model of the behavior of stock prices chapter 10

Post on 06-Jan-2016

33 Views

Category:

Documents

2 Downloads

Preview:

Click to see full reader

DESCRIPTION

Model of the Behavior of Stock Prices Chapter 10. Categorization of Stochastic Processes. Discrete time; discrete variable Discrete time; continuous variable Continuous time; discrete variable Continuous time; continuous variable. Modeling Stock Prices. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

10.1

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Model of the Behavior

of Stock Prices

Chapter 10

10.2

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Categorization of Stochastic Processes

• Discrete time; discrete variable

• Discrete time; continuous variable

• Continuous time; discrete variable

• Continuous time; continuous variable

10.3

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Modeling Stock Prices

• We can use any of the four types of stochastic processes to model stock prices

• The continuous time, continuous variable process proves to be the most useful for the purposes of valuing derivative securities

10.4

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Markov Processes (See pages 218-9)

• In a Markov process future movements in a variable depend only on where we are, not the history of how we got where we are

• We will assume that stock prices follow Markov processes

10.5

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Weak-Form Market Efficiency

• The assertion is that it is impossible to produce consistently superior returns with a trading rule based on the past history of stock prices. In other words technical analysis does not work.

• A Markov process for stock prices is clearly consistent with weak-form market efficiency

10.6

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Example of a Discrete Time Continuous Variable Model

• A stock price is currently at $40

• At the end of 1 year it is considered that it will have a probability distribution of(40,10) where (,) is a normal distribution with mean and standard deviation

10.7

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Questions• What is the probability distribution of the

stock price at the end of 2 years?

• ½ years?

• ¼ years?

• t years?

Taking limits we have defined a continuous variable, continuous time process

10.8

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Variances & Standard Deviations

• In Markov processes changes in successive periods of time are independent

• This means that variances are additive

• Standard deviations are not additive

10.9

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Variances & Standard Deviations (continued)

• In our example it is correct to say that the variance is 100 per year.

• It is strictly speaking not correct to say that the standard deviation is 10 per year.

10.10

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

A Wiener Process (See pages 220-1)

• We consider a variable z whose value changes continuously

• The change in a small interval of time t is z

• The variable follows a Wiener process if

1.

2. The values of z for any 2 different (non-overlapping) periods of time are independent

z t (0,1) where is a random drawing from

10.11

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Properties of a Wiener Process

• Mean of [z (T ) – z (0)] is 0

• Variance of [z (T ) – z (0)] is T

• Standard deviation of [z (T ) – z (0)] is

T

10.12

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Taking Limits . . .

• What does an expression involving dz and dt mean?

• It should be interpreted as meaning that the corresponding expression involving z and t is true in the limit as t tends to zero

• In this respect, stochastic calculus is analogous to ordinary calculus

10.13

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Generalized Wiener Processes(See page 221-4)

• A Wiener process has a drift rate (ie average change per unit time) of 0 and a variance rate of 1

• In a generalized Wiener process the drift rate & the variance rate can be set equal to any chosen constants

10.14

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Generalized Wiener Processes(continued)

The variable x follows a generalized Wiener process with a drift rate of a & a variance rate of b2 if

dx=adt+bdz

10.15

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Generalized Wiener Processes(continued)

• Mean change in x in time T is aT

• Variance of change in x in time T is b2T

• Standard deviation of change in x in time T is

x a t b t

b T

10.16

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

The Example Revisited

• A stock price starts at 40 & has a probability distribution of(40,10) at the end of the year

• If we assume the stochastic process is Markov with no drift then the process is

dS = 10dz

• If the stock price were expected to grow by $8 on average during the year, so that the year-end distribution is (48,10), the process is

dS = 8dt + 10dz

10.17

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Ito Process (See pages 224-5)

• In an Ito process the drift rate and the variance rate are functions of time

dx=a(x,t)dt+b(x,t)dz

• The discrete time equivalent

is only true in the limit as t tends to

zero

x a x t t b x t t ( , ) ( , )

10.18

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Why a Generalized Wiener Processis not Appropriate for Stocks

• For a stock price we can conjecture that its expected proportional change in a short period of time remains constant not its expected absolute change in a short period of time

• We can also conjecture that our uncertainty as to the size of future stock price movements is proportional to the level of the stock price

10.19

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

An Ito Process for Stock Prices(See pages 225-6)

where is the expected return is the volatility.

The discrete time equivalent is

dS Sdt Sdz

S S t S t

10.20

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Monte Carlo Simulation

• We can sample random paths for the stock price by sampling values for

• Suppose = 0.14, = 0.20, and t = 0.01, then

S S S 0 0014 0 02. .

10.21

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Monte Carlo Simulation – One Path (continued. See Table 10.1)

PeriodStock Price atStart of Period

RandomSample for

Change in StockPrice, S

0 20.000 0.52 0.236

1 20.236 1.44 0.611

2 20.847 -0.86 -0.329

3 20.518 1.46 0.628

4 21.146 -0.69 -0.262

10.22

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Ito’s Lemma (See pages 229-231)

• If we know the stochastic process followed by x, Ito’s lemma tells us the stochastic process followed by some function G (x, t )

• Since a derivative security is a function of the price of the underlying & time, Ito’s lemma plays an important part in the analysis of derivative securities

10.23

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Taylor Series Expansion• A Taylor’s series expansion of G (x , t ) gives

GG

xx

G

tt

G

xx

G

x tx t

G

tt

½

½

2

22

2 2

22

10.24

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Ignoring Terms of Higher Order Than t

In ordinary calculus we get

stic calculus we get

because has a component which is of order

In stocha

½

GG

xx

G

tt

GG

xx

G

tt

G

xx

x t

2

22

10.25

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Substituting for x

Suppose

( , ) ( , )

so that

= +

Then ignoring terms of higher order than

½

dx a x t dt b x t dz

x a t b t

t

GG

xx

G

tt

G

xb t

2

22 2

10.26

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

The 2t Term

Since

It follows that

The variance of is proportional to and can

be ignored. Hence

2

( , ) ( )

( ) [ ( )]

( )

( )

0 1 0

1

1

1

2

2 2

2

2

2

22

E

E E

E

E t t

t t

GG

xx

G

tt

G

xb t

10.27

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Taking Limits

Taking limits ½

Substituting

We obtain ½

This is Ito's Lemma

dGG

xdx

G

tdt

G

xb dt

dx a dt b dz

dGG

xa

G

t

G

xb dt

G

xb dz

2

22

2

22

10.28

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Application of Ito’s Lemmato a Stock Price Process

The stock price process is

For a function of &

½

d S S dt S d z

G S t

dGG

SS

G

t

G

SS dt

G

SS dz

2

22 2

10.29

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull

Examples1. The forward price of a stock for a contract

maturing at time

e

2.

T

G S

dG r G dt G dz

G S

dG dt dz

r T t

( )

( )

ln

2

2

top related