electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Post on 15-Jan-2016

37 Views

Category:

Documents

0 Downloads

Preview:

Click to see full reader

DESCRIPTION

Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?. Richard Green Institute for Energy Research and Policy. Transmission pricing. Geographical differentiation in the wholesale market Prices for connecting to and using the transmission network. Six objectives. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Electricity transmission pricing: getting the prices “good enough”?

Richard Green

Institute for Energy Research and Policy

Transmission pricing

• Geographical differentiation in the wholesale market

• Prices for connecting to and using the transmission network

Six objectives

1. Promote the efficient day‑to‑day operation of the bulk power market

2. Signal locational advantages for investment in generation and demand

3. Signal the need for investment in the transmission system

Six objectives

4 Compensate the owners of existing transmission assets

5 Be simple and transparent

6 Be politically implementableGreen (Utilities Policy, 1997)

Three approaches

• Ignore transmission issues

• Ignore transmission issues, then bribe market participants to sort things out

• Integrate transmission issues into your market design(s)

Major power flows

Source: UCTE

Major power flows and congestion

Source: UCTE

Congested 26-75% 76-99% 100%

If costs differ between areas

GW

P

GW

P

PL

PHPricetrade

Xpts Mpts

If costs differ between areas

GW

P

GW

P

Pricetrade

Xpts Mpts

Pricetrade

If costs differ between areas

GW

P

GW

P

and the lines are too thin…

Xpts Mpts

If costs differ between areas

T {

GW

P

GW

P

and the lines are too thin…

Xpts Mpts

Pricetrade

If costs differ between areas

GW

P

GW

P

and the lines are too thin…you could still ignore the problem

but someone will want money to sort it out!Xpts Mpts

Zones in the NEM

• NEM runs nodal model and dispatches according to nodal conditions (prices)

• Generators / loads grouped into regions

• All generators in a region receive the regional reference price– Marginal cost at a reference node

• No compensation for constrained running

From a line to a network…

• Electricity will flow along every path between two nodes

• It “cannot” be steered

• If one line fails, the flows instantly change

• Overloading any line can be catastrophic

(for example…)

A B

C

The impact of loop flows

A B

C

The impact of loop flows

Nodal prices

• Set price of power equal to marginal cost at each point (node) on the network– Marginal cost of generation (if variable)– MC of bringing in power from elsewhere

• Centralised market uses the nodal prices

• Bilateral trades which move power pay the difference in nodal prices

Nodal trading

• Price at A = 20, Price at B = 30

• I sell at A, I receive 20

• I sell at B, I receive 30

• I generate at A and sell at B, I receive the agreed bilateral price and pay (30 – 20)

• I generate at B and sell at A, I receive the agreed bilateral price and pay (20 – 30)

AB

A B

C

6 MW at C needs3 MW from A and3 MW from B

The impact of loop flowsand constraints

Prices – constraint AB• Price at C = (Pa + Pb)/2• 1 MW extra capacity allows 1.5 MW from A to

replace 1.5 MW from B• Shadow cost of constraint = 1.5 (Pb – Pa) • If Pa = 10, Pb = 30• Pc = 20, shadow cost = 30• Pc = Pa + 1/3 shadow cost

= Pb – 1/3 shadow cost

A B

C

3 MW at C needs–3 MW from A

The impact of loop flowsand constraints

and 6 MW from B

Prices – constraint AC

• Price at C = 2Pb – Pa• 1 MW extra capacity allows 3 MW from A

to replace 3 MW from B• Shadow cost of constraint = 3 (Pb – Pa) • If Pa = 10, Pb = 30• Pc = 50, shadow cost = 60• Pc = Pa + 2/3 Shadow cost

= Pb + 1/3 Shadow cost

A B

C

and constraints

3 MW at C needs 6 MW from A

The impact of loop flows

and–3 MW from B

Prices – constraint CB• Price at C = 2 Pa – Pb • 1 MW extra capacity allows 3 MW from A to

replace 3 MW from B• Shadow cost of constraint = 3 (Pb – Pa) • If Pa = 10, Pb = 30• Pc = –10, shadow cost = 60• Pc = Pa – 1/3 shadow cost

= Pb – 2/3 shadow cost

Summary

Constraint is on line:

None AB AC BC

Price at A 10 10 10 10

Price at B 10 30 30 30

Price at C 10 20 50 -10

Implications

• Nodal prices can vary significantly– Over time– Over space

• The first creates a need for hedging

• The second makes it harder

• The prices may be counter-intuitive

How to hedge

• Transmission Congestion Contract

• Spatial contract for differences– Pays the holder the difference in nodal prices

between two specified points (from A to B)– Price at B – Price at A– Perfect hedge if you generate that amount of

power at A and sell it at B• Remember the real-time charge is (PB – PA)

Who’d sell that hedge?

• The spot market charges raise a surplus– Who gets it?

• If the Transmission Congestion Contracts allocation is feasible, Hogan (1992) shows spot market surplus ≥ TCC payments

• Organisation receiving the spot surplus can issue TCCs and find itself hedged!

Inferior ways of hedging

• Financial Transmission Rights (options)– Only pay out when value is positive– Payments may exceed spot revenues

• Physical Transmission Rights– Limited by system capacity– If line limit on AB is 100, can only issue 100– With TCCs, 100 BA “allows” an extra 100 AB

• “Smeared” share of congestion revenues

What if you get it wrong?

• Operational difficulties– PJM’s first market

• Economic operating mistakes

• Investment mistakes– At present, we don’t know much about these

How much does it cost to get it wrong?

• Compare demand and operating patterns with different pricing rules

• Model applied to England and Wales, 1996 data

• Numbers are country- and time-specific

• Approach is general

The model

• NGC system in 1996/97

• Thirteen zones (two pairs of NGC’s zones are combined, one zone split into two)

• Iso-elastic demand in every zone

• Generation in most £/MWh

GW

Gas, Coal,Nuclear Oil

North

South-West

A DC load flow model with losses (proportional to the square of flows) and constraints on the total flows across NGC’s system boundaries

Transmission system model

Three pricing rules

• One price for generation and for demand in each zone (optimal)

• One price at each node for generation, but a common national price for demand

• One national price for generation and one national price for demand (actual system)– Constraints are managed via payments for

constrained-on and constrained-off running

What is welfare?

• NGC’s operating surplus– Kept the same under each of the rules

• Generators’ operating surpluses– Energy revenues less variable fuel costs– Gas contracts assumed not to be variable

• Consumer surplus– Area under their demand curve and above the

price they actually pay

Prices – winter peak

0

10

20

30

40

50

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 13

£/MWh

Optimal

G varying

Uniform

Prices – summer trough

0

2

4

6

8

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 13

£/MWh

Optimal

G varying

Uniform

Basic results

Pricing System Optimal Nodal (forGenerators)

Uniform

Av. Revenue (£/MWh) 27.17 27.39 28.21

Changes (% of optimal, competitive, revenue):

Consumer surplus -0.2% -3.4%

Generators’ profits -0.9% 2.1%

Welfare -1.2% -1.3%

Intuition for the results

• Adjustments to generation for constraints have to happen, whatever the pricing rule– Here, these are in the same direction as the

economic response to marginal losses

• Cost differences at stations partially offset marginal transmission losses

Market power

• Sometimes a problem in this market– General incentive to raise prices– Particular incentive to raise prices in import-

constrained area– Uniform pricing gives incentive to reduce

prices in export-constrained area

• Model two strategic generators plus fringe– Both firms change slope of bids (by region)

Generators’ capacities

0

2

4

6

8

10

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 9 10 8 12 13

Zone

GW OtherPowerGenNational Power

North

South-West

Prices – winter peak

0

25

50

75

100

125

150

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 13

£/MWh

Optimal MP Optimal

G varying MP G varying

Prices – summer trough

0

2

4

6

8

10

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 13

£/MWh

Optimal MP Optimal

G varying MP G varying

Prices – zone 12

0

25

50

75

100

125

150

Winterpeak

Trough Summerpeak

Trough

£/MWh MP Optimal

MP G varyingOptimal

G varyingUniform

Prices – zone 1

0

10

20

30

40

Winterpeak

Trough Summerpeak

Trough

£/MWh MP Optimal

MP G varyingOptimal

G varyingUniform

Market power

Pricing System Optimal Nodal (forGenerators)

Uniform

Av. Revenue (£/MWh) 44.70 46.90 45.25

Changes (% of optimal, competitive, revenue):

Consumer surplus -6.6% -1.0%

Generator profit 4.3% -2.1%

Welfare Rel. to optimal -2.3% -3.1%

Rel. to comp -5.4% -6.5% -7.2%

Conclusions of this study• Optimal pricing would create winners

(northern consumers, southern generators) and losers (northern generators, southern consumers)

• It would be less vulnerable to market power

• Welfare gains of 1% of turnover are quite large as Harberger triangles go!

Other transmission charges

• Connection assets – local costs• Capacity-based use of system

– Affect investment decision, not operating choices

• Output-based use of system– Affect operating choices and might be used to

offset consistent errors in the market rules

• Contracts for constrained running

Interactions between charges

• Investing generators should consider both spot market and transmission charges– With the right spot signals, transmission

charges should be uniform– Differentiated transmission charges needed if

spot prices send inadequate signals– Using both would over-signal, reducing

transmission costs, but raising generators’

Conclusion

• For major changes, transmission charging creates well-informed winners and losers– Gains typically small relative to transfers

• With good operators, the system is resilient to poor rules

• Better rules will create gains worth having

top related