microeconomics and financecermsem.univ-paris1.fr/davila/teaching/sbs/ch03_pindyck...microeconomics...

Post on 03-Nov-2020

21 Views

Category:

Documents

0 Downloads

Preview:

Click to see full reader

TRANSCRIPT

1 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

1

Microeconomics and Finance

Solvay Business School 08/09

Julio DAVILA

2 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

2

Microeconomics and Finance

Textbook:

Microéconomie, Pindyck & Rubinfeld Prentice Hall, 6th ed.

  Part 1 : Demand   Part 2 : Introduction to finance   Part 3 : Supply   Part 4 : Competitive equilibrium   Part 5 : Non-competitive markets

3 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

3

Microeconomics and Finance

  Teaching Assistant: Ritha Sukadi Ritha.Sukadi.Mata@ulb.ac.be

  Office hours: by appointment (e-mail Ritha)

  Slides: http://cermsem.univ-paris1.fr/davila/microfinance.html

4 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

4

Consumer behavior

Microéconomie, chapter 3

5 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

5

Consumer behavior

 Consumer behavior theory explains how the consumer chooses to spend his income in different goods and services

6 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

6

Consumer behavior

  The consumer’s choice depends on: his preferences

  They describe how the consumer ranks different bundles of goods or commodities

his budget constraint   The consumer has limited resources

the optimization of his preferences given his budget constraint

  The consumer seeks to maximize the «utility» he derives from consumption given his resources

7 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

7

Consumer preferences

Assumptions

1.  his preferences are complete   he is able to rank any two bundles of goods

2.  his preferences are transitive   if he prefers A to B, and B to C, then he must prefer

A to C 3.  his preferences are monotone

  he always prefers more to less

8 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

8

Consumer preferences

 Preferences can be represented graphically by means of indifference curves

 An indifference curve contains all the bundles of goods that satisfy equally the consumer  He is indifferent between any of two them

9 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

9

Indifference curves: example

bundles food clothes

A 20 30

B 10 50

D 40 20

E 30 40

G 10 20

H 10 40

10 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

10

Indifference curves: example

 The assumptions on preferences translate into graphical properties of the indifference curves

11 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

11

A is preferred to any bundle in the yellow box,

but any bundle in the pink box is preferred to A.

Indifference curves: example

food

10

20

30

40

10 20 30 40

clothes 50

G

A

E H

B

D

12 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

12

Indifference curves: example

  The indifference curve through A cannot intersect the areas to the NE and SW of point A

  It must be contained in the areas to the NW and SE of point A

 Conclusion: indifference curves must be decreasing  Otherwise they are not monotone:

  The consumer would be indifferent to a bundle having less of both goods!!!

13 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

13

• B, A, and D are indifferent • E is preferred to any bundle in U1 • Any bundle in U1 is preferred to H and G

Indifference curves: example

food

10

20

30

40

10 20 30 40

clothes 50

U1 G D

A

E H

B

14 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

14

Indifference curves

 Bundles to the NE of an indifference curve are preferred to those on the curve

 Bundles on the curve are preferred to those to the SW of the indifference curve

15 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

15

Indifference curves

 Indifference curves cannot cross  Crossings are incompatible with monotonicity

16 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

16

Indifference curves

food

clothes • A and B are indifferent • A and C are indifferent • B and C should be indifferent • but B is preferred to C!!

U1

U1

U2

U2

A

B

C

17 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

17

Indifference curves

 Through every bundle goes an indifference curve

 A consequence of preferences being complete

18 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

18

U2

U3

Indifference curves

food

clothes

U1

A B C

• Through every bundle goes just one indifference curve • A is preferred to B, and B to C.

19 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

19

Indifference curves

  The shape of indifference curves conveys the consumer willingness to trade one good for the other good

20 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

20

the number of clothes required to compensate for the loss of one unit of food increases from 1 to 6

Indifference curves

food

clothes

2 3 4 5 1

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16 A

B

C

D E

6

-1

-1

4

-1 2

-1 1

21 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

21

Indifference curves

  The shape of indifference curves conveys the consumer willingness to trade one good for the other   e.g., from A to B, 6 units of clothes for 1 unit of food   but from C to D, only 2 units of clothes for 1 unit of

food

  The more clothes one has, the more one is ready to trade clothes for food

22 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

22

Indifference curves

 The consumer willingness to trade goods is measured by his marginal rate of substitution (MRS)  It provides the amount of a good that he is

ready to trade for one more unit of the other good

 It is given by the slope of the indifference curve

23 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

23

Marginal rate of substitution

food 2 3 4 5 1

clothes

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16 A

B

C

D E

6

-1

-1

-1 -1

4

2 1

MRS = 6

MRS = 2 €

MRS = −ΔcΔf

24 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

24

Marginal rate of substitution

 Indifference curves are convex  The more one consumes of a good, the less

one is ready to give up other goods to increase additionally its consumption

 Consumers usually do prefer balanced bundles

25 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

25

Marginal rate of substitution

food 40 80 20

clothes

20

30

40

0

U1

A

B

• The bundles between A and B are preferred to these two

26 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

26

Marginal rate of substitution

 Decreasing marginal rate of substitution  The MRS decreases along the indifference

curve  In the example, the MRS goes down from 6

to 4, then to 2, and finally to 1

27 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

27

Marginal rate of substitution

 different shapes for an indifference curve represent different attitudes to substituting one good for another

 Special cases:  Perfect substitutes  Perfect complements

28 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

28

Marginal rate of substitution

 Perfect substitutes  The MRS is constant  Example: some may consider orange juice

and apple juice perfect substitutes  They would always be ready to exchange 1

glass of orange juice for 1 glass of apple juice

29 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

29

Consumer preferences

Apple juice

Orange juice

2 3 4 1

1

2

3

4

0

Perfect substitutes

30 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

30

Consumer preferences

 Perfect complements  The indifference curbes are L-shaped  Example: left and right shoes are used in

pairs (additional units of, say, just left shoes leave us indifferent)

31 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

31

Consumer preferences

Right shoes

Left shoes

2 3 4 1

1

2

3

4

0

Perfect complements

32 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

32

Consumer preferences

 Explaining the consumer behavior does not require an index measuring the consumer’s satisfaction

 A ranking suffices, but utility indexes are useful, mainly to represent attitudes towards risk

33 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

33

Consumer preferences

 Utility  A numerical value representing the level of

satisfaction derived from consuming a particular bundle of goods

34 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

34

Utility

 Utility function  A formula assigning a utility level to each

bundle of goods  Example 1: given the utility function

U(f,c) = f + 2c the bundle (8 units of food, 3 units of clothes)

provides a utility 14 = 8 + 2x3

35 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

35

Utility – Example 1

bundles food clothes utility

A 8 3 8 + 2x3 = 14

B 6 4 6 + 2x4 = 14

C 4 4 4 + 2x4 = 12

The consumer is indifferent between A and B but prefers both to C

36 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

36

Utility – Example 2

food

10 15 5

5

10

15

0

clothes

U1 = 25

U2 = 50

U3 = 100

bundle U = f x c A 25 = 2,5 x 10 B 25 = 5 x 5 C 25 = 10 x 2,5

B

C

A

37 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

37

Utility

 Ordinal utility function  Ranks bundles from less to more preferred

but does not convey any sense of intensity of preferences

 Cardinal utility function  It describes how much more is a bundle

preferred to another

38 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

38

Utility

 An ordinal utility sufices to explain most individual decisions

 A cardinal ranking is needed to explain decisions under uncertainty and risk

39 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

39

The budget constraint

 Preferences alone do not explain consumers’ choices

 The budget constraint limits the consumer’s decisions

40 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

40

The budget constraint

 The budget line  It contains all the bundles of goods whose

cost equals the consumer’s income or wealth

41 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

41

The budget line

  If f is the amount of food purchased c is the amount of clothes, Pf is the price for food, Pc is the price for clothes   then Pf f is the expenditure in food, and Pc c is the expenditure in clothes Pf f + Pc c is the total expenditure

42 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

42 €

Pf f + Pcc = I

The budget line

 The equation of the budget line is:

It says that the entire income is spent either on food or clothes

43 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

43

The budget constraint

bundles food Pf = €1

clothes Pc = €2

income I = Pf f + Pc c

A 0 40 €80

B 20 30 €80

C 40 20 €80

D 60 10 €80

E 80 0 €80

44 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

44

slope = - ΔcΔf

= - 12

= - Pf

Pc

The budget line

10

-20

A

B

C

D

E

I/Pc = 40

food

40 60 80 = I/Pf 20

10

20

30

0

clothes

45 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

45

The budget line

 Along the budget line any increase in the consumption of a good implies a decrease in the consumption of the other good

  The slope the negative of the ratio of the goods prices

  The slope is the rate at which goods can be substituted between them without changing the cost of the bundle

  The slope measures also the relative price of one good in terms of the other

46 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

46

The budget line

Pf f + Pcc = I

c =IPc−Pf

Pcf

47 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

47

The budget line

 The intersection I/Pc with the vertical axis is the maximum quantity of clothes c that can be purchased with an income I

 The interection I/Pf with the horizontal axis is the maxmum quantity of food f that can be purchased with an income I

48 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

48

slope = ΔcΔf

= - 12

= - Pf

Pc

The budget line

10

-20

A

B

C

D

E

I/Pc = 40

food

40 60 80 = I/Pf 20

10

20

30

0

clothes

49 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

49

The budget line

 Income and prices can change  Changes in prices and income shift the

budget line  Shifts in the budget line change the

consumer’s choice

50 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

50

The budget line

An increase of income shifts the budget line

outwards

food

clothes

80 120 160 40

20

40

60

80

0

I = €160 D2

I = €80 D1

D3

I = €40

An decrease of income shifts the budget line

inwards

51 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

51

The budget line

 Impact of a change in income:  An increase in income shifts outwards the

budget line (keeping the slope constant)  With the additional income one can buy more

of both goods

52 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

52

The budget line

 Impact of a change in income:  A decrease in income shifts inwards the

budget line (keeping the slope constant)  One cannot buy as much as before with the

smaller income

53 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

53

The budget line

Pf = 1

D1

An increase in the price of food to € 2

makes the budget line pivot inwards around 40

D2

Pf = 2 Pf = 0,50

D3

A decrease in the price of food to € 0,50 makes the budget line

pivot outwards around 40

40 food

clothes

80 120 160

40

54 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

54

The budget line

  Impact of changes in prices:  If the price of a good increases, the budget line pivots

inwards around its crossing with the axis of the other good

 e.g. if the price of food increases:

If the consumer only buys food he cannot buy as much as before (the intersection with the axis of food shifts leftwards)

If the consumer only buys clothes he can still by the same amount (the intersection with the axis of clothes stays put)

55 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

55

The budget line

  Impact of changes in prices:  If the price of a good decreases, the budget line

pivots outwards around its crossing with the axis of the other good

 e.g. if the price of food decreases:

If the consumer only buys food he can buy even more than before (the intersection with the axis of food shifts rightwards)

If the consumer only buys clothes he can still by the same amount (the intersection with the axis of clothes stays put)

56 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

56

The budget line

 Impact of changes in prices:  If all prices increase in the same proportion,

then the slope does not change  The budget line shifts inwards

57 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

57

The budget line

 Impact of changes in prices:  If all prices decrease in the same proportion,

then the slope does not change  The budget line shifts outwards

58 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

58

Consumer’s choice

 Given his preferences and budget constraint, how does the consumer choose a bundle of goods?

 The consumer chooses the bundle on the budget line that maximizes his utility

59 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

59

Consumer’s choice

  The consumer’s choice: 1.  is on the budget line

  The consumer spends all his income (since his preferences are monotone)

2.  gives the consumer his most preferred bundle on the budget line

60 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

60

Consumer’s choice

 Graphically, the consumer tries to reach the highest indifference curve on his budget line

61 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

61

Consumer’s choice

U3

D

U2

A

food 40 80 20

clothes

20

30

40

0

U1

B

C

• D give a higher utility than A, but it is too expensive • B and C are affordable, but they are less preferred than A • A gives the highest attainable utility • A is the consumer’s choice

62 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

62

Consumer’s choice

 Graphically, the consumer tries to reach the highest indifference curve on his budget line

 The highest attainable indifference curve is tangent to the budget line

 The slope of the budget line is equal to the slope of the indifference curve at the consumer’s choice

63 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

63

Consumer’s choice

 The slope of an indifference curve is:

slopeIC = −MRS

slopeBL = −Pf

Pc

the slope of the budget line is:

64 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

64

Consumer’s choice

 therefore, at the consumer’s chosen bundle:

MRS =Pf

Pc

65 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

65

Consumer’s choice

 Utility is maximized on the budget line when the marginal rate of substitution is equal to the relative price

 This happens ONLY at the optimal consumption bundle

66 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

66

Consumer’s choice

food

clothes

40 80 20

20

30

40

0

bundle B does not maximize the utility

since the MRS = -(-10/10) = 1 Is bigger than the relative price = 1/2

+10f U1

-10c

B

67 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

67

Consumer’s choice

  If MRS ≠ Pf /Pc the consumer can increase his utility spending his income differently

  If MRS > Pf /Pc  He will increase his consumption of food and

decrease his consumption of clothes until MRS = Pf /Pc holds

  If MRS < Pf /Pc  He will decrease his consumption of food and

increase his consumption of clothes until MRS = Pf /Pc holds

68 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

68

Consumer’s choice

U3

D

U2

A

food 40 80 20

clothes

20

30

40

0

U1

B

C

• at B the MRS> Pf/Pc and the utility increases as more food and less clothes are consumed • at C the MRS< Pf/Pc and the utility increases as less food and more clothes are consumed

69 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

69

Consumer’s choice

 A corner solution happens when the consumer does not buy one of the goods  In that case MRS needs not be equal to the

relative price Pf /Pc

70 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

70

Corner solution

food

clothes

B

A

U2 U3 U1

bundle B is a corner solution

71 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

71

Corner solution

 At bundle B, the MRS of clothes for food is bigger than the slope of the budget line

 The consumer would like to give up clothes in exchange for additional food

 But he has no more clothes to exchage

72 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

72

Corner solution

 When the optimal choice is located at the border of the budget constraint, the MRS needs not be equal to the relative price

 In this case:

MRS ≥Pf

Pc

73 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

73

Corner solution

 When the MRS is much bigger than the the relative price, a small change in the price for clothes will have no impact on the consumer’s choice

74 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

74

Revealed preferences

 If the consumer’s choices before many different prices and incomes are known, then the consumer preferences can be recovered

75 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

75

Revealed prices

D1

D2

B

A

• D1: chooses A instead of B • A is revealed preferred to B

• D2: chooses B instead of C • B is revealed preferred to C

food

clothes

C

76 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

76

Revealed preferences

D1

D2

B

A

food

clothes

C

All pink bundles are preferred

to A.

A is preferred to any yellow bundle

77 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

77

Revealed preferences

 As the budget line changes, the consumer’s choice changes

 The more the consumer reveals his choices, the more his preferences can be identified

 In the limit, the indifference curves can be obtained

78 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

78

All pink bundles are Preferred to A

food

Revealed preferences

clothes

L1

L2

L3

L4

A is preferred to any yellow bundle

D B

A

C

L3: C is revealed preferred to A

L4: D reveled preferred to A

L2: A revealed preferred to B

79 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

79

Marginal utility and the consumer’s choice

 Marginal utility mesures the additional satisfaction from the consumption of one more unit of a good  How much happier is a consumer due to an

additional unit of food?

80 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

80

Marginal utility - example

 Let 9 be the marginal utility from increasing the consumption of food from 0 to 1 units

 from 1 to 2, let the marginal utility be 7  from 2 to 3, let the marginal utility be 5  remark: marginal utility decreases as

consumption increases

81 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

81

Marginal utility

 Principle decreasing marginal utility: the more a good is consumed, the smaller the marginal utility of an additional unit of the good

 Total utility increases monotonically nonetheless, since preferences are monotone

82 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

82

Marginal utility and the consumer’s choice

 Along an indifference curve:  The increase in utility from the additional

consumption of a good must compensate for the decrease of utility from the smaller consumption of the other good

83 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

83

Marginal utility and the consumer’s choice

 formally:

0 = MgUf ⋅ Δf + MgUc ⋅ Δc

Total utility does not change along the indifference curve. The compensation leaves the consumer indifferent.

84 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

84

Marginal utility and the consumer’s choice

 That is to say:

− ΔcΔf

=MgU f

MgUc

and since MRS = −ΔcΔf

then MRS =MgU f

MgUc

85 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

85

Marginal utility and the consumer’s choice

 When the consumer maximizes his utility:

MRS = Pf

Pc

MgU f

MgUc

= Pf

Pc

Since the MRS equals also the ratio of marginal utilities from consuming f et c

86 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

86

Marginal utility and the consumer’s choice

 Condition for the utility maximization:

MgUf

Pf

=MgUc

Pc

87 Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles

87

Marginal utility and the consumer’s choice

 Equal marginal utilities principle: utility is maximized only if the marginal utility from spending an additional euro is the same for both goods

top related