buying groups and product variety - c r e s s e

32
Buying Groups and Product Variety Marie-Laure Allain * , Rémi Avignon , Claire Chambolle Preliminary and incomplete. Please do not circulate Abstract We study the impact of retailers’ buying groups on both product variety and the profit sharing within the vertical chain. We consider a setting in which capacity con- strained retailers operate in separated markets and must select their assortment among a set of differentiated products. Retailers may either adopt an independent listing strat- egy or a joint listing strategy (i.e they commit to listing the same product assortment) which may cover the whole product line (full coverage) or only part of it (partial cover- age). We show that retailers may enhance their buyer power by jointly committing to a common listing strategy. As a result, buying groups reduce the overall product variety. This results in lower overall consumer surplus. Interestingly buying groups with partial coverage may be more profitable for the retailers than those with full coverage. Keywords: Vertical relations, buying group, buyer power, vertical foreclosure. JEL Classification: L13, L42, L81. * CREST, CNRS, Ecole polytechnique, Université Paris-Saclay; email: marie- [email protected]. CREST, Université Paris-Saclay; email: [email protected]. ALISS UR1303, INRA, Université Paris-Saclay, F-94200 Ivry-sur-Seine, France, and CREST; email: [email protected].

Upload: others

Post on 30-Apr-2022

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

Buying Groups and Product Variety

Marie-Laure Allain∗, Rémi Avignon†, Claire Chambolle‡

Preliminary and incomplete. Please do not circulate

Abstract

We study the impact of retailers’ buying groups on both product variety and the

profit sharing within the vertical chain. We consider a setting in which capacity con-

strained retailers operate in separated markets and must select their assortment among

a set of differentiated products. Retailers may either adopt an independent listing strat-

egy or a joint listing strategy (i.e they commit to listing the same product assortment)

which may cover the whole product line (full coverage) or only part of it (partial cover-

age). We show that retailers may enhance their buyer power by jointly committing to a

common listing strategy. As a result, buying groups reduce the overall product variety.

This results in lower overall consumer surplus. Interestingly buying groups with partial

coverage may be more profitable for the retailers than those with full coverage.

Keywords: Vertical relations, buying group, buyer power, vertical foreclosure.

JEL Classification: L13, L42, L81.

∗CREST, CNRS, Ecole polytechnique, Université Paris-Saclay; email: marie-

[email protected].†CREST, Université Paris-Saclay; email: [email protected].‡ALISS UR1303, INRA, Université Paris-Saclay, F-94200 Ivry-sur-Seine, France, and CREST; email:

[email protected].

Page 2: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

1 Introduction

Buying groups, that is purchasing alliances between retailers, are widespread and often gather

retailers that operate in different countries. These agreements have long been well perceived

by competition authorities because they are likely to increase buyer-power and enable retailers

to obtain discounts that translate into lower consumer prices. This “countervailing power"

effect, first coined by Galbraith (1952), has been largely debated in the literature but recent

theoretical developments however point out that they rely on strong assumptions regarding

the shape of tariffs, namely linear contracts (see von Ungern-Sternberg (1996) and Iozzi and

Valletti (2014)). Yet it has been widely documented that tariffs in the retail sector are scarcely

linear (see Berto Villas-Boas (2007) Bonnet and Dubois (2010)). A more recent strand of

theory has developed to analyze the welfare effects of buyer power (see Roman Inderst and

Mazzarotto Nicola (2008)), pointing out its potential adverse effects on product variety,

innovation, and the scope for collusion. Despite these potential adverse effects, purchasing

alliances are not subject to approval by competition authorities, contrary to mergers.

Two waves of buying alliances in the grocery industry1 have recently attracted the at-

tention of the French competition authority. First, in 2014, three important purchasing

agreements have been signed in France. In September, System U and Auchan formed an

alliance, as well as Intermarché and Casino in November and Carrefour and Cora in Decem-

ber. This led the competition authority to take on a report on the welfare effects of buying

groups in 2015.2 The bright side of the analysis put forward that those buying groups were

likely to have limited anticompetitive effects, because their scope was restricted to national

brand products, hence they could not affect products manufactured by small suppliers, in

particular fresh agricultural products.3

In 2018, a second wave of international purchasing agreements involving French retailers

started.4 Three groups of retailers are involved. A first group called "Horizon" is composed1French grocery market shares in 2019 are the following: Carrefour (20.1%), E. Leclerc (21.3%), Inter-

marché (14.7%), Casino (11%), Système U (10.6%). Source: Kantar World Panel2See : Autorité de la concurrence (2015).3Following the report the Loi Macron 2015-990 made mandatory for retailers to notify to the Competition

Authority their decision to create a buying group at least two months in advance. Yet, no tools for controllingsuch alliances were granted to the Competition Authorities.

4The French competition authority launched a new evaluation in July 2018 in order to investigate "thecompetitive impact of these purchasing partnerships on the concerned markets, both upstream for the suppliers,

1

Page 3: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

of Auchan, Casino, Metro and Schiever, a second one is composed of Carrefour and Système

U and third one involves Carrefour and Tesco. An important difference between this wave

and the previous one is that the new buying groups gather retailers operating on separate

markets. Furthermore, they cover a wider scope of brands. In its press release of July 2018,

the French competition authority stipulates that new agreements "differ from the alliances

made in 2015 due to their larger scope involving an international dimension, and because they

include not only national brand goods but also store-brand products".5 The retailers argue that

this may give opportunities of international development to the suppliers of private labels.6

In this paper, we study the effect of buying groups on product variety, and we compare

the above-mentioned kinds of agreements, depending on whether or not their boundaries

include SMEs. To do so, we consider a setting in which two retailers act as monopolists

on two independent markets. They sell differentiated products manufactured by competing

suppliers: a large supplier who can offer two products denoted A and C in the two markets

(typically a multinational company selling well-know brands across markets), and, in each

market, a small local supplier who offers only one product l (typically, a private label SME).

To represent differences in the preferences of consumers living in different regions or even

different countries, we assume that, on one of these two markets preferences are such that

A > B > C, whereas this ranking is reversed on the other market (C > B > A).7 On each

market, the retailer is capacity constrained: each retailer can list two of the three available

products.

We consider that retailers may either adopt an independent listing strategy or a joint list-

ing strategy (i.e they commit to listing the same product assortment). Joint listing strategies

may cover the whole product line (full coverage, A, l and C), such as in the 2018 buying groups

quoted above, or only part of it (partial coverage, A and C), such as in the 2014 cases above.

In each of these situation, retailers and suppliers negotiate over three part tariffs as follows.

First, on each market, suppliers compete for being listed by the retailer by simultaneously

and downstream for the consumers."5For instance, Carrefour claimed that "the alliance will cover the strategic relationship with global sup-

pliers, the joint purchasing of own brand products and goods not for resale."(source: carrefour.com)6Horizon communication thus claimed that "Auchan Retail, Casino Group and METRO will assist SMEs

in their international development, [..] and will be able to launch invitations to tender for their generalexpenses and their non-differentiating basic private-label brands" (source: groupe-casino.fr).

7These assumptions are close to those made by Inderst and Shaffer (2007).

2

Page 4: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

offering lump-sum slotting fees conditional on the number of their products listed by the re-

tailer. If the slotting fee is not accepted, the corresponding assortment will not be sold. If it

is accepted, the retailer is committed to enter into the second stage negotiation process with

the supplier but is not tied to sell the product. After the listing decision which is publicly

observed, retailers thus engage in a "Nash-in-Nash" bargaining with the supplier(s) of the

selected products. Finally, retailers sell their products on the downstream market.

We first show that creating a buying group reduces the overall variety of products, thereby

harming consumer surplus and welfare. Indeed, by assumption the preferred assortment

differs on the two markets, therefore committing to a similar assortment in the two markets

generates inefficiencies on at least one of the markets. Despite this inefficiency retailers

may find this strategy profitable because when committing to a common listing strategy

they enhance their buyer power, by reinforcing the threat of being delisted on all suppliers

who thus compete more fiercely at the listing stage. This result is in line with Inderst and

Shaffer (2007) however in contrast to their paper we show that the buying group creation

may generates inefficiency on both markets. Indeed, when the multi-product supplier is able

to impose its two products to the retailer, the resulting assortment AC is inefficient on the

two markets. Second, we show that retailers jointly find profitable to create a buying group

only when their bargaining power is low: in that case, the buying group enables the retailers

to receive "a larger share of a smaller pie". When their bargaining power is large enough,

retailers jointly prefer to implement the efficient assortment.

We then compare the impact of partial and full coverage buying groups. In case of full

coverage, we assume that a small producer of type B on one market would have to pay a

fixed cost to sell on the second market. This assumption aims at representing the cost for a

small supplier to expand at an international level. As the intermediate product l is sold less

often in the case of a full coverage buying group, consumer surplus can be worse off under

full than under partial coverage. Besides, full coverage is more harmful for small suppliers,

and, whenever it is jointly profitable for the retailers, it also harms the large supplier more

than partial coverage. Finally, retailers joint profit is larger with partial coverage than with

full coverage when, in equilibrium, the small producer is excluded. This happens when the

3

Page 5: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

consumers valuation for the intermediate product is not too high. Indeed, in that case, the

slotting fee received by the retailer is paid by the large supplier, and this fee is higher when

the competitive pressure exerted by the small supplier is high, that is, when he does not incur

the export cost he faces under full coverage. By contrast, when the small producer is not

excluded in equilibrium, the retailers profit is larger under full coverage. Indeed, in that case,

the retailer captures the whole profit of the small supplier through the slotting fee, and this

one is larger when the relative quality of product l is higher (namely, when the consumers’

valuation for the intermediate product is close to their valuation for their preferred variety).

This article contributes to the growing theoretical literature on buying groups. Some

papers explain the rationality of retailers’ purchasing cooperation through competition on

the downstream market. Caprice and Rey (2015) consider competing retailers facing a unique

efficient supplier, and a fringe of inefficient suppliers. They show that a buying group increases

buyer power by enhancing each retailer’s outside option in the negotiation with the supplier.

Indeed, in case of a breakdown in the negotiation, the profit of the retailer decreases less when

his competitors also delist the products of the supplier, which happens when the retailers

adopt a joint listing strategy. Piccolo and Miklós-Thal (2012) and Doyle and Han (2014) show

that buying groups agreements can improve retailers’ ability to sustain collusive equilibrium

downstream coordinating on high wholesale price and using back margins payments.

Another bunch of papers analyse buying groups among firms that do not compete on the

downstream market8. Inderst and Shaffer (2007), which is the closest to our analysis, propose

a setting rationalising purchasing cooperation of retailers present on different downstream

markets and sourcing through common suppliers. They show that by merging (or forming

a buying group) retailers can increase their profit by reducing the total number of products8It is the case for the above-mentioned alliance between Carrefour and Tesco. Tesco holds stores in five

countries in Europe (Ireland, Poland, Hungary, Slovakia, Czech republic) and four in Asia (China, Japan,Malaysia and Thailand). Tesco’s main market is the United-Kingdom in which it represents 27.7% of totalgrocery market shares in 2019 (source: Kantar WorldPanel). Carrefour holds stores in seven countriesin Europe (Belgium, France, Italy, Poland, Slovakia, Spain, Turkey), two in South-America (ArgentinaBrazil) and two in Asia (China, Taiwan). Carrefour and Tesco are simultaneously present in two countriesin Europe and one in Asia. Similarly, the Horizon alliance gathers retailers active on separate markets.Auchan holds supermarkets in ten countries in Europe (France, Spain, Hungary, Italy, Poland, Portugal,Romania, Russia, Ukraine), three countries in Asia (China, Taiwan, Vietnam), four countries in Africa(Tunisia, Senegal, Mauritania, Algeria). Casino is active only in France in Europe, in four countries in SouthAmerica (Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, Uruguay) and in Indian Ocean (Madagascar, Mayotte, Reunion...).Metro’s retail brand is Real which is active in three countries in Europe (Germany, Turkey, Romania).

4

Page 6: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

sold in the economy. In this framework, buying group implementation leads to the exclusion

of a supplier, reduction of product diversity available to consumers and reduction of the total

industry profit. Retailers are able to capture a larger share of a smaller profit.

This paper is also related to the literature that analyses network formation in vertically

related markets. Marx and Shaffer (2010), Chambolle and Molina (2018) show that retailers

can strategically use capacity constraints in order to increase their buyer power. In these

papers, constraints on stocking capacity and slotting fees are used by retailers to extract a

larger share of a smaller industry profit. In the same vein, Ho and Lee (2019) develop a

bargaining procedure called "Nash-in-Nash with threat of replacement". Using this concept,

they rationalise American health insurers hospital network reduction, for profit extraction

motives. This paper adopts the timing developped in Chambolle and Molina (2018). In

their paper, they highlight close connections between their setting with a slotting fee stage

followed by a Nash-in-Nash bargaining stage within the selected network and the one stage

"Nash-in-Nash with threat of replacement" bargaining developed by Ho and Lee (2019).

The article is organised as follows. Section 2 presents the model and notations. Section 3

gives bargaining results common to the three listing strategies we consider : No buying group,

partial coverage buying group, full coverage buying group. Section 4 derives the equilibrium

outcome for each of the considered listing strategies. In Section 5, we compare suppliers

profits, product variety and retailers profits for each listing strategy. In section 7 we discuss

policy implications and robustness of our results.

2 Model

2.1 Firms and markets

There are two separated markets i ∈ {1, 2}. Each of these markets contains three firms

ki ∈ {si, li, ri}. Firms si and i are two suppliers offering horizontally differentiated goods of

characteristics θ through a monopolist retailer ri. Supplier l is a "large supplier", active on

the two markets (so l1 = l2 = l) and carrying two differentiated products of characteristics

θ ∈ {A,C}. By contrast, si is a "small supplier" active uniquely on one market and carry-

5

Page 7: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

ing only one product of characteristics θ = Bi, for the sake of simplicity we consider that

B1 = B2 = B.

Finally, in the economy there are three suppliers and two retailers ki ∈ {s1, s2, r1, r2} and

three characteristics of products θ ∈ {A,B,C}.

Suppliers have symmetric and constant marginal cost of production c, retailers do not

support any additional cost. Retailers have constrained stocking capacity N = 2, which

means that each retailer can source at most two varieties of products. On each market at

least one product is excluded.

2.2 Assumptions on industry profit

We introduce the primitive industry profit ΠXi and ΠXY

i (p) representing the maximum in-

dustry profit for a given assortment.

• ΠXi = arg maxs(p− c)DX

i (p) is the maximum industry profit on market i when ri offers

one product X.

DXi (p) denotes the demand function of product X sold at price p on market i when X

is the only product available on the market.

• ΠXYi = arg max{p,p′}(p − c)DXY

i (p, p′) + (p′ − c)DY Xi (p′, p) is the maximum industry

profit on market i when ri offers two products X and Y .

DXYi (p, p′) denotes the demand function for product X on market i when X and Y are

respectively sold at price p and p′ on the market.

We make the following assumptions on primitive industry profits:

Among all potential single product assortments, A (resp. C) generates the highest indus-

try profit on market 1 (resp. market 2):

ΠA1 ≥ ΠB

1 > ΠC1 > 0 (1)

ΠC2 ≥ ΠB

2 > ΠA2 > 0

6

Page 8: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

The above assumption implies that the preferences for the two products are inverted among

markets.

For the sake of simplicity, for each market, we will denote by "H" the preferred product,

"L" the least preferred product and M the middle one. Henceforth (1) becomes:

∀i ∈ {1, 2}ΠHi ≥ ΠM

i > ΠLi > 0 (2)

Among all two products assortments, AB (resp. BC) generates the highest industry profit

on market 1 (resp. market 2):

∀i ∈ {1, 2}ΠHMi ≥ ΠHL

i > ΠMLi > 0 (3)

Products can either be imperfect substitutes or independent, which implies that any

assortment of two products does not yield more surplus than the sum of industry profits

generated by each product:

∀i ∈ {1, 2}ΠHi + ΠL

i ≥ ΠHLi > ΠH

i (4)

The marginal contribution of M to the industry profit ΠHMi is lower than its marginal

contribution to the industry profit ΠMLi .

(ΠMLi − ΠL

i ) ≥ (ΠHMi − ΠH

i ) (5)

The only difference between market 1 and 2 is that preferences are inverted between

products A and C.

∀X ∈ {H,M,L},ΠX1 = ΠX

2 (6)

∀XY ∈ {HM,ML,HL},ΠXY1 = ΠXY

2

Assumption (1) is close to the one made Inderst and Shaffer (2007). Considering only one

market, assumptions (2) to (5) are common to Chambolle and Molina (2018). Assumption

7

Page 9: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

(6) is made for the sake of simplicity.

2.3 Timing and listing strategies

We are interested in comparing the economic outcome under three types of buying strategies:

no buying group, partial coverage buying group, full coverage buying group. For each case,

choices of suppliers and retailers can be represented by the following sequential game of two

stages:

- Stage 1: Suppliers observe retailers’ listing strategy and the set of listing assortments available.

They compete in slotting-fees for being listed. The number of products listed by each

retailer cannot exceed the capacity constraint N = 2. Slotting-fees are purely vertical,

they are conditional to bidder’s product(s) listed but cannot be conditional to other

supplier product(s) listed. Slotting fees are paid uniquely if the corresponding offer is

selected by the retailer.

- Stage 2: For listed products, retailer ri engages in a bilateral negotiation with suppliers to de-

termine the tariffs of products. Negotiation are simultaneous, contracts are secrets and

consist of a fixed-fee.

The three listing strategies may affect stage 1 of the game, other stages are unchanged.

Listing strategies are defined as follows.

• No buying group: Each retailer negotiates independently which product to list. Retailer

ri lists at most two products among: A and C offered by l and B offered by si. For

each market, suppliers si and l pay to ri the slotting fee corresponding to the chosen

listing assortment.

• Partial coverage buying group: Retailers take a joint listing decision on large supplier’s

product but continue to list independently small suppliers’ products. In this case,

asymmetric listing assortments of two product are not available: for example listing

AB in country 1 and BC in country 2 is not feasible.

Slotting fees are attributed as follows. For each market, assume si’s product listed,

then each retailer collect separately the corresponding slotting-fee. Now, assume l’s

8

Page 10: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

product(s) listed, then retailers collect and share a unique slotting-fee from l for both

markets. The chosen joint-listing decision is the one maximising the joint profit of

retailer. Common slotting fee sharing will discussed in section ...

• Full coverage buying group: Retailers take a joint listing decision over the whole product

line. Just like with limited coverage buying groups, retailers take a joint listing decision

on large supplier’s products. Under Full coverage buying group strategy, retailers take

a joint listing decision on small suppliers as well: at most one supplier of product B

is listed for serving both markets. In this case, small suppliers are able to serve both

markets at any fixed exporting cost E. The chosen joint-listing decision is the one

maximising the joint profit of retailer.

2.4 Equilibrium concept

The equilibrium concept we use here is the same as Chambolle and Molina (2018). In stage 2

of the game, each retailer engages in bilateral negotiation with suppliers of its listed products.

We use a bargaining protocol à la Horn and Wolinsky (1988) commonly referred as the "Nash-

in-Nash" according to Collard-Wexler et al. (2019), which is an extension of the contract

equilibrium concept developed in Crémer and Riordan (1987) and Allain and Chambolle

(2011). Several assumptions are made in this bargaining framework. First, negotiations

are simultaneous and contracts are secrets. Second, firms are assumed to be schizophrenic,

which means that a firm negotiating with a given firm do not know anything about its own

negotiations with other firms. Because of secret negotiation and schizophrenia, for a given

negotiation firms must perform beliefs on outcome of other negotiations outcomes. In this

setting, firms have passive beliefs which means that players don’t change their beliefs on

the other players’ action if they receive an offer out of the equilibrium path (McAfee and

Schwartz (1994)). Third, firm can have asymmetric exogenous bargaining, α (resp. (1 − α)

denotes exogenous bargaining power of the retailer (resp. supplier).

In this setting, some products are not listed because of the limited listing capacity of retailers,

thus suppliers compete for being listed. Scarce listing capacity play a role in the division of

surplus between retailers and suppliers through combination of stage 1 and stage 2. This

9

Page 11: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

framework closely relates to the bargaining literature on bargaining with outside options (eg :

Shaked and Sutton (1984), Binmore et al. (1989) ). In this literature status-quo payoff differs

from bargainer’s outside option. The status-quo payoff correspond to bargainer’s position if

negotiation lasts forever without finding an agreement whereas the outside option refers to

bargainer’s best alternative outside the negotiated agreement.

3 Resolution of the bargaining stage

Regardless of the listing strategy, the outcome of stage 2 negotiation depends on the outcome

of stage 1 assortment decision. The bargaining resolution is common to the three listing

strategies. The results founded here will be used in the following sections considering others

strategies. We consider the bargaining solution in one country, for a given outcome of stage

1 listing decision; results are symmetric in the other.

Assortment HL is chosen In this case, there is only one negotiation for each retailer,

who negotiates with the same supplier for both products simultaneously. Straightforward

resolution of the Nash bargaining in stage 2 yields the following equilibrium fee FHLli =

(1− α)ΠHL for the large supplier, and zero for the small one whose production is not sold.

In equilibrium, the retailer thus receives a share α and the large supplier a share 1−α of

the joint profit .

πHLri = αΠHL

πHLli = (1− α)ΠHL

πHLsi = 0

Product M is listed Consider first the subgames where retailer ri sells product M, that

is, assortment is XM , with X ∈ {H,L}. Straightforward resolution of the Nash bargaining

in stage 2 yields the following equilibrium fees:

10

Page 12: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

FXMli = (1− α)(ΠXM − ΠM) (7)

FXMsi = (1− α)(ΠXM − ΠX) (8)

Each supplier thus receives (1−α) times his contribution to the joint profit, and equilibrium

profits are as follows:

πXMli = FXM

li = (1− α)(ΠXM − ΠM)

πXMsi = FXM

si = (1− α)(ΠXM − ΠX)

πXMri = ΠXM − FXM

li − FXMsi = (1− α)(ΠX + ΠM) + (−1 + 2α)ΠXM

4 Resolution and equilibrium profits

In this section, we solve the game and present equilibrium profits for each listing strategy of

the retailers.

4.1 No buying group

Assume first that retailers have opted for no buying group strategy. In stage 1, for each

market suppliers si and l compete in slotting fees to be listed by retailer ri. Listing decision

are independent, we present here the resolution for a given market.

First note that large supplier l is never ready to pay a positive slotting fee to have only

one of its products listed by retailer ri: indeed, as there is only one possible other supplier

selling only one product, and as ri prefers to attributes its two slots, l does not have to pay

to have one product listed. He must however compete with the small supplier whenever he

wishes to ensure that his two products are sold, hence he will be ready to pay a positive fee

SHLli .

Assume now that retailer ri lists productM from si. Then ri is better off listing H instead

11

Page 13: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

of L, as the slotting fee paid by the small supplier is unchanged (by assumption the slotting

fee paid by the small supplier is not conditional upon the other product sold), and the sales

profit is higher:

πHMri > πML

ri (9)

⇔α(ΠHM − ΠML) + (1− α)((ΠML − ΠL)− (ΠHM − ΠH)) > 0 By assumption 5

Hence retailer ri will choose either to sell the assortment HM , or to sell the assortment

HL. Let us know consider the competition between the large and the small suppliers.

The maximum fee the large supplier will be ready to pay to have product L listed is:

SHLli ≡ πHL

li − πHMli (10)

= (1− α)(ΠHL − ΠHM + ΠM) (11)

The maximum fee the small supplier will be ready to pay to have product M listed is:

SHM

si ≡ πHMsi (12)

= (1− α)(ΠHM − ΠH) (13)

Proposition 1 In the baseline model with independent sourcing, markets are fully separated.

The equilibrium is such that in each country, the two favourite products are sold at the

equilibrium, i.e AB on market 1 and BC on market 2. Small suppliers s1 and s2 have to pay

a slotting fee for not being replaced by l ’s excluded good.

12

Page 14: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

Equilibrium profits are the followings:

ΠHMri = ΠHL − (1− α)(ΠHM − ΠM) if ΠHL − α(1− α)ΠH > 0 (14)

= (1− α)(ΠH + ΠM)− (1− 2α)ΠHM otherwise

ΠHMli = (1− α)(ΠHM − ΠM) (15)

ΠHMsi = ΠHM − ΠHL if ΠHL − α(1− α)ΠH > 0 (16)

= (1− α)(ΠHM − ΠH) otherwise

Sketch of proof for Proposition 1 For each market assortment HM is always chosen at

the equilibrium because small supplier is willing to offer an higher profit to have his product

listed than large supplier to have his two products listed. Formally it can be written as

follows :

πHMri + S

M

si ≥ πHLri + S

HL

li (17)

At the equilibrium, si secures a slot and maximises his profit, thus makes an offer such

that the retailer ri is indifferent between choosing HM and HL, so we have:

SHMsi = πHL

ri − πHMri + S

HLli (18)

⇔SHMsi = ΠHL − αΠHM − (1− α)ΠH .

Equilibrium profits are determined as follows :

ΠHMri = πHM

ri + SHMsi if + SHM

si > 0

= πHMri otherwise

ΠHMli = πHM

li

ΠHMsi = πHM

si − SHMsi if + SHM

si > 0

= πHMsi otherwise

13

Page 15: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

4.2 Limited coverage buying group

Assume now that retailers r1 and r2 have opted for a limited coverage buying-group. In stage

1, suppliers si, sj and l compete in slotting fees to be listed by retailers. Listing decision are

no longer independent because the listing decision on large supplier product(s) is common

for the two retailers. With such a limited coverage buying group, any asymmetric assortment

of two products by market is not feasible: both retailers commit to selling the same product

assortment, that is, either AB, BC, or AC – whenever product l is in the assortment however,

each retailer sources from his own local supplier.

As in the no buying group case, the large supplier l is never ready to pay a positive slotting

fee to have only one of its products listed by retailers. Consider now the supplier’s willingness

to pay for having its two products listed. Note that, because of assumption (5), retailers and

suppliers are indifferent between listing AB or BC, the two listing decisions give perfectly

symmetric economic outcome and arise at same conditions. For the sake of simplicity, we

focus here on competition between the large and small suppliers on assortments AB and AC.

The case of the assortment BC will be symmetric.

Lemma 1 large supplier l has a higher willingness to pay for having its two products listed

in both markets when retailers have opted for limited coverage buying group compared to the

case when they have opted for no buying group.

Sketch of proof for Lemma 1 The maximum fee the large supplier is ready to pay to

have product C listed is the difference between the profit he receives when he sells the two

products on both markets, and the profit he receives when he sells only one product on both

markets, that is,

SHLl ≡(πHL

l1 − πHMl1 ) + (πHL

l2 − πMLl2 )

This fee is larger than (πHLl1 − πHM

l1 ) + (πHLl2 − πHM

l2 ), the total willingness to pay of supplier

l for having its two products sold in each market with no buying group strategy.

Lemma 2 Sum of suppliers willingness to pay to have their products listed on market 1 and

14

Page 16: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

2 when retailers have opted for limited coverage buying group compared to the case when they

have opted for no buying group.

Ss = SHM

s1 + SML

s2 (19)

With SHMs1 = πHM

s1 and SMLs2 = πML

s2

The maximum fee small supplier 1 will be ready to pay to have product B listed on

market 1 is the same as in the no buying group case SHM

s1 = πHMs1 . The maximum fee small

supplier 2 will be ready to pay to have product B listed on market 2 is higher than in the no

buying group case SMLs2 = πML

s2 because of assumption (5).

Lemma 3 Product B is listed on market 1 if and only if it is listed on market 2. Retailers

decision to list product B on each market depends of the sum of slotting fees proposed by the

two small suppliers. Thus there exists a continuum of slotting fee SHMs1 and SML

s2 leading to

assortment AB.

Retailers take the listing decision which leads to the highest joint profit, so the listing

agreements depends of the sum of slotting fees proposed by the two suppliers. Finally, small

suppliers stay on the market if and only if:

ΠHMr1 + ΠML

r2 ≥ ΠHLr1 + ΠHL

r2 (20)

⇔πHMr1 + πML

r2 + SHMs1 + S

MLs2 ≥ πHL

r1 + πHLr2 + S

HLl

⇔(ΠHM1 − ΠHL

1 )− (ΠHL2 − ΠML

2 ) ≥ 0

⇔ΠHM + ΠML ≥ 2ΠHL

Proposition 2 When retailers have opted for limited coverage buying group, two types of

listing assortments can arise at the equilibrium:

• Large supplier partial listing: If ΠHM + ΠML ≥ 2ΠHL, listing decision is AB or

BC. Each small supplier si has its product listed on market i, large supplier l has a

15

Page 17: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

unique product listed on both markets. Resulting profits are:

ΠAB,pr = ΠAB

r1 + ΠABr2

= 2ΠHL + (1− α)(2ΠM − ΠML − ΠHM) if SABl ≥ 0

= (1− α)(ΠH + ΠL + 2ΠM − ΠHM − ΠML) + α(ΠHM + ΠML) otherwise

ΠAB,ps = ΠHM + ΠML − 2ΠHL if SAB

l ≥ 0

= (1− α)(ΠHM − ΠH + ΠML − ΠL) otherwise

ΠAB,pl = ΠAC

l1 + ΠACl2

= (1− α)(ΠHM − ΠM) + (1− α)(ΠML − ΠM)

• Small suppliers exclusion: If 2ΠHL > ΠHM + ΠML, listing decision is AC, thus

large supplier has its two products listed and small suppliers s1 and s2 are excluded.

Resulting profits are:

ΠAC,pr = ΠAC

r1 + ΠACr2

= α(ΠHM + ΠML) + 2(1− α)ΠM if SACl ≥ 0

= 2αΠHL otherwise

ΠAC,ps = ΠAC

s1 + ΠACs2 = 0

ΠAC,pl = ΠAC

l1 + ΠACl2

= 2ΠHL − α(ΠHM + ΠML)− 2(1− α)ΠM if SACl ≥ 0

= 2(1− α)ΠHL otherwise

Sketch of proof for Proposition 2 Retailers choose assortment AB against AC if small

suppliers s1 and s2 offer a slotting fee such that:

πHMr1 + πML

r2 + SAB,ps ≥ πHL

r1 + πHLr2 + S

HLl

16

Page 18: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

With SAB,ps = SHM

s1 + SMLs2 . So we have:

SAB,ps = (πHL

r1 + πHLr2 + S

HLl )− (πHM

r1 + πMLr2 )

= 2ΠHL − (1− α)(ΠH + ΠL)− α(ΠHM + ΠML)

Retailers choose assortment AC against AB if large supplierl offers a slotting fee such that:

πHLr1 + πHL

r2 + SAC,pl ≥ πHM

r1 + πMLr2 + Ss

So we have:

SAC,pl = πHM

r1 + πMLr2 + Ss − (πHL

r1 + πHLr2 )

= Max{0, 2(1− α)ΠM + α(ΠHM + ΠML − 2ΠHL)}

When assortment AB is chosen equilibrium profits are determined as follow :

ΠAB,pr = πHM

ri + πMLri + SAB,f

s if SAB,ps > 0

= πHMri + πML

ri otherwise

ΠAB,ps = πHM

si + πMLsi − SAB,f

s if SAB,ps > 0

= πHMsi + πML

si otherwise

ΠAB,pl = πHM

li + πMLli

When assortment AC is chosen equilibrium profits are determined as follow :

ΠAC,pr = 2πHL

ri + SAC,pl if SAC,p

l > 0

= 2πHLri otherwise

ΠAC,ps = 0

ΠAC,pl = 2πHL

li − SAC,pl if SAC,p

l > 0

= 2πHL,pl1 otherwise

17

Page 19: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

4.3 Full coverage buying group

Assume that retailers have opted for full coverage buying group strategy. This agreement

implies that retailers take a joint listing decision over the whole product line. The difference

with limited coverage buying group is that in this case, at most one supplier of product B is

listed for serving both markets. Serving both markets generate a fixed exporting cost E for

small suppliers. Products listed by each retailers are exactly the same (same product offered

by the same supplier). Candidate listing assortments are : AB, BC, AC.

As in the two previous cases, large supplier l is never ready to pay a positive slotting fee

to have only one product listed. As in the limited coverage buying group case, retailers and

suppliers are indifferent between assortments AB or BC. Let us consider retailers choice

between listing assortment AB and AC.

large supplier l has the same willingness to pay to have its two products listed in both

countries than in the limited coverage buying group case.

SAC

l = (πHLl1 − πHM

l1 ) + (πHLl2 − πHM

l2 )

Each small supplier si has to choose between being listed for the two market or not being

listed.

SACsi = (πHM

si + πMLsi )− E (21)

Retailers take the joint listing decision which leads to the highest joint profit. Assortment

AB is chosen if and only if :

ΠHMr1 + ΠML

r2 ≥ ΠHLr1 + ΠHL

r2

⇔πHMr1 + πML

r2 + SACs ≥ πHL

r1 + πHLr2 + S

HLl (22)

⇔(ΠHM1 − ΠHL

1 )− (ΠHL2 − ΠML

2 )− E ≥ 0

18

Page 20: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

Proposition 3 When retailers have opted for full coverage buying group, two types of listing

assortments can arise at the equilibrium:

• large supplier partial listing: If ΠHM +ΠML−E ≥ 2ΠHL, listing decision is AB or

BC. One of the two small supplier si has its product listed on both market, the second is

excluded, large supplier l has a unique product listed on both markets. Resulting profits

are :

ΠAB,fr = (1− α)(2ΠM) + α(ΠHM + ΠML)− E (23)

ΠAB,fs = 0 (24)

ΠAB,fl = (1− α)((ΠHM − ΠM) + (ΠML − ΠM)) (25)

• Small suppliers exclusion: If 2ΠHL > ΠHM + ΠML − E, listing decision is AC.

Small suppliers are excluded and large supplier has its two products listed on both mar-

kets. Resulting profits are :

ΠAC,fr = 2(1− α)(ΠM) + α(ΠML + ΠHM)− E if SAC

l > 0 (26)

= 2αΠHL otherwise

ΠAC,fs = 0 (27)

ΠAC,fl = 2ΠHL − 2(1− α)ΠM − α(ΠHM + ΠML) + E if SAC

l > 0 (28)

= 2(1− α)ΠHL otherwise

Sketch of proof for Proposition 3 Assume retailers choose listing assortment AB. Equi-

librium slotting fee paid by the chosen small supplier do not depend of large supplier willing-

ness to pay to have two products listed. Small suppliers compete in price and sell perfectly

substitutes products. Each retailer offers it maximal willingness to pay, no matter large

suppliers willingness to pay for selling two products:

SAB,fsi = (πHM

si + πMLsi )− E

= Max{0, (1− α)((ΠHM − ΠH) + (ΠML − ΠL))− E}

19

Page 21: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

Assume now that retailers choose listing assortment AC. Slotting fee paid by large

supplier to have its two products listed depends of small suppliers willingness to pay. Retailers

choose assortment AC if large supplier l offers a slotting fee such that:

πHLr1 + πHL

r2 + Sl ≥ πHMr1 + πML

r2 + SABsi

So we have:

SACl = πHM

r1 + πMLr2 + SAB

si − (πHLr1 + πHL

r2 )

= Max{0, (1− α)(2ΠM) + α(ΠHM + ΠML − 2ΠHL)− E}

When assortment AB is chosen equilibrium profits are determined as follows :

ΠAB,fr = πHM

ri + πMLri + SAB,f

s

ΠAB,fs = 0

ΠAB,fl = πAC

li + πACli

When assortment AC is chosen equilibrium profits are determined as follows :

ΠAC,fr = 2πHL

ri + SAC,fl if SAC,f

l > 0

= 2πHLri otherwise

ΠAC,fs = 0

ΠAC,fl = 2πHL

l1 − SAC,fl if SAC,f

l > 0

= 2πHLl1 otherwise

5 Comparison of the different listing strategies

In this section we compare suppliers profits, consumer surplus and retailers profits for the

different listing strategies.

20

Page 22: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

5.1 Listing strategies consequences for small suppliers profits

Proposition 4 (i) Small suppliers’ profit is negatively affected by the two types of buying-

groups (ie: their profits are reduced and they can be excluded from the market). (ii) full

coverage buying group is more harmful than partial coverage buying group (ie: exclusion is

more likely and profit reduction is larger).

Πs ≥ Πps ≥ Πf

s

Where Πs = Πs1 + Πs2

Sketch of proof for Proposition 4 (i) We show that Πs ≥ Πps ≥ Πf

s is always satisfied.

It is straightforward that Πps ≥ Πf

s and Πs ≥ Πfs are satisfied since Πf

s = 0 whereas Πps ≥ 0

and Πs. Πs ≥ Πps can be show comparing slotting fees paid by small suppliers. Assume there

is a situation in which Πs < Πps. It must in a situation in which with partial coverage buying

group assortment AB is chosen. Indeed, Πps = 0 when AC is chosen. As tariffs negotiated in

stage 2 are the same, SAB,ps > Ss must be satisfied, but this inequality is never satisfied.

(ii) We show that joint listing strategies can lead small retailers to be excluded and

particularly when a full coverage buying group is implemented. Small suppliers are never

excluded when there is no buying group, they are excluded when 2ΠHL > ΠHM + ΠML with

partial coverage buying group and when 2ΠHL > ΠHM + ΠML−E with full coverage buying

group. As E is positive it is clear that exclusion is more likely with full coverage buying

group.

5.2 Listing strategies consequences for large suppliers profits

Proposition 5 (i) The worst listing strategy for large suppliers profit is partial coverage

listing strategy. (ii) Large suppliers may earn higher profits when retailers adopt full coverage

listing strategy than when the adopt independent listing strategies.

Πpl ≤ Πl and Πp

l ≤ Πfl

21

Page 23: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

Sketch of proof for Proposition 5 (i) Large suppliers’ profit is lower when retailers

have formed partial coverage buying group than when they have not formed buying group.

Assume retailers have formed a partial coverage buying group and assortment is either AB

or BC, as in the case without buying group large supplier do not pay any slotting fee for

having one product listed. But in this case large supplier sell the least preferred good on one

of the market instead of the preferred good, so he earns a smaller tariff. Assume now that

with partial coverage buying group AC is chosen: large supplier pay a slotting fee to sell its

two products on both market instead of selling the preferred good in each market. Tariffs

increase on sales do not compensate the slotting fee (otherwise AC would arise in the no

buying group case) so its profit is lower than with no buying group.

Large suppliers’ profit is lower when retailers have formed a partial coverage buying group

than when they have formed a full coverage buying group. Assume retailers have formed a

full coverage buying group and assortment is either AB or BC: large supplier profit is the

same than with limited coverage buying group. Indeed, assortment would have been the

same under partial coverage buying group and for both listing strategy large suppliers do not

pay slotting fee. Assume now that retailers have formed a full coverage buying group and

assortment is AC. With partial coverage buying group assortment would have been AB or

AC. In both cases, large supplier pay a slotting fee less important with full coverage buying

group because of the exporting cost that reduce profitability to enter the market for small

suppliers.

(ii) Assume retailers have formed a full coverage buying group and the exporting cost E

for small supplier is so high that it is not profitable for small suppliers to enter the market,

then large suppliers are in a monopolistic situation, they do not have to pay a positive slotting

fee for having their two products listed.

5.3 Listing strategy consequences for consumers

Proposition 6 (i) Joint listing strategies exclude the efficient assortment where the two

preferred goods HM are sold in both markets. (ii) Full coverage buying group implementation

may generates more assortment inefficiency than partial coverage buying group.

22

Page 24: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

Sketch of proof for Proposition 6 (i) When retailers do not form buying group, the two

preferred products are sold in each market, AB on market 1 and BC on market 2. When

retailers adopt a joint listing strategy, the best assortment is not available by assumption.

Equilibrium assortments of the two joint listing assortments are either AB, BC or AC sold

in both markets. When the product assortment is AB or BC, on one of the two markets

the preferred product in no longer available. When the product assortment is AC, the least

preferred product is sold in both markets instead of the medium one.

(ii) When ΠHM + ΠML > 2ΠHL > ΠHM + ΠML − E assortments AB or BC are more

efficient than AC (ΠHM + ΠML > 2ΠHL), they are chosen when retailers have formed a

partial coverage buying group but not when they have formed a full coverage buying group

because 2ΠHL > ΠHM + ΠML − E. In this case

5.4 Listing strategy consequences for retailers

In this subsection we provide first general results on retailers joint profitability without

demand specification then we use a linear demand to provide more insights.

5.4.1 General results

Proposition 7 Joint listing strategy is jointly profitable for the two retailers if and only if

their bargaining power α is not too large.

Sketch of proof for Proposition 7 Result (i) is in accordance to Inderst and Shaffer

(2007). Creating a buying group reduces the overall variety of products, thereby harming

industry profit. Indeed, by assumption the preferred assortment differs on the two markets,

therefore committing to a similar assortment in the two markets generates inefficiencies on

at least one of the markets. Despite this efficiency retailers may find this strategy profitable

because committing to a common listing strategy they enhances their buyer power, as the

threat of being delisted on all markets enhances competition between the suppliers at the

listing stage. Forming a buying group retailers "capture a larger share of a smaller pie", this

is profitable when α is not to big, ie when not forming a buying group retailers capture a

relatively small share of the industry profit.

23

Page 25: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

Lemma 4 When 2ΠHL > ΠHM +ΠML−E full coverage buying group is dominated by partial

coverage buying group.

Sketch of proof for Lemma 4 When 2ΠHL > ΠHM +ΠML−E retailers listing assortment

is AC when they form a partial or full coverage buying group. Comparing retailers profits

for the two joint listing strategies consist in comparing slotting fees paid by large suppliers

which is increasing with small retailers willingness to pay to be listed. As with full coverage

buying group small suppliers support and exporting cost E their willingness to pay to be

listed is reduced.

5.4.2 Results obtained with linear demand application

In order to have more insights on best listing strategies we use a linear demand model and

provide graphic illustrations. For x, z ∈ {h,m, l} & x 6= z we assume that representative

consumer utility can be written as follows:

UxZ = xqx + zqz −12(q2

x + q2z)− aqx ∗ qz − pxqx − pzqz

Which leads to the following demand functions :

qx = x− az − px + apz

a2 − 1qz = z − ax− pz + apx

a2 − 1

Parameter a represents the degree of substitutability between goods. h,m, l represents

intrinsic preference for goods H,M,L. We assume h = 2, l = 1 m ∈ [1, 2] and a ∈ [0; 0.5]

which satisfies the hypothesis of the model.

These graphs provide three main insights :

(i) Forming a buying group is not profitable for retailers when m is close to l. In this

case, slotting fees paid by small suppliers on each market or close to their contribution to the

industry profit, hence it is not profitable to avoid the efficient assortment for rent extraction

motives. (ii) Forming a full coverage buying group is profitable when m is close to h. When

24

Page 26: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

forming a full listing decision retailers capture the whole profit generated by small suppliers.

it is interesting to do so when M has an important contribution to the industry profit and E

is not to high. (iii) Forming a partial coverage buying group is profitable is profitable when

m take intermediate values. When m is relatively low AC is chosen, the large supplier accept

to pay a high slotting fee to have his to products listed in the two markets.

(a) α = 0.1, E = 0.2 (b) α = 0.3, E = 0.2

(c) α = 0.5, E = 0.2

Figure 1. Listing strategies and market structures

25

Page 27: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

6 Robustness checks and policy implications

6.1 Discussion on retailers’ endogenous choice of listing strategy

Until now we have not endogenize the listing strategy decision. Here, we discuss quickly

challenges raised by such an endogenization. Assume an extension of the game we have

considered until now in which retailers choose their listing strategy before Stage 1. We

discuss the following decision rule : Retailers always adopt the listing strategy maximizing

their joint profit. Such a decision is always a best strategy for each retailer only if they

are able to commit on slotting fee sharing such that each of them is assured that he will

earn at least the same profit without forming a buying group. Sharing equally slotting

fees jointly earned may not satisfy this condition. Indeed, when joint listing strategy is

formed and asymmetric equilibrium assortment is chosen (either AB or BC) one of the two

retailers support an inefficient assortment on its market whereas the other continue to sell

the two preferred goods. Forming a buying group leading to small suppliers exclusion (listing

assortment is AC) always supports equal sharing of slotting fees jointly earned.

6.2 Tariffs

We have assumed that tariffs negotiated in stage 2 consist of a fixed fee. However, our

results extend to a more general secret contract framework with efficient two-part tariffs, as

Bernheim and Whinston (1985) O’Brien and Shaffer (1997) have shown that in a vertical

structure where manufacturers sell to a common retailer, bilateral efficiency requires that

unit wholesale prices are set to marginal cost. This result hold for public or secret contracts.

More generally, any setup leading to efficient, cost based tariff would yield the same result.

6.3 Policy implications

In line with Inderst and Shaffer (2007) this article shows that buying groups may harm welfare

by reducing product variety. This paper provides additional insights for competition policy

in particularly it is the first to question the economic impact of the buying group coverage.

This is precisely the question the french competition authority mentioned in July 2018 when

26

Page 28: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

opening its new investigation. First, we show that full coverage buying groups may be more

harmful for consumers than partial coverage buying groups because they increase retailers

incentives to choose inefficient assortment for profit extraction purpose. Second, we show

that full coverage buying groups affect more suppliers than partial coverage buying groups.

Finally we show that small suppliers may be affected by buying groups implementation even

if they are outside of the agreement’s coverage.

7 Conclusion

This article analyzes the impact of retailers’ buying groups on both product variety and profit

sharing within the vertical chain.

First, we find that creating a buying group reduces the overall variety of products, thereby

harming consumer surplus and welfare. Retailers may find this strategy profitable because

when committing to a common listing strategy they enhance their buyer power, then they

are able to capture a larger share of a smaller industry profit. This result is in line with

Inderst and Shaffer (2007), however we show that the buying group creation may generate

inefficiency on both markets.

Second, we find that buying groups affect negatively suppliers profits. For small suppliers,

both types of buying groups are harmful but full coverage is the worst. For large suppliers,

full coverage buying groups are worst than partial coverage buying groups whenever they are

jointly profitable for the retailers. Finally, retailers joint profit is larger with partial coverage

than with full coverage when, in equilibrium, the small producer is excluded.

27

Page 29: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

8 Appendix

8.1 Stage 2 negotiation

8.1.1 Product M is sold

Consider first the subgames where retailer ri sells product M, that is, assortment is XM ,

with X ∈ {H,L}.

Consider the negotiation between retailer ri and supplier b. The retailer’s profit when he

succeeds in both negotiations is ΠXM −FXMli −FXM

si , while his status quo profit in case of a

breakdown is ΠM−FXMsi . The supplier’s profit if the negotiation succeeds is FXM

li +Flj, while

his status quo profit in case of a breakdonw is Flj. Consider now the negotiation between

retailer ri and supplier si. The retailer’s profit when he succeeds in both negotiations is

ΠXM − FXMli − FXM

si , while his status quo profit in case of a breakdown is ΠM − FXMli . The

supplier’s profit if the negotiation succeeds is FXMsi , while his status quo profit in case of a

breakdonw is 0.

Standard resolution of the Nash bargaining thus yields the following profit sharing:

(1− α)(ΠXM − FXMli − FXM

si − (ΠM − FXMsi ) = α(FXM

li + Flj − Flj)

(1− α)(ΠXM − FXMli − FXM

si − (ΠM − FXMli ) = αFXM

si

It leads to the following equilibrium values:

FXMli = (1− α)(ΠXM − ΠM) (29)

πXMri = ΠXM − FXM

li − FXMsi = (1− α)(ΠX + ΠM) + (−1 + 2α)ΠXM (30)

πXMli = FXM

li = (1− α)(ΠXM − ΠM) (31)

πXMsi = FXM

si = (1− α)(ΠXM − ΠX) (32)

28

Page 30: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

8.1.2 Assortment HL is chosen

Consider the negotiation between retailer ri and supplier b. The retailer’s profit when he

succeeds in both negotiations is ΠHL−FHLli , while his status quo profit in case of a breakdown

is 0. The supplier’s profit if the negotiation succeeds is FHLli +FHL

lj , while his status quo profit

in case of a breakdonw is FHLlj . In this case, there is only one negotiation, retailer negotiate

for both products simultaneously, and the nash condition can be written as follows:

(1− α)(ΠHL − FHLli ) = αFHL

li

It leads to the following equilibrium values:

FHLli = (1− α)(ΠHL) (33)

πHLri = ΠHL − FHL

l1 = αΠHL (34)

πHLli = FHL

li = (1− α)(ΠHL) (35)

πHLsi = 0 (36)

29

Page 31: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

References

Allain, M.-L. and C. Chambolle (2011, July). Anti-competitive effects of resale-below-cost

laws. International Journal of Industrial Organization 29(4), 373–385.

Autorité de la concurrence (2015). Avis n° 15-A-06 du 31 mars 2015 relatif au rapprochement

des centrales d’achat et de référencement dans le secteur de la grande distribution. pp. 90.

Bernheim, B. D. and M. D. Whinston (1985). Common Marketing Agency as a Device for

Facilitating Collusion. The RAND Journal of Economics 16(2), 269–281.

Berto Villas-Boas, S. (2007, April). Vertical Relationships between Manufacturers and Re-

tailers: Inference with Limited Data. The Review of Economic Studies 74(2), 625–652.

Binmore, K., A. Shaked, and J. Sutton (1989, November). An Outside Option Experiment.

The Quarterly Journal of Economics 104(4), 753.

Bonnet, C. and P. Dubois (2010, March). Inference on vertical contracts between manu-

facturers and retailers allowing for nonlinear pricing and resale price maintenance. The

RAND Journal of Economics 41(1), 139–164.

Caprice, S. and P. Rey (2015, December). Buyer Power from Joint Listing Decision. The

Economic Journal 125(589), 1677–1704.

Chambolle, C. and H. Molina (2018). Full-line forcing and product assortment in vertically

related markets. Working Paper.

Collard-Wexler, A., G. Gowrisankaran, and R. S. Lee (2019). “Nash-in-Nash” Bargaining:

A Microfoundation for Applied Work. journal of political economy, 33.

Crémer, J. and M. H. Riordan (1987). On Governing Multilateral Transactions with Bilateral

Contracts. The RAND Journal of Economics 18(3), 436–451.

Doyle, C. and M. A. Han (2014, May). Cartelization Through Buyer Groups. Review of

Industrial Organization 44(3), 255–275.

30

Page 32: Buying Groups and Product Variety - C R E S S E

Galbraith, J. K. (1952). American Capitalism: TheConcept of Countervailing Power. Boston:

Hough-ton Mifflin Co, 76.

Ho, K. and R. S. Lee (2019, February). Equilibrium Provider Networks: Bargaining and

Exclusion in Health Care Markets. American Economic Review 109(2), 473–522.

Horn, H. and A. Wolinsky (1988). Bilateral Monopolies and Incentives for Merger. The

RAND Journal of Economics 19(3), 408–419.

Inderst, R. and G. Shaffer (2007). Retail Mergers, Buyer Power and Product Variety. The

Economic Journal 117(516), 45–67.

Iozzi, A. and T. Valletti (2014, August). Vertical Bargaining and Countervailing Power.

American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 6(3), 106–135.

Marx, L. M. and G. Shaffer (2010). Slotting Allowances and Scarce Shelf Space. Journal of

Economics & Management Strategy 19(3), 575–603.

McAfee, R. P. and M. Schwartz (1994). Opportunism in Multilateral Vertical Contracting:

Nondiscrimination, Exclusivity, and Uniformity. The American Economic Review 84(1),

210–230.

O’Brien, D. P. and G. Shaffer (1997). Nonlinear Supply Contracts, Exclusive Dealing, and

Equilibrium Market Foreclosure. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 6(4),

755–785.

Piccolo, S. and J. Miklós-Thal (2012, September). Colluding through suppliers. The RAND

Journal of Economics 43(3), 492–513.

Roman Inderst and Mazzarotto Nicola (2008). Buyer power in distribution. In Issues in

Competition Law and Policy, Volume 3 of ABA, pp. 1953–1978.

Shaked, A. and J. Sutton (1984). Involuntary Unemployment as a Perfect Equilibrium in a

Bargaining Model. Econometrica 52(6), 1351–1364.

von Ungern-Sternberg, T. (1996, June). Countervailing power revisited. International Journal

of Industrial Organization 14(4), 507–519.

31