation of N(f(t)) = 0.

dX(t)/X(t) = [π f(t) + β(1+ f(t)) – cf(t) + (1+ f(t))a(t) ] dt +[(1+ f(t))σpdwp – f(t)σcdwc] (6.8)

dX(t)/X(t) = M(f(t)) dt + N(f(t)).

M[f(t)] =[π f(t) + β(1+ f(t)) – cf(t) + (1+ f(t))a(t)]

N(f(t)) = [(1+ f(t))σpdwp – f(t)σcdwc]. E[N(f)] = 0, E[M(f)dt,N(f)] = 0 .

Page 13: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 13

6.5 . Solution of the for the Optimum liability ratio in General Model

As explained in chapter 4/appendix, using the Ito equation, solve equation (6.8) for the

expectation of d[ln X(t)]. This is equation (6.9) in terms of M(f(t)), which I call MEAN, and

R(f(t)), which I call RISK. A great advantage of this approach is that it can be interpreted as a

M-V “Mean-Variance” analysis, as was done in figures 4.1 and 4.2.

E[d ln X(t)] = M(f(t)) – (1/2)R(f(t)) (6.9)

RISK R(f(t)) = [(1+f)2σp2 + f2σc

2 – 2f(1+f)ρσpσc] (6.10)

MEAN M(f(t)) = [π f(t) + β(1+ f(t)) – cf(t) + (1+ f(t))a(t)] (6.11).

The optimal liability/surplus f*(t) in equation (6.12) is the liability ratio that maximizes

E[d ln X(t)] in equation (6.9). Term σ2 = (σ2p + σ2

c – 2ρσpσc) is in effect the variance of the

difference between the capital gains and the claims, var (dP/P – C(t)). The negative correlation

ρ < 0 increases the risk.

The first term in brackets in (6.12) for the optimum ratio is (π – c) the premium less the drift of

the claims plus (β +a(t)) the sum of the deterministic rate of return on assets plus the time

varying drift of the capital gain. The second term and the denominator involve the risks of the

capital gains and claims.

f*(t) = argmaxf {E[d ln X(t)] = [M(f(t)) – (1/2)R(f(t))]} (6.12)

= [(π – c) + (β +a(t))] – (σ2p – ρσpσc)]/(σ2

p + σ2c – 2ρσpσc)

σ2 = (σ2p + σ2

c – 2ρσpσc )

6.6. Model Uncertainty and Optimal Liability Ratio

Part 6.1 explained that AIG sold CDS on reference securities/financial

instruments that were primarily made up of subprime mortgages. AIG’s downfall

stemmed in a very large part from its CDS on multi-sector CDOs, which exposed the firm

to the vaporization of the value in the subprime market. The value of the reference

securities, the CDOs containing the subprime mortgages corresponds to A(t), and the

value of the insurance liabilities CDS corresponds to L(t), in equations (6.3), (6.4).

Page 14: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 14

When the debt ratio f(t) exceeds f-max in figure 4.1, the expected growth is

negative and the risk R(f) is high. Thus the excess debt f(t) – f*(t), the actual less the

optimal, is a warning signal of a crisis. That is, leverage and risk are “too high”. A crucial

variable in evaluating the optimal debt ratio and risk is dP(t)/P(t) in equation (6.5). The

question is how should one model and estimate the drift a(t) in that equation. This is the

issue of model uncertainty.

Fisher Black (quoted in Derman), who would have won the Nobel prize for

options modeling – had he lived - explained that a financial theory: "is accepted not

because it is confirmed by conventional empirical tests, but because researchers persuade

one another that the theory is correct and relevant." Black argues that given the models'

limitations, "the right way to engage with a model is, like a fiction reader or a really

great pretender, is to suspend disbelief and push it as far as possible... But then, when

you've done modeling, you must remind yourself that ... although God's world can be

divined by principles, humanity prefers to remain mysterious. Catastrophes strike when

people allow theories to take on a life of their own and hubris evolves into idolatry."

The question is what is the optimal liability and the excessive liability that should

have been a warning signal for the crisis. How should we model

dP(t)/P(t) = a(t) dt + σp dwp that corresponds to HPI/CAPGAIN = [P(t+1) – P(t)]/P(t)? Is

the capital gain equal to a constant drift a(t) = a plus a Brownian Motion term, or is the

drift ergodic mean reverting to a constant trend plus a Brownian Motion term? Are the

capital gains terms independent or are they serially correlated? How can we characterize

the distribution of the capital gains?

I approach the problem of deciding on the appropriate way to model the capital

gain equation by looking at Figure 6.1. It plots the appreciation of single-family housing

prices, CAPGAIN/HPI, a 4 quarter appreciation of US Housing prices HPI, percent p.a. It

corresponds to dP(t)/P(t). Figure 6.1 covers a recent period 1991q1 – 2011q1, pre and

post, crisis. Consider, however, the information available before the crisis. What can one

say about the distribution of the change in house prices over the period 1980q1 –

2007q4?

Page 15: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 15

From figures 3.4/5.2, we can reject the hypothesis that the distribution of the

CAPGAIN series is normal. Table 6.2 tests for serial correlation of the capital gains. Are

they independent? The Q-Statistics reject the null hypothesis that there is no

autocorrelation up to order k. This means that the Brownian Motion assumption used in

modeling dP/P is questionable.

Page 16: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 16

Figure 6.1. HPI/CAPGAIN Capital gains [P(t) – P(t-1)]/P(t-1), percent change in index

of house price HPI, sample 1991q1 – 2011q1.

Page 17: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 17

Table 6.2. Tests for Autocorrelation CAPGAIN(t) against CAPGAIN (t-k) Sample: 1980Q1 2007Q4 Included observations: 111

lag AC PAC Q-Stat Prob

Autocorrelation AC at lag k = Sum [covariance Y(t+k), Y(t)]/variance Y(t)

Q-Stat Probability = probability of null hypothesis that there is no autocorrelation up to order k 1 0.929 0.929 98.423 0.000

2 0.847 -0.118 180.98 0.000 3 0.748 -0.164 245.97 0.000 4 0.628 -0.204 292.17 0.000 5 0.545 0.246 327.30 0.000 6 0.466 -0.028 353.20 0.000 7 0.390 -0.087 371.51 0.000 8 0.331 -0.011 384.89 0.000

Page 18: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 18

In chapters four and five, two models for the capital gain term were considered. In

model I the price P(t) was ergodic mean reverting to a constant trend plus a BM term. In

model II, the capital gains term was BM with a constant drift. The choice between the

models depends upon a unit root test. Table 6.3, which tests for a unit root, is concerned

with the question whether or not the capital gains term is stationary. This is the null

hypothesis

Ho: r = 1, CAPGAIN(t) = r CAPGAIN(t-1) + e(t), e(t) random.

If the null r = 1 is not rejected one can conclude that a BM with drift is the

appropriate way to model the capital gains equation. If the null hypothesis is rejected, the

appropriate way to model the capital gains equation is ergodic mean reversion with a BM

term. The conclusion of the unit root test in table 6.3 is that: One cannot reject the null

hypothesis at the 5% level, but can at the 10% level. Neither hypothesis is inconsistent

with the data. Since there is model uncertainty, my approach is to consider a general

formulation for the optimal debt liabilities in equation (6.12) and compare it with the

actual debt liabilities.

Page 19: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 19

Table 6.3. Unit root tests Null Hypothesis: CAPGAIN has a unit root; Ho: r = 1. CAPGAIN(t) = r CAPGAIN(t-1) + e(t). Exogenous: Constant Lag Length: 5 (Automatic based on SIC, MAXLAG=8)

t-Statistic Prob.* Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -2.662054 0.0841

Test critical values: 1% level -3.493747 5% level -2.889200 10% level -2.581596 *MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.

.

Page 20: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 20

6.7. Early Warning Signals

The optimal debt ratio f*(t) is positively related to the drift of the capital gain and

negatively related to the drift of claims. The negative correlation between the capital gains

and the claims reduces the optimal debt ratio, because it increases the total risk.

The early warning signal follows the analysis in chapters four and five. The

excess debt of the mortgagors/households is the difference between the actual debt ratio

and an upper bound f**(t) of the optimal liability ratio. The use of f**(t) the upper, bound

allows the analysis to be done on the assumption that either model is correct. The Ψ (t) =

EXCESSDEBT = [f(t) – f**(t)] is plotted below as figure 6.2. The greater is the value of

Ψ (t): (a) the lower is the expected growth of surplus and the greater is the risk, as is seen

in figure 4.1 and (b) it is more likely is it that households/mortgagors will default on the

mortgages thereby increasing the claims on AIG.

My strategy is to compare this measure Ψ (t) = EXCESSDEBT of the mortgagors

with the actual liabilities L(t) of AIG to derive a warning signal. If actual liabilities L(t)

are rising when Ψ (t) is increasing, the liklihood of claims on AIG and a crisis is more

probable.

Consider AIG liabilities, L(t) or f(t). AIG’s business of offering credit protection on

assets such as mortgage backed securities and CDO’s grew from $20 billion in 2002 to

$211 billion in 2005 and $533 billion in 2007. (FCIC, 141). The company as a whole had

a much higher leverage ratio than did other insurance companies. As of December 2007,

leverage for AIG was 11:1, whereas leverage for Berkshire Hathaway 2:1, Travelers 4:1

and Chubb 4:1. A nine percent decline in the value of assets of AIG would wipe out

surplus.

The EXCESSDEBT rose considerably from 2002 to 2007 by more than two standard

deviations, whereas the actual AIG liabilities rose, L(2007)/L(2002) = 533/20 = 26.6

during this period. This means that the probability of large claims was very high. When

the value of house prices P(t) declined, the value of the CDOs insured by AIG declined.

AIG’s credit rating was downgraded, it had to post additional collateral or compensate the

insured for the difference between the notional and market values of the reference

Page 21: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 21

securities. However, AIG lacked the liquidity to meet the collateral calls and banks

refused to refinance. This led to the crisis of AIG. Part 6.1/table 6.1 shows that the crisis

was not predicted and came as a shock- contrary to Gorton’s model (see part 1 above). On

the other hand, the SOC analysis provided a good early warning signal.

The market did not exhibit qualms about AIG. Table 6.4 shows the total notional

amounts of CDS outstanding in column (1). Column (2) is the CDS rate on AIG, which

reflects the probability that AIG will default. Note the AIG-CDS rate declined from 30.7

in 2005h1 to 11.5 in 2007h1, while the notional total of CDS outstanding rose from

$12429 billion in 2005h1 to $62173 billion in 2007h2. The price of AIG insurance

declined while (a) the total amount of insurance increased and (b) The EXCESSDEBT

rose considerably from 2002 to 2007 by more than two standard deviations. The market

was taken by surprise because it ignored available information on household debt.

Page 22: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 22

Figure 6.2. Ψ (t) = EXCESSDEBT, normalized excess debt ratio of the

mortgagors/households

Page 23: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 23

Table 6.4. Notional amount CDS outstanding $billions, AIG-CDS rate 2001h1 – 2010h2

Date, half year (1) Notional amount CDS outstanding,

$billions (rounded)

(2)AIG-CDS rate

2001h1 631 15.57

2001h2 918 22.64

2002h1 1563 37.3

2002h1 2191 64.11

2003h1 2687 40.4

2003h2 3779 27.74

2004h1 5441 22.11

2004h2 8422 21.25

2005h1 12429 30.7

2005h2 17096 23.8

2006h1 26005 18.13

2006h2 34422 11.82

2007h1 4564 11.5

2007h2 62173 48.95

2008h1 54611 153.7

2008h2 38563 938.8

2009h1 31223 1487.9

2009h2 30428 935.6

2010h1 26263 417.4

Page 24: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 24

6.8.An Evaluation of The Bailout

The COP Report (2010) evaluates the Federal Reserve and Treasury justifications

for the bailout. I paraphrase this Report, which is a suitable closing for this chapter.

6.8.1.Government’s Justification for Rescue

The Federal Reserve was the only governmental entity at the time with the legal authority

to provide liquidity to the financial system in emergency circumstances. The Board and

FRBNY ultimately chose to provide AIG with assistance after identifying the systemic

risks associated with the company and contemplating the consequences of an AIG

bankruptcy or partial rescue. On September 16, the Board, with the full support of

Treasury, authorized Federal Reserve Bank of New York (FRBNY) to lend up to $85

billion to AIG in order to assist the company in meeting its obligations as they came due.

The Board determined that, in the then-existing environment, “a disorderly failure of AIG

could add to already significant levels of financial market fragility and lead to

substantially higher borrowing costs, reduced household wealth, and materially weaker

economic performance.”

The Federal Reserve’s actions were based upon its judgment that an AIG

collapse would have been much more severe than that of Lehman Brothers because of its

global operations, substantial and varied retail and institutional customer base, and the

various types of financial services it provided. At September 2008 the time of the initial

decision to assist AIG, the Federal Reserve and Treasury publicly identified three

primary ways in which an AIG failure posed systemic risk. First, they concluded that,

given AIG’s role as a large seller of CDSs on CDOs, an AIG failure could have exposed

its counterparties to large losses and disrupted the operation of the payments and

settlements system. According to Secretary Geithner, if the AIG parent holding company

had filed for bankruptcy, defaults on over $100 billion of debt and on trillions of dollars

of derivatives would have resulted. The Federal Reserve and Treasury argued that this

would have adversely impacted numerous financial institutions and the financial system

as a whole. The primary fear of the Federal Reserve and Treasury was that defaults

directly related to AIG would have spread throughout the financial system, affecting

transactions between other counterparties, negatively affecting investor confidence, and

Page 25: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 25

further destabilizing the economy. Second, the Federal Reserve and Treasury concluded

that an AIG default on its commercial paper could have adversely impacted money

market mutual funds since AIG had issued $20 billion in commercial paper to money

market mutual funds, approximately four times as much as Lehman Brothers. In the

government’s view, this could have substantially disrupted the commercial paper market

by reducing credit availability for borrowers even on a short-term basis and causing

higher lending rates. This concern escalated after the money market disruptions that

occurred in the wake of the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy filing, including the “breaking

of the buck” at the Reserve Primary Fund.

Third, the Federal Reserve and Treasury asserted that they feared that an AIG

failure could have undermined an already fragile economy by weakening business and

investor confidence. After the placement of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into

government conservatorship on September 7 and the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy filing

on September 15, financial markets destabilized considerably. AIG maintained financial

relationships with a large number of banks, insurance companies, and other market

participants across the globe. A failure of AIG in this environment, according to the

Federal Reserve and Treasury, could have further shaken investor confidence and

contributed to increased borrowing costs and additional economic deterioration.

In this context, the Federal Reserve and Treasury officials stated that they believed that

the unfolding crisis and the increasingly fragile state of the economy necessitated swift

action to prevent a total collapse of the financial system.

6.8.2. Panel’s Analysis of Options Available to the Government and Decisions

The Panel recognized that policymakers faced a deepening financial crisis and that there

were many issues of serious concern and a limited amount of time in which to respond to

AIG in September 2008. The Panel stated that FRBNY’s decisions were made in the

belief that it alone could act and that it had to choose between options that were all

unattractive. There is nothing unusual about central banks acting as the lender of last

resort. However, by adopting the terms developed by the private sector consortium and

Page 26: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 26

retaining most of its terms and conditions, FRBNY chose to act in effect as if it were a

private investor in many ways, when its actions also had serious public consequences

whose full extent it may not have appreciated. FRBNY also failed to recognize the AIG

problem and get involved at a time when it could have had more options.

While the reasons for FRBNY’s failure are not clear, it is clear that when FRBNY

finally realized AIG was failing and that there would be no private sector solution,

Chairman Bernanke and President Geithner failed to consider any options other than a

full rescue. To have the government step in with a full rescue was not the approach used

in prior crises, including Bear Stearns and Long-Term Capital Management. FRBNY

chose lawyers from a limited pool and did not seek legal advice from a debtor’s counsel

(such as AIG’s bankruptcy counsel or independent bankruptcy counsel). As a result,

there were many options FRBNY evidently did not consider, including a combined

private/public rescue (which would have maintained some market discipline), a loan

conditioned on counterparties granting concessions, and a short-term bridge loan from

FRBNY to provide AIG time for longer-term restructuring. Providing a full government

rescue with no shared sacrifice among the creditors who dealt with AIG fundamentally

changed the relationship between the government and the markets, reinforcing moral

hazard and undermining the basic tenets of capitalism. The rescue of AIG dramatically

added to the public’s sense of a double standard – where some businesses and their

creditors suffer the consequences of failure and other, larger, better connected businesses

do not. The FRBNY’s decision-making also suggest that it neglected to give sufficient

attention to the crucial need – more important in a time of crisis than ever – for

accountability and transparency.

The Panel asked: Was It Truly an All-or-Nothing Choice? The Treasury/Fed

presented the decision to rescue AIG as an all-or-nothing “binary” decision. In other

words, the government asserted that it was necessary to rescue AIG in its entirety or let it

fail in its entirety. It was not possible to pick and choose which businesses or subsidiaries

could be saved. The Panel tested this assertion and considered whether bankruptcy had to

be an all-or-nothing option, in terms of the entities covered, the obligations covered, or in

terms of timing. If a bankruptcy was not a real option in September 2008, was it later?

The potential impact of an AIG bankruptcy can be guessed by examining how the

Page 27: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 27

markets continued to deteriorate even after AIG was rescued. As shown in the Table 6.1

above, the spread between the London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) and the

Overnight Index Spread Rate (OIS) – used as a proxy for fears of bank bankruptcy –

dramatically increased in September 2008 amid the growing concerns of financial

collapse. Former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan stated that the “LIBOR-OIS

spread remains a barometer of fears of bank insolvency.” In the immediate aftermath of

the Lehman bankruptcy this spread spiked to a level indicating actual illiquidity in the

interbank market – not merely a high cost for obtaining funds – meaning that banks were

not willing to lend to one another. Prior to the beginning of the credit market crisis in

August 2007, the LIBOR-OIS spread was 10 basis points. The LIBOR-OIS

spread reflected the contraction of liquidity that crippled the financial markets in 2008, as

seen in table 6.1.

The Panel recognized that the government was faced with a deepening financial

crisis, and its attention was on a number of troubled institutions besides AIG in the course

of just a few days. Given this context, the government took actions that it thought would

facilitate rapid intervention in the midst of deteriorating economic conditions.

Nonetheless, if the government concluded that it could not impose conditions on its

assistance once it had decided to backstop AIG with taxpayer funds, or that other possible

rescue alternatives were unattractive or impracticable, then it had an obligation to fully

explain why it decided what it did, and especially why it was of the opinion that all

AIG’s creditors and counterparties would receive all amounts they were owed. In

addition, while the Panel acknowledged the number of complex issues and troubled

institutions that policymakers were concerned with at the time, it appears that the

government was neither focused on nor prepared to deal with the AIG situation. By

placing a tremendous amount of faith in the assumption that a private sector solution

would succeed in resolving AIG, the government had no legitimate alternative on the

table once that assumption turned out to be incorrect. In its assessment of government

actions to deal with the current financial crisis, the Panel has regularly called for

transparency, accountability, and clarity of goals. These obligations on the part of the

government do not vanish in the midst of a financial crisis. In fact, it is during times of

crisis, when difficult decisions must be made, that a full accounting of the government’s

Page 28: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 28

actions is especially important.

6.9 Conclusions: Lessons to be learned

From 1994-2006 AIGFP operating income grew by 18% pa paralleling the boom

in the overall derivative market as well as in the CDS market. The risk involved in this

business was dramatically disproportionate to the revenue produced. Losses in one year

2007 totaling $11.5 billion were twice the aggregate net income produced by the division

over the entire period 1994-2006.

AIGFP relied on Gorton’s actuarial model that did not provide a tool for

monitoring the CDO’s market value. Gorton’s model had determined with 99.85%

confidence that the owners of super-senior tranches of the CDO’s insured by AIGFP

would never suffer real economic losses. The company’s auditor PWC apparently was

also not aware of the collateral requirements. PWC concluded that “..the risk of default

on the [AIG] portfolio has been effectively removed as a result of a risk management

perspective…”. AIG was led to accumulate staggering amounts of risk, especially in its

Financial Products subsidiary.

What lessons can be learned from AIGs experience? AIG made several serious

mistakes. First, the financial structure of derivatives CDS insured by AIG, was ultimately

based upon the systemic risk from the inability of the mortgagors to service their debts.

The exaggerated view of the drift of the capital gain, which drove the bubble, was based

upon the growth of the value of housing, the housing price index 2004-06. This growth

ranging from 10-14% pa exceeded the mean interest rate. Mortgagors consumed the

difference between the refinancing of the loan and the associated debt. They expected to

service their debts from the appreciation of the housing price in excess of the rate of

interest. This free lunch would disappear when the unsustainable capital gain declined

below the interest rate.

Second, risk was underestimated because AIG ignored the negative correlation

between the capital gain and the claims. The CDS claims grew when the value of the

Page 29: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 29

insured obligations CDO declined. This set off collateral requirements and the stability of

AIG was undermined.

Acting Director of the OTS Polakoff acknowledged that AIG and OTS did not

forsee the extent of risk concentration and profound systemic impact CDS caused within

AIG. The AIG crisis leads one to ask the following questions. What is an optimal liability

ratio or capital requirement for a large insurer of financial derivatives that balances the

expected growth against risk? What is an optimal risk? What are theoretically founded

early warning signals of a crisis? Neither the economics literature nor the Cramér-

Lundberg literature answers these questions. I explained why the application of stochastic

optimal control (SOC)/dynamic risk management is an effective approach to answer

these questions. The theoretically derived early warning signal of a crisis is the excess

liability ratio, equal to the difference between the actual and optimal ratio. This SOC

analysis should have been used by those charged with surveillance of financial markets.

Page 30: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 30

References

Aggarwal, R, Jacques, K.T. 1998, Assessing the impact of prompt action on bank capital and risk, Federal Reserve Bank, NY, Economic Policy Review.

Congressional Oversight Panel, 2010 ,The AIG Rescue, Its Impact on Markets and the Government’s Exit Strategy, Washington D.C. June.

Cummins, J.D. and Somer, D.W. 1996, Capital and Risk in property–liability insurance markets, Jour. Bank. & Finan. 20, 1069-92 Derman, Emanuel, 2004, My Life as a Quant, John Wiley and Sons

Financial Crisis Inquiry Report, FCIC Final Report of National Commission, 2011, Public Affairs, New York

Korteweg Arthur, 2010, The Net Benefits to Leverage, Journal of Finance, LXV No. 6, pp. 2089- 2136.

Meyers, S.C. 2001, Capital Structure, Jour. Econ.Perspect. 15, 81-102.

Meyers, S.C., and Read, J.A. 2001, Capital allocation for insurance companies, Jour. Risk and Insurance, 68, 545-80.

Shim, Jeungbo, 2010, Capital-based regulation, portfoio risk and capital determinants: Empirical evidence from US property insurers, Jour. Bank. & Fin. 34, 250-61.

Stein, Jerome L, 2010, “Greenspan’s Retrospective of Financial Crisis and Stochastic Optimal

Control”, European Financial Management, Vol. 16, No. 5858-871.

Volchan, S. 2007, The fundamental theorem of actuarial risk science, Math. Sci. 31 (2) 73-84

Page 31: Chapter Six AIG 1 Chapter Six AIG in the Crisis Abstract ... · Chapter Six AIG 2 stochastic differential equations, and the stochastic processes. The solution for the optimal capital

Chapter Six AIG 31