chapter 11 imperfect competition © 2004 thomson learning/south-western

61
Chapter 11 Imperfect Competitio n © 2004 Thomson Learning/South- Western

Upload: luke-chandler

Post on 17-Dec-2015

225 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

Chapter 11

Imperfect Competition

© 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

Page 2: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

2

Imperfect Competition

Pricing in these markets falls between perfect competition and monopoly.

Three topics considered:– Pricing of homogeneous goods in markets with few

firms.– Product differentiation in these markets.– How entry and exit affect long-run outcomes in

imperfectly competitive markets.

Page 3: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

3

Pricing of Homogeneous Goods

In this market a relatively few firms produce a single homogeneous good.– Assume demanders are price takers.– Assume there are no transactions or informational

costs.

These assumptions result in a single equilibrium price for the good.

Initially, assume a fixed, small number of identical firms.

Page 4: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

4

Quasi-Competitive Model

A model of oligopoly pricing in which each firm acts as a price taker even though there may be few firms is a quasi-competitive model.

As a price taker, a firm will produce where price equals long-run marginal costs.

This equilibrium will resemble the perfectly competitive solution, even with few firms.

Page 5: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

5

Quasi-Competitive Model

In Figure 11.1, the quasi-competitive equilibrium is PC (= MC), QC.

This equilibrium represents the highest quantity and lowest price that can prevail in the long run given the demand curve D.– A lower price would not be sustainable in the long

run because it would not cover average costs.

Page 6: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

6

Price

PC

MCC

MR

D

Quantityper week

QC0

FIGURE 11.1: Pricing under Imperfect Competition

Page 7: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

7

Cartel Model

A model of pricing in which firms coordinate their decisions to act as a multiplant monopoly is the cartel model.

Assuming marginal costs are constant and equal across firms, the cartel output is point M (the monopoly output) in Figure 11.1.– The plan would require a certain output by each firm

and how to share the monopoly profits.

Page 8: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

8

Price

PM

PA

PC

MCC

A

M

MR

D

Quantityper week

QM

QA

QC0

FIGURE 11.1: Pricing under Imperfect Competition

Page 9: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

9

Cartel Model

Maintaining this cartel solution poses three problems:– Cartel formations may be illegal, as it is in the U.S.

by Section I of the Sherman Act of 1890.– It requires a considerable amount of costly

information be available to the cartel. The market demand function. Each firm’s marginal cost function.

Page 10: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

10

Cartel Model

– The cartel solution may be fundamentally unstable.Each member produces an output level for which

price exceeds marginal cost.Each member could increase its own profits by

producing more output than allocated by the cartel.

If the cartel directors are not able to enforce their policies, the cartel my collapse.

Page 11: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

11

APPLICATION 11.1: The De Beers Cartel

In the 1870s the discovery of the rich diamond fields in South Africa lead to major gem and industrial markets.

After a competitive start, the ownership of the richest mines became incorporated into the De Beers Consolidated Mines which continues to dominate the world diamond trade.

Page 12: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

12

APPLICATION 11.1: The De Beers Cartel

Operation of the De Beers Cartel– Since the 1880s diamonds found outside of South

Africa are usually sold to De Beers who markets the diamonds to the final consumers through its central selling organization (CSO) in London.

– By controlling supply, the CSO maintains high prices which have been estimated to be as much as one thousand times marginal cost.

Page 13: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

13

APPLICATION 11.1: The De Beers Cartel

Dealing with Threats to the Cartel– This large markup promotes threat of entry with any

new diamond discovery.– De Beers has used its market power to control

would-be-chiselers. They drove down prices when the former Soviet Union and

Zaire tried market entry in the 1980s. New finds in Australia were sold to the CSO rather than try

to fight the cartel.

Page 14: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

14

APPLICATION 11.1: The De Beers Cartel

The Glamour of D Beers– De Beers controls most print and television

advertising, including “Diamonds Are Forever”.– They convinced Japanese couples to adopt the

western habit of buying engagement rings.– De Beers has attempted to generate a brand name

with customers to get consumers to judge De Beers diamonds superior to other suppliers.

Page 15: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

15

The Cournot Model

The Cournot model of duopoly is one in which each firm assumes the other firm;s output will not change if it changes its own output level.

Assume – A single owner of a costless spring.– A downward sloping demand curve for water has

the equation Q = 120 - P.

Page 16: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

16

The Cournot Model

As shown in Figure 11.2, the monpolist would maximize profit by producing Q = 60 with a price = $60 and profits (revenue) = $3600.– Note, this output equals one-half of the quantity that

would be demanded at a price of zero.

Assume a second spring is discovered.

Page 17: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

17

Price120

60

MR D Outputper week

60 1200

FIGURE 11.2: Spring Monopolist’s Output Choice

Page 18: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

18

Duopoly Model

Cournot assumed that firm A, say, chooses its output level (qA) assuming the output of firm B (qB) is fixed and will not adjust to A’s actions.

The total market output is given by

.)120(

120

is curve demand sA' fixed, is Bq Assuming

Pqq

PqqQ

BA

BA

Page 19: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

19

Duopoly Model

If the demand curve is linear, the marginal revenue curve will bisect the horizontal axis between the price axis and the demand curve.

Thus, the profit maximizing point is given by

[11.4] .2

120 BA

qq

Page 20: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

20

Duopoly Model

If firm B chooses to produce 60 units, firm A would choose 30 [=(120 - 60) 2].

Equation 11.4 is called a reaction function which, in the Cournot model, is a function or graph that shows how much one firm will produce given what the other firm produces.

Page 21: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

21

Output offirm B(qB)

120

Firm A’s reactions

Output offirm A(qA)60 1200

FIGURE 11.3: Cournot Reaction Functions in a Duopoly Market

Page 22: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

22

Duopoly Model

Firm A’s reaction function is shown in Figure 11.3. Firm B’s reaction function is given below and also

shown in Figure 11.3

[11.5] 2

120 AB

qq

Page 23: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

23

Output offirm B(qB)

120

60

Firm A’s reactions

EquilibriumFirm B’s reactions

Output offirm A(qA)60 1200

FIGURE 11.3: Cournot Reaction Functions in a Duopoly Market

Page 24: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

24

Cournot Equilibrium

The actions of the two firms are consistent with each other only at the point where the two lines intersect.

The point of intersection is the Cournot equilibrium, a solution to the Cournot model in which each firm makes the correct assumption about what the other firm will produce.

Page 25: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

25

Output offirm B(qB)

120

40

60

Firm A’s reactions

EquilibriumFirm B’s reactions

Output offirm A(qA)6040 1200

FIGURE 11.3: Cournot Reaction Functions in a Duopoly Market

Page 26: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

26

Cournot Equilibrium

In this Cournot equilibrium each firm produces 40 units of output.

Total industry profit is $3,200, $1600 for each firm). Because the firms do not fully coordinate their actions,

their profits are less than the cartel profit ($3,600) but much greater than the competitive solution where P = MC = 0.

.40 40 BA qq

Page 27: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

27

Price Leadership Model

A model in which one dominant firm takes reactions of all other firms into account in its output and pricing decisions is the price leadership model.

A formal model assumes the industry is composed of a single price-setting leader and a competitive fringe which is a group of firms that act as price takers.

Page 28: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

28

Price Leadership Model

This model is shown in Figure 11.4. The demand curve D represents the total

demand curve for the industry’s product. The supply curve SC represents the supply

decisions of all the firms in the competitive fringe.

Page 29: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

29

Price

D

SC

Quantityper week

0

FIGURE 11.4: Formal Model of Price Leadership Model

Page 30: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

30

Price Leadership Model

The demand curve (D’) for the dominant firm is derived as follows:– For a price of P1 or above the competitive fringe

will supply the entire market.– For a price of P2 or below, the dominant firm will

supply the entire market.– Between P2 and P1 the curve D’ is constructed by

subtracting what the fringe will supply from the total market demand.

Page 31: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

31

Price

P1

P2

D’

D

SC

Quantityper week

0

FIGURE 11.4: Formal Model of Price Leadership Model

Page 32: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

32

Price Leadership Model

Given D’, the leader’s marginal revenue curve is MR’ which equals the leader’s marginal cost (MC) at the profit maximizing level QL.

Market price is PL and equilibrium output is QT (= QC + QL).

The model does not explain how the leader is chosen.

Page 33: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

33

Price

PL

P1

P2

D’

MR’ D

SC

MC

Quantityper week

QL

QC

QT

0

FIGURE 11.4: Formal Model of Price Leadership Model

Page 34: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

34

APPLICATION 11.2: Cournot in California

Borenstein and Bushnell paper: Perhaps the most elaborate attempt at modeling the impact of electricity deregulation in California.– Authors focus on competition between the three

major electricity-generating firms.– They argue that the smaller suppliers can be treated

as competitive suppliers but that the major in-state producers behave in the way assumed in the Cournot model.

Page 35: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

35

APPLICATION 11.2: Cournot in California

Borenstein and Bushnell show that under certain circumstances there is substantial market power in California wholesale electricity markets.

One way to measure that power is by the Lerner Index, the ratio (P – MC/P).

The authors showed with the Lerner Index that during peak periods, equilibrium in these markets is far from the competitive ideal.

They also show that market power can be significantly restrained by larger price elasticities of demand for electricity.

Page 36: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

36

Product Differentiation: Market Definition and Firms Choices

A product group is a set of differentiated products that are highly substitutable for one another.

Assume few firms in each product group. Firms will incur additional costs to differentiate

their product up to the point where the additional revenue from this activity equals the marginal cost.

Page 37: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

37

Product Differentiation: Market Equilibrium

The demand curve for each firm depends on the prices and product differentiation activities of its competitors.

The firm’s demand curve may shift frequently, and its position at any point in time may only be partially understood.– Each firm must make assumptions about its

competitors’ actions, and whatever one firm decides may affect its competitor’s actions.

Page 38: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

38

APPLICATION 11.3: Price Leadership in Financial Markets

The Prime Rate at New York Commercial Banks– Major New York commercial banks quote a “prime

rate” which purports to be the interest rate that they charge on loans to their most creditworthy customers.

– Recent research indicates actual pricing is more complex, but the prime provides a visible and influential indicator or rate change.

Page 39: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

39

APPLICATION 11.3: Price Leadership in Financial Markets

While rates changes are sluggish, when “large” changes (0.25 or more) are required one of the major banks will act like a leader and announce a new prime rate on a trial basis.

After a few days, either most banks will follow or the initiator will return to its old rate.

Page 40: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

40

APPLICATION 11.3: Price Leadership in Financial Markets

– A number of researchers have found that rates tend to rise soon after an increase in bank costs, but decline only slowly when costs fall.

– Similarly, a rise in the prime tends to hurt the stock prices of banks that increase because the increase signals that profits hare being squeezed by costs.

– Alternatively, stock prices rise when the prime rate falls.

Page 41: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

41

APPLICATION 11.3: Price Leadership in Financial Markets

Price Leadership in the Foreign Exchange Market– The large market for world currencies is dominated

by major financial institutions and is heavily influenced by the “intervention” of various nations’ central banks.

– Because central bank intervention is not announced in advance, well informed traders may have an information market advantage.

Page 42: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

42

APPLICATION 11.3: Price Leadership in Financial Markets

– In a study of the German Mark (DM), an author found that one bank tended to pay the role of leader in setting the DM/$ exchange rate.

– This leadership role arose because of the bank’s ability to foresee intervention by the German central bank in exchange markets.

Quoted exchange rate between 25 and 60 minutes before the intervention were copied by other banks, while within 25 minutes (with information more diffused) no clear cut pattern emerged.

Page 43: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

43

APPLICATION 11.4: Competition in Breakfast Space

Industrial Concentration– Three major firms control approximately 80 percent

of the market.– Returns on invested capital are more than double

those of the average industry.– It is unclear why the market is not more competitive

since there do not seem to be any major economies of scale and no obvious barriers to entry.

Page 44: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

44

APPLICATION 11.4: Competition in Breakfast Space

The FTC Complaint and Product Differentiation– In 1972 the U.S. Federal Trade Commission (FTC)

claimed the largest producers actions tended to establish monopoly-like conditions.

Proliferation of new, highly advertised, brands left no room for potential new entrants.

Brand identification also prevented new entrants from duplicating existing cereal.

Page 45: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

45

APPLICATION 11.4: Competition in Breakfast Space

Demise of the Legal Case– Firms claimed that they were engaging in active

competition by creating new cereal brands.– Also, many new “natural” cereals did enter the

market in the 1970s.– The case was quietly dropped in 1982.

Recent studies still indicate a lack of competition and continued higher profits.

Page 46: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

46

APPLICATION 11.4: Competition in Breakfast Space

One of illustrating the contention that major firms so proliferated their brands so as to keep potential competitors out was developed by S. Salop.

Figure 1 depicts consumers evenly located along the circle which may represent an actual geographic space or product space.

The presence of two firms (A and B) with two products each deters entry by C.

Page 47: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

47

Application Figure 1: Salop’s Model of Spatial Competition.

.

..

. B1

B2

A1

A2

C

Page 48: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

48

Product Differentiation: Entry by New Firms

The degree to which firms can enter the market plays an important role.

Even with few firms, to the extent that entry is possible, long-run profits are constrained.

If entry is completely costless, long-run economic profits will be zero (as in the competitive case).

Page 49: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

49

Monopolistic Competition

If firms are price takers, P = MR = MC for profit maximization.

Since P = AC, if entry is to result in zero profits, production will take place where MC = AC (at minimum average cost).

If, say through product differentiation, firms have some control over price, each firm faces a downward sloping demand curve.

Page 50: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

50

Monopolistic Competition

Entry still may reduce profits to zero, but production at minimum cost is not assured.

Monopolistic competition is a market in which each firm faces a negatively sloped demand curve and there are no barriers to entry.

This type of market is illustrated in Figure 11.5.

Page 51: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

51

Price,costs

P*

mr

d

MC AC

Quantityper week

q*0

FIGURE 11.5: Entry Reduces Profitability in Oligopoly

Page 52: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

52

Monopolistic Competition

Initially the demand curve is d, marginal revenue is mr, and q* is the profit-maximizing output level.

If entry is costless, the entry shifts the firm’s demand curve inward to d’ where profits are zero.

At output level q’, average costs are not minimum, and qm - q’ is excess capacity.

Page 53: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

53

Price,costs

P*

P’

mr’

mr

d

d’

MC AC

Quantityper week

q*q’ qm

0

FIGURE 11.5: Entry Reduces Profitability in Oligopoly

Page 54: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

54

Sustainability of Monopolistic Competition

Monopolistic competition focuses only on the behavior of actual entrants but ignores the effects of potential entrants.

A broader perspective of the “ invisible hand” is the distinction between competition in the market and competition for the market.

Page 55: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

55

Determination of Industry Structure

Let q* represent that output level for which average costs are minimized.

Let Q* represent the total market for the commodity when price equals market (and average) cost.

The number of firms, n, in the industry (which may be relatively small) is given by

[11.7] *

*

q

Qn

Page 56: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

56

Determination of Industry Structure

As shown in Figure 11.6, for example, only four firms fulfill the market demand Q*.

The contestability assumption will ensure competitive behavior even though firms may recognize strategic relationships among themselves.

The potential for entrants constrains the types of behavior that are possible.

Page 57: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

57

Price

P*

AC1AC2 AC3 AC4

D

Quantityper week2*q 3*q Q* = 4*

qq*0

FIGURE 11.6: Contestability and Industry Structure

Page 58: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

58

APPLICATION 11.4: Airline Deregulation Revisited

Airlines Contestability– Since planes are mobile, they can be moved into a

market that promises excess profits.– Such potential entry should hold prices at

competitive levels even with few firms.– However, terminal facilities are market specific and

brand loyalty appears to exist.– Also, some major airports have limited potential for

growth.

Page 59: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

59

APPLICATION 11.4: Airline Deregulation Revisited

Effects of Deregulation– Studies suggest that fares declined after

deregulation with one study suggesting yearly gains to customers of about $8.6 billion.

– However, this study found that additional welfare gains of about $2.5 billion were not realized because of the limitations of landing slots and computer reservations systems may aid in price collusion among major airlines.

Page 60: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

60

APPLICATION 11.4: Airline Deregulation Revisited

Trend in Airline Competition– Many new airlines entered after the 1978

deregulation, but they were often consolidated into larger carriers.

– Several existing airlines went out of business.– The hub-and-spoke designs of flight networks were

introduced which has lead to dominance of one or two airlines in a hub city which may have resulted in higher fares.

Page 61: Chapter 11 Imperfect Competition © 2004 Thomson Learning/South-Western

61

Barriers to Entry

The existence of barriers to entry change the type of analysis.

In addition to those previously discussed, barriers include brand loyalty and strategic pricing.– Firms may drive out potential entrants with low

prices followed later by price increases or they may buy up smaller firms.