are emily and greg more employable than lakisha and jamal...

24
Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal? A Field Experiment on Labor Market Discrimination By MARIANNE BERTRAND AND SENDHIL MULLAINATHAN* We study race in the labor market by sending fictitious resumes to help-wanted ads in Boston and Chicago newspapers. To manipulate perceived race, resumes are randomly assigned African-American- or White-sounding names. White names receive 50 percent more callbacks for interviews. Callbacks are also more respon- sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial gap is uniform across occupation, industry, and employer size. We also find little evidence that employers are inferring social class from the names. Differential treatment by race still appears to still be prominent in the U.S. labor market. {JEL ill, J64). Every measure of economic success reveals significant racial inequality in the U.S. labor market. Compared to Whites, African-Ameri- cans are twice as likely to be unemployed and earn nearly 25 percent less when they are em- ployed (Council of Economic Advisers, 1998). This inequality has sparked a debate as to whether employers treat members of different races differentially. When faced with observ- ably similar African-American and White ap- plicants, do they favor the White one? Some argue yes, citing either employer prejudice or employer perception that race signals lower pro- ductivity. Others argue that differential treat- ment by race is a relic of the past, eliminated by some combination of employer enlightenment, affirmative action programs and the profit- maximization motive. In fact, many in this latter camp even feel that stringent enforcement of affirmative action programs has produced an environment of reverse discrimination. They would argue that faced with identical candi- * Bertrand: Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 E. 58th Street, RO 229D, Chicago, IL 60637, NBER, and CEPR (e-mail; marianne.bertrand@gsb. uchicago.edu); Mullainathan: Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 50 Memorial Drive, E52-380a, Cambridge, MA 02142, and NBER (e-mail: [email protected]). David Abrams, Victoria Bede, Simone Berkowitz, Hong Chung, Almudena Fernandez, Mary Anne Guediguian, Christine Jaw, Richa Maheswari, Beverley Martis, Alison Tisza, Grant Whitehora, and Christine Yee provided excellent research assistance. We are also grateful to numerous colleagues and seminar participants for very helpful comments. dates, employers might favor the African- American one.' Data limitations make it difficult to empirically test these views. Since researchers possess far less data than employers do. White and African-American workers that appear similar to researchers may look very different to employers. So any racial difference in labor market outcomes could just as easily be attributed to differences that are observable to employers but unobservable to researchers. To circumvent this difficulty, we conduct a field experiment that builds on the correspon- dence testing methodology that has been pri- marily used in the past to study minority outcomes in the United Kingdom. We send resumes in response to help-wanted ads in Chi- cago and Boston newspapers and measure call- back for interview for each sent resume. We ' This camp often explains the poor performance of African-Americans in terms of supply factors. If African- Americans lack many basic skills entering the labor market, then tliey will perform worse, even with parity or favoritism in hiring. ^ See Roger Jowell and Patricia Prescott-Clarke (1970), Jim Hubbuck and Simon Carter (1980), Colin Brown and Pat Gay (1985), and Peter A. Riach and Judith Rich (1991). One caveat is that some of these studies fail to fully match skills between minority and nonminority resumes. For ex- ample some impose differential education background by racial origin. Doris Weichselbaumer (2003, 2004) studies the impact of sex-stereotypes and sexual orientation. Rich- ard E. Nisbett and Dov Cohen (1996) perform a related field experiment to study how employers' response to a criminal past varies between the North and the South in the United States. 991

Upload: others

Post on 25-Aug-2020

6 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha andJamal? A Field Experiment on Labor Market Discrimination

By MARIANNE BERTRAND AND SENDHIL MULLAINATHAN*

We study race in the labor market by sending fictitious resumes to help-wanted adsin Boston and Chicago newspapers. To manipulate perceived race, resumes arerandomly assigned African-American- or White-sounding names. White namesreceive 50 percent more callbacks for interviews. Callbacks are also more respon-sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racialgap is uniform across occupation, industry, and employer size. We also find littleevidence that employers are inferring social class from the names. Differentialtreatment by race still appears to still be prominent in the U.S. labor market. {JELill, J64).

Every measure of economic success revealssignificant racial inequality in the U.S. labormarket. Compared to Whites, African-Ameri-cans are twice as likely to be unemployed andearn nearly 25 percent less when they are em-ployed (Council of Economic Advisers, 1998).This inequality has sparked a debate as towhether employers treat members of differentraces differentially. When faced with observ-ably similar African-American and White ap-plicants, do they favor the White one? Someargue yes, citing either employer prejudice oremployer perception that race signals lower pro-ductivity. Others argue that differential treat-ment by race is a relic of the past, eliminated bysome combination of employer enlightenment,affirmative action programs and the profit-maximization motive. In fact, many in this lattercamp even feel that stringent enforcement ofaffirmative action programs has produced anenvironment of reverse discrimination. Theywould argue that faced with identical candi-

* Bertrand: Graduate School of Business, University ofChicago, 1101 E. 58th Street, RO 229D, Chicago, IL 60637,NBER, and CEPR (e-mail; [email protected]); Mullainathan: Department of Economics,Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 50 Memorial Drive,E52-380a, Cambridge, MA 02142, and NBER (e-mail:[email protected]). David Abrams, Victoria Bede, SimoneBerkowitz, Hong Chung, Almudena Fernandez, Mary AnneGuediguian, Christine Jaw, Richa Maheswari, BeverleyMartis, Alison Tisza, Grant Whitehora, and Christine Yeeprovided excellent research assistance. We are also gratefulto numerous colleagues and seminar participants for veryhelpful comments.

dates, employers might favor the African-American one.' Data limitations make itdifficult to empirically test these views. Sinceresearchers possess far less data than employersdo. White and African-American workers thatappear similar to researchers may look verydifferent to employers. So any racial differencein labor market outcomes could just as easily beattributed to differences that are observable toemployers but unobservable to researchers.

To circumvent this difficulty, we conduct afield experiment that builds on the correspon-dence testing methodology that has been pri-marily used in the past to study minorityoutcomes in the United Kingdom. We sendresumes in response to help-wanted ads in Chi-cago and Boston newspapers and measure call-back for interview for each sent resume. We

' This camp often explains the poor performance ofAfrican-Americans in terms of supply factors. If African-Americans lack many basic skills entering the labor market,then tliey will perform worse, even with parity or favoritismin hiring.

^ See Roger Jowell and Patricia Prescott-Clarke (1970),Jim Hubbuck and Simon Carter (1980), Colin Brown andPat Gay (1985), and Peter A. Riach and Judith Rich (1991).One caveat is that some of these studies fail to fully matchskills between minority and nonminority resumes. For ex-ample some impose differential education background byracial origin. Doris Weichselbaumer (2003, 2004) studiesthe impact of sex-stereotypes and sexual orientation. Rich-ard E. Nisbett and Dov Cohen (1996) perform a related fieldexperiment to study how employers' response to a criminalpast varies between the North and the South in the UnitedStates.

991

Page 2: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

992 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2004

experimentally manipulate perception of racevia the name of the fictitious job applicant. Werandomly assign very White-sounding names(such as Emily Walsh or Greg Baker) to half theresumes and very African-Amedcan-soundingnames (such as Lakisha Washington or JamalJones) to the other half. Because we are alsointerested in how credentials affect the racialgap in callback, we experimentally vary thequality of the resumes used in response to agiven ad. Higher-quality applicants have on av-erage a little more labor market experience andfewer holes in their employment history; theyare also more likely to have an e-mail address,have completed some certification degree, pos-sess foreign language skills, or have beenawarded some honors.^ In practice, we typicallysend four resumes in response to each ad: twohigher-quality and two lower-quality ones.We randomly assign to one of the higher- andone of the lower-quality resumes an African-American-sounding name. In total, we respondto over 1,300 employment ads in the sales,administrative support, clerical, and customerservices job categories and send nearly 5,000resumes. The ads we respond to cover a largespectrum of job quality, from cashier work atretail establishments and clerical work in a mailroom, to office and sales management positions.

We find large racial differences in callbackrates.'* Applicants with White names need tosend about 10 resumes to get one callbackwhereas applicants with African-Americannames need to send about 15 resumes. This50-percent gap in callback is statistically signif-icant. A White name yields as many more call-backs as an additional eight years of experienceon a resume. Since applicants' names are ran-domly assigned, this gap can only be attributedto the name manipulation.

Race also affects the reward to having a bet-ter resume. Whites with higher-quality resumesreceive nearly 30-percent more callbacks than

•* In creating the higher-quality resumes, we deliberatelymake small changes in credentials so as to minimize the riskof overqualification.

•* For ease of exposition, we refer to the effects uncov-ered in this experiment as racial differences. Technically,however, these effects are about the racial soundingness ofnames. We briefly discuss below the potential confoundsbetween name and race. A more extensive discussion isoffered in Section IV, subsection B.

Whites with lower-quality resumes. On theother hand, having a higher-quality resume hasa smaller effect for African-Americans. In otherwords, the gap between Whites and African-Americans widens with resume quality. Whileone may have expected improved credentials toalleviate employers' fear that African-Americanapplicants are deficient in some unobservableskills, this is not the case in our data.^

The experiment also reveals several otheraspects of the differential treatment by race.First, since we randomly assign applicants'postal addresses to the resumes, we can studythe effect of neighborhood of residence on thelikelihood of callback. We find that living in awealthier (or more educated or Whiter) neigh-borhood increases callback rates. But, interest-ingly, African-Americans are not helped morethan Whites by living in a "better" neighbor-hood. Second, the racial gap we measure indifferent industries does not appear correlated toCensus-based measures of the racial gap inwages. The same is true for the racial gap wemeasure in different occupations. In fact, wefind that the racial gaps in callback are statisti-cally indistinguishable across all the occupationand industry categories covered in the experi-ment. Federal contractors, who are thought to bemore severely constrained by affirmative actionlaws, do not treat the African-American re-sumes more preferentially; neither do larger em-ployers or employers who explicitly state thatthey are "Equal Opportunity Employers." InChicago, we find a slightly smaller racial gapwhen employers are located in more African-American neighborhoods.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows.Section I compares this experiment to earlierwork on racial discrimination, and most nota-bly to the labor market audit studies. Wedescribe the experimental design in SectionII and present the results in Section III, subsec-tion A. In Section IV, we discuss possible in-terpretations of our results, focusing especiallyon two issues. First, we examine whether the

' These results contrast with the view, mostly based onnonexperimental evidence, that African-Americans receivehigher returns to skills. For example, estimating earningsregressions on several decades of Census data, JamesJ. Heckman et al. (2001) show that African-Americansexperience higher returns to a high school degree thanWhites do.

Page 3: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

VOL 94 NO. 4 BERTRAND AND MULLAINATHAN: RACE IN THE LABOR MARKET 993

race-specific names we have chosen might alsoproxy for social class above and beyond the raceof the applicant. Using birth certificate data onmother's education for the different first namesused in our sample, we find little relationshipbetween social background and the name-specific callback rates. Second, we discuss howour results map back to the different models ofdiscrimination proposed in the economics liter-ature. In doing so, we focus on two importantresults: the lower returns to credentials forAfrican-Americans and the relative homogene-ity of the racial gap across occupations andindustries. We conclude that existing models doa poor job of explaining the full set of findings.Section V concludes.

I. Previous Research

With conventional labor force and householdsurveys, it is difficult to study whether differ-ential treatment occurs in the labor market.^Armed only with survey data, researchers usu-ally measure differential treatment by compar-ing the labor market performance of Whites andAfrican-Americans (or men and women) forwhich they observe similar sets of skills. Butsuch comparisons can be quite misleading.Standard labor force surveys do not contain allthe characteristics that employers observe whenhiring, promoting, or setting wages. So one cannever be sure that the minority and nonminorityworkers being compared are truly similar fromthe employers' perspective. As a consequence,any measured differences in outcomes could beattributed to these unobserved (to the re-searcher) factors.

This difficulty with conventional data hasled some authors to instead rely on pseudo-experiments.* Claudia Goldin and Cecilia

' We also argue that a social class interpretation wouldfind it hard to explain some of our findings, such as whyliving in a better neighborhood does not increase callback ratesmore for African-American names than for White names.

' See Joseph G. Altonji and Rebecca M. Blank (1999)for a detailed review of the existing literature on racialdiscrimination in the labor market.

* William A. Darity, Jr. and Patrick L. Mason (1998)describe an interesting nonexperimental study. Prior to theCivil Rights Act of 1964, employment ads would explicitlystate racial biases, providing a direct measure of differentialtreatment. Of course, as Arrow (1998) mentions, discrimi-nation was at that time "a fact too evident for detection."

Rouse (2000), for example, examine the effectof blind auditioning on the hiring process oforchestras. By observing the treatment of fe-male candidates before and after the introduc-tion of blind auditions, they try to measure theamount of sex discrimination. When such pseu-do-experiments can be found, the resultingstudy can be very informative; but finding suchexperiments has proven to be extremelychallenging.

A different set of studies, known as auditstudies, attempts to place comparable minorityand White actors into actual social and eco-nomic settings and measure how each groupfares in these settings.^ Labor market auditstudies send comparable minority (African-American or Hispanic) and White auditors infor interviews and measure whether one is morelikely to get the job than the other.'° While theresults vary somewhat across studies, minorityauditors tend to perform worse on average: theyare less likely to get called back for a secondinterview and, conditional on getting calledback, less likely to get hired.

These audit studies provide some of thecleanest nonlaboratory evidence of differentialtreatment by race. But they also have weak-nesses, most of which have been highlighted inHeckman and Siegelman (1992) and Heckman(1998). First, these studies require that bothmembers of the auditor pair are identical in alldimensions that might affect productivity inemployers' eyes, except for race. To accomplishthis, researchers typically match auditors onseveral characteristics (height, weight, age, di-alect, dressing style, hairdo) and train them forseveral days to coordinate interviewing styles.Yet, critics note that this is unlikely to erase thenumerous differences that exist between the au-ditors in a pair.

Another weakness of the audit studies is thatthey are not double-blind. Auditors know thepurpose of the study. As Turner et al. (1991)

'Michael Fix and Marjery A. Turner (1998) provide asurvey of many such audit studies.

'" Earlier hiring audit studies include Jerry M. Newman(1978) and Shelby J. Mclntyre et al. (1980). Three morerecent studies are Harry Cross et al. (1990), Franklin Jamesand Steve W. DelCastillo (1991), and Turner et al. (1991).Heckman and Peter Siegelman (1992), Heckman (1998),and Altonji and Blank (1999) summarize these studies. Seealso David Neumark (1996) for a labor market audit studyon gender discrimination.

Page 4: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

994 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2004

note: "The first day of training also included anintroduction to employment discrimination,equal employment opportunity, and a review ofproject design and methodology." This maygenerate conscious or subconscious motivesamong auditors to generate data consistent orinconsistent with their beliefs about race issuesin America. As psychologists know very well,these demand effects can be quite strong. It isvery difficult to insure that auditors will notwant to do "a good job." Since they know thegoal of the experiment, they can alter theirbehavior in front of employers to express (indi-rectly) their own views. Even a small belief byauditors that employers treat minorities differ-ently can result in measured differences in treat-ment. This effect is further magnified by the factthat auditors are not in fact seeking jobs and aretherefore more free to let their beliefs affect theinterview process.

Finally, audit studies are extremely expen-sive, making it difficult to generate largeenough samples to understand nuances and pos-sible mitigating factors. Also, these budgetaryconstraints worsen the problem of mismatchedauditor pairs. Cost considerations force the useof a limited number of pairs of auditors, mean-ing that any one mismatched pair can easilydrive the results. In fact, these studies generallytend to find significant differences in outcomesacross pairs.

Our study circumvents these problems. First,because we only rely on resumes and not peo-ple, we can be sure to generate comparabilityacross race. In fact, since race is randomly as-signed to each resume, the same resume willsometimes be associated with an African-American name and sometimes with a Whitename. This guarantees that any differences wefind are caused solely by the race manipulation.Second, the use of paper resumes insulates usfrom demand effects. While the research assis-tants know the purpose of the study, our proto-col allows little room for conscious orsubconscious deviations from the set proce-dures. Moreover, we can objectively measurewhether the randomization occurred as ex-pected. This kind of objective measurement isimpossible in the case of the previous auditstudies. Finally, because of relatively low mar-ginal cost, we can send out a large number ofresumes. Besides giving us more precise esti-mates, this larger sample size also allows us to

examine the nature of the differential treatmentfrom many more angles.

II. Experimental Design

A. Creating a Bank of Resumes

The first step of the experimental design is togenerate templates for the resumes to be sent.The challenge is to produce a set of realistic andrepresentative resumes without using resumesthat belong to actual job seekers. To achievethis goal, we start with resumes of actual jobsearchers but alter them sufficiently to createdistinct resumes. The alterations maintain thestructure and realism of the initial resumes with-out compromising their owners.

We begin with resumes posted on two jobsearch Web sites as the basis for our artificialresumes." While the resumes posted on theseWeb sites may not be completely representativeof the average job seeker, they provide a prac-tical approximation.'^ We restrict ourselves topeople seeking employment in our experimentalcities (Boston and Chicago). We also restrictourselves to four occupational categories: sales,administrative support, clerical services, andcustomer services. Finally, we further restrictourselves to resumes posted more than sixmonths prior to the start of the experiment. Wepurge the selected resumes of the person's nameand contact information.

During this process, we classify the resumeswithin each detailed occupational category intotwo groups: high and low quality. In judgingresume quality, we use criteria such as labormarket experience, career profile, existence ofgaps in employment, and skills listed. Such aclassification is admittedly subjective but it ismade independently of any race assignment onthe resumes (which occurs later in the experi-mental design). To further reinforce the qualitygap between the two sets of resumes, we add toeach high-quality resume a subset of the follow-ing features: summer or while-at-school em-ployment experience, volunteering experience,extra computer skills, certification degrees, for-eign language skills, honors, or some military

' ' The sites are www.careerbuilder.cora and www.americasjobbank.com.

'^ In practice, we found large variation in skill levelsamong people posting their resumes on these sites.

Page 5: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

VOL. 94 NO. 4 BERTRAND AND MULLAINATHAN: RACE IN THE LABOR MARKET 995

experience. This resume quality manipulationneeds to be somewhat subtle to avoid making ahigher-quality job applicant overqualified for agiven job. We try to avoid this problem bymaking sure that the features listed above arenot all added at once to a given resume. Thisleaves us with a high-quality and a low-qualitypool of resumes.'^

To minimize similarity to actual job seekers,we use resumes from Boston job seekers toform templates for the resumes to be sent out inChicago and use resumes from Chicago jobseekers to form templates for the resumes to besent out in Boston. To implement this migra-tion, we alter the names of the schools andprevious employers on the resumes. More spe-cifically, for each Boston resume, we use theChicago resumes to replace a Boston schoolwith a Chicago school.'* We also use the Chi-cago resumes to replace a Boston employer witha Chicago employer in the same industry. Weuse a similar procedure to migrate Chicago re-sumes to Boston.'^ This produces distinct butrealistic looking resumes, similar in their edu-cation and career profiles to this subpopulationof job searchers.

B. Identities of Fictitious Applicants

The next step is to generate identities for thefictitious job applicants: names, telephone num-bers, postal addresses, and (possibly) e-mailaddresses. The choice of names is crucial to ourexperiment.'^ To decide on which names areuniquely African-American and which areuniquely White, we use name frequency datacalculated from birth certificates of all babiesbom in Massachusetts between 1974 and 1979.We tabulate these data by race to determine

'^ In Section III, subsection B, and Table 3, we providea detailed summary of resume characteristics by qualitylevel.

'* We try as much as possible to match high schools andcolleges on quality and demographic characteristics.

" Note that for applicants with schooling or work expe-rience outside of the Boston or Chicago areas, we leave theschool or employer name unchanged.

'* We also generate a set of different fonts, layouts, andcover letters to further differentiate the resumes. These areapplied at the time the resumes are sent out.

" We chose name over other potential manipulations ofrace, such as affiliation with a minority group, because wefelt such affiliations may especially convey more than race.

which names are distinctively White and whichare distinctively African-American. Distinctivenames are those that have the highest ratio offrequency in one racial group to frequency inthe other racial group.

As a check of distinctiveness, we conducted asurvey in various public areas in Chicago. Eachrespondent was asked to assess features of aperson with a particular name, one of which israce. For each name, 30 respondents were askedto identify the name as either "White," "African-American," "Other," or "Cannot Tell." In gen-eral, the names led respondents to readilyattribute the expected race for the person butthere were a few exceptions and these nameswere disregarded.'*

The final list of first names used for this studyis shown in Appendix Table Al. The tablereports the relative likelihood of the names forthe Whites and African-Americans in the Mas-sachusetts birth certificates data as well asthe recognition rate in the field survey.'^ AsAppendix Table Al indicates, the African-American first names used in the experiment arequite common in the population. This suggeststhat by using these names as an indicator ofrace, we are actually covering a rather largesegment of the African-American population.^"

Applicants in each race/sex/city/resume qual-ity cell are allocated the same phone number.This guarantees that we can precisely track em-ployer callbacks in each of these cells. Thephone lines we use are virtual ones with only avoice mailbox attached to them. A similar out-going message is recorded on each of the voicemailboxes but each message is recorded bysomeone of the appropriate race and gender.

'* For example, Maurice and Jerome are distinctivelyAfrican-American names in a frequency sense yet are notperceived as such by many people.

" So many of names show a likelihood ratio of ^ be-cause there is censoring of the data at five births. If there arefewer than five babies in any race/name cell, it is censored(and we do not know whether a cell has zero or wascensored). This is primarily a problem for the computationof how many African-American babies have "White"names.

°̂ We also tried to use more White-sounding last namesfor White applicants and more African-American-soundinglast names for African-American applicants. The last namesused for White applicants are: Baker, Kelly, McCarthy,Murphy, Murray, O'Brien, Ryan, Sullivan, and Walsh. Thelast names used for African-American applicants are: Jack-son, Jones, Robinson, Washington, and Williams.

Page 6: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

996 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2004

Since we allocate the same phone number forapplicants with different names, we cannot usea person name in the outgoing message.

While we do not expect positive feedbackfrom an employer to take place via postal mail,resumes still need postal addresses. We there-fore construct fictitious addresses based on realstreets in Boston and Chicago using the WhitePages. We select up to three addresses in each5-digit zip code in Boston and Chicago. Withincities, we randomly assign addresses across allresumes. We also create eight e-mail addresses,four for Chicago and four for Boston.^' Thesee-mail addresses are neutral with respect to bothrace and sex. Not all applicants are given ane-mail address. The e-mail addresses are usedalmost exclusively for the higher-quality re-sumes. This procedure leaves us with a bank ofnames, phone numbers, addresses, and e-mailaddresses that we can assign to the templateresumes when responding to the employmentads.

C. Responding to Ads

The experiment was carried out between July2001 and January 2002 in Boston and betweenJuly 2001 and May 2002 in Chicago.^^ Overthat period, we surveyed all employment ads inthe Sunday editions of The Boston Globe andThe Chicago Tribune in the sales, administra-tive support, and clerical and customer servicessections. We eliminate any ad where applicantswere asked to call or appear in person. In fact,most of the ads we surveyed in these job cate-gories ask for applicants to fax in or (morerarely) mail in their resume. We log the name(when available) and contact information foreach employer, along with any information onthe position advertised and specific require-ments (such as education, experience, or com-puter skills). We also record whether or not thead explicitly states that the employer is an equalopportunity employer.

For each ad, we use the bank of resumes to

^' The e-mail addresses are registered on Yahoo.com,Angelfire.com, or Hotmail.com.

^̂ This period spans tighter and slacker labor markets. Inour data, this is apparent as callback rates (and number ofnew ads) dropped after September 11, 2001. Interestingly,however, the racial gap we measure is the same across thesetwo periods.

sample four resumes (two high-quality and twolow-quality) that fit the job description and re-quirements as closely as possible.^^ In somecases, we slightly alter the resumes to improvethe quality of the match, such as by adding theknowledge of a specific software program.

One of the high- and one of the low-qualityresumes selected are then drawn at random toreceive African-American names, the otherhigh- and low-quality resumes receive Whitenames. '̂* We use male and female names forsales jobs, whereas we use nearly exclusivelyfemale names for administrative and clericaljobs to increase callback rates.^^ Based on sex,race, city, and resume quality, we assign a re-sume the appropriate phone number. We alsoselect at random a postal address. Finally, e-mail addresses are added to most of the high-quality resumes.^^ The final resumes areformatted, with fonts, layout, and cover letterstyle chosen at random. The resumes are thenfaxed (or in a few cases mailed) to the em-ployer. All in all, we respond to more than1,300 employment ads over the entire sampleperiod and send close to 5,000 resumes.

D. Measuring Responses

We measure whether a given resume elicits acallback or e-mail back for an interview. Foreach phone or e-mail response, we use the con-tent of the message left by the employer (nameof the applicant, company name, telephonenumber for contact) to match the response to thecorresponding resume-ad pair.^^ Any attemptby employers to contact applicants via postalmail cannot be measured in our experimentsince the addresses are fictitious. Several hu-man resource managers confirmed to us that

^̂ In some instances, our resume bank does not have fourresumes that are appropriate matches for a given ad. In suchinstances, we send only two resumes.

^ Though the same names are repeatedly used in ourexperiment, we guarantee that no given ad receives multipleresumes with the same name.

^' Male names were used for a few administrative jobs inthe first month of the experiment.

•̂"In the first month of the experiment, a few high-quality resumes were sent without e-mail addresses and afew low-quality resumes were given e-mail addresses. SeeTable 3 for details.

^' Very few employers used e-mail to contact an appli-cant back.

Page 7: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

VOL 94 NO. 4 BERTRAND AND MULLAINATHAN: RACE IN THE LABOR MARKET 997

TABLE 1—MEAN CALLBACK RATES BY RACIAL SOUNDINGNESS OF NAMES

Sample:All sent resumes

Chicago

Boston '

Females

Females in administrative jobs

Females in sales jobs

Males

Percent callbackfor White names

9.65[2,435]8.06[1,352]11.63[1,083]9.89[1,860]10.46[1,358]8.37[502]8.87[575]

Percent callback forAfrican-American names

6.45[2,435]5.40[1,352]7.76[1,083]6.63[1,886]6.55[1,359]6.83[527]5.83[549]

Ratio

1.50

1.49

1.50

1.49

1.60

1.22

1.52

Percent difference(p-value)

3.20(0.0000)2.66(0.0057)4.05(0.0023)3.26(0.0003)3.91(0.0003)1.54(0.3523)3.04(0.0513)

Notes: The table reports, for the entire sample and different subsamples of sent resumes, the callback rates for applicants witha White-sounding name (column 1) an an African-American-sounding name (column 2), as well as the ratio (column 3) anddifference (column 4) of these callback rates. In brackets in each cell is the number of resumes sent in that cell. Column 4also reports the p-value for a test of proportion testing the null hypothesis that the callback rates are equal across racial groups.

employers rarely, if ever, contact applicants viapostal mail to set up interviews.

E. Weaknesses of the Experiment

We have already highlighted the strengths ofthis experiment relative to previous audit stud-ies. We now discuss its weaknesses. First, ouroutcome measure is crude, even relative to theprevious audit studies. Ultimately, one caresabout whether an applicant gets the job andabout the wage offered conditional on gettingthe job. Our procedure, however, simply mea-sures callbacks for interviews. To the extent thatthe search process has even moderate frictions,one would expect that reduced interview rateswould translate into reduced job offers. How-ever, we are not able to translate our results intogaps in hiring rates or gaps in earnings.

Another weakness is that the resumes do notdirectly report race but instead suggest racethrough personal names. This leads to varioussources of concern. First, while the names arechosen to make race salient, some employersmay simply not notice the names or not recog-nize their racial content. On a related note,because we are not assigning race but onlyrace-specific names, our results are not repre-sentative of the average African-American(who may not have such a racially distinct

^ We return to this issue in Section IV,subsection B.

Finally, and this is an issue pervasive in bothour study and the pair-matching audit studies,newspaper ads represent only one channel forjob search. As is well known from previouswork, social networks are another commonmeans through which people find jobs and onethat clearly cannot be studied here. This omis-sion could qualitatively affect our results ifAfrican-Americans use social networks more orif employers who rely more on networks differ-entiate less by race.29

III. Results

A. Is There a Racial Gap in Callback?

Table 1 tabulates average callback rates byracial soundingness of names. Included inbrackets under each rate is the number of re-sumes sent in that cell. Row 1 presents ourresults for the full data set. Resumes with White

''̂ As Appendix Table Al indicates, the African-American names we use are, however, quite commonamong African-Americans, making this less of a concern.

*̂ In fact, there is some evidence that African-Americansmay rely less on social networks for their job search (HarryJ. Holzer, 1987).

Page 8: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

998 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2004

names have a 9.65 percent chance of receivinga callback. Equivalent resumes with African-American names have a 6.45 percent chance ofbeing called back. This represents a differencein callback rates of 3.20 percentage points, or 50percent, that can solely be attributed to the namemanipulation. Column 4 shows that this differ-ence is statistically significant.^" Put in otherwords, these results imply that a White appli-cant should expect on average one callback forevery 10 ads she or he applies to; on the otherhand, an African-American applicant wouldneed to apply to about 15 different ads toachieve the same result.^'

How large are these effects? While the cost ofsending additional resumes might not be largeper se, this 50-percent gap could be quite sub-stantial when compared to the rate of arrival ofnew job openings. In our own study, the biggestconstraining factor in sending more resumeswas the limited number of new job openingseach week. Another way to benchmark the mea-sured return to a White name is to compare it tothe returns to other resume characteristics. Forexample, in Table 5, we will show that, at theaverage number of years of experience in oursample, an extra year of experience increasesthe likelihood of a callback by a 0.4 percentagepoint. Based on this point estimate, the return toa White name is equivalent to about eight ad-ditional years of experience.

Rows 2 and 3 break down the full sample ofsent resumes into the Boston and Chicago mar-kets. About 20 percent more resumes were sentin Chicago than in Boston. The average call-back rate (across races) is lower in Chicago thanin Boston. This might reflect differences in la-bor market conditions across the two cities overthe experimental period or maybe differences inthe ability of the MIT and Chicago teams ofresearch assistants in selecting resumes thatwere good matches for a given help-wanted ad.The percentage difference in callback rates is,however, strikingly similar across both cities.White applicants are 49 percent more likely

'"These statistical tests assume independence of caii-backs. We have, however, verified that the results staysignificant when we assume that the callbacks are correlatedeither at the employer or first-name level.

•" This obviously assumes that African-American appli-cants cannot assess a priori which firms are more likely totreat them more or less favorably.

than African-American applicants to receive acallback in Chicago and 50 percent more likelyin Boston. These racial differences are statisti-cally significant in both cities.

Finally, rows 4 to 7 break down the fullsample into female and male applicants. Row 4displays the average results for all female nameswhile rows 5 and 6 break the female sample intoadministrative (row 5) and sales joT̂ s (row 6);row 7 displays the average results for all malenames. As noted earlier, female names wereused in both sales and administrative job open-ings whereas male names were used close toexclusively for sales openings.^^ Lookingacross occupations, we find a significant racialgap in callbacks for both males (52 percent) andfemales (49 percent). Comparing males to fe-males in sales occupations, we find a largerracial gap among males (52 percent versus 22percent). Interestingly, females in sales jobs ap-pear to receive more callbacks than males; how-ever, this (reverse) gender gap is statisticallyinsignificant and economically much smallerthan any of the racial gaps discussed above.

Rather than studying the distribution of call-backs at the apphcant level, one can also tabu-late the distribution of callbacks at theemployment-ad level. In Table 2, we computethe fraction of employers that treat White andAfrican-American applicants equally, the frac-tion of employers that favor White appli-cants and the fraction of employers that favorAfrican-American applicants. Because we sendup to four resumes in response to each sampledad, the three categories above can each takethree different forms. Equal treatment occurswhen either no applicant gets called back, oneWhite and one African-American get calledback or two Whites and two African-Americansget called back. Whites are favored when eitheronly one White gets called back, two Whitesand no African-American get called back or twoWhites and one African-American get calledback. African-Americans are favored in allother cases.

As Table 2 indicates, equal treatment occursfor about 88 percent of the help-wanted ads. Asexpected, the major source of equal treatmentcomes from the high fraction of ads for which

'^ Only about 6 percent of all male resumes were sent inresponse to an administrative job opening.

Page 9: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

VOL 94 NO. 4 BERTRAND AND MULLAINATHAN: RACE IN

Equal Treatment:88.13 percent[1,166]Whites Favored (WF):8.39 percent[111]African-Americans Favored3.48 percent[46]Ho: WF = BFp = 0.0000

TABLE 2—DISTRIBUTION OF CALLBACKS BY

No Callback83.37

[1,103]lW + OB

5.59[74]

(BF): IB + OW2.49[33]

THE LABOR MARKET

EMPLOYMENT AD

lW + IB3.48[46]

2W + OB1.44[19]

2B + OW0.45[6]

999

2W + 2B1.28[17]

2W + IB1.36[18]

2B + lW0.53[7]

Notes: This table documents the distribution of callbacks at the employment-ad level. "No Callback" is the percent of ads forwhich none of the fictitious applicants received a callback. "1W + IB" is the percent of ads for which exactly one White andone African-American applicant received a callback. "2W + 2B" is the percent of ads for which exactly two White applicantsand two African-American applicants received a callback. "Equal Treatment" is defined as the sum of "No Callback," "lW -I-lB," and "2W + 2B." "lW + OB" is the percent of ads for which exactly one White applicant and no African-Americanapplicant received a call back. "2W + OB" is the percent of ads for which excatly two White applicants and noAfrican-American applicant received a callback. "2W + IB" is the percent of ads for which exactly two White applicants andone African-American applicant received a callback. "Whites Favored" is defined as the sum of "lW + OB," "2W + OB,"and "2W + IB." "IB + OW" is the percent of ads for which exactly one African-American applicant and no White applicantreceived a callback. "2B + OW" is the percent of ads for which exactly two African-American applicants and no Whiteapplicant received a callback. "2B + lW" is the percent of ads for which exactly two African-American applicants and oneWhite applicant received a callback. "African-Americans Favored" is defined as the sum of "IB -f- OW," "2B + OW," and"2B + iw." In brackets in each cell is the number of employment ads in that cell. "Ho: WF = WB" reports the p-value fora test of symmetry between the proportion of employers that favor White names and the proportion of employers that favorAfrican-American names.

no callbacks are recorded (83 percent of theads). Whites are favored by nearly 8.4 percentof the employers, with a majority of these em-ployers contacting exactly one White applicant.African-Americans, on the other hand, are fa-vored by only about 3.5 percent of employers.We formally test whether there is symmetry inthe favoring of Whites over African-Americansand African-Americans over Whites. We findthat the difference between the fraction of em-ployers favoring Whites and the fraction ofemployers favoring African-Americans is sta-tistically very significant {p = 0.0000).

B. Do African-Americans Receive DifferentReturns to Resume Quality?

Our results so far demonstrate a substantialgap in callback based on applicants' names.Next, we would like to leam more about thefactors that may infiuence this gap. More spe-cifically, we ask how employers respond to im-provements in African-American applicants'credentials. To answer this question, we exam-ine how the racial gap in callback varies byresume quality.

As we explained in Section II, for most of the

employment ads we respond to, we send fourdifferent resumes: two higher-quality and twolower-quality ones. Table 3 gives a better senseof which factors enter into this subjective clas-sification. Table 3 displays means and standarddeviations of the most relevant resume charac-teristics for the full sample (column 1), as wellas broken down by race (columns 2 and 3) andresume quality (columns 4 and 5). Since appli-cants' names are randomized, there is no differ-ence in resume characteristics by race. Columns4 and 5 document the objective differences be-tween resumes subjectively classified as highand low quality. Higher-quality applicants haveon average close to an extra year of labor mar-ket experience, fewer employment holes (wherean employment hole is defined as a period of atleast six months without a reported job), aremore likely to have worked while at school,and to report some military experience. Also,higher-quality applicants are more likely tohave an e-mail address, to have received somehonors, and to list some computer skills andother special skills (such as a certificationdegree or foreign language skills) on their re-sume. Note that the higher- and lower-qualityresumes do not differ on average with regard to

Page 10: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

1000

TABLE

Sample:

Characteristic:College degree( Y = 1)Years of experience

Volunteering experience?( Y = 1)Military experience?( Y = 1)E-mail address?( Y = 1)Employment holes?( Y = 1)Work in school?( Y = 1)Honors?( Y = 1)Computer skills?( Y = 1)Special skills?( Y = 1)Fraction high school dropouts in

applicant's zip codeFraction college or more in

applicant's zip codeFraction Whites in applicant's zip

codeFraction African-Americans in

applicant's zip codeLog(median per capital income)

in applicant's zip code

Sample size

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

3—RESUME CHARACTERISTICS:

All resumes

0.72(0.45)7.84

(5.04)0.41

(0.49)0.10

(0.30)0.48

(0.50)0.45

(0.50)0.56

(0.50)0.05

(0.22)0.82

(0.38)0.33

(0.47)0.19

(0.08)0.21

(0.17)0.54

(0.33)0.31

(0.33)9.55

(0.56)

4,870

White names

0.72(0.45)7.86

(5.07)0.41

(0.49)0.09

(0.29)0.48

(0.50)0.45

(0.50)0.56

(0.50)0.05

(0.23)0.81

(0.39)0.33

(0.47)0.19

(0.08)0.21

(0.17)0.55

(0.33)0.31

(0.33)9.55

(0.56)

2,435

SUMMARY STATISTICS

African-

SEPTEMBER 2004

American Higher quality Lower quality

0.72(0.45)7.83

(5.01)0.41

(0.49)0.10

(0.30)0.48

(0.50)0.45

(0.50)0.56

(0.50)0.05

(0.22)0.83

(0.37)0.33

(0.47)0.19

(0.08)0.21

(0.17)0.54

(0.33)0.31

(0.33)9.55

(0.55)

2,435

0.72(0.45)8.29

(5.29)0.79

(0.41)0.19

(0.39)0.92

(0.27)0.34

(0.47)0.72

(0.45)0.07

(0.25)0.91

(0.29)0.36

(0.48)0.19

(0.08)0.21

(0.17)0.53

(0.33)0.32

(0.33)9.54

(0.54)

2,446

0.71(0.45)7.39

(4.75)0.03

(0.16)0.00

(0.06)0.03

(0.17)0.56

(0.50)0.40

(0.49)0.03

(0.18)0.73

(0.44)0.30

(0.46)0.18

(0.08)0.22

(0.17)0.55

(0.33)0.31

(0.33)9.56

(0.57)

2,424

Notes: The table reports means and standard deviations for the resume characteristics as listed on the left. Column 1 refersto all resumes sent; column 2 refers to resumes with White names; column 3 refers to resumes with African-American names;column 4 refers to higher-quality resumes; column 5 refers to lower-quality resumes. See text for details.

applicants' education level. This reflects the factthat all sent resumes, whether high or low qual-ity, are chosen to be good matches for a givenjob opening. About 70 percent of the sent re-sumes report a college degree.''^

The last flve rows of Table 3 show summarycharacteristics of the applicants' zip code ad-dress. Using 1990 Census data, we compute thefraction of high school dropouts, fraction ofcollege educated or more, fraction of Whites,fraction of African-Americans and log(medianper capital income) for each zip code used in the

•̂' This varies from about 50 percent for the clerical andadministrative support positions to more than 80 percentfor the executive, managerial, and sales representativespositions.

experiment. Since addresses are randomizedwithin cities, these neighborhood quality mea-sures are uncorrelated with race or resumequality.

The differences in callback rates betweenhigh- and low-quality resumes are presented inPanel A of Table 4. The first thing to note is thatthe resume quality manipulation works: higher-quality resumes receive more callbacks. As rowI indicates, we record a callback rate of close toI1 percent for White applicants with a higher-quality resume, compared to 8.5 percent forWhite applicants with lower-quality resumes.This is a statistically significant difference of2.29 percentage points, or 27 percent {p =0.0557). Most strikingly, African-Americansexperience much less of an increase in callback

Page 11: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

VOL. 94 NO. 4 BERTRAND AND MULLAINATHAN: RACE IN THE LABOR MARKET 1001

TABLE 4—AVERAGE CALLBACK RATES BY RACIAL SOUNDINGNESS OF NAMES AND RESUME QUALITY

White names

African-American names

White names

African-American names

Panel A:

Low8.50

[1,212]6.19

[1,212]

Panel B:

Low7.18[822]5.37[819]

Subjective Measure of Quality(Percent Callback)

High10.79

[1,223]6.70

[1,223]

Predicted Measure of Quality(Percent Callback)

High13.60[816]8.60[814]

Ratio1.27

1.08

Ratio1.89

1.60

Difference (p-value)2.29

(0.0557)0.51

(0.6084)

Difference (p- value)6.42

(0.0000)3.23

(0.0104)

Notes: Panel A reports the mean callback percents for applicant vidth a White name (row 1) and African-American name (row 2)depending on whether the resume was subjectively qualified as a lower quality or higher quality. In brackets is the number ofresumes sent for each race/quality group. The last column reports the p-value of a test of proportion testing the null hypothesis thatthe callback rates are equal across quality groups within each racial group. For Panel B, we use a third of the sample to estimatea probit regression of the callback dummy on the set of resume characteristics as displayed in Table 3. We further control for a sexdummy, a city dummy, six occupation dummies, and a vector of dummy variables for job requirements as listed in the employmentad (see Section in, subsection D, for details). We then use the estimated coefficients on the set of resume characteristics to estimatea predicted callback for the remaining resumes (two-thirds of the sample). We call "high-quality" resumes the resumes that rankabove the median predicted callback and "low-quality" resumes the resumes that rank below the median predicted callback. Inbrackets is the number of resumes sent for each race/quaUty group. The last column reports the ;>-value of a test of proportion testingthe null hypothesis that the callback percents are equal across quality groups within each racial group.

rate for similar improvements in their creden-tials. African-Americans with higher-quality re-sumes receive a callback 6.7 percent of the time,compared to 6.2 percent for African-Americanswith lower quality resumes. This is only a 0.51-percentage-point, or 8-percent, difference andthis difference is not statistically significant{p = 0.6084).

Instead of relying on the subjective qualityclassification. Panel B directly uses resumecharacteristics to classify the resumes. Morespecifically, we use a random subsample ofone-third of the resumes to estimate a probitregression of the callback dummy on the resumecharacteristics listed in Table 3. We further con-trol for a sex dummy, a city dummy, six occu-pation dummies, and a vector of jobrequirements as listed in the employment ads.̂ '*We then use the estimated coefficients on theresume characteristics to rank the remainingtwo-thirds of the resumes by predicted callback.In Panel B, we classify as "high" those resumesthat have above-median-predicted callback;similarly, we classify as "low" those resumes

•'" See Section III, subsection D, for more details on theseoccupation categories and job requirements.

that have below-median-predicted callback. Asone can see from Panel B, qualitatively similarresults emerge from this analysis. While African-Americans do appear to significantly benefitfrom higher-quality resumes under this alterna-tive classification, they benefit less than Whites.The ratio of callback rates for high- versuslow-quality resumes is 1.60 for African Amer-icans, compared to 1.89 for Whites.

In Table 5, we directly report the results ofrace-specific probit regressions of the callbackdummy on resume characteristics. We, how-ever, start in column 1 with results for the fullsample of sent resumes. As one can see, manyof the resume characteristics have the expectedeffect on the likelihood of a callback. The ad-dition of an e-mail address, honors, and specialskills all have a positive and significant effecton the likelihood of a callback.^^ Also, moreexperienced applicants are more likely to getcalled back: at the average number of years ofexperience in our sample (eight years), each

^' Note that the e-mail address dummy, because it isclose to perfectly correlated with the subjective resume-quality variable, may in part capture some other unmeasuredresume characteristics that may have led us to categorize agiven resume as higher quality.

Page 12: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

1002 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2004

TABLE 5—EFFECT OF RESUME CHARACTERISTICS ON LIKELIHOOD OF CALLBACK

Dependent Variable: Callback DummySample: All resumes White names African-American names

Years of experience (*10)

Years of experience^ (*100)

Volunteering? (Y = I)

Military experience? (Y = 1)

E-mail? (Y = 1)

Employment holes? (Y = 1)

Work in school? (Y = 1)

Honors? (Y = 1)

Computer skills? (Y = 1)

Special skills? (Y = 1)

Ho: Resume characteristics effects are allzero (p-value)

Standard deviation of predicted callback

Sample size

0.07(0.03)-0.02(0.01)-0.01(0.01)-0.00(0.01)0.02

(0.01)0.02

(0.01)0.01

(0.01)0.05

(0.02)-0.02(0.01)0.05

(0.01)

54.50(0.0000)

0.047

4,870

0.13(0.04)-0.04(0.01)-0.01(0.01)0.02

(0.03)0.03

(0.01)0.03

(0.02)0.02

(0.01)0.06

(0.03)-0.04(0.02)0.06

(0.02)

57.59(0.0000)

0.062

2,435

0.02(0.03)-0.00(0.01)0.01

(0.01)-0.01(0.02)-0.00(0.01)0.01

(0.01)-0.00(0.01)0.03

(0.02)-0.00(0.01)0.04

(0.01)

23.85(0.0080)

0.037

2,435

Notes: Each column gives the results of a probit regression where the dependent variable is the callback dummy. Reportedin the table are estimated marginal changes in probability for the continuous variables and estimated discrete changes for thedummy variables. Also included in each regression are a city dummy, a sex dummy, six occupation dummies, and a vectorof dummy variables for job requirements as listed in the employment ad (see Section III, subsection D, for details). Samplein column 1 is the entire set of sent resumes; sample in column 2 is the set of resumes with White names; sample in column3 is the set of resumes with African-American names. Standard errors are corrected for clustering of the observations at theemployment-ad level. Reported in the second to last row are the p-values for a ) ^ testing that the effects on the resumecharacteristics are all zero. Reported in the second to last row is the standard deviation of the predicted callback rate.

extra year of experience increases the likelihoodof a callback by about a 0.4 percentage point.The most counterintuitive effects come fromcomputer skills, which appear to negatively pre-dict callback, and employment holes, which ap-pear to positively predict callback.

The same qualitative patterns hold in column2 where we focus on White applicants. Moreimportantly, the estimated returns to an e-mailaddress, additional work experience, honors,and special skills appear economically strongerfor that racial group. For example, at the aver-age number of years of experience in our sam-ple, each extra year of experience increases thelikelihood of a callback by about a 0.7 percent-age point.

As might have been expected from the two

previous columns, we find that the estimatedreturns on these resume characteristics are alleconomically and statistically weaker forAfrican-American applicants (column 3). Infact, all the estimated effects for African-Americans are statistically insignificant, exceptfor the return to special skills. Resume charac-teristics thus appear less predictive of callbackrates for African-Americans than they are forWhites. To illustrate this more saliently, wepredict callback rates using either regressionestimates in column 2 or regression estimates incolumn 3. The standard deviation of the pre-dicted callback from column 2 is 0.062, whereasit is only 0.037 from column 3. In summary,employers simply seem to pay less attention ordiscount more the characteristics listed on the

Page 13: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

VOL 94 NO. 4 BERTRAND AND MVLLAINATHAN: RACE IN THE LABOR MARKET 1003

TABLE 6—EFFECT OF APPLICANT'S ADDRESS ON LIKELIHOOD OF CALLBACK

Dependent Variable: Callback

Zip code characteristic;

Zip code characteristic

Zip code characteristic*African-American name

African-American name

Dummy

Fraction

0.020(0.012)

Whites

0.020(0.016)-0.000(0.024)-0.031(0.015)

Fraction college ormore

0.054 0.053(0.022) (0.031)

— -0.002(0.048)

— -0.031(0.013)

Log(per capital

0.018(0.007)

income)

0.014(0.010)0.008

(0.015)-0.112(0.152)

Notes: Each column gives the results of a probit regression where the dependent variable is the callback dummy. Reportedin the table is the estimated marginal change in probability. Also included in columns 1, 3, and 5 is a city dummy; alsoincluded in columns 2,4, and 6 is a city dummy and a city dummy interacted with a race dummy. Standard errors are correctedfor clustering of the observations at the employment-ad level.

resumes with Afiican-American-sounding names.Taken at face value, these results suggest thatAfrican-Americans may face relatively lowerindividual incentives to invest in higher skills.^^

C. Applicants' Address

An incidental feature of our experimental de-sign is the random assignment of addresses tothe resumes. This allows us to examine whetherand how an applicant's residential address, allelse equal, affects the likelihood of a callback.In addition, and most importantly for our pur-pose, we can also ask whether African-Ameri-can applicants are helped relatively more byresiding in more affluent neighborhoods.

We perform this analysis in Table 6. We start(columns 1, 3, and 5) by discussing the effect ofneighborhood of residence across all applicants.Each of these columns reports the results of aprobit regression of the callback dummy on aspecific zip code characteristic and a citydummy. Standard errors are corrected for clus-tering of the observations at the employment-adlevel. We find a positive and significant effectof neighborhood quality on the likelihood of acallback. Applicants living in Whiter (column1), more educated (column 3), or higher-income(column 5) neighborhoods have a higher prob-ability of receiving a callback. For example, a10-percentage-point increase in the fraction ofcollege-educated in zip code of residence in-

'* This of course assumes that the changes in job andwage offers associated with higher skills are the same acrossraces, or at least not systematically larger for African-Americans.

creases the likelihood of a callback by a 0.54percentage point (column 3).

In columns 2,4, and 6, we further interact thezip code characteristic with a dummy variablefor whether the applicant is African-Americanor not. Each of the probit regressions in thesecolumns also includes an African-Americandummy, a city dummy, and an interaction of thecity dummy with the African-Americandummy. There is no evidence that African-Americans benefit any more than Whites fromliving in a Whiter, more educated zip code. Theestimated interactions between fraction Whiteand fraction college educated with the African-American dummy are economically very smalland statistically insignificant. We do find aneconomically more meaningful effect of zipcode median income level on the racial gap incallback; this effect, however, is statisticallyinsignificant.

In summary, while neighborhood quality af-fects callbacks, African-Americans do not ben-efit more than Whites from living in betterneighborhoods. If ghettos and bad neighbor-hoods are particularly stigmatizing for African-Americans, one might have expected African-Americans to be helped more by having a"better" address. Our results do not support thishypothesis.

D. Job and Employer Characteristics

Table 7 studies how various job requirements(as listed in the employment ads) and employercharacteristics correlate with the racial gap incallback. Each row of Table 7 focuses on aspecific job or employer characteristic, with

Page 14: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

1004 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2004

TABLE 7—EFFECT OF JOB REQUIREMENT AND EMPLOYER CHARACTERISTICS ON RACIAL DIFFERENCES IN CALLBACKS

Job requirement:

Any requirement? (Y = 1)

Experience? (Y = 1)

Computer skills? (Y = 1)

Communication skills? (Y = 1)

Organization skills? (Y = 1)

Education? (Y = 1)

Total number of requirements

Employer characteristic:

Equal opportunity employer? (Y = 1)

Federal contractor? (Y = 1)(N = 3,102)Log(employment)(N = 1,690)Ownership status:(N = 2,878)Privately held

Publicly traded

Not-for-profit

Fraction African-Americans in employer's zip code(N = 1,918)

Sample mean(standard deviation)

0.79(0.41)0.44

(0.49), 0.44

(0.50)0.12

(0.33)0.07

(0.26)0.11

(0.31)1.18

(0.93)

Sample mean(standard deviation)

0.29(0.45)0.11

(0.32)5.74

(1.74)

0.74

0.15

0.11

0.08(0.15)

Marginal effect on callbacksfor African-American names

0.023(0.015)0.011

(0.013)0.000

(0.013)-0.000(0.015)0.028

(0.029)-0.031(0.017)0.002

(0.006)

Marginal effect on callbacksfor African-American names

-0.013(0.012)-0.035(0.016)-0.001(0.005)

0.011(0.019)-0.025(0.015)0.025

(0.042)0.117

(0.062)

Notes: Sample is all sent resumes (N = 4,870) unless otherwise specified in column 1. Column 2 reports means and standarddeviations (in parentheses) for the job requirement or employer characteristic. For ads listing an experience requirement, 50.1percent listed "some," 24.0 percent listed "two years or less," and 25.9 percent listed "three years or more." For ads listingan education requirement, 8.8 percent listed a high school degree, 48.5 percent listed some college, and 42.7 percent listedat least a four-year college degree. Column 3 reports the marginal effect of the job requirement or employer characteristiclisted in that row on differential treatment. Specifically, each cell in column 3 corresponds to a different probit regression ofthe callback dummy on an African-American name dummy, a dummy for the requirement or characteristic listed in that rowand the interaction of the requirement or characteristic dummy with the African-American name dummy. Reported in eachcell is the estimated change in probability for the interaction term. Standard errors are corrected for clustering of theobservations at the employment-ad level.

summary statistics in column 2. Column 3shows the results of various probit regressions.Each entry in this column is the marginal effectof the specific characteristic listed in that row onthe racial gap in callback. More specifically,each entry is from a separate probit regressionof a callback dummy on an African-Americandummy, the characteristic listed in that row andthe interaction of that characteristic with the

African-American dummy. The reported coef-ficient is that on the interaction term.

We start with job requirements. About 80percent of the ads state some form of require-ment. About 44 percent of the ads require someminimum experience, of which roughly 50 per-cent simply ask for "some experience," 24 per-cent less than two years, and 26 percent at leastthree years of experience. About 44 percent of

Page 15: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

VOL. 94 NO. 4 BERTRAND AND MULLAINATHAN: RACE IN THE LABOR MARKET 1005

ads mention some computer knowledge require-ment, which can range from Excel or Word tomore esoteric software programs. Good com-munication skills are explicitly required inabout 12 percent of the ads. Organization skillsare mentioned 7 percent of the time. Finally,only about 11 percent of the ads list an expliciteducation requirement. Of these, 8.8 percentrequire a high school degree, 48.5 percent somecollege (such as an associate degree), and therest at least a four-year college degree.^^

Despite this variability, we find little system-atic relationship between any of the require-ments and the racial gap in callback. The pointestimates in column 3 show no consistent eco-nomic pattern and are all statistically weak.Measures of job quality, such as experience orcomputer skills requirements, do not predict theextent of the racial gap. Communication orother interpersonal skill requirements have noeffect on the racial gap either.^^

We also study employer characteristics. Col-lecting such information is a more difficult tasksince it is not readily available from the em-ployment ads we respond to. The only piece ofemployer information we can directly collectfrom the employment ad is whether or not theemployer expUcitly states being an "Equal Op-portunity Employer." In several cases, the nameof the employer is not even mentioned in the adand the only piece of information we can rely onis the fax number which apphcations must besubmitted to. We therefore have to turn to sup-plemental data sources. For employment adsthat do not list a specific employer, we first usethe fax number to try to identify the companyname via Web reverse-lookup services. Basedon company names, we use three different datasources {Onesource Business Browser, ThomasRegister, and Dun and Bradstreet Million Dol-lar Directory, 2001) to track company informa-tion such as total employment, industry, andownership status. Using this same set of data

^' Other requirements sometimes mentioned include typ-ing skills for secretaries (with specific words-per-minuteminimum thresholds), and, more rarely, foreign languageskills.

•'* Other ways of estimating these effects produce a sim-ilar nonresult. Among other things, we considered includinga city dummy or estimating the effects separately by city;we also estimated one single probit regression including allrequirements at once.

sources, we also try to identify the specific zipcode of the company (or company branch) thatresumes are to be sent to. Finally, we use theFederal Procurement and Data Center Web siteto find a list of companies that have federalcontracts.^^ The racial difference in callbackrates for the subsamples where employer char-acteristics could be determined is very similar inmagnitude to that in the full sample.

Employer characteristics differ significantlyacross ads. Twenty-nine percent of all employ-ers explicitly state that they are "Equal Oppor-tunity Employers." Eleven percent are federalcontractors and, therefore, might face greaterscrutiny under affirmative action laws. The av-erage company size is around 2,000 employeesbut there is a lot of variation across firms. Fi-nally, 74 percent of the firms are privately held,15 percent are publicly traded, and 11 percentare not-for-profit organizations.

Neither "Equal Opportunity Employers" norfederal contractors appear to treat African-Americans more favorably. In fact, each ofthese employer characteristics is associatedwith a larger racial gap in callback (and thiseffect is marginally significant for federal con-tractors). Differential treatment does not varywith employer size.'*" Point estimates indicateless differential treatment in the not-for-profitsector; however, this effect is very noisilyestimated.**'

In an unpublished Appendix (available fromthe authors upon request), we also study howthe racial gap in callback varies by occupationand industry. Based on the employment ad list-ings, we classify the job openings into six oc-cupation categories: executives and managers;administrative supervisors; sales representa-tives; sales workers; secretaries and legal assis-tants; clerical workers. We also, when possible.

*̂ This Web site (www.fpdc.gov) is accurate up to andincluding March 21, 2000.

'"' Similar results hold when we measure employer sizeusing a total sales measure rather than an employmentmeasure.

•*' Our measurement of the racial gap by firm or em-ployer type may not be a good indicator of the fraction ofAfrican-Americans actually employed in these firms. Forexample, "Equal Opportunity Employers" may receive ahigher fraction of African-American resumes. Their actualhiring may therefore look different from that of non "EqualOpportunity Employers" when one considers the full set ofresumes they receive.

Page 16: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

1006 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2004

classify employers into six industry categories:manufacturing; transportation and communica-tion; wholesale and retail trade; finance, insur-ance, and real estate; business and personalservices; health, educational, and social services.We then compute occupation and industry-specific racial gaps in callback and relate thesegaps to 1990 Census-based measures of oc-cupation and industry earnings, as well as Census-based measures of the White/African-Americanwage gap in these occupations and industries.

We find a positive White/African-Americangap in callbacks in all occupation and industrycategories (except for transportation and com-munication). While average eamings vary a lotacross the occupations covered in the experi-ment, we find no systematic relationship be-tween occupation eamings and the racial gap incallback. Similarly, the industry-specific gaps incallback do not relate well to a measure ofinter-industry wage differentials. In fact, whilethe racial gap in callback rates varies somewhatacross occupations and industries, we cannotreject the null hypothesis that the gap is thesame across all these categories.

The last row of Table 7 focuses on the mar-ginal effect of employer location on the racialgap in callback. We use as a measure ofemployer location the zip code of the company(or company branch) resumes were to be sentto. More specifically, we ask whether differen-tial treatment by race varies with the fraction ofAfrican-Americans in the employer's zip code.We find a marginally significant positive effectof employer location on African-American call-backs but this effect is extremely small. In re-gressions not reported here (but available fromthe authors upon request), we reestimate thiseffect separately by city. While the point esti-mates are positive for both cities, the effect isonly statistically significant for Chicago.

IV. Interpretation

Three main sets of questions arise when in-terpreting the results above. First, does a highercallback rate for White applicants imply thatemployers are discriminating against African-

Americans? Second, does our design only iso-late the effect of race or is the namemanipulation conveying some other factors thanrace? Third, how do our results relate to differ-ent models of racial discrimination?

A. Interpreting Callback Rates

Our results indicate that for two identicalindividuals engaging in an identical job search,the one with an African-American name wouldreceive fewer interviews. Does differentialtreatment within our experiment imply that em-ployers are discriminating against African-Americans (whether it is rational, prejudice-based, or other form of discrimination)? In otherwords, could the lower callback rate we recordfor African-American resumes within our ex-periment be consistent with a racially neutralreview of the entire pool of resumes the sur-veyed employers receive?

In a racially neutral review process, employ-ers would rank order resumes based on theirquality and call back all applicants that areabove a certain threshold. Because names arerandomized, the White and African-Americanresumes we send should rank similarly on av-erage. So, irrespective of the skill and racialcomposition of the applicant pool, a race-blindselection rule would generate equal treatment ofWhites and African-Americans. So our resultsmust imply that employers use race as a factorwhen reviewing resumes, which matches thelegal definition of discrimination.

But even rules where employers are not try-ing to interview as few African-American ap-plicants as possible may generate observeddifferential treatment in our experiment. Onesuch hiring rule would be employers trying tointerview a target level of African-Americancandidates. For example, perhaps the averagefirm in our experiment aims to produce an in-terview pool that matches the population baserate. This rule could produce the observed dif-ferential treatment if the average firm receives ahigher proportion of African-American resumesthan the population base rate because African-Americans disproportionately apply to the jobsand industries in our sample.''^

^^ For previous work on the effect of employer locationon labor market discrimination, see, for example, StevenRaphael et al. (2000).

''"' Another variant of this argument is that the (up to) twoAfrican-American resumes we sent are enough to signifi-

Page 17: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

VOL. 94 NO. 4 BERTRAND AND MULLAINATHAN: RACE IN THE LABOR MARKET 1007

Some of our other findings may be consistentwith such a rule. For example, the fact that"Equal Opportunity Employers" or federal con-tractors do not appear to discriminate any lessmay reflect the fact that such employers receivemore applications from African-Americans. Onthe other hand, other key findings run counter tothis rule. As we discuss above, we find nosystematic difference in the racial gap in call-back across occupational or industry categories,despite the large variation in the fraction ofAfrican-Americans looking for work in thosecategories. African-Americans are underrepre-sented in managerial occupations, for example.If employers matched base rates in the popula-tion, the few African-Americans who apply tothese jobs should receive a higher callback ratethan Whites. Yet, we find that the racial gap inmanagerial occupations is the same as in all theother job categories. This rule also runs counterto our findings on returns to skill. Suppose firmsare struggling to find White applicants but over-whelmed with African-American ones. Thenthey should be less sensitive to the quality ofWhite applicants (as they are trying to fill intheir hiring quota for Whites) and much moresensitive to the quality of Black applicants(when they have so many to pick from). Thus, it

cantly distort the racial composition of the entire applicantpool. This is unlikely for two reasons. First, anecdotalevidence and the empirically low callback rates we recordsuggest that firms typically receive many hundreds of re-sumes in response to each ad they post. Hence, the (up to)four resumes we send out are unlikely to influence the racialcomposition of the pool. Second, the similar racial gap incallback we observe across the two cities goes counter tothis interpretation since the racial composition base ratesdiffer quite a lot across these two cities. Another variant ofthis argument is that, for some reason, the average firm inour sample receives a lot of high-quality resumes fromAfrican-American applicants and much fewer high-qualityresumes from White applicants. Hypothetically, this mightoccur if high-quality African-Americans are much morelikely to use help-wanted ads rather than other job searchchannels. If employers perform within-race comparisonsand again want to target a certain racial mix in their inter-viewing and hiring, our African-American resumes maynaturally receive lower callbacks as they are competing withmany more high-quality applicants. This specific argumentwould be especially relevant in a case where the averagesampled employer is "known" to be good to African-Americans. But our selection procedure for the employmentads did not allow for such screening: we simply respondedto as many ads as possible in the targeted occupationalcategories.

is unlikely that the differential treatment weobserve is generated by hiring rules such as these.

B. Potential Confounds

While the names we have used in this exper-iment strongly signal racial origin, they mayalso signal some other personal trait. More spe-cifically, one might be concerned that employ-ers are inferring social background from thepersonal name. When employers read a namelike "Tyrone" or "Latoya," they may assumethat the person comes from a disadvantagedbackground."*^ In the extreme form of this socialbackground interpretation, employers do notcare at all about race but are discriminating onlyagainst the social background conveyed by thenames we have chosen.'*^

While plausible, we feel that some of ourearlier results are hard to reconcile with thisinterpretation. For example, in Table 6, wefound that while employers value "better" ad-dresses, African-Americans are not helped morethan Whites by living in Whiter or more edu-cated neighborhoods. If the African-Americannames we have chosen mainly signal negativesocial background, one might have expected theestimated name gap to be lower for better ad-dresses. Also, if the names mainly signal socialbackground, one might have expected the namegap to be higher for jobs that rely more on softskills or require more interpersonal interactions.We found no such evidence in Table 7.

We, however, directly address this alternativeinterpretation by examining the average socialbackground of babies bom with the names usedin the experiment. We were able to obtain birthcertificate data on mother's education (less thanhigh school, high school or more) for babiesbom in Massachusetts between 1970 and

** Roland Fryer and Steven Levitt (2003) provide a re-cent analysis of social background and naming conventionsamongst African-Americans.

"' African-Americans as a whole come from more dis-advantaged backgrounds than Whites. For this social classeffect to be something of independent interest, one mustassert that African-Americans with the African-Americannames we have selected are from a lower social backgroundthan the average African-American and/or that Whites withthe White names we have selected are from a higher socialbackground than the average White. We come baek to thispoint below.

Page 18: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

1008

Name

EmilyAnneJillAllisonLaurieSarahMeredithCarrieKristen

AverageOverall

Correlation

Name

ToddNeilGeoffreyBrettBrendanGregMatthewJayBrad

AverageOverall

Correlation

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

TABLE 8—CALLBACK RATE AND MOTHER'S EDUCATION

White female

Percent callback

7.98.38.49.59.79.810.213.113.1

-0.318

White male

Percent callback

5.96.66.86.87.77.89.013.415.9

-0.0251

Mother education

96.693.192.395.793.497.981.880.793.4

91.783.9

{p = 0.404)

Mother education

87.785.796.093.996.788.393.185.490.5

91.783.5

(p = 0.949)

Name

AishaKeishaTamikaLakishaTanishaLatoyaKenyaLatonyaEbony

Average. Overall

Correlation

Name

RasheedTremayneKareemDarnellTyroneHakimJamalLeroyJermaine

AverageOverall

Correlation

BY FIRST NAME

African-American

Percent callback

2.23.85.55.55.88.48.79.19.6

-0.383

African-American

Percent callback

3.04.34.74.85.35.56.69.49.6

-0.595

SEPTEMBER 2004

female

Mother education

77.268.861.555.664.055.570.231.365.6

61.070.2

(p = 0.309)

male

Mother education

77.3—

67.466.164.073.773.953.357.5

66.768.9

(p = 0.120)

Notes: This table reports, for each first name used in the experiment, callback rate and average mother education. Mothereducation for a given first name is defined as the percent of babies bom with that name in Massachusetts between 1970 and1986 whose mother had at least completed a high school degree (see text for details). Within each sex/race group, first namesare ranked by increasing callback rate. "Average" reports, within each race-gender group, the average mother education forall the babies bom with one of the names used in the experiment. "Overall" reports, within each race-gender group, averagemother education for all babies bom in Massachusetts between 1970 and 1986 in that race-gender group. "Correlation" reportsthe Spearman rank order correlation between callback rate and mother education within each race-gender group as well as thep-value for the test of independence.

1986.'*^ For each first name in our experiment,we compute the fraction of babies with that

"** This longer time span (compared to that used to assessname frequencies) was imposed on us for confidentialityreasons. When fewer than 10 births with education dataavailable are recorded in a particular education-name cell,the exact number of births in that cell is not reported and weimpute five births. Our results are not sensitive to thisimputation. One African-American female name (Latonya)and two male names (Rasheed and Hakim) were imputed inthis way. One African-American male name (Tremayne)had too few births with available education data and wastherefore dropped from this analysis. Our results are quali-

name and, in that gender-race cell, whose moth-ers have at least completed a high schooldegree.

In Table 8, we display the average callbackrate for each first name along with this proxy forsocial background. Within each race-gendergroup, the names are ranked by increasing call-back rate. Interestingly, there is significant

tatively similar when we use a larger data set of Califomiabirths for the years 1989 to 2000 (kindly provided to us bySteven Levitt).

Page 19: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

VOL. 94 NO. 4 BERTRAND AND MULLAINATHAN: RACE IN THE LABOR MARKET 1009

variation in callback rates by name. Of course,chance alone could produce such variation be-cause of the rather small number of observa-tions in each cell (about 200 for the femalenames and 70 for the male names).'*'

The row labeled "Average" reports the aver-age fraction of mothers that have at least com-pleted high school for the set of names listed inthat gender-race group. The row labeled "Over-all" reports the average fraction of mothers thathave at least completed high school for the fullsample of births in that gender-race group. Forexample, 83.9 percent of White female babiesbom between 1970 and 1986 have mothers withat least a high school degree; 91.7 percent of theWhite female babies with one of the names usedin the experiment have mothers with at least ahigh school degree.

Consistent with a social background interpre-tation, the African-American names we havechosen fall below the African-American aver-age. For African-American male names, how-ever, the gap between the experimental namesand the population average is negligible. ForWhite names, both the male and female namesare above the population average.

But, more interestingly to us, there is substan-tial between-name heterogeneity in social back-ground. African-American babies named Kenyaor Jamal are affiliated with much higher moth-ers' education than African-American babiesnamed Latonya or Leroy. Conversely, Whitebabies named Carrie or Neil have lower socialbackground than those named Emily orGeoffrey. This allows for a direct test of thesocial background hypothesis within our sam-ple: are names associated with a worse socialbackground discriminated against more? In thelast row in each gender-race group, we reportthe rank-order correlation between callbackrates and mother's education. The social back-ground hypothesis predicts a positive correla-tion. Yet, for all four categories, we find the

"' We formally tested whether this variation was signif-icant by estimating a probit regression of the callbackdummy on all the personal first names, allowing for clus-tering of the observations at the employment-ad level. Forall but African-American females, we cannot reject the nullhypothesis that all the first name effects in the same race-gender group are the same. Of course, a lack of a rejectiondoes not mean there is no underlying pattern in the between-name variation in callbacks that might have been detectablewith larger sample sizes.

exact opposite. The p-values indicate that wecannot reject independence at standard signifi-cance levels except in the case of African-American males where we can almost reject it atthe 10-percent level (p = 0.120). In summary,this test suggests little evidence that social back-ground drives the measured race gap.

Names might also influence our resultsthrough familiarity. One could argue that theAfrican-American names used in the experi-ment simply appear odd to human resourcemanagers and diat any odd name is discrimi-nated against. But as noted earlier, the nameswe have selected are not particularly uncommonamong African-Americans (see Appendix TableAl). We have also performed a similar exerciseto that of Table 8 and measured the rank-ordercorrelation between name-specific callbackrates and name frequency within each gender-race group. We found no systematic positivecorrelation.

There is one final potential confound to ourresults. Perhaps what appears as a bias againstAfrican-Americans is actually the result of re-verse discrimination. If qualified African-Americans are thought to be in high demand,then employers with average quality jobs mightfeel that an equally talented African-Americanwould never accept an offer from them andthereby never call her or him in for an inter-view. Such an argument might also explain whyAfrican-Americans do not receive as strong areturn as Whites to better resumes, since higherqualification only strengthens this argument.But this interpretation would suggest thatamong the better jobs, we ought to see evidenceof reverse discrimination, or at least a smallerracial gap. However, as we discussed in SectionIII, subsection D, we do not find any suchevidence. The racial gap does not vary acrossjobs with different skill requirements, nor doesit vary across occupation categories. Evenamong the better jobs in our sample, we findthat employers significantly favor applicantswith White names.'**

"* One might argue that employers who reverse-discrim-inate hire through less formal channels than help-wantedads. But this would imply that African-Americans are lesslikely to find jobs through formal channels. The evidence onexit out of unemployment does not paint a clear picture inthis direction (Holzer, 1987).

Page 20: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

1010 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2004

C. Relation to Existing Theories

What do these results imply for existing mod-els of discrimination? Economic theories of dis-crimination can be classified into two maincategories: taste-based and statistical discrimi-nation models.'*^ Both sets of models can obvi-ously "explain" our average racial gap incallbacks. But can these models explain ourother findings? More specifically, we discussthe relevance of these models with a focus ontwo of the facts that have been uncovered in thispaper: (i) the lower returns to credentials forAfrican-Americans; (ii) the relative uniformityof the race gap across occupations, job require-ments and, to a lesser extent, employer charac-teristics and industries.

Taste-based models (Gary S. Becker, 1961)differ in whose prejudiced "tastes" they empha-size: customers, coworkers, or employers. Cus-tomer and co-worker discrimination modelsseem at odds with the lack of significant varia-tion of the racial gap by occupation and industrycategories, as the amount of customer contactand the fraction of White employees vary quitea lot across these categories. We do not find alarger racial gap among jobs that explicitly re-quire "communication skills" and jobs forwhich we expect either customer or coworkercontacts to be higher (retail sales for example).

Because we do not know what drives employertastes, employer discrimination models could beconsistent with the lack of occupation and indus-try variation. Employer discrimination alsomatches the finding that employers located inmore African-American neighborhoods appear todiscriminate somewhat less. However, employerdiscrimination models would struggle to explainwhy African-Americans get relatively lower re-tums to their credentials. Indeed, the cost of in-dulging the discrimination taste should increase asthe minority applicants' credentials increase.^"

Statistical discrimination models are theprominent alternative to the taste-based models

•*' Darity and Mason (1998) provide a more thoroughreview of a variety of economic theories of discrimination.

'" One could, however, assume that employer tastes dif-fer not just by race but also by race and skill, so thatemployers have greater prejudice against minority workerswith better credentials. But the opposite preferences, em-ployers having a particular distaste for low-skilled African-Americans, also seem reasonable.

in the economics literature. In one class of sta-tistical discrimination models, employers use(observable) race to proxy for unobservableskills (e.g., Edmund S. Phelps, 1972; Kenneth J.Arrow, 1973). This class of models struggle toexplain the credentials effect as well. Indeed,the added credentials should lead to a largerupdate for African-Americans and hence greaterreturns to skills for that group.

A second class of statistical discriminationmodels "emphasize the precision of the infor-mation that employers have about individualproductivity" (Altonji and Blank, 1999). Spe-cifically, in these models, employers believethat the same observable signal is more precisefor Whites than for African-Americans (DennisJ. Aigner and Glenn G. Cain, 1977; Shelly J.Lundberg and Richard Startz, 1983; BradfordCornell and Ivo Welch, 1996). Under such mod-els, African-Americans receive lower returns toobservable skills because employers place lessweight on these skills. However, how reason-able is this interpretation for our experiment?First, it is important to note that we are using thesame set of resume characteristics for both ra-cial groups. So the lower precision of informa-tion for African-Americans cannot be that, forexample, an employer does not know what ahigh school degree from a very African-Americanneighborhood means (as in Aigner and Cain,1977). Second, many of the credentials on theresumes are in fact extemally and easily verifiable,such as a certification for a specific software.

An alternative version of these models wouldrely on bias in the observable signal rather thandifferential variance or noise of these signals byrace. Perhaps the skills of African-Americansare discounted because affirmative actionmakes it easier for African-Americans to getthese skills. While this is plausible for creden-tials such as an employee-of-the-month honor,it is unclear why this would apply to moreverifiable and harder skills. It is equally unclearwhy work experience would be less rewardedsince our study suggests that getting a job ismore, not less, difficult for African-Americans.

The uniformity of the racial gap across occu-pations is also troubling for a statistical discrim-ination interpretation. Numerous factors thatshould affect the level of statistical discrimina-tion, such as the importance of unobservableskills, the observability of qualifications, theprecision of observable skills and the ease of

Page 21: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

VOL. 94 NO. 4 BERTRAND AND MULLAINATHAN: RACE IN THE LABOR MARKET 1011

performance measurement, may vary quite a lotacross occupations.

This discussion suggests that perhaps othermodels may do a better job at explaining ourfindings. One simple alternative model is lexi-cographic search by employers. Employers re-ceive so many resumes that they may use quickheuristics in reading these resumes. One suchheuristic could be to simply read no furtherwhen they see an African-American name. Thusthey may never see the skills of African-American candidates and this could explainwhy these skills are not rewarded. This mightalso to some extent explain the uniformity of therace gap since the screening process (i.e., look-ing through a large set of resumes) may be quitesimilar across the variety of jobs we study.^'

' ' Another explanation could be based on employer ste-reotyping or categorizing. If employers have coarser stereo-types for Afirican-Americans, many of our results wouldfollow. See Melinda Jones (2002) for the relevant psychol-ogy and MuUainathan (2003) for a formalization of thecategorization concept.

V. Conclusion

This paper suggests that African-Americansface differential treatment when searching forjobs and this may still be a factor in why they dopoorly in the labor market. Job applicants withAfrican-American names get far fewer call-backs for each resume they send out. Equallyimportantly, applicants with African-Americannames find it hard to overcome this hurdle incallbacks by improving their observable skillsor credentials.

Taken at face value, our results on differen-tial returns to skill have possibly important pol-icy implications. They suggest that trainingprograms alone may not be enough to alleviatethe racial gap in labor market outcomes. Fortraining to work, some general-equilibriumforce outside the context of our experimentwould have to be at play. In fact, if African-Americans recognize how employers rewardtheir skills, they may rationally be less willingthan Whites to even participate in theseprograms.

Page 22: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

W12 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2004

TABLE A1—FIRST NAMES USED IN EXPERIMENT

White femaleName

AllisonAnneCarrieEmilyJillLaurieKristenMeredithSarah

White maleName

BradBrendanGeoffreyGregBrettJayMatthewNeilTodd

L(W)/L(B)

00

00

00

ooOD

ooCO

00

00

Fraction of all births:

3.8 percent

Perception White

0.9260.9620.9230.9250.8890.9630.9630.9260.852

L(W)/L(B) Perception White

00

00

CO

00

00

00

00

00

00

Fraction of all births:

1.7 percent

10.6670.73110.9230.9260.8880.6540.926

African-American femaleName

AishaEbonyKeishaKenyaLakishaLatonyaLatoyaTamikaTanisha

L(B)/L(W)

209oo

116CO

00

00

00

28400

Fraction of all births:

7.1 percent

African-American maleName

DarnellHakimJamalJermaineKareemLeroyRasheedTremayneTyrone

L(B)/L(W)

00

25790.500

44.5CO

00

62.5Fraction of all births:

3.1 percent

Perception Black

0.970.90.930.9670.9671111

Perception Black

0.9670.9330.96710.9670.9330.9310.8970.900

Notes: This table tabulates the different first names used in the experiment and their identifiability. The first column reportsthe likelihood that a baby bom with that name (in Massachusetts between 1974 and 1979) is White (or African-American)relative to the likelihood that it is African-American (White). The second column reports the probability that the name waspicked as White (or African-American) in an independent field survey of people. The last row for each group of names showsthe proportion of all births in that race group that these names account for.

REFERENCES

Aigner, Dennis J. and Cain. Glenn G. "StatisticalTheories of Discrimination in Labor Mar-kets." Industrial and Labor Relations Re-view, January 1977, 30{l), pp. 175-87.

Altonji, Joseph G. and Blank, Rebecca M. "Raceand Gender in the Labor Markey," in OrleyAshenfelter and David Card, eds.. Handbookof labor economics, Vol. 30. Amsterdam:North-Holland, 1999, pp. 3143-259.

Arrow, Kenneth, J. "The Theory of Discrimina-tion," in Orley Ashenfelter and Albert Rees,eds.. Discrimination in labor markets.Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,1973, pp. 3-33.

"What Has Economics to Say aboutRacial Discrimination?" Journal of EconomicPerspectives, Spring 1998, 72(2), pp. 91-100.

Becker, Gary S. The economics of discrimina-tion, 2nd Ed. Chicago: University of ChicagoPress, 1961.

Brown, Colin and Gay, Pat. Racial discrimina-tion 17 years after the act. London: PolicyStudies Institute, 1985.

Cornell, Bradford and Welch, Ivo. "Culture, In-formation, and Screening Discrimination."Journal of Political Economy, June 1996,704(3), pp. 542-71.

Council of Economic Advisers. Changing America:Indicators of social and economic well-beingby race and Hispanic origin. September 1998,http://w3.access.gpo.gov/eop/ca/pdfs/ca.pdf.

Cross, Harry; Kenney, Genevieve; Mell, Jane andZimmerman, Wendy. Employer hiring prac-tices: Differential treatment of Hispanic andAnglo job applicants. Washington, DC: Ur-ban Institute Press, 1990.

Page 23: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial

VOL. 94 NO. 4 BERTRAND AND MULLAINATHAN: RACE IN THE LABOR MARKET 1013

Darity, William A., Jr. and Mason, Patrick L."Evidence on Discrimination in Employ-ment: Codes of Color, Codes of Gender."Journal of Economic Perspectives, Spring1998, 72(2), pp. 63-90.

Fix, Michael and Turner, Margery A., eds. Anational report card on discrimination inAmerica: The role of testing. Washington,DC: Urban Institute Press, 1998.

Fryer, Roland and Levitt, Steven. "The Causesand Consequences of Distinctively BlackNames." Mimeo, University of Chicago,2003.

Goldin, Claudia and Rouse, Cecilia. "Orchestrat-ing Impartiality: The Impact of Blind Audi-tions on Female Musicians." AmericanEconomic Review, September 2000, 90(4),pp. 715-41.

Heckman, James J. "Detecting Discrimination."Journal of Economic Perspectives, Spring1998, 72(2), pp. 101-16.

Heckman, James J.; Lochner, Lance J., and Todd,Petra E. "Fifty Years of Mincer Earnings Re-gressions." Mimeo, University of Chicago,2001.

Heckman, James J. and Siegelman, Peter. "TheUrban Institute Audit Studies: Their Methodsand Findings," in Michael Fix and RaymondJ. Struyk, eds.. Clear and convincing evi-dence: Measurement of discrimination inAmerica. Lanham, MD: Urban InstitutePress, 1992, pp. 187-258.

Holzer, Harry J. "Informal Job Search and BlackYouth Unemployment." American EconomicReview, June 1987, 77(3), pp. 446-52.

Hubbuck, Jim and Carter, Simon. Half achance? A report on job discriminationagainst young blacks in Nottingham. London:Commission for Racial Equality, 1980.

James, Franklin and DelCastillo, Steve W. "Mea-suring Job Discrimination by Private Em-ployers Against Young Black and HispanicSeeking Entry Level Work in the DenverMetropolitan Area." Mimeo, University ofColorado-Denver, 1991.

Jones, Melinda. Social psychology of prejudice.Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education, 2002.

Jowell, Roger and Prescott-Clark, Patricia. "Ra-cial Discrimination and White-Collar Work-

ers in Britain." Race, November 1970, 77(4),pp. 397-417.

Lundberg, Shelly J. and Starz, Richard. "PrivateDiscrimination and Social Intervention inCompetitive Labor Market." American Eco-nomic Review, June 1983, 75(3), pp. 340-47.

Mclntyre, Shelby J.; Moberg, Dennis J. and Pos-ner, Barry Z. "Discrimination in Recruitment:An Empirical Analysis: Comment." Indus-trial and Labor Relations Review, July 1980,55(4), pp. 543-47.

MuUainathan, Sendhil. "Thinking Through Cat-egories." Mimeo, Massachusetts Institute ofTechnology, 2003.

Neumark, David. "Sex Discrimination in Res-taurant Hiring: An Audit Study." QuarterlyJournal of Economics, August 1996, 777(3),pp. 915-42.

Newman, Jerry M. "Discrimination in Recruit-ment: An Empirical Analysis." Industrial andLabor Relations Review, October 1978,52(1), pp. 15-23.

Nisbett, Richard E. and Cohen, Dov. The cultureof honor: The psychology of violence in theSouth. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1996.

Phelps, Edmund S. "The Statistical Theory ofRacism and Sexism." American EconomicReview, September 1972, 62(4), pp. 659-61.

Raphael, Steven; Stoll, Michael A. and Holzer,Harry J. "Are Suburban Firms More Likelyto Discriminate against African Americans?"Journal of Urban Economics, November2000, 48(3), pp. 485-508.

Riach, Peter A. and Rich, Judity. "Testing forRacial Discrimination in the Labour Market."Cambridge Journal of Economics, September1991, 75(3), pp. 239-56.

Turner, Margery A.; Fix, Michael and Struyk,Raymond J. Opportunities denied, opportuni-ties diminished: Racial discrimination in hir-ing. Washington, DC: Urban Institute Press,1991.

Weichselbaumer, Doris. "Sexual OrientationDiscrimination in Hiring." Labour Econom-ics, December 2003, 70(6), pp. 629-42.

"Is it Sex or Personality? The Impactof Sex-Stereotypes on Discrimination in Ap-plicant Selection." Eastern Economic Jour-nal, Spring 2004, 50(2), pp. 159-86.

Page 24: Are Emily and Greg More Employable Than Lakisha and Jamal ...adkugler/Bertrand&Mullainathan.pdf · sive to resume quality for White names than for African-American ones. The racial