benefits from environmental taxation

42
MASTER’S THESIS Benefits from Environmental Taxation A Case Study of the US Tax on Ozone Depleting Substances HENRIK GÅVERUD 2004:035 SHU Social Science and Business Administration Programmes ECONOMICS PROGRAMME Department of Business Administration and Social Sciences Division of Social Sciences Supervisor: Anna Dahlqvist 2004:035 SHU • ISSN: 1404 – 5508 • ISRN: LTU - SHU - EX - - 04/35 - - SE

Upload: others

Post on 06-Jun-2022

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

MASTER’S THESIS

Benefits fromEnvironmental Taxation

A Case Study of the US Tax on Ozone Depleting Substances

HENRIK GÅVERUD

2004:035 SHU

Social Science and Business Administration Programmes

ECONOMICS PROGRAMME

Department of Business Administration and Social SciencesDivision of Social SciencesSupervisor: Anna Dahlqvist

2004:035 SHU • ISSN: 1404 – 5508 • ISRN: LTU - SHU - EX - - 04/35 - - SE

Page 2: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

i

ABSTRACT

In subsequent years the production and consumption of ozone depleting substances (ODS)

have been rapidly and worldwide reduced in order to fulfill the conditions in the Montreal

Protocol (1987). According to economic theory it is more effective to use a market-based

system than a regulatory one since the former combines environmental improvements and

economic efficiency. A regulatory system will instead cause economic inefficiency. The US is

one country that decided to use a market-based tax system in order to replace ODS. The

purpose of this thesis is to evaluate the environmental benefits in monetary terms and in terms

of reduced cases of negative human health effects caused by the US tax on ODS. Additionally

the economic costs and the net result of the tax will be calculated by combining the result of

two existing studies. The approximated estimations of the net results of the ODS tax in the US

is at least 32.87 billion of 1997 US Dollars. Additionally the tax has lead to at least 2,812

reduced cases of melonama skin cancer, 221 reduced cases of non-melonama skin cancer,

19,006 reduced cases of cataracts and 49 reduced fatalities from skin cancer.

Page 3: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

ii

SAMMANFATTNING

I enlighet med Montrealprotokollet (1987) har produktionen och konsumtionen av

ozonförtunnande substanser (ODS) kraftigt reducerats över hela världen. Ekonomisk teori

förespråkar ekonomiska styrmedel såsom skatter och överlåtbara utsläppsrättigheter framför

kvantitativa regleringar då de förstnämnda genererar både ekonomisk effektivitet och

miljömässiga förbättringar medan den sistnämnda metoden visserligen med större sannolikhet

når måluppfyllelsen men samtidigt skapar ineffektivitet på marknaden. USA har, till skillnad

från de flesta andra länder, använt sig av skattestyrmedlet vid sidan av de internationellt

överenskomna regleringarna vid reduktionen av användandet av ODS. Denna studie syftar till

att utvärdera de miljömässiga förbättringar som beskattningen av ODS i USA genererat.

Metoden som används är att analysera tidigare gjorda studier inom ämnet. Genom att

kombinera två av dessa studier beräknas ett nettoresultat av USA:s beskattning av ODS. Detta

nettoresultat uppskattas till minst 32,87 miljarder US Dollar i 1997 års värde. Vidare har

skatten bidragit till minst 2812 minskade fall av melonama hudcancer, 221 minskade fall av

övrig hudcancer, 19006 minskade fall av starr och 49 reducerade dödsfall som en följd av

hudcancer.

Page 4: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

iii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

ABSTRACT…………………………………………………………………..i

SAMMANFATTNING……………………………………………………....ii

TABLE OF CONTENTS…………………………………………………....iii

TABLES AND FIGURES…………………………………………………...v

Chapter I INTRODUCTION……………………………………………….1

1.1 Background………………………………………………………………1

1.2 Purpose…………………………………………………………………...2

1.3 Methodological Framework……………………………………………..2

1.4 Scope……………………………………………………………………...3

1.5 Disposition………………………………………………………………..3

Chapter II OZONE AND OZONE DEPLETION…………………………4

2.1 Ozone in the Atmosphere……………………………………………….4

2.2 The Depletion of the Ozone in the Stratosphere………………………4

2.3 Ozone-Depleting Substances (ODS)……………………………………6

2.4 Impacts from Ozone Depletion…………………………………………8

2.4.1 Biological Impacts from Ozone Depletion………………………….8

2.4.2 Climate Impacts from Ozone Depletion…………………………….8

Chapter III THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK……………………………9

3.1 Market Failures………………………………………………………….9

3.1.1 Externalities…………………………………………………………9

3.1.2 Collective Goods……………………………………………………10

3.1.3 Policy Failures………………………………………………………11

3.2 Environmental Policies………………………………………………….11

3.2.1 Command-and-Control Systems……………………………………11

3.2.2 Taxes………………………………………………………………..12

3.2.3 Tradable Permits……………………………………………………13

Page 5: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

iv

3.2.4 Subsidies……………………………………………………………14

3.3 Valuing the Environment……………………………………………….15

3.4 Environmental Valuation Methods…………………………………….16

3.4.1 Revealed Preference Methods………………………………………17

3.4.2 Expressed Preference Methods……………………………………..17

3.5 Summary…………………………………………………………………18

Chapter IV COSTS AND BENEFITS FROM TAXING ODS……………19

4.1 The US Taxation of ODS………………………………………...………19

4.2 Costs and Benefits from Reducing the ODS-production………………21

4.2.1 Costs from Substituting ODS………………………………………..21

4.2.2 Benefits from Substituting ODS…………………………………….23

4.3 The Estimated Net Benefits from the US Tax on ODS………………..25

Chapter V CONCLUSIONS AND DISCUSSION…………………………28

REFERENCES………………………………………………………………31

APPENDIX A…………………………………………………………………33

APPENDIX B………………………………………………………………...35

Page 6: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

v

TABLES AND FIGURES

Tables

Table 2.1 The Montreal Protocol plan for phasing out ODS……………….7

Table 4.1 The ODS and their ODP…………………………………….…20

Table 4.2 Estimated Costs of Replacing ODS 1987-2060 in units

of Billion of 1997 US Dollars…………………………….……..22

Table 4.3 Health Benefits from Reducing the Production and

Consumption of ODS in Accordance with the Montreal

Protocol 1987-2060……………………………………………23

Table 4.4 Non-Health Benefits in Billion of 1997 US Dollars of

Reducing the Production and Consumption of ODS in

Accordance with the Montreal Protocol 1987-2060…………….24

Table 4.5 Net Global Benefits from Phasing out ODS in units of

1997 US Dollars……………………………………………….25

Table 4.6 Health Benefits from the US Tax on ODS………………………26

Figures

Figure 3.1 Optimal Pollution………………………………………….…...10

Figure 3.2 Regulation of Emissions……………………………………...…11

Figure 3.3 Optimal Pigovian Tax………………………………………..…12

Figure 3.4 Market Equilibrium for Tradable Pollution Permits………………13

Figure 3.5 Introducing a Subsidy………………………………………..…14

Figure 3.6 Compensating Surplus (CS) and Equivalent Surplus (ES)……….16

Page 7: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

1

Chapter I INTRODUCTION

1.1 Background

The ozone layer constitutes a naturalising factor in the stratosphere. The depletion of the

ozone layer affects the absorption of ultraviolet- (UV) and infrared radiation. High radiation

may reduce human welfare since it can increase the risk of cancer and eye injuries, reduce

crop yields, lower ocean productivity and disrupt terrestrial ecosystems. (Barrow, 1995)

In the early 1970s it was first claimed that the ozone in the atmosphere was being depleted.

These claims were not satisfactorily verified, but in the mid-1980s the scientific community

concluded a significant reduction of the ozone concentration. The main cause of ozone

depletion appears to be emission of chloroflourcarbons (CFCs). The most important sources

of CFC emissions are the production, use and disposal of refrigerators, air-conditioning

systems, foams, aerosol sprays and cleaning materials (Perman et al, 1999).

Hydrofluorocarbons (HCFCs), Halons, Methyl chloroform, Carbon tetrachloride and Methyl

Bromide are other substances that contribute to the ozone depletion (ARC, 1997).

The depletion of the ozone layer is, in economic terms, a negative external effect. An external

effect, or an externality, is a market failure that occurs when the production or consumption of

one agent affects the utility of at least one other agent. In order to minimize the externalities

taxes are one among other (subsidies, regulations and tradable permits) instruments used.

Economic theory prefer to give the actors in the market incentive to change their behavior

rather than force them to do so, i.e. using taxes or a tradable permit system instead of

quantitative regulations. In the US initially a tradable permit system was introduced (1989)

but this system was replaced after just one year in use (1990) by a tax system. The reason of

this change between economic instruments took place because the US government wanted to

reduce the consumption of ODS below the caps. (Hoerner, 1995)

Page 8: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

2

1.2 Purpose

The purpose of this thesis is to evaluate the environmental benefits in monetary terms and in

terms of reduced cases of negative human health effects caused by the US tax on ozone

depleting substances (ODS). Additionally the economic costs and the net result of the tax will

be calculated.

1.3 Methodological Framework

The theoretical framework for this study is environmental economic theory. The theoretical

chapter will focus on market failures, in particular externalities, and policies used in order to

solve the problems occurring due to these failures. In the empirical framework studies

evaluating the effect of the ozone depletion, the reduction of the use of ODS and the existing

taxes on ozone-depleting chemicals in the US, will be reviewed and analyzed with the

theoretical framework as a point of reference. In order to get a monetary estimation of the

costs and benefits from the US tax of ODS calculations have been done in order to combine

different studies/data. These calculations are based on data from the study Global Benefits

and Costs of the Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer by Applied

Research Consultants (ARC, 1997) and statistics from the report Production and

Consumption of Ozone Depleting Substances under the Montreal Protocol 1986-2000 by

United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP, 2003). Additionally the empirical

framework and conclusions from the study Tax Tools for Protecting the Atmosphere: The US

Ozone-depleting Chemicals Tax (Hoerner, 1995) has been used.

ARC (1997) have estimated the costs and the environmental benefits from phasing out ODS

in accordance with the Montreal Protocol. The costs are in units of 1997 US Dollars and the

benefits are divided into two groups, health effects and non-health effects. The non-health

effects are also in terms of 1997 US dollars and the health effects are in terms of reduced

cases and fatalities of skin cancer and cataracts. From this data it is possible to calculate a

payback per cent, i.e. how much will one dollar spent on replacement investments pay back to

the investor in terms of environmental improvements. Assuming that this payback is the same

in the US as the mean global payback a calculation has been done estimating the US total

benefit from phasing out ODS. Hoerner (1995) means that the tax has contributed to at least

290 thousand tones of a total decrease of 530 thousand tones of CFC-11 emissions. That

means that the tax can credit about 56 per cent of the decrease. This share may give an

indication of the total contribution of the tax. Given this an estimation of the net dollar

Page 9: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

3

benefits was made in order to give an indication of the value of using the tax besides the

regulations in order to phase out ODS.

1.4 Scope

The Montreal Protocol strictly regulates the production and consumption of ODS. Then each

country can choose how to fulfill the goals in the Protocol. The thesis will evaluate the

environmental benefits and the economic costs from the tax on ODS in the US.

1.5 Disposition

The thesis proceeds as follows. Chapter two, background, aims to give the reader a

summarizing illustration of the ozone in the atmosphere, the human depletion of the ozone

layer by producing and consuming given substances and finally the impacts from ozone

depletion. Chapter three provides the theoretical background. The empirical framework,

chapter four, introduces the reader to the US ODS-tax and additionally evaluates how existing

studies estimate the benefits and costs from reducing the production of ODS. A calculation of

the net benefit from taxing ODS in US is also made. In chapter five an discussion and the

resulting conclusions will follow.

Page 10: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

4

Chapter II

OZONE AND OZONE DEPLETION

This chapter constitutes the background of the thesis and is thought to give the reader an

insight in the problems of depleting the ozone in the stratosphere. Why is ozone essential for

human life on Earth? Which substances affect the ozone layer negatively and in which

industries are/were these substances used? Finally, what are the long run effects of ozone

depletion?

2.1 Ozone in the Atmosphere

Ozone ( 3O ), which is one of the key components in the atmosphere, is produced by the action

of ultraviolet light on oxygen molecules. This chemical process, which occurs in the upper

layers of the atmosphere, has perplexed scientists for decades and is still not completely

understood. What is known is that the ozone concentration varies continuously as a result of

decay and creation processes. There are also large variations of ozone concentration by time,

spatial location and altitude. (Perman et al, 1999)

Ozone occurs at two levels in the atmosphere; in the stratosphere, which is between 15 and 50

kilometres above the ground, and in the troposphere, below 15 kilometres from the surface of

the Earth. It is the ozone in the stratosphere, usually named the ozone layer, that protects all

organisms on earth from about 90 percent of the high-energy solar ultraviolet (UV) radiation.

On the other hand the ozone in the troposphere is harmful to health and vegetation since high

levels of it can damage plants and forests and cause problems to people with respiratory

ailments (e.g. asthma). (Pearce, 1995)

2.2 The Depletion of the Ozone in the Stratosphere

Since ozone in the lower parts of the atmosphere has negative effects on ecosystems and

human beings this chapter will focus on the depletion of the ozone in the stratosphere.

Page 11: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

5

In 1926 the first measurement of ozone in the stratosphere took place. Until 1970 no

significant change was noticed: the layer was getting neither thinner nor thicker. However in

1970 a reduction of the concentration of ozone was reported, the ozone-layer had become

thinner and more UV-radiation was let through. (Pearce, 1995)

In the early 1970s scientists began to investigate the relationship between the use of certain

chemicals and the depletion of the ozone in the stratosphere (Barrett, 2003).

Chlorofluorocarbons, usually named CFCs, were one among other chemicals that scientists

focused on (Ibid.). In 1974 two scientists at University of California warned about the

destructive impact that CFCs could have on the atmosphere (Ibid.). However at first the

relationship was not completely verified, but in the late 1970s CFCs in aerosol sprays were

banned in some developed countries e.g. the US and Sweden (Ibid.). In the mid-1980s World

Meteorological Office and United Nations Environmental Programme (UNEP) confirmed that

CFCs stayed in the atmosphere for a long time and destroyed the ozone layer through release

of chlorine (Pearce, 1995). The chlorine stays active for long a time and one single chlorine

atom can destroy 100,000 molecules of ozone (Hanley et al, 1997).

In 1984 the journal Nature published a study showing that the ozone-concentration had

steadily fallen since 1956 (Ibid.). Two years later, in 1986, a British survey team discovered a

huge “hole” in the ozone layer over Antarctica (Perman et al, 1999). The “ozone-hole” was in

fact a reduction in ozone concentration between 60-95 percent over an area big as the United

States (Ibid.).

To reduce the emissions of CFCs international meetings and negotiations started to take place,

the first one in Vienna in 1985 (The Swedish Environmental Protection Agency, 2003). At the

Vienna Convention an international cooperation in research, monitoring and exchange of

information was agreed (Ibid.). Two years later, in the autumn of 1987, 25 countries agreed

the Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer (Ibid.). The Montreal

Protocol came into force in 1989 and the initially 25 countries were then increased by four

more (Ibid.). The domestic production and consumption of ODS, in particular the use of

CFCs, was by then international restricted (Ibid.). Nowadays 183 countries have signed the

Protocol and thus there are just a handful of countries (e.g. Afghanistan, Eritrea, Iraq and San

Page 12: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

6

Marino) left (Barett, 2003). Since 1987 there have been new meetings several times1,

resulting in the Protocol being more and more restrictive (The Swedish Environmental

Protection Agency, 2003). All CFCs, all Halons, 1,1,1-trichloroethane and HBFC are

nowadays banned in all developed countries (Ibid.). The plan is that all ODS are going to be

phased out all over the world in 2030 (Ibid.).

2.3 Ozone-Depleting Substances (ODS)

Before the relationship between ozone-depletion and CFCs was verified, CFCs were

commonly used in refrigerators, air-conditioner systems, aerosol sprays, foams and cleaning

materials (e.g. dry-cleaning establishments) (The Swedish Environmental Protection Agency,

2003). Until 1985, when the “ozone-hole” was discovered, the annual consumption of CFCs

was about 750,000 tons (Linden, 1993). The total amount of CFC-emissions was thereby

about 20 million tons (Ibid.).

When the Montreal Protocol was agreed the production and consumption of ODS were

radically decreased, especially in the developed countries but also in the developing world. In

Denmark, which is one of the leading countries phasing out ODS, the usage of these

substances declined by 98 percent between 1986 and 1998. (The State of Environment in

Denmark, 2001)

Since 1996 CFCs are banned in the developed countries (Perman et al, 1999). However in

developing countries the production increased until 1999, but thereafter it decreased

progressively and will continue to do so until it ends in 2010 (Ibid.). Initially

hydrochlorofluorocarbons (HCFCs), which together with CFCs use to be called Freon, were

used as the main substitute to CFCs in e.g. aerosols, foams, refrigeration and air-conditioning

systems and solvents (The State of Environment in Denmark, 2001). However besides CFCs,

HCFCs also have a negative effect on the ozone layer and therefore are strictly restricted.

(Ibid.). Other substances that affect the ozone layer negatively are controlled in the Montreal

Protocol, or one of the amendments to the Protocol (Applied Research Consultants, 1997).

These are for example Halons, Methyl Chloroform, Carbon Tetra Chloride and Methyl

Bromide (Ibid.). Halons, or halogenated hydrocarbons, are/were used primarily in fire fighting

applications (Ibid.). Methyl Chloroform and Carbon Tetrachloride were added to the list of

1 London (1990), Copenhagen (1992), Vienna (1995), Montreal (1997) and Bejing (1999).

Page 13: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

7

ODS at the conference in London in 1990 (Applied Research Consultants, 1997). The main

use for these was/is as solvents (Ibid.). At the Copenhagen meeting in 1992 the last substances

to be added to the ODS list was Methyl Bromide (Ibid.).

Table 2.1 The Montreal Protocol plan for phasing out ODS.

Substance Year phased out/ planned

to be phased out in

Developed Countries

Year phased out/ planned

to be phased out in

Developing Countries

Bromochloromethane 2002 2002

Carbon Tetrachloride 1996 2010

CFCs 1996 2010

Halons 1994 2010

HBFC 1996 1996

HCFCs 2030 2040

Methyl Bromide 2005 2015

Methyl Chloroform 1996 2015

Source: ARC, 1997.

Table 2.1 shows the plan for phasing out the ODS in the developed countries and in the

developing countries2. Note that exceptions can exist for some substances in both developed

and Article 5 countries.

Reducing the production and consumption of ODS means that other substances need to

replace the ODS. Hydrofluorocarbons (HFCs) have become the fundamental substitute to

Freon. HFCs do not contain any chlorine atoms and thus have no effect on the ozone in the

stratosphere. HFCs are described to have “the appropriate thermodynamic properties to be

used as technically and economically effective refrigerants fluids alternative to CFCs and

HCFCs”. (EFTC, 2003)

2 Named as Article 5 countries in the Montreal Protocol.

Page 14: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

8

2.4 Impacts from Ozone Depletion

To give the reader a well-illustrated example of the seriousness of ozone depletion one can

mention that before the ozone layer was formed in the stratosphere the living on Earth was

restricted to the seas. Thus ozone reduction may have both biological and climate impacts.

(Barrow, 1995)

2.4.1 Biological Impacts from Ozone Depletion

The biological impacts from depletion of the ozone layer are severe and in some ways

uncertain (Ibid.). Since increased UV-radiation may reduce crops (e.g. soybeans) one negative

effect is the threat to the world’s food supply (Ibid.). Other negative external effects from

ODS are health damages (e.g. skin cancer, different kinds of eye injuries and allergic

reactions) and upsets of natural biological cycles (e.g. loss of wildlife) (Ibid.). In particular the

marine plankton is very sensitive to UV-radiation and a significant reduction of plankton

affects the marine life and oceanic biogeochemical cycles seriously (Ibid.). That is because

phytoplankton is at the very bottom of the ocean food chain (Ibid.). In fact the “ozone-hole”

has reduced the fish stock with 6-9 percent (Pearce, 1995). In the long run ozone depletion

also may affect the human and animal immune system in a negative way although this impact

is more uncertain (Barrow, 1995).

2.4.2 Climate Impacts from Ozone Depletion

The climate impacts from ozone depletion are more uncertain than the biological (Barrow,

1995). The long run impact will depend on different factors such as the quantity of the

decreased ozone, the altitude of the depletion and the ozone concentration in the troposphere

(Ibid.). If, for example, the ozone concentration in the troposphere increases the effect may be

global cooling (Ibid.). Thus it is likely that increased UV-radiation is a contributor to global

warming (Pearce et al., 1991).

Page 15: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

9

Chapter III

THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

This chapter aims to give the reader a theoretical insight in the environmental problem of

market failures, different policies used to solve these problems and some practical issues on

each solution. Finally there is also a discussion on different environmental valuation methods;

which are the benefits and problems with each of these methods?

3.1 Market Failures

According to fundamental economic theory the price will adjust the market into equilibrium,

i.e. the supply curve equals the demand curve that generates an optimum price level (p*) and

an optimum quantity (q*). However this assumes perfect competition, i.e. that the agents of

the market have perfect information, that the property rights are well defined etc. If these

assumptions are not satisfied we may not reach the market equilibrium. This can occur in

different ways, e.g. if the market price is too high or too low. This phenomenon, called market

failure, is frequently occurring in markets for environmental goods. This chapter aims to

illustrate the problem with market failures in environmental markets. (Pearce & Turner, 1990)

3.1.1 Externalities

An external effect, or an externality, occurs when 1) one agents’ activity affects at least one

other agents’ utility and 2) this welfare loss/win not is compensated for. Pollution from

emissions is an example of a negative externality. Assume for example that firm A pollutes

and that has a negative effect on person B (i.e. a negative externality or an external cost).

Furthermore assume that this effect is not compensated for. Depending on the property rights,

i.e. whether firm A has the right to pollute or person B has the right to breathe fresh air, the

agents (A and B) compensate each other and the optimal pollution level, W* in figure 3.1., is

reached. (Ibid.)

Page 16: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

10

Figure 3.1 Optimal Pollution Source: Pearce & Turner, 1990

If B initially has the right to pollute, the starting point will be BW , i.e. the firm is profit

maximizing without including the marginal external cost for A ( AMEC ) in the calculations.

However if this is the case, “trade” will occur between firm B and person A. That is because

the external cost for A when B pollutes is higher than B:s benefit ( BMNPB ) from polluting.

Therefore A will compensate B if lowering its emissions. Both A and B will get higher utility

of this compensation. The compensating “trade” will continue until the marginal cost is equal

to the marginal benefit, in point W*. If the situation initially is the opposite, i.e. if A has the

right to non-polluting air, then B will compensate A. B:s marginal net private benefit

( BMNPB ) from polluting is higher than A:s disutility of some pollution ( AMEC ). Initially

the case will be AW but as in the previous situation we will end up in W*, which is the optimal

pollution level. (Pearce & Turner, 1990)

3.1.2 Collective Goods

A collective good is characterized of non-exclusion and non-rivalry. When a market fail to

deny access to a good for agents who do not pay for it, a market failure has occurred since the

resources then are not efficiently allocated. Fresh air is a well-illustrating example of this

phenomenon of non-exclusion. Non-rivalry is when one persons’ consumption does not affect

another persons’ consumption of the same good. An example of a non-rivalry market is the

“consumption” of a national park. (Perman et al, 1995)

AMEC

BMNPB

*WW

BenefitCost /

AW BW

Page 17: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

11

3.1.3 Policy Failures

Another type of market failure is a political one. If there are for example well-organized

interest groups (e.g. unions) who are capable of organizing many voters a government may

make decisions that benefit these groups but harm the rest of the society. A government may

also make a decision that give short run benefits despite the decision is “bad” in the longer

run. (Pearce & Turner,1990)

3.2 Environmental Policies

The examples of market failure, described above, are common in environmental markets.

Undefined property rights, information problems and short run incentives to act long run

irrational are examples of reasons of market failures. This chapter aims to go through the

government policy alternatives to compensate existing environmental market failures.

3.2.1 Command-and-Control Systems

When the government uses a command-and-control system, i.e. a regulation, it decides how

much the market at a maximum is allowed to pollute. Giving the agents quotas has the

advantage that the uncertainty, which occurs when using taxes as environmental policy (see

chapter 3.2.2), is eliminated since the goal is going to be fulfilled. However this system is, as

we will see below, inefficient. (Pearce & Turner, 1990)

Figure 3.2 Regulation of Emissions

Source: Pearce & Turner, 1990.

The regulation is not cost efficient since it does not give the market the right to abate

emissions at the lowest cost. In this example firm A has a lower marginal abatement cost

(MAC) compared to firm B. Nonetheless the firms will abate the same quantity of emissions.

The outcome is that the society will lose welfare. Area A is the dead-weight loss of the

regulation. (Ibid.)

AMAC BMACRegulation

AMAC

BMAC

A

Page 18: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

12

3.2.2 Taxes

Instead of giving the firms a maximum level allowed to pollute, the government can, by

introducing environmental taxes, give the polluters economic incentives to abate or reduce the

emissions. The idea of a tax aimed to add the social external cost to the initial private price

was first introduced by the British economist Arthur C. Pigou (1877-1959) in his opus

Economics of Welfare in 1920. (Pearce & Turner, 1990)

Figure 3.3 Optimal Pigovian Tax

Source: Pearce & Turner, 1990.

In figure 3.3 the optimal Pigovian tax rate, t*, is shown. Initially the produced quantity is 1Q

because at this point the marginal net private benefit (MNPB) is maximized. At quantity 1Q

however the marginal external cost (MEC) is higher than MNPB from the production. This

means that 1Q is not a Pareto-efficient production quantity since the MNPB curve does not

include the external cost. The optimal quantity is instead Q*, i.e. where MEC is equal to

MNPB. To give the producer incentive to decrease the produced quantity to Q* the

government introduces the tax t*, i.e. a tax which is equal to MEC at the Pareto-efficient

outcome Q*. (Ibid.)

As shown above the policy with environmental taxes has the benefit that it is economic

efficient at the same time as it solves the problem with too much emissions. However there

are some practical problems occurring in environmental taxation:

• Cross-border issues: How to solve the pollution problem internationally? A country

can not “tax” pollution from abroad.

MEC

taxMNPB −

*t

BenefitCost /

Q*Q

MNPB

1Q

Page 19: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

13

• Goal fulfillment: In theory we will end up in an efficient point (Q*) but in reality the

impact of the tax on emissions is more uncertain.

• Inflation issue: The tax has to be adjusted continuously in accordance with the

inflation.

• The environmental valuation: The environment has to be valued in monetary terms.

(See chapter 3.4 for more information about environmental valuation and its methods.)

• The assumptions: This taxation model assumes pure competition, well-defined

property rights and perfect information, including the information about the MEC- and

MNPB-curves. (Pearce & Turner, 1990)

3.2.3 Tradable Permits

With the purpose to combine the advantages with taxes (economic efficiency) and regulations

(goal fulfillment) a system with tradable pollution permits has been introduced as a

combination of both a market solution and a policy solution of environmental problems. The

fundamental idea of tradable permits is that the government decides how much each market

should be allowed to pollute. Then a firm in every single industry is given permits to pollute

(the total outcome of all permits is the optimal pollution quantity, Q* in figure 3.3). The

agents can sell and buy permits as they wish without governmental involvement and

accordingly a market for the permits is going to be established. (Ibid.)

Figure 3.4 Market Equilibrium for Tradable Pollution Permits

Source: Pearce & Turner, 1990.

Agents to the left of the supply curve (S) will buy permits since their demand is higher than

the equilibrium price, P*, and firms to the right of the supply curve are going to sell their

permits since they will profit maximize by lowering their production (and decrease waste) or

abate emissions (if MNPBMAC < ). (Ibid.)

Number of permits

D

Price

*P

S

Page 20: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

14

Tradable pollution permits generate, as we have seen, both economic efficiency and a secure

goal fulfillment. Since the system is Pareto-optimal it also gives the firms the same incentives

as taxes to technological progress. There are at least three more advantages with this kind of

system: 1) new firms can enter the market without impacting the markets total waste, 2) non-

polluters (e.g. environmental organizations such as Greenpeace) can buy pollution permits

without having the intention to pollute and 3) supply and demand on the permit market

guaranties that the price for the permits is the “true” price hence the government do not have

to adjust the price in line with inflation. (Pearce & Turner, 1990)

However there are a few problems with the tradable permits system: 1) it is hard to establish a

functioning market for the permits, 2) the administration cost of the system may be high and

(3) so called “hot spots”, i.e. many polluters in a small area, may occur. (Ibid.)

3.2.4 Subsidies

A subsidy is a government solution that aims to give the firms a positive economic incentive

to reduce emissions. In practice the government provides one unit subsidy for each unit

emitted below a certain standard. (Ibid.)

Figure 3.5 Introducing a Subsidy

Source: Pearce & Turner, 1990.

When a subsidy is introduced the government pays firms who pollute below the prescribed

level. As the firm gets paid for the production, the average cost curve will shift down

(AC→AC-S). Thus in the example above the marginal cost curve will shift upwards

(MC→MC+S) since the subsidy is a lost revenue if production increases. In this case the

introduction of the subsidy will lower the firms production ( 1* QQ → ) in the short run. Thus

The Firm The Market

D

MC+S MC AC

AC-S

q* 1q

1S0S

0Q 1Q

0P1P

q Q

P P

Page 21: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

15

the firm will be able to do supernormal profits at this stage. These supernormal profits give

potential entrants incentive to enter the market. When firms enter the market the market

supply will increase ( 10 SS → ), thus the equilibrium quantity will rise ( 10 QQ → ) and the

price will fall ( 10 PP → ). In this case the long run effect of the subsidy is the opposite from

the purposed one since the markets total quantity increased instead of decreased. Thus the

emissions may also increase in this case. (Pearce & Turner, 1990)

The long run response from subsidies is very different and uncertain. Among economists

subsidies are not that popular because of the risk of altering the entry and exit conditions in a

way as was illustrated in the above example. (Ibid.)

3.3 Valuing the Environment

In order to measure the externalities and the effect of the government policies it is necessary

to put a monetary value on the environmental good and the change in value due to the external

effect. Specifically there are two political reasons for valuing the environment: 1) ex-post

valuation, i.e. evaluate realized environmental policies, and 2) ex-ante valuation, i.e.

estimations used when taking political decisions on public investments. (Perman et al., 1999)

Assume an individual that derives utility from two factors, Q and Z, where Z represents

environmental goods and Q represents all other consumption possibilities available to the

individual. The individuals’ utility function can then be written as

),( ZQfU = (3.1)

A positive change in Z or Q will have a positive effect on the utility (U). Also assume that Z

is a collective good that is non-exclusive and non-divisible. Given this, consider a project that

causes a significant negative change in Z (i.e an external cost), e.g. ozone-depletion that

causes a fall in crop yields. (Ibid.)

Page 22: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

16

(a) (b) Figure 3.6 Compensating Surplus (CS) and Equivalent Surplus (ES)

Source: Sundqvist & Söderholm, 2002.

Above is the environmental change as an externality illustrated ( 10 ZZ → ). Starting with the

left figure (a), we are initially in the point where 0U is equal to 0Z . Now the actual project

that decreases 0Z to 1Z is considered. If the project will be realized then the compensating

surplus (CS) measures the minimum compensation, in terms of Q, that a person is willing to

accept to get less Z. As the figure shows CS is derived by keeping utility constant at the new

relative price. (Perman et al., 1999)

In the CS case the reference point is the situation before the welfare change, when measuring

ES in figure 3.6 (b) the situation is the opposite, i.e. we use the situation after the change as a

reference point. The equivalent surplus (ES) then measures how much a person at a maximum

are willing to pay, in terms of Q, to get back to the initial quantity of Z. Keeping the former

relative price at the new value of utility ( 1U ) gives the ES value. (Ibid.)

3.4 Environmental Valuation Methods

This section aims to describe different economic valuation techniques that can be used for

estimating the value of environmental goods and also the CS and ES value. Environmental

economists usually make a distinction between two main environmental valuation methods

used in order to estimate the demand for environmental goods; revealed preference methods

and expressed preference methods. Revealed preference methods approach is indirect since

this methods use the demand for a complementary- or a substitute good as a reference when

deriving the demand curve. Commonly used indirect methods are the Hedonic Price Method

0U

0Z 1Z Z

Q

ES

1Z1U

0U

Z

Q

0Z

CS

Page 23: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

17

(HPM) and the Travel Cost Method (TCM). The expressed preference methods have instead a

direct approach and create hypothetical markets by asking individuals about their willingness

to pay (WTP) or willingness to accept (WTA). Examples of expressed preference methods are

Contingent Valuation Method (CVM) and Stated Preference Methods (SPM). (Garrod &

Willis, 1999)

3.4.1 Revealed Preference Methods

The HPM is a revealed preference method that illustrates the basic idea of these indirect

valuation techniques. HPM assumes that housing prices provide information about the

environmental quality in the neighborhood. HPM aims to separate the effect of the

environment in the housing prices, i.e. evaluate how much the housing prices will change

when the environmental conditions are changed. (Ibid.)

nP αααα +++= ...321 (3.2)

Equation 3.2 shows the theoretical derivation of a housing price, P. 1α represents for example

the size of the house, 2α represents the distance to a supermarket and 3α reflects the

environmental quality (air quality, water quality, the distance to the sea etc.). The HPM

derives the demand for an environmental good by trying to separate the variable reflecting the

environment ( 3α ) from the other variables, i.e. how will a change in 3α affect P. (Ibid.)

Revealed preference methods have the advantage that the market that is analyzed exists and

we do not have to create a hypothetical market. Thus the indirect approach only covers the

user value of a good. A good may also have an existing value, i.e. the good may give

individuals utility without usage. The method may also cause econometric problems. (Ibid.)

3.4.2 Expressed Preference Methods

The Contingent Valuation Method (CVM) is an example of a direct approach that involves

asking individuals about their hypothetical WTP and WTA for environmental goods. The

main use for CVMs are according to Perman et al. (1999) to “provide inputs to analyses of

changes in the level of provision of public goods/bads, and especially of environmental

‘commodities’ which have the characteristics of non-excludability and non-divisibility”.

Compared to the revealed preference methods the direct methods have the advantage to

Page 24: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

18

include both user- and non-user values, i.e. the total economic value of a good. However the

fact that the methods deal with hypothetical markets, and not existing ones, may cause a

problem. It is impossible to evaluate if there is a difference between the “real” WTP/WTA

and the estimated WTP/WTA. There are also a few potential problems with biases using

CVM3. (Perman et al., 1999).

3.5 Summary

Negative externalities from emissions is a common problem in markets with environmental

goods. In order to include the external costs in the market price environmental taxes can be

used. There are two main groups of environmental valuation methods; revealed preference

methods, i.e. using the market for a complementary or a substitute good to value the

environmental good, and expressed preference methods, i.e. asking individuals about their

WTP or WTA for the environmental good. Using an optimal Pigovian tax means trying to set

the tax equal to the external cost at the optimal production/consumption point (see figure 3.3).

3 For further reading about biases problems see Garrod & Willis (1999).

Page 25: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

19

Chapter IV

COST AND BENEFITS FROM TAXING OZONE DEPLETING SUBSTANCES

As shown in chapter three there are several policies available trying to regulate emissions.

The Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer does not recommend any

certain policy; every country can choose a policy that the government finds best for their

country. Many countries decided to use a regulatory system in order to reduce the production

of ODS, while other countries preferred a market-based system, i.e. taxes or tradable permits.

In the US the government initially decided to use the latter and in 1989 a tradable permit

system was introduced. However this system was only in use for one year, in 1990 a change

to a tax system took place. The purpose of the change was to “serve both to control windfall

profits and also to provide an incentive to reduce the amount of production of ozone-depleting

chemicals below the levels allowed by the EPA4 regulations”. Thus the tax constitutes a key

component of the US ozone protection policy. (Hoerner, 1995)

4.1 The US Taxation of ODS

According to economic theory on taxes (see chapter 3.2.2) the goal with an environmental tax

is to make the net price equal to the gross price plus the external cost. In other words, the

purpose with a Pigovian tax is to design it to be equal to the social cost that occurs in the

production/consumption of the good. In practice it is almost impossible to design a tax in this

way and the ODS tax is no exception. According to Barthold (1994) the ODS tax was based

primarily on a revenue target, i.e. the tax was designed to maximize the government income,

rather than being set equal to the external social cost of the production of ODS. “There is no

evidence that the base rate of tax, $1.37 per pound in 1990, in any way reflected the

environmental harm posed by these chemicals” (Barthold, 1994). According to Hoerner

(1995) the value of the environmental damages probably are much higher than the tax rate.

The ODS tax may not be optimal but it is however differentiated, i.e. the substances are taxed

based on how much they harm the ozone layer. When the tax was introduced each chemical

4 Environmental Protection Agency.

Page 26: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

20

was given a value between 0.1 and 10.0 depending on their ozone depleting potential (ODP).

The reference point when estimating this value was CFC-11s ODP which was set at 1.0. In

the table below the taxed substances and their ozone depleting potential value are shown.

Note that most substances nowadays are phased out (see table 2.1). (Hoerner, 1995)

Table 4.1 The ODS and their ODP.

Common name Chemical Nomenclature Ozone Depleting Potential

CFC-11 trichlorofluoromethane 1.0 CFC-12 dichlorodifluoromethane 1.0 CFC-113 trichlorotrifluoroethane 0.8

CFC-114 1,2-dichloro-1,1,2,2,-tetra-fluoroethane 0.6

CFC-115 chloropentafluoroethane 0.6 Halon 1211 bromochlorodifluoromethane 3.0 Halon 1301 bromotrifluoromethane 10.0 Halon 2402 dibromotetrafluoroethane 6.0 Carbon tetrachloride tetrachloromethane 1.1 Methyl chloroform 1,1,1-trichloroethane 0.1 CFC-13, CFC-111, CFC-112, CFC-211, CFC-212, CFC-213, CFC-214, CFC-215, CFC-216, CFC-217

- 1.0

Source: Hoerner, 1995.

Both domestically produced and imported substances are taxed. However exported ODS are

rebated. That is because the tax is designed in accordance with the destination principle, i.e.

the tax is paid in the country where the good is consumed. Hoerner (1995) argues that the

reason for the application of this principle is 1) to avoid the movement of the production to

other countries and 2) to tax imported ODS in the same way as domestically manufactured

ODS. However this principle may reduce the environmental benefit from the tax since agents

in a country that does not have a ODS -tax do not have to pay for the externality.

The tax on the production of ODS is calculated by multiplying three values: the number of

pounds produced (or imported), the base tax amount per pound and the ozone-depleting

potential value. The initial (1990) base tax rate was 1.37 US Dollar but it has been increased

frequently. In 1995 the rate was 5.35 US Dollars and in subsequent years it has been added by

0.45 US Dollar annually. Hoerner (1995) argues that “it is probable that this predictable

increase in the tax rate is as important to the incentive effect of the tax as the current tax rate,

Page 27: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

21

since it should have a strong effect on the planning process of producers and consumers of

ODS”.

4.2 Costs and Benefits from Reducing the ODS-Production

This chapter, which is based on estimates made by ARC for Environment Canada in 1997 and

statistics from UNEP (United Nations Environment Programme), will describe the economic

costs and environmental benefits from reducing the production of ODS. This is essential to

the empirical framework since these factors are fundamental for the forthcoming calculation

of the net benefit from the US-tax of ODS. All effects have been estimated using “the best

quantitative estimates possible given the current level of knowledge”. However uncertainties

remain and the estimations should be “interpreted as indicative of the health effects avoided

by the Montreal Protocol”. (ARC, 1997)

4.2.1 Costs from Substituting ODS

ARC defines the cost of substituting from ODS to non-ozone-depleting substances as “the

additional quantity of resources needed to produce this constant level of output” (Ibid.). Of

the total amount of the worlds 1,492.8 ozone-depleting potential units in 1986 CFCs was the

main contributor by 1,065.0 units or about 71 percent. However in the US, and in many other

developed countries, CFCs was already banned in certain industries (e.g. sprays) in the late

1970s or in the early 1980s. Thus the costs of substitution were relatively low in these

countries since the ban already had reduced the quantities of CFCs. It had also provided a

technical knowledge in the use of substitutes (e.g. hydrocarbon).

In order to give the reader a comprehensive summary of how substitution costs were

calculated a summary of the methodological framework used by ARC when estimating the

costs of the substitution of CFCs will follow below.

1. Identifying conversion approaches (A) and adjustments by firms in each industry (e.g.

refrigeration and air conditioning sector). ( nAAA ..., 21 )

2. Evaluate and determine the cost per kilogram of CFCs ( nCCC ..., 21 ) that is substituted

by using published data and industry estimates.

3. Estimate the number of kilograms replaced in a single industry. ( nQQQ ..., 21 )

4. Calculate the total cost of the industry. ( nn QCAQCAQCA *...** 2211 ++ )

Page 28: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

22

Table 4.2 Estimated costs of replacing ODS 1987-2060 in units of billion of 1997 US Dollars.

Global Costs

(including the US)

Estimated Costs for

the US

CFCs 128.0 23.97

Halons 12.6 4.12

HCFCs 33.1 13.70

Methyl Chloroform 47.8 16.73

Carbon Tetrachloride 5.7 0.20

Methyl Bromide 7.8 3.06

TOTAL 235.0 61.78

Source: ARC, 1997 (Global Costs) and UNEP, 2000 (US Costs).

Table 4.2 shows the estimated costs of reducing ODS in accordance with the requirements of

the Montreal Protocol in the period of 1987-2060. The reason for choosing this time period is

that the Montreal Protocol was signed in 1987 and the ozone layer is estimated to recover to

its pre-1970 ozone-concentration by 2060, given that the plan for the Montreal Protocol is

realized. The values in the right column (Estimated Costs for the US) are based on statistics

from UNEP. The US share of all developed countries production of each substance has been

calculated by the base year, i.e. the year before an international agreement of regulating the

production of the substance5. The estimation is based on two scenarios, the no-control

scenario and the scenario of the Montreal Protocol controls. The production the years after the

base year is influenced by the Montreal Protocol controls. The latter is the real scenario and

the former is a hypothetical comparable scenario. Years before the base year do not illustrate

the production share in a satisfactory way since the production is affected by the Montreal

Protocol these years. Furthermore the value of the US share of the production of each

substance has been multiplied by the total cost of replacing the substance for all developed

countries. This means that the calculation assumes that the US’ replacement cost is the same

as the mean replacement cost for all developed countries. The replacement costs for e.g. CFCs

are also different depending on the area of use. Furthermore the calculations also assumes that

the US’ area of use is the same as the mean ditto for the developed countries. For further

information about the US total replacement cost see Appendix A.

5 The base year is 1986 for CFCs and Halons. For Carbon Tetrachloride, Methyl Chloroform and HCFCs the base year is 1989. The base year for Methyl Bromide is 1991.

Page 29: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

23

To sum up this section of the chapter, the US has increased its costs by about 61.78 billion

1997 US Dollars over the time 1987-2060 by replacing ODS.

4.2.2 Benefits from Substituting ODS

ARC divides benefits from substituting ODS into two main groups, health effects and non-

health effects. The health effects are then divided into three groups: non-melonama skin

cancer, melonama skin cancer and eye injuries (cataracts). These effects are measured in cases

and fatalities (not US Dollars) and are shown in table 4.3.

Table 4.3 Health benefits from reducing the production and consumption of ODS in accordance with the

Montreal Protocol 1987-2060

Health Benefits Reduced Cases

Reduced Cases of Non-Melonama

Skin Cancer

19,100,000 cases

Reduced Cases of Melonama Skin Cancer 1,500,000 cases

Reduced Cases of Cataracts 129,100,000 cases

Reduced Skin Cancer Fatalities 333,500 fatalities6

Source: ARC, 1997.

The above estimations are made using a model that determines the effects on human health

when increasing the UV-radiation. ARC have estimated the difference between the scenario

under the Montreal Protocol and the fictive non-regulation scenario. Cancer incidence rates

are estimated from a regression model using data from cancer registries controlling life

expectancy, economic development, skin colour, latitude and religious practices pertaining to

clothing. The data on eye-injuries are from American Academy of Ophthalmology

(Cataracts), data on melonama skin cancer are from the 1994 UNEP Environmental Effects

Panel Report and population data are from World Bank and the US Central Intelligence

Agency. (ARC, 1997)

“A degree of uncertainty exists with all calculated values” however the estimates shows that

“the health effects avoided through the Montreal Protocol remain substantial”. The

estimations on reduced cases of cataracts and reduced skin cancer fatalities are the mean value

of a determined interval (58.2 million to 200 million on cataracts and 171,000 to 496,000 on

6 19,000 fewer deaths from non-melonama skin cancer and 152,000 fewer deaths from melonama skin cancer.

Page 30: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

24

deaths from skin cancer). All health effects seem to increase progressively over time. For

example extending the non-melonama skin cancer analysis to 2070 would add more than 10

million additional cases, i.e. more than 50 per cent increase. (ARC, 1997)

The non-health effects from avoiding the depletion of the ozone layer have also been

identified. These effects are as well divided into three groups by ARC; fisheries effects,

agricultural effects and material effects. The non-health effects are shown in the below table.

Table 4.4 Non-health benefits in billion of 1997 US Dollars of reducing the production and consumption of

ODS in accordance with the Montreal Protocol 1987-2060.

Non-Health Effects Dollar Benefits in 1997 billion

US Dollars

Reduced Fisheries Damage 238

Reduced Agricultural Damage 191

Reduced Damage to Materials 30

Total Dollar Benefits 459

Source: ARC, 1997.

The above data, calculated by ARC, measure effects affecting the human welfare indirectly.

These effects are, according to ARC, more difficult to estimate. The above effects are just a

selection of all non-health effects. Thus the estimated effect may be a minimum non-health

benefit from reducing the use of ODS. The reduced fisheries damage is an effect from

reducing the decrease of phytoplankton which is at the very bottom of the aquatic food chain.

Agricultural damage comes from the fact that increased UV-radiation decrease yields (e.g.

soybeans). Increased ozone-depletion can also, according to ARC, have a significant negative

impact on materials, e.g. plastics, paints and other materials used in outdoor applications.

However this benefit is, as shown in table 4.4, fairly low. (Ibid.)

Page 31: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

25

4.3 The Estimated Net Benefits from the US Tax on ODS

In order to fulfill the purpose of the thesis this chapter aims to separate the costs and benefits

to the US from the reduction of ODS. Table 4.5 summarize the estimated data over global

benefits and costs from tables 4.2-4.4.

Table 4.5 Net Global Benefits from phasing out ODS in units of billion 1997 US Dollars.

Global Dollar Benefits 459

Global Dollar Costs 235

Global Dollar Net Benefit 224

Source: ARC, 1997.

The global net benefit from phasing out ODS in accordance with the Montreal Protocol is as

shown 224 billion 1997 US Dollars. This means that each dollar spent on costs related to

reduce the ODS production and consumption will give 1.95 US Dollars back since

459/235=1.95 (4.1)

Assuming that the US payback is the same as the global mean ditto the US benefit from

phasing out ODS can be calculated as

1.95*61.78=120.47 (4.2)

Thus the US net benefit is approximately

120.47-61.78=58.69 (4.3)

However this net benefit is a consequence of both the regulation and the ODS tax. Separating

the effect of just the tax has not been done in existing studies but Hoerner (1995) concludes

that the tax has contributed to a substantial reduction of the use of ODS. “The ozone-depleting

chemicals tax is probably responsible for reducing the production of those chemicals below

the amount allowed under the caps, it does not follow that the caps had no effect” (Hoerner,

1995). Thus it is, given existing studies, almost impossible to separate the effect caused by the

tax from the total effect in a satisfied way. However Hoerner (1995) argues that “290

thousand tonnes would appear to be the lower boundary of the environmental benefit

Page 32: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

26

attributable to the tax” and “this amount is 126 per cent of the difference between the caps and

the business-as-usual projection” (i.e. the no-control scenario). Given this the environmental

benefit of the ODS tax is approximately 56 per cent of the total change.7

58.69*0.56=32.87 (4.4)

The health effects attributed to the tax can be estimated in the same way. The results of these

calculations are shown in the below table. The calculations follow in Appendix B.

Table 4.6 Health benefits from the US-tax on ODS

Health Benefit Reduced Cases

Reduced Cases of Non-Melonama

Skin Cancer 2,812

Reduced Cases of Melonama Skin Cancer 221

Reduced Cases of Cataracts 19,006

Reduced Skin Cancer Fatalities 49

Source: Own construction.

Combining the studies of Hoerner (1995) and ARC (1997) in this way gives the rough net

result of the US-tax on ODS to be at a minimum of 32.87 billion of 1997 US Dollars.

Additionally 2,812 reduced cases of non-Melonama skin cancer, 221 reduced cases of

Melonama skin cancer, 19,006 reduced cases of cataracts and 49 reduced deaths from skin

cancer can be constituted to the US ODS tax. However this value is a general estimation made

by combining the two studies. The value is in no way exact but it seems to be, to quote

Hoerner (1995), “the lower boundary of the environmental benefit attributable to the tax”.

One must remember that the used method to combine these two studies assumes 1) the US

costs to be equal to the mean costs of phasing out ODS in all developed countries, 2) the US

area of use to be the same as the mean ditto for developed countries, 3) the US rate of

investment (ROI) of replacing ODS is the same as the mean global ROI (195 per cent) and 4)

7 If 290 thousand tonnes constitutes 126 per cent of the difference between the no-control scenario and the regulation then the difference between these scenarios is 290/1.26=230 thousand tonnes. The difference between the no-control scenario and the regulation plus the difference between the regulation and the tax is then equal to 520 (290+230) thousands tonnes. Thus the regulation constitutes 230/520=0.44, i.e. 44 per cent, and the tax constitutes 290/520=0.56, i.e. 56 per cent, of the total difference.

Page 33: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

27

the tax affects the replacement of ODS in the same way from 1987 until the substances have

been completely replaced8 as it did in the period of Hoerners’ study (1990-1995).

Summarizing the taxation of ODS one can mention that before the tax was introduced the rest

of the world was achieving less rapid growth or more effective reductions in the use of ODS

than the US. However after the introduction of the tax the situation was reversed (Hoerner,

1995). Hoerner (1995) concludes that “the history of the ozone-depleting chemicals tax

establishes beyond reasonable doubt that tax instruments can be a powerful tool for

environmental protection”. The ODS tax has shown that the theoretical framework on

environmental taxes can work in reality since “by stimulating innovation and allowing a

flexible response, environmental taxes in effect balance economic and environmental risks,

causing large reductions where they can be cheaply achieved but allowing a smaller response

when technically feasible alternatives are more costly” (Ibid.).

8 Most substances are phased out in developed countries now (2003). However the production and consumption of HCFCs and Methyl Bromide will continue in some certain industries in a strictly way until 2030 respectively 2005 (see table 2.1).

Page 34: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

28

Chapter V

CONCLUSIONS AND DISCUSSION

The Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer seems to be a successful

example in the international environmental co-operation. The main reasons of this success

seems to be 1) the collective description of the good, i.e. the ozone layer, and 2) the large and

obvious positive net result from phasing out ODS (The Economist, 2003). Because of these

two reasons the parties have incentives to co-operate in a satisfactory way. Thus free riders

easily can be punished in order to minimize the incentive to cheat. Giving the developing

countries more time to phase out these substances than the developed ones, i.e. letting the rich

pay more than the poor, seems to be another reason of the success of the Montreal Protocol.

The US tax of ODS seems to be a successful national method of reducing the use of ODS

substantially. The estimations in chapter four shows that the net benefit from the tax is at least

32.87 billion 1997 US Dollars, 2,812 reduced cases of non-melonama skin cancer, 221

reduced cases of melonama skin cancer, 19,006 reduced cases of cataracts and finally 49

reduced fatalities from skin cancer. There was a problem separating the effect from the tax

from the total effect. However a minimum of 56 per cent of the total effect seems to be caused

by the tax. This according to Hoerner (1995) which argues that “because the caps have never

been the binding constraint, it is probable that much of the observed reduction would have

occurred even without the caps” and “it is not completely certain that the caps had any

impacts”. Thus these values should be seen as approximate estimations and not exact ones.

However the main conclusion of this result is that there is an obvious positive net result in the

US from reducing the ODS in accordance with the Montreal Protocol by using the tax tool.

Since the replacement of ODS seems to have been fairly successful not just in the US but also

in most other countries it seems to be reasonable to suppose that the net result are positive

also in these countries.

The estimations made by ARC have used a variant of a revealed preference valuation method,

i.e. the good (the ozone layer) is valued during analyzing markets for a complementary good

(e.g. the fish stock and crop yields). Thus ARC assumes that the price of fish and soybeans

Page 35: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

29

depend on the ozone concentration in the stratosphere. Since there is a obvious negative

relation between the supply of fish and soybeans and the depletion of the ozone this

assumption is surely fulfilled. However there are a few general disadvantages occurring when

using this type of methods and this environmental valuation is no exception since ARC have

not solved these problems. First, the method only covers the user value of a good. The user

value is the direct value of consuming a good that can be priced in a market (e.g. the market

for fish). However this value is only a part of the total value of a good since it may also have

an existing value, i.e. the good may give individuals utility without usage. Using this method

the fish in the oceans do not have any value for people that do not eat fish. The conclusion of

this discussion is that it is reasonable to assume that ARC have underestimated the value of

the Dollar benefits from replacing ODS. Secondly the method may cause econometric

problems but since ARC do not discuss this in their study it is impossible to know weather

this is the case here.

According to the empirical framework it seems to be pretty clear that the estimation of the

environmental benefit from taxing ODS in the US is at the lower boundary of the total effect.

Even if most indicates that this is the case there is at least one contradiction to this statement.

This is the problem of an international black market on ODS and the fact that the US has

become the main target for this illegal trade. However both the US and the EU in subsequent

years have succeeded to decrease the smuggling through more controls and tougher penalties.

Thus in the future the developing countries may be the states that will have the most serious

problems with the illegal trade of ODS. In fact the phase-out schedule for these countries are

threaten by the smuggling. (EIA, 2003)

To summarize, there is a lot of uncertainty about the effects of the Montreal Protocol and the

phase-out of ODS. The estimation in the empirical framework seems to be the minimum net

benefit from the taxation of ODS in the US. However because of the illegal trade of ODS

estimations of the environmental benefits are more uncertain. In spite of all uncertainties it

can be established that the benefits from reduce ODS emissions certainly is significantly

higher than the replacement costs. Barrett (2003) argues that estimating costs and benefits in

these kind of cases is never easy but in the case of the ODS “the basic economics of ozone

policy thus implied that , for the United States – and probably for most industrial countries –

the benefit of acceding to the Montreal Protocol exceeded the cost by a wide marginal,

irrespective of the behavior of other countries”.

Page 36: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

30

Another conclusion of this study is that the US seems to have been one of the countries that

have replaced ODS in the most satisfactory way according to the Montreal Protocol. An

interesting question is why the US have acted in this way in this case but in the case with the

Kyoto Protocol the country have not even ratified the agreement and do not have the intention

to ratify it in the future either (e.g. Lindahl, 2002). From an environmental point of view

these both protocols seems to be comparable since the external costs in both cases are

relatively high and there are substitutes available. A comparison between the US behavior in

the environmental agreements in Montreal respectively Kyoto could be a interesting

forthcoming study.

Page 37: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

31

REFERENCES

ARC (Applied Research Consultants) (1997) for Environment Canada. Global Benefits and

Costs of the Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer.

Barrett, S. (2003). Environment & Statecraft, Oxford University Press Inc., New York.

Barrow, C. J. (1995). Developing the Environment. Problems & Management, Longman

Group Limited, Harlow, Essex.

Barthold, T. A. (1994). Issues in the Design of Environmental Excise Taxes. Journal of

Economic Perspectives vol. 8 no. 1.

EIA (Environmental Investigation Agency). (2003-12-15). [WWW:]

http://www.salvonet.com/eia/cgi/reports/reports.cgi?a=31&t=template_search.htm

EFTC (European Fluorocarbon Technical Committee). (2003-11-12) [WWW:]

http://www.fluorocarbons.org/frame.htm?g-info/faq/faq.htm

Garrod, G. & Willis, K. G. (1999). Economic Valuation of the Environment, Edward Elgar

Publishing Inc., Northampton, Massachusetts.

Hanley, N., Shogren, J. & White, B. (1997). Environmental Economics in Theory and

Practice, Oxford University Press Inc., New York.

Hoerner, J. A. (1995). “Tax Tools for Protecting the Atmosphere: The US Ozone-depleting

Chemicals Tax“ in Green Budget Reform (Edited by Barg, S., Gillies, A. & Gale, R.) (p. 200-

219), Earthscan Publisher Limited, London.

Lindahl, B. (2002). Avtalet riskerar kollaps om inte fler länder ansluter sig, Svenska

Dagbladet. (2004-02-08). [WWW:] http://www.svd.se/dynamiskt/naringsliv/did_2456782.asp

Page 38: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

32

Linden, E. (1993). Who lost the ozone?, Time 5/10/1993.

Pearce, D. & Turner, K. (1990). Economics of natural resources and the environment.

Harvester Wheatsheaf, New York.

Pearce, D. (Editor), Barbier, E., Markandya, A., Barrett, S., Turner, R. K. & Swanson, T.

(1991). Blueprint 2: Greening the World Economy, Earthscan Publications Ltd., London.

Pearce, D. (1995). Blueprint 4: Capturing global environmental value, Earthscan Publications

Ltd., London.

Perman, R., Ma, Y., McGilvray, J & Common, M. (1999). Natural Resource &

Environmental Economics, Pearson Education Inc., New York.

Sundqvist, T. & Söderholm, P. (2002). Valuing the environmental impacts of electricity

generation: A critical survey. Journal of Energy Literature vol. 8 no. 2

The Economist 4/19/2003 (page 64). Economics focus. Atmospheric pressure.

The State of the Environment in Denmark (2001). (2003-11-15). [WWW:]

http://www.dmu.dk/1_Viden/2_Miljoe-

tilstand/3_samfund/tilstandsrapport_2001_eng/rapport/NM2001_GB_0.pdf

The Swedish Environmental Protection Agency (2003). (2003-11-15). [WWW:]

http://www.naturvardsverket.se/bokhandeln/pdf/620-5320-5.pdf

UNEP (United Nations Environment Protection) (2002). (2003-11-25). [WWW:]

http://www.unep.org/ozone/15-year-data-report.pdf

Page 39: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

33

APPENDIX A

Table A.1 Consumption of ODS in 1986 (1), 1989 (2) respectively 1991 (3) in units of ODP tonnes

Substance All Developed

Countries

The US The US Share of

the Developed

Countries

CFCs (1) 940,888 305,964 32.52%

Halons (1) 172,720 57,803 33.47%

Carbon

Tetrachloride (2)

253,044 11,924 4.71%

Methyl Bromide (3) 33,577 15,317 45.62%

Methyl Chloroform

(2)

60,570 25,597 42.26%

HCFCs (2) 11,978 6,363 53.12% Source: UNEP, 2003.

Page 40: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

34

Table A.2 Costs of replacing ODS in units of billions of 1997 US Dollars.

Substance Total Replacement

Costs for all

Developed

Countries9

The US share of

the consumption of

all Developed

Countries

Total Replacement

Costs in the US

CFCs 73.7 32.52% 23.97

Halons 12.3 33.47% 4.12

Carbon

Tetrachloride

4.2 4.71% 0.20

Methyl Bromide 6.7 45.62% 3.06

Methyl Chloroform 39.6 42.26% 16.73

HCFCs 25.8 53.12% 13.70

All substances 162.3 - 61.78 Source: ARC, 1997.

9 For further information about these estimates see ARC, 1997.

Page 41: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

35

APPENDIX B

Non-Melonama Skin Cancer

Reduced cases (global): 19,100,000

Total global costs: 235,000,000,000

Reduced cases per spent billion dollars: 28.81000,235

000,100,19=

Total US costs: 61,780,000,000

Reduced cases per spent billion dollars: 021,528.81*78.61 ≈

Assuming the tax to contribute by 56 per cent of this → 281256.0*021,5 ≈

Melonama Skin Cancer

Reduced cases (global): 1,500,000

Reduced cases per spent billion dollars: 38.6000,235000,500,1

22156.0*38.6*78.61 ≈

Cataracts

Reduced cases (global): 129,100,000

Reduced cases per spent billion dollars: 36.549000,235

000,100,129≈

006,1956.0*36.549*78.61 ≈

Page 42: Benefits from Environmental Taxation

36

Fatalities

Reduced deaths (global): 333,500

Reduced deaths per spent billion dollars: 42.1000,235500,333

4956.0*42.1*78.61 ≈

For further information about the estimates over the number of global cases/fatalities see ARC

(1997).