arianna tozzi emr report

Upload: john-cash

Post on 02-Jun-2018

221 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    1/50

    6/12/2013

    Internship Report | Arianna Tozzi | Student number: 42266984

    ABSOLUTE

    INVESTMENT

    PARTNERS

    ELECTRICITY MARKET REFORM IN THE UKPOLICY ASSESSMENT

    Company Supervisor : Nick Koidl | Managing Director at Absolute Investment Partners

    University Supervisor: Linda Kamp | Technical University of Delft | TBM Faculty

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    2/50

    2

    Summary

    1. Introduction ................................................................................................................................................... 4

    2. Renewable Energy policy in the UK ............................................................................................................... 6

    2.1 Feed-In-Tariff and Renewable Obligation Certificates ............................................................................ 72.2 Transition towards the Electricity Market Reform .................................................................................. 8

    3. The Electricity Market Reform ....................................................................................................................... 9

    3.1 Contract For Difference ........................................................................................................................... 9

    3.1.1 Working principle ........................................................................................................................... 10

    3.1.2 Eligibility criteria and Allocation method ....................................................................................... 11

    First Come First Served ............................................................................................................................ 13

    Unconstrained Allocation Rounds ........................................................................................................... 13

    Constrained allocation rounds ................................................................................................................ 13

    3.1.3 From the allocation of a contract to project construction and energy delivery ............................ 14

    4. Research results ....................................................................................................................................... 15

    4.1 Why is a reform needed and what are the main changing introduced with respect to the previous

    mechanism .................................................................................................................................................. 15

    4.2 Consultation process ............................................................................................................................. 16

    4.3 Transition process.................................................................................................................................. 17

    4.4 The Pay-When-Paid principle.............................................................................................................. 17

    4.5 Eligibility and allocation methodology issue ......................................................................................... 17

    4.6 Strike Price setting and Digression ........................................................................................................ 18

    4.7 Power Purchase Agreement .................................................................................................................. 19

    4.8 Subsidizing nuclear energy .................................................................................................................... 21

    4.9 Exemption of Energy Intensive Industries (EIIs) from CfDs costs .......................................................... 22

    1A- Compensation mirror: ....................................................................................................................... 23

    1B-Reduced Exemption Level: ................................................................................................................. 23

    2A- Wider eligibility: ................................................................................................................................ 23

    2B- Compensation plus a taper for additional sectors: ........................................................................... 23

    4.10 State Aid measures and the EMR in the EU prospective ..................................................................... 24

    5.Conclusions ................................................................................................................................................... 26

    Appendix .......................................................................................................................................................... 29

    Feed in Tariff- Generation Tariff level from April 2013 .............................................................................. 29

    Renewable Obligation banding level 2013/2017 ........................................................................................ 30

    Draft Strike Price for available technologies ............................................................................................... 31

    List of relevant Organizations and People interviewed for the report. ..................................................... 31

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    3/50

    3

    Organizations: .......................................................................................................................................... 31

    People: ..................................................................................................................................................... 32

    Interviews .................................................................................................................................................... 33

    Tim Warham - Senior policy Adviser at the Department of Energy and Climate change- 10-10-13 ...... 33

    David Handley- Chief Economist at RES- 15-10-13 .................................................................................. 35

    Keith MacLean- Director of Policy and Research at SSE and Board Member of European Wind Energy

    Association- 29-10-13 ............................................................................................................................. 37

    Srinivasan KavitaStrike price setting and digression specialist at the CCC- 5- 11-13 ......................... 39

    Jenny Hill- Exemption of Energy Intensive Industries from low carbon levy specialist at the CCC- 15-11-

    13 ............................................................................................................................................................. 42

    Malcom Keay -Senior Research Fellow at Oxford Institute of Energy Studies ........................................ 43

    Stewart Jamie- Deputy editor at ICIS and electricity market expert- 20-11-13 ...................................... 46Bibliography ..................................................................................................................................................... 49

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    4/50

    4

    SummaryIn order to be competitive with common carbon derived energy sources, low carbon technologies still highly

    need effective energy policies to be implemented at national level. The British government is actively trying to

    reach this goal by implementing the Electricity Market Reform, a new low carbon policy scheme that will

    substitute the current subsidy regime from mid 2014. The reform aims at boosting renewable energy

    electricity generation, together with nuclear power and carbon capture and storage, by means of a new

    supporting mechanism known and Feed-In Tariff with Contract For Difference (CfD). This scheme offers a 15

    years fixed revenue for the above mentioned low carbon categories at a fixed level set by the government and

    known as the strike price. In contrast with all the previous mechanisms, CfDs offer a subsidy payment that is

    function of the relative difference between the spotted market reference price and the strike price.

    This report will analyse in depth the proposed CfD mechanism in order to assess the effectiveness of the

    scheme in bringing forward the future decarbonization goals in the British electricity system. In order to

    answer this question, deep desk researches together with a series of interviews with relevant people actively

    involved in the EMR have been organized. The desk research has been used as a preliminary study to identify

    and understand the main changings introduced by the reform, the main controverted points of the reform and

    the most relevant involved parts. A series of interviews has subsequently been arranged with the selected

    stakeholders and governmental bodies. This process aimed at discussing more into details core and more

    controverted topics of the EMR in order to deeply understand the opinions of all the involved parts. The

    interviewed stakeholders are: Tim Warham, senior policy adviser at the Department of Energy and Climate

    Change; David Handley, Chief Economist at Renewable Energy Solutions; Keith MacLean, Director of Policy and

    Research at SSE; Srinivasan Kavita, Strike price setting and digression specialist at the Committee on ClimateChange; Jenny Hill, expert in Exemption of Energy Intensive Industries from low carbon levy at the CCC;

    Malcom Keay , Senior Research Fellow at Oxford Institute of Energy Studies and Stewart Jamie, Deputy editor

    at ICIS and electricity market expert. By tailoring the questions each time according to the area of expertise

    and competence of the interviewee; a wider picture of the effect of the new policy has been drawn.

    By examining the results of the desk research and of the field interviews, conclusions on the proposed CfD

    have been drawn. With no doubts, there are few weaknesses in the proposed mechanism and in the way it has

    been implemented. Firstly, the lack of a clear timetable with regards to the dates of publication of final strike

    price level, together with an unclear final date on when the proposed EMR will effectively become active

    created a climate of uncertainty among stakeholders. Uncertainty has also been encouraged by the lack ofspecific guidelines on the contract allocation method and by the uncertainty that every eligible projects will

    get accredited for a CfD. On the other hand however, the reform has all the potential to efficiently drive the

    required technological development and cost reduction among renewable technologies. This will be done by

    encouraging early competition and by making use of an effective and wide spread consulting process with

    regards to many of the major points of the contracts. Moreover, the certainty of long-term revenues offered

    within the CfD framework and the ability to sell the electricity to the grid at a higher price with respect to the

    previous mechanism, will help creating the right initial environment that is needed encourage projects at an

    early stage of the reform. The Government should however speed up the decision making process and clarify

    all the final details of the reform as soon as possible in order to dissipate the uncertainty climate surrounding

    the above mentionedaspects of the reform.

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    5/50

    5

    1. IntroductionIncreasing energy demand is posing a serious dilemma for those responsible for security of supply and

    worldwide decarbonization targets. On one hand the increase in population and expected standard of living

    is posing difficulties to the security of supply. On the other hand increasing carbon emissions resulting from

    disproportionate energy consumption produced via fossil fuels is threatening the environment we are living

    in and is posing challenging carbon reduction goals to industries. In order to be able to match these

    opposing needs, the current fossil fuel use must be drastically reduced and gradually replaced by green-low

    carbon power generation. To drive the required energy revolution, technological development together

    with cost reduction for renewable technologies should be achieved through a substantial increase in

    installed capacity. This process needs to be supported by the government by means of the implementation

    of policies that aim at creating the right environment for low carbon generation.

    Even though some renewable technologies, such as wind or solar, are now well developed and have

    reached grid parity in some EU locations (Theenergycollective, 2013), subsidies are still needed due to the

    characteristic high capital and low operational costs these technologies face. This is in contrast with fossilfuel generation which tends to have relatively low capital costs and high operational costs.(DECC, 2013a)

    Since the current electricity market was shaped in an environment where fossil fuel plants predominantly

    ruled the energy scene, the price of electricity is strictly correlated with the cost of fossil fuel plants. Low

    carbon technology is considered as non-price setting and it is therefore more exposed to volatility in

    electricity wholesale price resulting from fossil fuel price variation in the market. A government

    intervention in the electricity market is therefore aimed at assuring a certain fixed level of income for low

    carbon investments that would limit uncertainty of revenues.

    Most of the European states have a governmental incentive scheme in place to help countries meeting

    carbon reduction targets dictated by the European Union. This report will analyze in details energy policiesin the United Kingdom and will assess the effect low carbon subsidies are having on the national energy

    sector. The particular interest in the British energy legislation is due to the imminent implementation for an

    energy reform called the Electricity Market Reform (EMR) that will drastically change the existing low

    carbon incentives system.

    The main research question this assessment will answer is:

    How effective will the EMR be in efficiently decarbonizing the British electricity sector?

    In order to answer this question the following sub questions have been formulated:

    Why was an electricity market reform needed and what are the main changings introduced with

    respect to the previous supporting scheme?

    What are the main strength and weaknesses of the proposed reform?

    How will revenues for renewable energy investments change after the implementation of the

    reform?

    How does the EMR fit within the European Union legislation and how effective it is to efficiently

    meet the 2020 decarbonization targets?

    In order to answer these questions the opinions of various experts on the UK electricity market and

    renewable energy policies have been collected by means of interviews conducted on the phone or inperson where interviewees answered specific questions each time tailored to their area of expertise. In

    order to select the most relevant stakeholders, an initial detailed desk research has been performed mainly

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    6/50

    6

    on the Internetvia government and energy supplier websites as well as energy related debate platform -

    and by collecting informative leaflets, booklets, by studying the consultation process and drafts of the

    reform published periodically by the government. This first initial theoretical background helped building a

    deep knowledge on the previous and on the proposed future supporting scheme and to identify the main

    differences, challenges and controverted issues surrounding the EMR. With this in mind, the involved

    stakeholders have been identified via the initial desk research and by participating to a series of

    conferences on the topic. The selected people have then been contacted via e-mail in order check their

    availability to take part of this survey. Some of the contacted people were unfortunately too busy and

    therefore have not been able to take part to the assessment. The response has however been really

    encouraging and all the main topics of interest have successfully been covered with relevant experts. While

    performing the assessment, the following people have been interviewed: Tim Warham, senior policy

    adviser at the Department of Energy and Climate Change; David Handley, Chief Economist at Renewable

    Energy Solutions; Keith MacLean, Director of Policy and Research at SSE; Srinivasan Kavita, Strike price

    setting and digression specialist at the Committee on Climate Change, Jenny Hill, expert in Exemption of

    Energy Intensive Industries from low carbon levy at the CCC, Malcom Keay -Senior Research Fellow atOxford Institute of Energy Studies and Stewart Jamie- Deputy editor at ICIS and electricity market expert.

    The collected responses have subsequently been analyzed and divided into main topics of discussions in

    order to give an organic and extensive overview on how the EMR is perceived by all the involved parts.

    The following section of the report will give the reader a wide overview on the low carbon energy policy in

    the UK and on how the current supporting scheme works. The third chapter will analyze more into details

    the proposed Electricity Market Reform with a particular focus on the Contract for Difference supporting

    scheme that will effectively substitute the current regime from mid 2014. The fourth and last section will

    present the research outcome divided into ten different sub-sections. Each sub-section analyzes one

    different aspect of the reform that has been considered as crucial and of particular interest to assure asuccessful implementation of the reform. In the conclusion section, each of the above-mentioned sub-

    questions will be answered in order to finally assess whether the proposed EMR will create the right

    environment to push forward the decarbonization process of the electricity sector in the UK.

    2. Renewable Energy policy in the UKLooking at the European legislation, there is a common intent to increase low carbon production up to 20%

    before 2020. (European Commission, 2009) Each member state can adopt the most consistent regulation to

    achieve this goal on time. The specific UK carbon reduction target corresponds to meet at least 15% of thenational energy demand by means of green energy generation.(European Commission, 2009) In order to

    achieve this target the UK government has set a series of legislations throughout the past decade that

    boosted the percentage of electricity derived from renewable sources from 5.6 % in 2008 to 11.3 % in

    2012.(DECC, 2013). Currently Great Britain adopts a combined supporting scheme for low carbon

    generation, which makes use of a combined fixed Feed in Tariff (FiT) and Quota system for respectively

    small and bigger size installations. Renewable developments up to 5MW could benefit from a fixed feed in

    tariff mechanism whereas installation larger that 5MW can alternatively opt for one of the two options- FiT

    or tradable Quotas. (Uk government, 2013) . In order for a generator to effectively receive one of those

    subsidies; an application must be submitted to Ofgemto get an eligibility certificate in which the level of

    support is also clearly specified.

    In the following chapter a brief overview on the current supporting scheme will be given.

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    7/50

    7

    2.1 Feed-In-Tariff and Renewable Obligation Certificates

    In April 2010 the government launched the FiT scheme to encourage hauseholds and businesses to

    generate their own low-carbon electricity. The FiT scheme is an obligation for certain licensed electricity

    supplier to make pre-determined tariff payments to developers for generation and export of low carbon

    electricity.(Ofgem, 2013) Therefore as a renewable energy generator you are assured the electricity

    produced by your installation will receive a certain fixed income for a period of 20 years. The UK FiT system

    is a fixed tariff; meaning that once the generation tariff has been determined according to your

    application date, it will be guaranteed for a 20 years period and will only change in accordance to the Retail

    Price Index (RPI) to reflect inflation. However, since most renewable energy technologies are expected to

    get cheaper over time, a baseline digression for new applicants is used to ensure that resources are

    efficiently allocated without overcompensating investments. The extent of digression is technology specific

    and is periodically revised in order to better reflect current levels of development.

    Effectively, the income received under this subsidy scheme is made of two different components:

    Generation tariff

    Export tariff

    The generation tariff represents the main element of the FiT income and consists of a fixed payment per

    kWh produced, irrespective whether you feed electricity into the grid or use it yourself. The actual level of

    generation tariff depends on the renewable technology in use and on the size of the installation. Obviously,

    the larger the installation and the more mature a technology is; the lower the generation tariff. The current

    technology specific generation tariffs are available in Appendix. On top of this, generators will also get an

    extra payment for the electricity they export to the grid, which corresponds to a bonus payment for every

    kWh sold to the energy supplier. The export tariff has been implemented to provide an additional bonus for

    energy efficient generators. There is a minimum floor price for this payment, which is set by the

    government and currently corresponds to 4.64p/kWh. (DECC, 2013c) Each generator can either take this

    floor price as export tariff or negotiate a more convenient one by signing a Power Purchase Agreement

    with trusted rated suppliers. PPAs are effectively contracts signed by both energy generator and purchaser

    in which the price at which the electricity will be sold for a fixed period of time is determined. On top of

    this, the Levy Exemption Certificates (LEC) exempt renewable generators from the climate change levy

    therefore adding an additional net profit. The overall cost of this scheme is borne by the electricitysuppliers that will then pass on the costs onto consumers.

    Projects exceeding 5 MW can choose to either benefit of FiT or opt for the so-called Renewables

    Obligation which effectively consists of tradable quota permit. The ROs are the main supporting

    mechanism currently in use for large-scale green projects in the UK since 2002. The working principle of RO

    is as follows: on one side an obligation is placed on electricity suppliers to source an increasing portion of

    the supplied electricity from green sources. On the other hand, Renewable Obligation Certificates (ROCs)

    are issued by Ofgem to eligible green energy electricity generators according to the technology they use.

    Generators can then trade their ROCs in the market with other partieseither suppliers or other generators.

    Ultimately, the ROCs purchased by the suppliers are presented back to Ofgem to demonstrate theircompliance with the Obligation. In case a supplier does not present enough ROCs with respect to the

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    8/50

    8

    obligation issued, a penalty corresponding to the so called buy-out-price must be paid to Ofgemthat

    collects and divides the return among those suppliers that presented enough ROCs.(DECC, 2012a)

    The number of ROCs issued to each generator varies with the type of technology in use and the amount of

    green electricity produced.(DECC, 2013d). The variation in number of ROCs received between technologies

    reflects the difference between the level of development and costs of each technology: the moreROC/MWh received, the more costly a technology is, and the greater the level of support. Whereas the

    level of supplier obligation increases with time to reflect the decarbonization target, the level of ROC/MWh

    steadily decreases throughout the years to reflect cost reduction and learning processes among

    stakeholders. The ROCs levels are revised every four years and published on the DECC webpage. The RO

    banding for each technology for the period between 2013 and 2014 is available in the Appendix.

    The RO supporting mechanism offers an additional payment on top of the wholesale market electricity

    price, which corresponds to the market price for certificates. This payment is therefore not fixed- as in the

    case of the FiT- but varies accordingly to the price of the ROC in the obligation market and strictly depends

    on the negotiation between the supplier and the generator. For the government purposes, the value of aROC is calculated as a 10% increase in the buy-out-price which currently corresponds to 45/ROC.(DECC,

    2013d) Each October the overall obligation level is published by the government and expressed as number

    of ROCs/MWh (for the year 2013/2014 it was set as 0.206 ROCs/MWh). According to this value, each

    supplier obligation is calculated by simply multiplying this value by the total electricity production. In order

    to guarantee there will always be a market for the certificates, Ofgem uses a fixed 10% headroom between

    obligation and certificates, the headroom works by providing a set margin between supplier and demand

    for ROC. In this way generators are assured they will receive a suitable profit and the ROCs price itself is

    adequately stabilized.

    As in the case of FiT it is assumed that suppliers will pass the costs of the scheme onto consumers. It has

    been estimated that the average price of RO scheme per households in 2012 has been of 30.(DECC,

    2013d)

    2.2 Transition towards the Electricity Market Reform

    Generators have until the 31st

    of March 2017 to choose between the RO and the new Contract for

    Difference subsidy scheme. From the 1st

    April 2017, generators will not be allowed to apply for the RO

    scheme anymore and only the new CfD subsidy scheme will be available for large-scale generation. (DECC,

    2013e) The government will however guarantee that for a period of 20 years till the 31st

    of March 2037-

    there will be a market for ROCs. The transition period after 2017 will probably be held in two phases: a first

    phase that runs till 2027 and a second phase that will carry on till the last RO expires in 2037. (Ceeney,

    2013) Regarding the period between 2017 and 2027; the government plans to simply adapt the current RO

    system by fixing a higher headroom between supply and demand for certificates thus ensuring that

    demand for ROCs will continue. This will continue until 2027 when there will only be few projects under RO

    and therefore it will no longer be possible to guarantee a market for certificates. In this view the

    government is planning to switch to a Premium-FiT system, which will fix the price for the remaining ROCs

    for the following 10 years. The commitment of effectively grandfathering RO projects for the last 10 years

    seems to convince investors and therefore there is confidence that the RO will efficiently operate

    throughout the entire lifetime.(Keith MacLEan, 2013a) A public consultation is however going on with

    regards to the RO transition and will be published shortly with the definite outline of the transition

    method.(DECC, 2013e)

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    9/50

    9

    3. The Electricity Market ReformThis chapter will explore the details and characteristics of the proposed Electricity Market Reform that will

    be implemented in mid 2014 that will drive the UK electricity market to meet the 2020 decarbonization

    target.

    The challenges the government is encountering with regards to energy and climate change and that are

    addressed in the EMR are threefold:

    Maintain security of supply for future generations which is currently being challenged by a drastic

    increase in electricity demand

    Meet climate change target and lower carbon emission by changing the current energy mix

    Minimize the costs of the transition for consumers

    In order to meet these goals in time and to better direct the UK electricity sector towards the

    decarbonization target, the UK government designed the Electricity Market Reform (EMR) in November

    2012 with the aim of attracting investments and supporting employment in the low carbon sector. It isestimated that the reform will attract 110 billion investments and will create up to 250,000 new jobs in

    the next decade. (DECC, 2012b) The reform is currently under consideration and is being revised by the

    government to introduce final improvements and measures before it will effectively become a law in mid

    2014.

    The major market mechanisms that will become active with the reform are respectively:

    Capacity market: payments for reliable capacity that is available when needed and that therefore

    helps covering base load at all times.

    Feed-in Tariffs with Contract for Difference (FiT-CfDs) : long term contracts that provides securerevenues for low carbon generation such as renewable energy, nuclear power and Carbon Capture

    and Storage

    These mechanisms will be supported by:

    The Carbon Price Floor: a fixed tax for carbon emission.

    The Emission Performance Standard: a regulatory measure which provides a maximum limit for

    emissions from power stations

    While it is the government role to design the policy and set the goals for the reform, the National Grid on

    behalf of the EMR Delivery Body will administer the mechanism in its details by considering eligibility

    criteria for generators and allocation rules. Finally, Ofgem will supervise that the delivery body carries out

    duties efficiently and cost effectively.

    3.1 Contract For Difference

    This report will mainly focus on the FiT-CfDs supporting scheme that will be introduced within the EMR in

    mid 2014. The other measures mentioned above will therefore not be directly considered in this review

    since they do not constitute a major changing with respect to the previous regime and therefore do not

    constitute a major concern for green energy stakeholders. With regards of the CfD regime, the following

    sections will analyze in details the working principle of the CfD mechanism with respect to the payment

    method for low carbon generation, eligibility criteria and allocation methodology for a contract.

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    10/50

    10

    3.1.1 Working principle

    As previously mentioned CfDs will substitute the current RO regime for big scale low carbon generation

    including renewable, nuclear and CCS.CfDs effectively consist of a 15 years contract between low carbon

    generators and the so-called CfD Counterparty and will offer renewable energy investments a feed in

    premium with a variable premium. Meaning that renewable energy generators will get revenues by selling

    electricity to the grid as usual and, on top of this, they will receive a top-up payment, which varies with

    wholesale prices. The additional payment is calculated as the difference between a pre-agreed strike price

    and a market reference price. The cash flow can go in two different directions depending on the mutual

    difference between the strike and reference price. In case the strike price is higher than the reference price

    the generator gets paid, otherwise the generator needs to pay the consumers back by the same amount.

    Figure 1 CfD working principle(DECC, 2012b)

    The strike price represents the estimated cost related to investing in a particular technology, it is adjustedon an annual basis and it is linked to the Consumer Price Index (CPI) in order to reflect inflation. The final

    strike prices should be published in December 2013; at the moment only a draft is available which does not

    include prices for nuclear nor CCS - see Appendix for the complete table.

    Table 1 Draft strike price for most important renewable energy technologies. Values in the table below refers to /MWh. (DECC,

    2013f)

    Technology 2014/2015 2015/2016 2016/2017 2017/2018 2018/2019

    Solar PV 125 125 120 115 110

    Onshore wind 100 100 100 95 95

    Offshore wind 155 155 150 140 135

    The reference price is the estimated value of the market price for electricity. In order to set revenues for

    low carbon technologies at the right level, reference price calculations should match as much as possible an

    achievable sale price of electricity for low carbon generation. In case reference price estimation is not

    accurate, CfDs strike prices would need to be increased to reflect any risks in significant shortfalls. The

    estimation of the reference price is calculated differently for base load and intermittent technologies. In

    case of base load, such as nuclear or biomass, it is set as a season ahead price whereas for intermittent

    technology such as most of renewable it is set as a hourly day ahead price. (DECC, 2012c)

    By looking at the exact capacity covered by CfDs, it is still under discussion whether the 5MW threshold for

    FiT will be maintained or if it will be increased. Regardless, this is a controversial topic that will be finally

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    11/50

    11

    decided on a later stage this year. In the case the threshold will be increased up to 10 MW- as some

    generators wishes (The Clean Energy Forum, 2013)- most of the projects will benefit from the old fixed FiT

    and the reform will effectively fail to deliver the required cost reduction. It is therefore more likely that the

    5MW level will not be changed. (Handley David, 2013a)

    As mentioned before, CfDs effectively consist of contracts signed by two parts: low carbon generators andthe so called CfD Counterparty. Low carbon generators must meet certain eligibility criteria that will be

    assessed by the Delivery Bodyand that will assure that the site under consideration will deliver a certain

    capacity within a certain time and that it will be capable of bearing reverse payment costs. The other

    subscriber of the contract is the so-called CfD Counterpartywhich is a government owned limited liability

    company that administer payments scheme to and from generators. The government will therefore not be

    a signatory of the contract or have any obligation under it. The payments to generators are made by the

    Counterparty, which in turn receives funds from electricity suppliers by mean of the Supplier Obligation.

    (DECC, 2013g) The intention is to impose equal obligations on UK suppliers in relation to their market

    share; money raised by means of these obligations will be paid to the Counterparty and will then be used to

    meet the contract terms with generators. In order to give confidence to low carbon investors, Supplier

    Obligations must be designed in a way that ensures the Counterparty will be able to meet payments to

    generators without negatively affect suppliers and consumers. In this view a number of mechanisms, also

    known as backstops, will be implemented to ensure that generators will get payments in the event of

    suppliersfinancial issues. As will be described later in this report, security of payments between generators

    and counterparty is still a controversial topic that is raising fierce discussion among stakeholders and it

    therefore need to be carefully addressed in future stages of the reform.

    The figure presented below is a schematization of the involved parts and their interactions with regards of

    the CfD mechanism.

    Figure 2 Key institutional and legislative framework(DECC, 2012c)

    3.1.2 Eligibility criteria and Allocation method

    As previously stated, it will be the National Grid on behalf of the Delivery Body to administer eligibility

    criteria and allocation methodology. In order to be eligible to get a contract the developer will need to

    provide evidence that a number of eligibility criteria have been met before the Delivery Body allows a

    project to enter a contract with the Counterparty. Besides the 5MW capacity threshold, the two more

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    12/50

    12

    stringent requirements for meeting eligibility criteria for a CfD are: having planning permission approval

    from the council for construction and having accepted the grid connection offer- meaning the grid quote

    letter from the Distribution Network Operator must be signed and the initial deposit paid. Additionally,

    since developers must pay the Counterparty back in case the strike price is lower than the market reference

    price, minimum financial bankability requirements for the generators are required to assure its ability to

    handle payments under any scenario.(DECC, 2013h) More details on the financial requirements will be

    published later this year.

    Once the eligibility criteria are met, the site must go through the allocation process to assure a valid

    contract with the Counterparty. The total budget available for CfDs will be set within the Levy Control

    Framework (LCF) and it will increase over time reaching 7.6 billion pounds in 2020. The LCF in fact fixes the

    maximum cap that can be taken from consumers as a tax for energy regulation; it therefore protects

    consumers from excessive levies. As noticeable from the table below there is no specific budget allocated

    for each technology; this might in turn raise questions on whether or not renewables are ready to compete

    with more mature technologies such as nuclear within the same budget. It might be appropriate implement

    a minima to ensure that technologies at an early stage of development will effectively receive contracts and

    will not be suffocated by the huge capacity of nuclear or offshore wind. This eventuality is under

    consideration and subject to public consultation. The final decision is expected to be published along with

    final strike price in December. (DECC, 2013h)

    Table 2 Levy control Framework expressed in bn

    2014/15 2015/16 2016/17 2017/18 2018/19 2019/20 2020/21

    3.3 4.3 4.9 5.6 6.45 7 7.6

    Effectively the allocation process will be held in three different stages:

    First-Come-First-Served:

    Unconstrained allocation rounds

    Constrained allocation rounds

    The reason why the government designed three different stages for the allocation process is to closely

    follow and efficiently encourage low carbon generation in reaching its complete maturity. Each of the

    phases in fact reflects different stage of the development and therefore different competition

    requirements between technologies. In the first two phases, the strike prices for each technology will be

    set administratively, meaning set by the government and published well in advance. This will allow a

    moderate competition between technologies but with no alteration of the final revenues, which is

    determined by a pre-agreed strike price. It is likely that in the initial phase a certain minimum number of

    contracts will be allocated to more niche technologies in order to facilitate their development that would

    in other ways be hindered by more mature technologies such as nuclear wind and solar, the

    implementation of this mechanism is still under consideration. The Government has however stated its

    clear intention to move to a more competitive price setting as soon as practicable to effectively integrate

    low carbon technologies in the wide electricity market.(DECC, 2013h)

    The picture below summarizes the characteristics of each of the three allocation phases. Each phase is

    then described more in details in the following paragraph.

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    13/50

    13

    Figure 3 Allocation methodology under CfDs (DECC, 2013h)

    First Come First Served

    As the name suggests, during this phase each contract will be allocated to eligible generators by looking at

    the application order. Each developer will apply to get a contract in a specific delivery year as soon as the

    site have met all the eligibility criteria. This will in turn encourage developers to move fast during the initial

    phase of development. This first phase will continue till approximately 50% of the budget available for

    every delivery year for CfDs will be allocated. The first year that will extinguish the 50% budget limit will

    trigger the unconstrained allocation for every year. The Delivery Body will however inform DECC when the

    budget is close to running out and it might be the case that the Department will release additional budget

    and continue with the FCFS for an additional time. There are in fact concerns that the CfDs budget will only

    last for a really short period and this might harm the entire development process.

    Unconstrained Allocation Rounds

    In order to bring the required cost reduction the government is willing to introduce competition between

    technologies at an early stage of development by introducing allocation rounds. Once approximately 50%

    of the LCF for a specific delivery year will be allocated, contracts will be awarded through round held at

    fixed points in the year- supposedly in April and September. The government is reassuring stakeholders

    that all the bids will successfully get a contract. Stakeholders are however not entirely convinced this will be

    the case and are asking for more security regarding contracts allocation through rounds.

    Constrained allocation roundsWhen also all the budget to satisfy bids will be allocated, then auctions will be held. The strike price for

    each project will then be set more efficiently during each auction thus delivering the required cost

    reduction. In this phase strike price will therefore stop being administratively set and each site will have

    different revenues according to the agreed strike price during the auction. Auctions mechanism is still

    unclear and it is currently subject to public consultation to be published soon. What should however be

    implemented is an initial technology specific auction mechanism running between 2017 and 2020 followed

    by a technologic neutral auction system that will finally drive technologies to be effectively incorporated in

    the wholesale market.

    The scheme below is a representation of how the various phases will come in succession and the relativeexpected timescale.

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    14/50

    14

    Figure 4 transition to competitive price setting under CfDs (DECC, 2012b)

    3.1.3 From the allocation of a contract to project construction and energy delivery

    The signed contract will set out all the terms of the agreement between the involved parts. First indicative

    contract terms has been published in August 2013 and the final terms are expected to come out in

    December this year. Since the government is aware that there might be variations in market conditions

    resulting from developments in technologies, changing in market patterns or integration with the European

    electricity system, it will retain the power to revise standard CfDs terms to ensure they remain updated and

    effective in delivering government objectives. (DECC, 2013e)

    In order to avoid late delivery of capacity by generators, three different measures will be implemented in

    the contract terms:

    The Substantial Financial Milestone (SFM) is an economic commitment that needs to be met within

    one year of the signature of the contract. Generators are obliged to provide to the CfD

    Counterparty the evidence they have spent or committed a percentage of the overall site scost by

    the milestone date.

    The Target Commissioning Window (TCW) is the period of time within which the generator is ableto commission without penalty. The duration of the TCW will be set by the government to reflect

    the practical realities of developing each technology and will provide developers with an adequate

    degree of flexibility. Generators that commission after the TCW will still benefit from the agreed

    strike price but will have the term of the CfD reduced to reflect the length of the delay beyond the

    TCW.

    The Long Stop Date is the point beyond the end of the TCW after which a project that have failed to

    meet its commissioning will see its CfD terminated by the Counterparty.

    When finally a project is built, the plant will start generating and selling electricity to the market normally.

    In addition, the developer will either receive or make payments to the Counterparty depending on therelative difference between strike and reference price.

    There are certain circumstances under which changing in the contracts terms or even unexpected

    termination are admitted. Since the reform is designed to give investors the comfort of a secure, long term

    return of investment, they will also be covered against certain changes in law and regulation that will put

    into risks contract terms and revenues for generators. Moreover, in the contract a cost-free capacity

    adjustment will be included. The current proposal is to allow a 5% adjustment in capacity to be made at

    each stage of the development. Besides this, capacity can also be adjusted because of force majeure causes

    or geological conditions. (Neil Budd, 2013). Any additional reduction in capacity with respect to the claimed

    one at the beginning of the contract will lead to a reduction in strike price of 0.5% for every 1% capacityreduction. It is also possible that the Counterparty terminates the contract in case the installed capacity is

    reduced to 70% of the initial agreed value.

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    15/50

    15

    4. Research resultsThis section will give a better insight on the CfD mechanism by effectively looking at specific topics that

    have been considered to be of a main interest with regards to the reform. The opinion of various experts

    was collected via direct interviews and will here be presented in an organic way. This will give the reader a

    good overview on the main issues of the reform and on the effect that its implementation will have on the

    domestic as well as on the European electricity market. Each of the following subsection will be focused on

    one specific topic that has been considered as crucial for the successful development of the reform. All the

    results will mainly refer to the opinions collected via the interviews. The complete transcript of the

    interviews is available in Appendix.

    4.1 Why is a reform needed and what are the main changing introduced

    with respect to the previous mechanism

    What the government is trying to achieve with the CfDs is to gradually integrate low carbon generation in

    the electricity market by setting a top up payment that is function of the markets wholesale price. The

    government is however setting a secure long-term revenue for generators corresponding to the strikeprice, which is giving confidence to stakeholders in terms of revenues. On top of this, DECC is also trying to

    achieve substantial cost reduction for low carbon technologies in the most cost effective way by efficiently

    allocating resources and by homogeneously balancing risks between generators and consumers by means

    of the reverse payment in the case market price is above the strike price. (DECC, 2012c).

    According to Tim Warham- Senior policy adviser at DECC - the former FiT-RO mechanism was not enough to

    effectively bring the required transformation in the electricity sector and a reform was therefore needed to

    efficiently address sustainability and security of supply issues. (Warham, 2013) According to him, the long

    term FiT-RO scheme created a stagnant situation where entrepreneurs were offered too high and secure

    revenues and were therefore not encouraged to bring down the cost of technology. However, if renewabletechnologies want to fairly compete with fossil fuels in the market sales, their cost need to be drastically

    reduced and they need to be actively integrated in the electricity market and not be shielded from it. A

    reform was therefore required to push development forward and to increase low carbon investments by

    the amount required. (Warham, 2013)

    Another important issue that needed to be addressed by the British government is related to the stop of

    operation of many nuclear and coal plants in the coming 10-20 years from now. These plants currently

    cover a big portion of the base-load and need to be substituted. This fact offers a great opportunity to

    change the domestic energy mix by implementing a reform that encourages in a more efficient, less

    expensive way low carbon energy production. (Srinivasan, 2013)The table below reassumes the key pointsof the FiT/RO and CfD mechanism.

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    16/50

    16

    Table 3 Main characteristics of the FiT, RO and CfD system

    4.2 Consultation process

    As previously mentioned, the EMR is currently under consultation and will become active after the

    parliament approval expected in mid 2014. At least 2 years will pass from the first CfD reform proposal in

    2012 to its forecasted implementation. During this two years the Government tried to solve problems and

    refine the CfD scheme by interactively initiate a conversation with the involved parts. Many public

    consultations, conferences, information lectures and polls have been issued and published alongside with

    variations of the reform. This process not only helped to increase awareness on the reform itself but also

    encouraged a good learning process at all stages of the reform by encouraging communication between

    parts. The enhanced communication is part of the governments goal to improve transparency of theadopted reform. However, although we acknowledge the governments effort to inc rease transparency of

    the CfD schem, the intrinsic complexity of the reform could in turn discourage the entrance of new, small-

    scale developers into the market due to their inability to effectively be able to sign a convenient contract.

    (Srinivasan, 2013) In addition some people might argue that this transparent and interactive process

    initiated by the government has considerably slowed down the implementation of the reform which has

    now been under discussion for more than one and a half years.(Jamie, 2013a) Some stakeholders are in

    fact not confident the government will be able to solve all the issues related with the reform before mid

    2014 and therefore suggest the implementation of a plan B subsidy to become active till all issues related

    to the reform will be solved.(The Clean Energy Forum, 2013) The government however denies this option is

    being considered and is confident the reform will be delivered on time. (Warham, 2013)

    FiT RO FiT-CfDs

    Consists of a fixed payment

    received by renewable generator

    for the electricity produced for a

    20 years period

    Consists of a premium

    payment on top of the

    electricity sold to the

    market. The premium is not

    fixed but it is function of the

    price at which tradable

    certificates are sold to

    suppliers

    Long term contracts that provide a

    secure income for renewable

    energies, nuclear power and CCS.

    Low carbon generators sell

    electricity in the market and

    receives a top up payment which

    corresponds to the difference

    between a pre determined strike

    price and the forecasted market

    reference price

    Generation Tariff: /MWh

    payment for all renewable

    electricity produced. Varies for

    every technology and it is

    periodically revised to reflect cost

    reduction.

    ROC are issued to eligible

    generators according to the

    low carbon technology in

    use. An obligation is set onto

    suppliers to purchase a

    certain amount of

    certificates from generators.

    Strike price: estimated cost related

    to investing in a particular

    technology. Linked to CPI

    Reference price: expected price for

    electricity. Calculated on a seasonal

    or day ahead basis depending on

    technology.

    Export tariff: additional fixed

    income for exporting renewable

    electricity to the grid. Floor price

    for export is set by the

    government at 4.64p/kWh. By

    Signing a PPAs generators can

    negotiate a higher price with

    suppliers

    Suppliers that do not present

    enough ROCs need to pay a

    fine for each missing

    certificate to ofgem. The

    money collected is then

    divided among lawful

    suppliers.

    CfDs are effectively bilateral

    contract, thus cash flow can go in

    two different directions depending

    on the reciprocal difference

    between strike and reference

    price.

    20 years duration 20 years duration 15 years duration

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    17/50

    17

    4.3 Transition process

    The government is committed to make the transition from RO to CfDs as gradual as possible. The timescale

    with which the transition will take place and the commitment to grandfather projects financed under the

    RO regime from 2027 to 2037, is giving investors the required security they need in order not to lose

    confidence on the RO system.(Keith MacLean, 2013) Moreover, as will be described into more details in the

    strike price section, the initial strike price will be set in a way that reflects returns under the RO regime in

    order to create less distortions during the transition as possible. However, a substantial difference between

    the two regimes is underlined by the 14 categories of strike prices and the 35 renewable obligation support

    bands, meaning that competition will be introduced as soon as CfDs will become active. (Keith MacLEan,

    2013a)

    4.4 The Pay-When-Paid principle

    Among the terms of the contract that regulate payments between the CfD Counterparty and generators, it

    is stated that The payment obligation on the single CfD Counterparty will be conditional on it having

    received payments from electricity supplies under the supplier obligation (DECC, 2012b) In order to reducerisks the CfD Counterparty may encounter in case of insolvency of suppliers, the Pay-When-Paid principle

    has been introduced. In simple words it is a system that protects the Counterparty from supplier insolvency

    by obliging the Counterparty itself to pay generators back only when money from suppliers obligation have

    been received. (DECC, 2012c) This will in turn introduce a time-issue, since financial payments between

    parts should be made in real time in order to prevent investors to perceive the risk of passing time

    mismatches back onto generators. Exponents of the government reassure that it is extremely unlikely that

    the Counterparty will go insolvent since many suppliers will be obliged to pay obligation to a single

    Counterparty. (Warham, 2013) This issue is however still of mayor concern since there are no clear time

    restrictions yet on when the payments between the parts should be issued.

    4.5 Eligibility and allocation methodology issue

    The methodology used to award a contract is a key element for the success of CfDs and constitutes a

    controversial topic between government and stakeholders. As previously mentioned, allocation will be

    issued in three different stages each one reflecting a different level of development in low carbon power

    generation. Each stage is meant to push the development forward by encouraging competition between

    technologies and integration in the market in order to finally reach complete development of green power.

    What stakeholders argues with respect to this point is thatin contrast with the previous RO regime where

    certificates are allocated to all eligible technologies with the CfD scheme there is no guarantee of a

    contract.(Handley David, 2013a) On top of this, specific technology goals have not been set and smallerscale installations fear it is still too early to compete with more mature technologies such as nuclear and

    offshore wind power generation. Additionally, investors argues that is it not true that it will be able to apply

    for a contract at an early stage of the development as the government repeatedly assured. Getting

    planning permission and accepting grid connection offer from the DNO requires a great amount of

    investments that is however not counterbalanced by the certainty of a contract. (Handley David, 2013a).

    What Stewart Jamie from ICISa company specialized at analyzing the electricity market in the UK- argues

    is that, since all big offshore installations as well as nuclear power will get into planning only in the next 3

    years, they will probably be out of the FCFS eligibility stage. This will therefore leave a lot of space to small

    and medium solar and wind developers to effectively secure a contract within the initial FCFS stage. (Jamie,2013a). Although there will be an initial substantial request for securing a contract with the FCFS

    mechanism; the expectation is that the LCF and the government will be able to manage this process in the

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    18/50

    18

    smoothest way possible without creating delays. In addition, the government is committed to inform

    stakeholders way in advance before the allocation rounds will start and this will supposedly give enough

    time to adapt to the new regime. Mr Jamie however does not deny that some installations will not be able

    to get a contract and will be forced to reapply the following year with resulting substantial delays in the

    project delivery.

    The government still needs to publish many details with regards to the allocation process such as the final

    % of the LCF that will trigger to allocation rounds as well as specific auction details and possible technology

    specific goals to be assigned to certain niche technologies. There is therefore still time for DECC to address

    these issues carefully and to partially meet stakeholders needing.

    4.6 Strike Price setting and Digression

    The key factor that determines whether or not the CfD scheme will be able to efficiently support green

    energy generation is determined by the strike price level and its consequent digression over time. It is not

    surprising that this topic is at the center of attention in the discussions between government and

    renewable energy stakeholders. It is therefore of a great interest to analyze more into details the method

    used to calculate initial strike prices and their digression and to expose the main critiques coming from

    stakeholders as well as from governmental Advisory bodies such as the Committee on Climate Change

    (CCC).

    In order to be consistent with the previous RO scheme, for the years 2014/15 and 2016/17 the strike prices

    have been determined by the government using the so-called RO minus X formula. RO underlines the

    intent to provide a supporting mechanism aligned to that received under the Renewable Obligation system

    and the minus X underlines the assumption that the required rate of return for renewable projects under

    the CfD scheme will be lower than the one under to RO, due to a predicted decrease in perceived risks.

    From 2017 on, strike prices will be calculated by looking at the expectation of declining costs due to

    learning curvesand will not have any link with the RO mechanism. (DECC, 2013i)

    Although only an initial draft strike price is available at the moment-see Appendix- stakeholders have

    complained that the initial level of support is too low and that it decreases too fast over time. What Dr

    Keith MacLean Director of policy and Research at SSE- argues is that the EMR has introduced big

    distortions in the electricity market and that these distortions mainly come from issues related to strike

    prices. The first mistake made by the government has been the ambition to set the strike price in

    conformity with the RO revenues for each technology. The decision of using the wholesale price under the

    RO - a completely different supporting mechanism- as a reference for CfD revenues calculation, represents

    a wrong first assumption. In addition, he argues that the fact that investors will perceive their green

    investment as less risky and will therefore accept a lower rate of return is only an idealized assumption.

    (Keith MacLEan, 2013b) These two factors resulted in a too low first draft strike price that is depressing the

    low carbon sector. In addition, he underlines that the digression of strike prices is purely based on idealized

    learning curves calculated on the base of estimated increase in installed capacity. The extent of this

    increase in installed capacity is however only an idealized estimation and it is not based on available

    figures. (Keith Mac Lean. 2013)

    The CCC is on the same page of Mr MacLean. The CCC however does not consider the initial strike price as

    totally inconsistent and focus more on the strike price digression as a sign of the governments failure. The

    general opinion is that, in addition of an unclear pathway for renewable energy project after 2020, the

    government proposes a rate of digression of strike prices that is faster than implied by evidence.(CCC,

    2013) With regards to this point Mrs Srinivasan Kavita specialist at the CCC on strike price setting and

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    19/50

    19

    digressionunderlines that, besides the problems pointed out by Mr MacLean it is also unclear how the

    government calculated the digression curve. She argues that, in the documents available to the public, the

    technique used to calculate the digression curves it is not clear. It is therefore very hard also for the CCC to

    point which factors have been wrongly addressed or misinterpreted by the government. The CCC argues

    that there are three different factors that should guide the strike price decision and these are:

    Technology specific factors

    Market conditions

    Policy considerations

    The issues pointed out by the involved parts with regards to strike prices are therefore twofold. Leveling

    returns for projects under two different supporting mechanisms is complicated and has lead the

    government to slightly wrong initial strike price value. This is because, although the reduced perceived risk

    in renewable investment might be the reality, it is not possible to foresee that this effect will effectively

    happen before the mechanism is proven in the field. Moreover, the digression mechanism should only

    reflect the evidence of an achievable cost reduction under current market conditions and not under

    idealized ones. There is in fact significant uncertainty on how projects costs will evolve as a result of

    learning curves. There is however still time for DECC to consider these opinions and to address them when

    publishing the final strike price in December this year.

    4.7 Power Purchase Agreement

    Profits for low carbon energy technologies do not only depend on the level of subsidy received; they are

    also extremely dependent on the price at which each single project is able to sell the electricity produced to

    the market. However, since the current electricity market has been developed in an environment where

    large-scale fossil fuel plant made up the bulk of the generation capacity, renewable energys wholesale

    electricity price is largely subject to the continuous variation of fossil fuel price. For this reason signing a

    contract that defines a fixed-long term price at which renewable plants will be able to sell their electricity is

    vital to achieve a good return in investments. Therefore, renewable generators often enter so called Power

    Purchase Agreements (PPA) which effectively consist of legal contracts stipulated between the electricity

    generator (the seller) and the power purchaser (the buyer) in which the terms for the sale of electricity

    between the two parties are specified. This partially protects renewable generators income from the

    volatility of wholesale price.

    Due to the importance of signing a convenient long term PPA, it is of interest to analyze how these

    agreements work and how their market will change as a result of the introduction of the EMR-CfD. In order

    to present all the opinion on the issue, the opinion Neas Energy and David Handley will be presented. The

    first is one of the biggest PPA providers in the UK and the latter is an expert of PPA market especially from

    an independent generators point of view. He works at RES- one of the biggest renewable energy

    independent developer - and he is actively involved in the debate surrounding the evolution of PPA

    agreements under to EMR.

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    20/50

    20

    Figure 5 PPA under RO and CfD scheme(Neas Energy, 2013)

    The picture above represents how PPAs will change in the transition from RO to CfDs. Under the RO a PPA

    provider such as Neas Energy will offer a fixed price for electricity, which increases with RPI over time. The

    revenues for generators will vary according to the market price for ROCs. On the other hand, under CfDs

    PPA providers will pay the generator the electricity at a discounted reference price with respect to a

    predicted market price. The generator will however reach a fixed income due to the top-up to the strike

    price from the Counterparty. According to Neas Energy the majority of risks for the PPA providers will becancelled under the CfD market since there will be less risks related to ROC price volatility. For this reason

    lower PPA fees should apply and generators will be able to increase their incomes. However, risks related

    to the uncertainty in the prediction of the reference price on a day ahead basis will not lower risks related

    to imbalance costs.(Neas Energy, 2013)

    Particularly, projects that require long-term finance need to sign convenient long term PPAs in order to be

    bankable and receive the required long-term finance. The majority of these projects are carried out by

    independent generators, which are likely to develop 35-50% of renewable energy projects by 2020.

    (Cornwall energy, 2013). It is therefore of a great importance to protect their interests by providing them

    with viable PPAs. There are however only around 6 to 10 credit rated counterparties able to offer long termPPAs in the UK and therefore the resulting market is relatively illiquid and non competitive. As a result, long

    term PPA often include up to 20% or more discount against wholesale prices. The non liquidity of the

    market is due to severe restrictions posed on long terms PPA providers with regards to their ability to make

    the agreed payment over the 20 years lifetime of a contract.(Handley David, 2013b)

    When moving to the CfD market, problems might arise

    in terms of revenues for independent generators.

    Developers might in fact not be able to sell their

    electricity at the reference price due to non-convenient

    PPAs. In case this factor is not taken into account when

    calculating the strike price, generators will never

    receive an income corresponding to the strike price and

    therefore revenues will be consistently lowered- as

    shown in figure 6 .

    According to Mr Handley, on behalf of independent

    generators, there are three possible solutions to this

    issue:

    1.

    Increasing the strike price in a way it fully reflects the missed revenues for independent generators.This measure will in turn increase costs to consumers.

    Figure 6 Effects of a non viable PPA on projects under CfD

    (Handley David, 2013)

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    21/50

    21

    2. Let independent generators to be squeezed out of the market- thus putting into serious hazard

    green energy targets.

    3. Creating an alternative solution that allows generators to achieve required income.

    The solution proposed by a group of independent generators was to establish the so-called Green Power

    Auction Market (GPAM). Within the GPAM, the reference price for each site is set via auctions held every 6months. Independent generators argue that this solution will ensure that all developers will achieve the

    pre-determined strike price without any additional costs to consumers. It will also introduce more liquidity

    in the market thus helping balancing revenues between generators and PPA providers. (Handley David,

    2013b) According to Mr Handley it is unlikely that the government will implement this solution. Anyway,

    DECC is aware of the lack of liquidity among long-term PPA providers and is currently looking into

    alternative propositions. The one that appear to be the most likely is the so-called PPA of last resort under

    which it will be assured that each independent generator will secure a minimum viable PPA contract. It

    effectively consists of an obligation on suppliers to offer a floor PPA to green projects in case they have not

    been able to get one before the beginning of the contract. In David Handleys opinion, the success of this

    option will mainly depend on the price set by the government for the floor price in terms of /MWh. For

    independent generators the appropriate level would be fixing the PPA floor at 75-80% of the wholesale

    price. In fact, in case of a higher value there will be no incentive for generators to try to arrange their own

    PPA and in case of a lower value then revenues for investors under the PPA of last resort will be put into

    serious hazard.

    There is still a lot to discuss before the government will come to a solution with respect to the lack of

    liquidity in long terms PPAs but it seems that the problem is already widely acknowledged by all the

    involved parts which are well cooperating to find a solution. However, although the PPA of last resort is

    regarded as an adequate solution to the problem, only when the PPA floor price will be set it will be

    possible to properly judge whether independent generators will be able to efficiently make profits with

    green investment or if they will have a hard time to remain competitive in the market. From a wider

    prospective, the CfD scheme will increase generatorsrevenues due to more convenient PPAs. This could

    therefore generally increase low carbon revenues thus encouraging investments.

    4.8 Subsidizing nuclear energy

    According to Stewart Jamie, the British government has longer ago committed to nuclear generation; way

    before the Japanese and German anti-nuclear plan. Britain considers nuclear power as a reliable technology

    to be used to cover base load capacity at all times when fossil fuel generation will be extinguished. (Stewart

    Jamie, 2013) The EMR will increase low carbon production in the UK electricity sector by particularly

    focusing on the generation side of the market. It therefore does not directly consider subsidizing big scale

    low carbon storage measures such as fuel cells or batteries. By looking at the reform from the generation-

    side prospective, nuclear production is therefore the perfect candidate to cover renewable energy

    intermittency in electricity production. Renewable energy stakeholders are however particularly concerned

    that big scale nuclear installation will become dominant and use most of the available budget allocated

    within the LCF leaving no space for other technologies. An extreme view is the one offered by Mr Mac Lean,

    that suggests that the whole EMR reform was implemented only to offer an excuse to subsidize nuclear

    generation (Keith Mac Lean,2013). Although this seems a pretty extreme position, it is undeniable that the

    British position with regards to the nuclear issue has surprised most of the people in the low carbon

    business, especially at a European level. This will cause problems to the EMR- as will be shown in thefollowing sections- especially when considering the UK within the EU context. The EU is in fact currently

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    22/50

    22

    trying to push all the member states towards the implementation of an homogeneous approach with

    regards to low carbon policies that does not currently include nuclear generation.

    The reason why low carbon energy policies are needed is mainly because green power generation is still at

    an early stage of development and therefore need incentives to keep the price of electricity competitive

    with respect to fossil fuels produced one. It is therefore a surprise when nuclear power- a well-establishednon 100% environmentally friendly technology is regarded- together with renewable generation- as a low

    carbon technology to subsidize. The debate surrounding nuclear power is fierce at the moment especially

    after the Fukushima disaster in Japan and the German step back with regards to nuclear generation. It is

    however undeniable that electricity produced by means of nuclear fission of Uranium is a low carbon

    technology. Moreover the implementation of third generation reactors, which can partially re-use

    radioactive waste to produce additional energy while lowering considerably the lifetime of radioactive

    waste, is a really interesting option not to underestimate.

    4.9 Exemption of Energy Intensive Industries (EIIs) from CfDs costs

    The government is actively raising suppliers cost of production by imposing them a payment with respects

    to their carbon emission. This obligation is in turns affectively lowering their revenues. The increases in

    costs will directly be passed into electricity consumers that will ultimately bear the costs of the scheme.

    This fact is well acknowledged by low carbon policy makers that need to find a balance between two

    opposing concepts. On one side the main aim of low carbon policies is to decrease carbon consumption by

    discouraging fossil fuel utilization; on the other side there is the need to protect energy consumers and

    particularly competitiveness of national energy industries that are among the major electricity users in the

    country. Industries that make use of great amounts of electricity throughout their production chain are in

    fact the ones that will be more negatively affected by little variations in the electricity price, as shown by

    the table below. What the government wants to prevent when implementing low carbon strategies, is the

    so-called carbon leakage phenomenon. This phenomenon effectively consists in the delocalization of

    manufacturing industries towards countries where prices for carbon emissions are lower, thus

    impoverishing national economies. In order to avoid this, the British government wants to implement,

    alongside with the EMR, a measure that exempt from CfDs payments certain categories of national

    industries which particularly contributes to the economic wealth (DECC, 2013j) .The idea is to only exempt

    companies which are both electricity and trade intensive and that are in direct contact with oversea

    markets.The alarm to the British government is caused by the already high price in electricity faced by

    British consumers with respect to the rest of Europe. (Jamie, 2013b) Any additional cost will therefore put

    into serious hazard international EIIs competitiveness

    If the government is to exempt energy intensive industries from CfD payments, this will surely add big

    distortions in the electricity market. However, what Jenny Hillan expert on the matter of energy intensive

    industries regulation at the CCC - argues is that distortions are in this case inevitable due to the lack of a

    homogeneous approach on decarbonization at a global level. (Jenny Hill, 2013)She adds that if we want to

    point the finger at serious distortions introduced by low carbon policies, than we should think about direct

    carbon emission taxation. This idea is also supported by Stewart Jamie on behalf of ICIS. The figures

    provided by ICIS in fact show that 3.8% of the electricity bill British consumers pay is due to carbon floor

    price. (Stewart Jamie,2013) A distortion that needs to be avoided at all costs is however the one resulting

    from an intrinsic discouragement of energy saving measures or the penalization of companies that

    effectively invests in energy efficiency measures.

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    23/50

    23

    It has been estimated that the EMR-CfDs will add on average 5.80/MWh to the electricity prices between

    2016 and 2020. (DECC, 2013j)Partial exemption of EIIS from CfD levies means that the additional costs will

    be divided between the remaining non-exempted consumers. As table 5 suggests, according to the extent

    of exemption, between 30p and 80p/ MWh will be added to electricity bills for non-exempted consumers

    according to the exemption option. Currently there are four exemption options being considered and

    subject to public consultation. These are listed and explained into details below.

    1A- Compensation mirror:

    This is currently the governmentspreferred option. All eligible industries within this option will be

    exempted from 80% of CfD costs. The eligible exempted sectors and sub sectors are listed in a

    document published by the European Commission, which list categories that are considered to be

    at risk of carbon leakage.

    1B-Reduced Exemption Level:

    In this options eligible sectors and sub-sectors are unvaried with respect to option 1A. The main

    difference consists in the amount of the exemption, which decreases from 80% under option 1A

    down to 67% under option 1B. In this scenario non-exempted consumers are more protected

    whereas big industries are less.

    2A- Wider eligibility scenario:

    In this scenario eligible industries are increased with respect to the European Commission guideline

    and might include also medium electricity intensive firms. The exemption level is targeted at 80 %

    of the CfD costs as in option 1A. This option will inevitably have more impacts on non-exempted

    consumers and will also increase the costs for the government.

    2B- Compensation plus a taper for additional sectors:

    In option 2B all eligible industries under option 2A are included but divided into 2 different bands.

    The core band comprise all the sectors outlined by the European Commission guidelines (the ones

    included in option 1A/B) that will receive a 80% exemption such as in case 1A. In addition to this,

    medium scale electricity intensive industries that would have been included into 2A will receive a

    50% exemption on CfD prices. This allows a differentiation between big and medium-scale

    industries thus reducing the impact onto consumers with respect to option 2A.

    Table 4 How costs of the CfD scheme will be perceived by consumers and EIIs in normal

    conditions and under the four proposed exemption levels (DECC, 2013j)

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    24/50

    24

    A public survey published earlier this year by n-power one of the big six energy suppliers in the UK-

    showed that low carbon stakeholders would prefer the implementation of option 1B.(n-power,2013) This is

    in contrast with the government preferred option 1A. The four exemption options described above are

    currently subject to public consultation. The final decision with regards to this measure will be published in

    a later stage when the public consultation results will be out.

    What is clear is that a serious homogeneous approach at international level is needed if we are to

    considerably reduce carbon consumption and protect national industries and consumers. The European

    Union is actively moving in this direction by trying to implement various measures to push low carbon

    policies in its member states to become slowly uniform thus discouraging the carbon leakage

    phenomenon. For this homologation of policies issue, the exemption of energy intensive industries from

    CfD levies will encounter some obstacles at a European level, as will be better explained in the next

    chapter. The problem of carbon leakage is however a global issues and need to be addressed horizontally in

    each country if we are to succeed in the decarbonization process.

    4.10 State Aid measures and the EMR in the EU prospectiveState Aid is defined as any form of advantage conferred on a selective basis by national public authorities to

    certain undertakings. State aid measures are generally prohibited within the European Union unless they

    can be justified by reasons of general economic development. Within the EU, the European Commission

    (EC) is the body in charge of assuring that all member states respect state aid prohibition or alternatively

    that state aid complies with EU rules. (European Union, 2013).

    Currently, it is at the center of discussion whether or not and to which extent the EMR should be

    considered a state aid measure and therefore apply for clearance to the European Commission. At the

    moment there is not enough awareness among stakeholders on the state aid issue and the debate is

    isolated between economics experts, European Union Parliament members and the UK government. It is

    however a critical issue in terms of the consequences this might have with regards to radical adjustments

    that might be required to the reform and of severe delays that might be encountered during the clearance

    process. For this reason a section of this report has been dedicated at explaining how state aid works and

    which are the consequences this might have on the green energy reform.

    The European Union claims that, to be regarded as state aid, a measure needs to have the following

    features:

    There has to be a direct intervention by the state through state resources

    The intervention gives the recipient an advantage on a selective basis Competition has been or may be distorted

    The intervention might affect trade between member states.

    There are however circumstances in which a state aid measure is allowed in virtue of its importance into

    achieving common European goals. These cases are covered within the so-called European Guidelines,

    which currently include energy efficiency, renewable, and CHP as allowed state aid technologies. Member

    states are however obliged to notify and seek approval from the Commission before implementing a state

    aid measure and in any circumstances the EC has the right to approve, refuse, or impose changing to the

    examined measure. It might take from several months up to several years to get EC clearance depending on

    the case and on the extent of legal issues encountered. (European Union, 2013)

  • 8/11/2019 Arianna Tozzi EMR Report

    25/50

    25

    According to Mr Malcolm Keayresearcher and expert on energy policies and European laws at the Oxford

    institutes of energy studies- there are two main elements that suggest that the EMR should be regarded as

    a state aid measure and these are respectively the substantial amount of renewable energies incentives

    introduced by the EMR and the presence of nuclear energy regarded as green technology.

    Although renewable energies are included within the commission guidelines, the level of support allowedwill probably be lowered when the revised Guidelines will be published by the end of the year. According to

    Mr Keay, this might put into risk EMR acceptance at EU level. The reason is because the Committee

    considers renewable technologies ready to start being slowly driven into the market by decreasing the level

    of support received and by implementing a homogeneous policy approach within member states which is

    more market orientated and less shield from it. This is therefore in contrast with the fixed-income provided

    by FiT-CfDs. Although CfDs are more linked to the market price than pure FiT, since payment to generators

    will stop once the market price have reached the strike price, the commission is likely not to totally support

    the proposed reform especially considering that the previous RO scheme was in a certain sense more

    market orientated and therefore more compliant with Europeans new directives. (Keay, 2013)

    The second issue regards nuclear power generation. As previously mentioned, nuclear power is for the first

    time in a European legislation regarded as a green energy technology and therefore subject to the same

    subsidy scheme as for renewable technologies. As stated by Mr Warham on behalf of DECC, nuclear energy

    is strongly supported by the UK government as it is considered a low carbon, affordable safe technology

    capable of covering base and peak load at all the times(Warham, 2013). Although the EC is generally in

    favor of nuclear generation, the debate at European level is encountering the fierce opposition of many

    member states such as Germany and Austria(Keay, 2013). It is therefore still unknown whether nuclear

    generation will be included in the new Commission Guidelines for State Aid in December 2013. In

    In addition to the above-mentioned problems, also the proposed exemption of energy intensive industries

    will need to seek commission clearance. In fact, although others EU member states might already have

    exemption in place, such as in the case of Germany, it is the intention of the EC to start limiting this

    exemption mechanism and to bring all the involved parts to pay for their carbon consumption.(Keay, 2013)

    The UK government has not applied for state aid clearance yet but the commission is aware of the issue

    and discussions have already started. It will however take some time before all the issues will be clarified

    and it is therefore probable that the EMR will be approved by the UK parliament and become active before

    clearance is received. Renewable and nuclear generators will therefore enter a contract with the CfD

    Counterparty before the EU issue is cleared. According to Mr MacLean the contracts will not be legally

    b