chap17.pdf

Upload: jaz

Post on 02-Jun-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/11/2019 chap17.pdf

    1/6

    CHAPTER 17

    Exercise 17.2

    1. (a) yt+1= yt+ 7 (b) yt+1= 1.3yt (c) yt+1= 3yt 9

    (a) Iteration yieldsy1= y0+ 1, y2= y1+ 1 =y0+ 2, y3= y2+ 1 = y0+ 3, etc. The solution

    is yt= y0+t= 10 +t.

    (b) Since y1= y0, y2= y1= 2y0, y3= y2= 3y0, etc., the solution is yt = ty0= t.

    (c) Iteration yields y1 = y0 , y2 = y1 = 2y0 , y3 = y2 = 3y0

    2 , etc. The solution is yt = ty0 (t1+

    t2 +. . .+| {z }a total of t terms

    + 1).

    (a) yt+1 yt = 1, so that a = 1and c = 1. By(17.90), the solution is yt= y0+ ct= 10 + t.

    The answer checks.

    (b) yt+1yt= 0, so that a = , and c = 0. Assuming 6= 1,(17.80)applies, and we have

    yt =y0t =t. It checks. [ Assuming = 1 instead, we find from (17.90) that yt = ,

    which is a special case ofyt = t.]

    (c) yt+1 yt = , so that a = , and c = . Assuming 6= 1, we find from (17.80)

    that yt = y0+ 1t

    1 . This is equivalent to the earlier answer, because we can

    rewrite it as yt = y0t

    1t

    1

    = y0t (1 ++2 +. . .+t1).

    (a) To find yc, try the solution yt = Abt in the homogeneous equation yt+1+ 3yt = 0. The

    result is Abt+1 + 3Abt = 0; i.e., b = 3. Hence yc = Abt = A(3)t. To find yp, try the

    solution yt = k in the complete equation, to get k+ 3k = 4; i.e. k = 1. Hence yp = 1.

    The general solution isyt= A(3)t + 1. Settingt = 0in this solution, we get y0= A + 1.

    The initial condition then gives us A= 3. The definite solution is yt= 3(3)t + 1.

    (b) After normalizing the equation to yt+1 (12)yt = 3, we can find yc = Ab

    t = A( 12)t, and

    yp= k = 6. Thus,yt = A(12)t + 6. Using the initial condition, we get A = 1. The definite

    solution is yt = (12)

    t + 6.

    (c) After rewriting the equation as yt+1 0.2yt = 4, we can find yc = A(0.2)t, and yp = 5.

    Thus yt = A(0.2)t + 5. Using the initial condition, this solution can be definitized to

    yt= (0.2)t + 5.

    118

  • 8/11/2019 chap17.pdf

    2/6

    Exercise 17.3

    1. (a) Nonoscillatory; divergent.

    (b) Nonoscillatory; convergent (to zero).

    (c) Oscillatory; convergent.

    (d) Nonoscillatory; convergent.

    2. (a) From the expression3(3)t, we have b = 3(region VII). Thus the path will oscillate

    explosively around yp= 1.

    (b) Withb = 12 (region III), the path will show a nonoscillatory movement from 7 toward

    yp= 6.

    (c) With b = 0.2 (region III again), we have another convergent, nonoscillatory path.

    But this time it goes upward from an initial value of 1 toward yp= 5.

    3. (a) a = 13 , c = 6, y0 = 1. By (17.80), we have yt = 8(

    13)

    t + 9 nonoscillatory and

    convergent.

    (b) a= 2, c = 9, y0= 4. By(17.80), we have yt = (2)

    t + 3 oscillatory and divergent.

    (c) a = 14 , c = 5, y0 = 2. By (17.80), we have yt = 2(

    14)

    t + 4 oscillatory and

    convergent.

    (d) a= 1,c = 3,y0= 5. By(17.90), we have yt = 5+3t nonoscillatory and divergent

    (from a moving equilibrium 3t).

    Exercise 17.4

    1. Substitution of the time path(17.120)into the demand equation leads to the time path ofQdt,

    which we can simply write as Qt (since Qdt= Qst by the equilibrium condition):

    Qt =

    Pt = P0

    P

    t

    P

    Whether Qt converges depends on the

    tterm, which determines the convergence ofPt

    as well. Thus Pt and Qt must be either both convergent, or both divergent.

    2. The cobweb in this case will follow a specific rectangular path.

    119

  • 8/11/2019 chap17.pdf

    3/6

    3. (a) = 18, = 3, = 3, = 4. Thus P = 217 = 3. Since > , there is explosive

    oscillation.

    (b) = 22, = 3, = 2, = 1. Thus P = 244 = 6. Since < , the oscillation is

    damped.

    (c) = 19, = 6, = 5, = 6. Thus P = 2412 = 2. Since = , there is uniform

    oscillation.

    4. (a) The interpretation is that if actual pricePt1exceeds (falls short of) the expected price

    Pt1, then P

    t1 will be revised upward (downward) by a fraction of the discrepancy

    Pt1 P

    t1, to form the expected price of the next period, P

    t. The adjustment

    process is essentially the same as in (16.34), except that, here, time is discrete, and

    the variable is price rather than the rate of inflation.

    (b) If = 1, then Pt =Pt1 and the model reduces to the cobweb model (17.10). Thus

    the present model includes the cobweb model as a special case.

    (c) The supply function gives Pt = Qst+

    , which implies that Pt1 =

    Qs,t1+

    . But

    since Qst = Qdt= Pt, and similarly, Qs,t1= Pt1, we have

    Pt =+ Pt

    and Pt1=

    + Pt1

    Substituting these into the adaptive expectations equation, and simplifying and shift-

    ing the time subscript by one period, we obtain the equation

    Pt+1

    1

    Pt=

    (+)

    which is in the form of (17.6) with a =

    1

    6= 1, and c= (+)

    .

    (d) Since a 6= 1, we can apply formula (17.80) to get

    Pt = P0 +

    +1

    t

    ++

    +

    =

    P0 P

    1

    t+ P

    This time path is not necessarily oscillatory, but it will be if

    1

    is negative,

    i.e., if +

  • 8/11/2019 chap17.pdf

    4/6

    (e) If the price path is oscillatory and convergent (region V in Fig. 17.1), we must have

    1 < 1

    < 0, where the second inequality has to do with the presence

    of oscillation, and the first, with the question of convergence. Adding ( 1), and

    dividing throught by, we have1 2

    <

  • 8/11/2019 chap17.pdf

    5/6

    [These results are the same as Table 17.2 withset equal to 0.] To have a positive P, we must

    have k

  • 8/11/2019 chap17.pdf

    6/6

    It follows that

    k=

    +

    P

    =

    +

    P

    123