82.mashallah.salarpour

Upload: uyustiarso8536

Post on 30-May-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    1/24

    The impact of trade liberalisation on the

    Iranian economy

    By

    Mashallah Salarpour

    A paper for the ICBM Bangkok

    November 2007

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    2/24

    2

    Abstract

    The war with Iraq and the subsequent embargo caused the economy of Iran to deteriorate

    from 1979 to 1988. The economic role of the Iranian government expanded during that

    time. The government rationed food and intervened in the pricing of most commodities. Italso paid subsidies on food, petrol and other productive inputs.

    To revive the economy, three five-year development plans were implemented after the end

    of the war with Iraq in 1988. Rations and subsidies were removed and the domination of

    the government over the economy was reduced by the deregulation of prices and exchange

    rates after 1989. Further, the government presence in the economy diminished in size by

    privatization from 1989 to 1993. The economy of Iran grew significantly in the third five-

    year development plan (2000-2005). Tariffication of non-tariff barriers, facilitating exportsand unifying exchange rates were successfully achieved during 2005.

    This study explains the results of trade reforms for a scenario where the government

    achieved the above aims and also reduced tariffs for all imported commodities under the

    Uruguay Round (UR) since 1995. The Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) analysis

    and input-output data for Iran using a base year, 1991, were applied simulating the short

    and long-run effects under the UR. It was proposed that 24 per cent and 27 per cent

    decreases in ad valorem tariffs on imported agricultural and non-agricultural commodities,respectively, could occur in the short run from 1995. The same scenario was simulated in

    the long run to examine the impact of trade reforms on Iran for the past decade. The

    macroeconomic and sectoral results of this scenario were analysed by considering the

    projections.

    The results confirm a positive impact on the economy of Iran if tariffs were reduced under

    the UR. Employment was estimated to grow by 2.4 per cent and real GDP increased by

    0.71 per cent in the short run and real GDP rose by 3.47 per cent in the long run. The

    aggregate capital stock and average real wage rose by 11.99 and 8.24 per cent, respectively,

    in the long run.

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    3/24

    3

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    4/24

    Introduction

    Governments in many countries have established many programs to keep their producers

    producing by supporting the domestic price. They levy import tariffs, allocate quotas or pay

    subsidies to defend their farmers and manufacturers. Thus, governments have implemented

    protection programs in developed countries in the hope (not always realised) that they will

    enable their producers to compete on the world market. In addition, sophisticated

    technologies, scale economies, provision of finance, high purchasing power and strong

    currency are other key factors creating success in trade with other countries. World trade is

    governed by a variety of agreements.

    Trade negotiation in the Dillon, Kennedy and Tokyo rounds caused substantial trade reform

    in industrial products in the early half of last century, while the members of WTO signed

    the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture (URAA) to reduce agricultural support and

    protection in 1994 (Athukorala, 2004). Most of the GATT rules were previously for

    manufacturing goods and domestic agricultural products were supported by import quotas,

    some non-tariff barriers (NTBs), and export subsidies but these restrictions should be

    removed under the URAA. Before URAA, most developed and developing countries had

    high levels of support for agricultural producers. For instance the USA and the EU spent

    US$26 billion in 1986 and US$34 billion in 1988, respectively, to support their agricultural

    producers (Overseas Development Institute, 1995).

    Under the Uruguay Round, members of WTO agreed in 1994 that developed countries

    would reduce tariff rates on agricultural products by an average of 36 per cent and on

    manufacturing goods by an average of 15 per cent over 6 years. Developing countries

    would cut the tariffs on agricultural products by an average rate of 24 per cent and onmanufacturing by an average rate of 27 per cent over 10 years (World Trade Organisation,

    2006). The URAA rules include three areas: market access, domestic support, and export

    competition. Market access consists of removing all non-tariff barriers and converting into

    bound tariff then also reducing tariff levels. Under URAA, developed countries should

    reduce tariffs by 36 per cent overall or a minimum of 15 per cent within 6 years and

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    5/24

    5

    developing countries by 24 per cent overall or a minimum of 10 per cent during 10 years.

    The members of WTO also agreed to remove export subsidies and domestic support.

    Developed countries reduce export subsidies by 21 per cent over 6 years and developing

    countries by 14 per cent over 10 years from the base year under URAA (Regmi et al.,

    2000).

    The reduction of tariffs and tariff quotas leads to growth in trade in developed and

    developing countries; whereas, it decreases government revenue especially in developing

    countries. Government revenue of some countries strongly depends on trade taxation. For

    example, Swaziland and Uganda tariff revenues were more than 40 per cent of all

    government revenue (Gallagher, 2006). The percentage share of tariffs in the Iranian

    government revenue was about 28 per cent in 2004 (Central Bank of Iran, 2005).

    Three development plans have been implemented by the government since 1989 to increase

    the rate of economic growth in Iran. The first five-year development plan covered the

    period from 1989 to 1994, and targeted a reduction in the size of the government through a

    privatization program, the removal of subsidies on food and medicine, and deregulation of

    investment and prices. Most prices were deregulated, a majority of subsidies were removed

    and non-oil exports volumes rose considerably.

    The second five-year development plan between 1995 and 1999 was designed to reduce

    subsidies on fuel (gas, petrol, gasoline), improve non-oil exports, and develop the capital

    market and stock exchanges. Non-tariff export barriers were eliminated in this plan but it

    was unsuccessful in achieving its targets. The reasons for this failure are explained in

    chapter two. In particular, the economic growth of Iran was curtailed by a dramatic fall in

    the oil price in 1998.

    The third fiveyear development plan targeted the removal of all non-tariff barriers to

    foreign trade, replacing them with tariffs. A facilitatory policy was designed to expand

    investment in industrial activities and export production in free trade zones. Reductions in

    fuel subsidies, programs to facilitate exports and a single exchange rate were also

    introduced in this plan. The results of this plan were notable: employment rose, the GDP

    growth rate was more than 5 per cent and non-oil exports grew rapidly because of trade

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    6/24

    6

    reforms. More explanation on the Iranian development plans, trade and monetary policies

    is offered in the next chapter.

    The above-mentioned tariffication of non-tariff barriers, unifying exchange rate and the

    removal of all non-oil export barriers were done in the third five-year development plan asthe country was aspiring to join the WTO. Economic policy in each development plan was

    based on advice from the International Monetary Fund (IMF). The International Monetary

    Fund (2004) acknowledged that the Iranian GDP growth rate was high (6.5 per cent) in

    2004 because of an increase in the oil price, and increased private and foreign investment.

    Manufacturing, mining, and employment rose, and domestic demand leapt as a result of an

    expansionary monetary policy. But inflation remained at 15.5 per cent at the same time.

    Iran had applied for WTO membership 19 times but had been rejected by the USA before

    giving permission to attend as an observer in May 2005. This study attempts to analyse the

    impacts of trade liberalisation on the economy of Iran for the past decade.

    The economy of Iran

    The economy of Iran

    The economy of Iran before the revolution (1973-1978)

    The Iranian economy has undergone positive and negative changes, promotion and

    disruptions, over the past 32 years (1973-2005). Oil export revenues have been around 80

    per cent of total export earnings, about 50 per cent of the government revenue and about 20

    per cent of GDP in Iran (Alexander's Gas&Oil Connections, 2002). Fluctuations in the oil

    price have had significant effects on the revenue of the government and created a lot of

    problems and shocks to the economy of Iran. A rise in the price of oil is favourable for the

    Iranian economy whereas a decline in oil prices causes economic crises. When OPEC

    adopted price-setting policies for oil, the price of oil rose sharply between 1973 and 1977.

    This price rise led to the successful implementation of the fourth and fifth development

    plans (1969-77) and an annual growth in GDP of more than 10 per cent during this period.

    Pre-revolution Iranian GDP approximately doubled during the eight years (1969-1977).

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    7/24

    7

    The first international oil price crisis in 1973 increased financial inflows to Iran and caused

    a substantial increase in the money supply. Thus, inflation grew dramatically between 1973

    and 1977. After 1977, the price of oil fell to about US$15 per barrel, which led to a decline

    in Iranian government revenue. Oil revenue dropped from US$20,713 million in 1977 to

    US $17,867 million in 1978. The government borrowed from the Central Bank of Iran. A

    sharp decrease in GDP by 12 per cent below the peak level recorded in 1979 resulted due to

    cuts in the budget in 1978. Because of the economic recession that followed, the gap in the

    level of income grew quickly, making Iranian people dissatisfied with the government in

    early 1979 (United Nations Industrial Development Organization, 1999).

    The economy after the revolution (from February 1979 to October 1980)

    A change in government in February 1979 led to a rapid decline in GDP of about 8 per centbecause of transitional dislocation. The second international oil crisis in late 1979 and 1980

    allowed the current account of Iran to recover, leading to a current account surplus of some

    US $12 billion. A trade embargo by Irans greatest trading partner (the USA) at the time

    weakened the economy of Iran because Iran was strongly dependent on imported American

    commodities. However, the oil price continued to rise and oil revenue increased, so

    demand for goods went up and inflation rose 21 per cent by 1980 (United Nations

    Industrial Development Organization, 1999). As 50 per cent of government revenue is due

    to oil earnings (Esser, 2005) the Iranian government plays a crucial role in the provision of

    foreign currency (Moradi, 2002). Prior to the revolution, the gap between the official and

    free exchange rates was small. It widened dramatically from 1979. These exchange rates

    closed in 1992 when the government of the time introduced a new exchange rate regime.

    Eight years of war (1980-1988)

    Another external shock to the Iranian economy occurred when Iraq attacked Iran in

    October 1980. A substantial decrease in international oil prices added to the war shock

    between 1982 and 1986. These events prompted a substantial reduction in Irans foreign

    exchange earnings and forced the government to increase borrowing from the banking

    system. The government raised the countrys money supply by approximately 18 per cent

    from 1979 to 1988, and the annual inflation rate reached 19.3 per cent. By the time Iran

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    8/24

    8

    signed a cease-fire with Iraq in 1988, its economy was extremely weak and its population

    had grown from 37.2 million to about 52 million. The first decade after the revolution

    (1979-1989) was characterized by declining per capita income, inflationary pressures, and a

    lack of employment opportunities for unskilled labour. The importance of the government

    in the economy expanded rapidly after 1979. Eight years of bombing of cities and

    infrastructure wore the people down and collapsed the economy of Iran. A decline in oil

    prices from US$30.60 per barrel to US$13.30 caused a reduction in oil earnings from about

    US$20,000 million to about US$ 6,250 million per year and produced a budget deficit, a

    reduction in the money supply and further inflationary pressure during the period from

    1982 to 1986. Therefore, the government rationed some foods and established an institute

    to control the wholesale and retail prices of goods. Five-year development plans and

    recovery

    Literature review

    Many world-wide studies are available for review, but here our aim is to focus on the

    Middle East and application CGE model in Iran

    Static models

    The static CGE model is a generalization of the simple input-output (I-O) model. It

    comprises equations of consumption demand and production supply, demand for factors

    and intermediate goods, market clearance, income and expenditure of government and so

    on. The functions of demand for factors and intermediate commodities are derived in the

    model and the data are required in I-O form for one year. Cobb-Douglas production and

    utility functions are used, resulting in calculations which are simpler with linear and

    nonlinear equations. Furthermore, they can write a complicated model and calibrate it in

    the linear functions. CGE models are based on neoclassical general equilibrium theory

    (Monaco, 1997).

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    9/24

    9

    Atici (2002) studied the impacts of full trade liberalisation on household groups in the

    Turkish economy using a static-CGE model. He considered three scenarios: the removal of

    tariffs, elimination of the export subsidy, and elimination of both tariff and export

    subsidies. The results show that tobacco production decreased by about 31 per cent and

    manufactures by 2 per cent while other agricultural outputs such as agribusiness and

    services increased in the first scenario of a tariff cut. The first scenario had an influence on

    increasing household income at different levels in urban and rural areas but the revenue of

    Turkeys government declined by 18 per cent. Moreover, it led to a 19 per cent

    depreciation in the Turkish currency. The second scenario expanded agribusiness

    government revenue and the exchange rate by 2.36, 3.76 and 1.67 per cent respectively but

    other effects were less than one per cent. The third scenario had a decrease in tobacco and

    manufactures output, similar to the first scenario, but household incomes declined because

    of the reduction in factor earnings. However, the elimination of export subsidies

    compensated for the loss of government revenue in comparison to the first scenario (from

    18 per cent to 13 per cent).

    Konan and Maskus (1999) analysed tax reform and tariff unification in Egypt. They

    improved an earlier Egyptian CGE model to simulate the impact of reforms in the tax

    system, capital tax and tariff structure on welfare in Egypt. The results of tax reform were a

    one per cent gain in welfare in respect to fixed factor prices and the exchange rate. Konan

    and Maskus studied the impacts of trade policy reform alone as well. Firstly, tariff rates on

    all imports were unified at 10 per cent; secondly, they tested the model under a free trade

    agreement with the European Union; and finally, they assessed full unilateral tariff

    liberalisation. The results of shocking the model by the three trade policies indicate the

    largest gain from unification at 10 per cent; the FTA with EU lowered welfare. In the full

    trade liberalisation scenario, the welfare gain was 0.89 per cent and there was a smalldepreciation in Egypts currency value. When the reform was a complex of tariff and tax

    reforms, the welfare gain rose to 1.09 per cent. Konan and Maskus concluded that tax and

    trade limitations led to a distortion of commodity consumption and capital usage and that

    reform would bring a welfare gain to Egypt.

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    10/24

    10

    Khondker and Raihan (2004) used a standard multi-sector, multi-factor and multi-

    household CGE model to examine the impacts of policy reforms on allocation of resources,

    income distribution and poverty for Bangladesh. Their model calibrates the social

    accounting matrix (SAM) of Bangladesh to 1995/1996. This model has three sectors

    (Agriculture, Industry and Services) and two institutions (1-Household 2-both Government

    and rest of the world). Agriculture is disaggregated to crops and non-crops; crops consist of

    traded products and non-traded products such as rice. Non-crops are branched into two

    groups, traded and non-traded. Traded crops include items such as livestock and fish,

    whereas non-traded are domestic fixed goods (for example, forestry). Households were

    disaggregated into rural and urban. Also, each of these categories are disaggregated into

    three further groups. Rural has three levels: the first group is household labour, the second

    group is small farmers and the third group is large farmers. Urban is comprised of low

    skilled, medium skilled and professionals. Equivalent variations (EV) and Foster-Greer-

    Thorbecke (FGT) measures were applied to forecast welfare and poverty changes in

    Bangladesh. The model is simulated by applying three shocks: tariffs are eliminated

    completely and new taxes are imposed to fix government revenue, ready-made garments

    export is decreased by 25 per cent in quantity, and remittances to Bangladesh are increased

    by 50 per cent.

    The effects of these shocks show that complete trade liberalisation results in a welfare loss

    for households. Households are worse-off in rural regions and poorer households in urban

    areas suffer from higher welfare losses. The results of FGT measures show higher poverty

    in urban than in rural areas. The second shock generates a fall in total exports and

    consequently a decrease in GDP. Declining GDP aggravates welfare when it is calculated

    by equivalent variation analysis. Finally, increasing remittances only raises urban incomes

    and does not lead to increases in total benefits as most people who send money from

    overseas to Bangladesh emigrated from cities.

    The results of a tariff reduction in Pakistan were estimated by Sidiqui and Iqbal (2001). A

    CGE model was built and data used based on a SAM for 1989/90. It is a neoclassical model

    and has a constant elasticity of transformation (CET) assumption for the domestic market

    and exports, and constant elasticity of substitution (CES) assumption for imported and

    domestically produced goods. The production function is Cobb-Douglas with constant

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    11/24

    11

    returns to scale and unit elasticity of substitution between inputs. It has two factors, labour

    and capital. This model comprises five sectors: agriculture, industry, education, health and

    others. Four institutions are described: households, firms, government and the rest of the

    world. The institutions receive income from the endowments of primary factors and their

    rental values, which in turn are used for consumption and investment. If the exchange rate

    is fixed and the current account balance is exogenous, prices of imports will decline by

    16.37 per cent when the tariff rate is reduced by 80 per cent. This tariff reduction causes

    increases in real income due to price decline and an improvement in income equality. The

    share of labour in GDP increases while that of capital decreases.

    Siddiqui and Kemal (2002) studied the effects of remittances, trade liberalisation and

    poverty in Pakistan using the same CGE model and SAM data. The model entailed two

    simulations. The first simulation eliminated tariffs and the second used a decrease in

    remittance inflow. The tariff reduction produced more welfare gain for urban than for rural

    regions and the decrease in poverty was greater in urban areas than in rural areas. There

    was a positive correlation between remittance inflow and both welfare and poverty

    reduction.

    Daryanto (1999) researched the role of agriculture in the growth of the Indonesian

    economy. He used a CGE model for Indonesia and emphasized agriculture. A decline in

    the price of oil and agricultural exports, agricultural development and tax policy were some

    of the changes that he used to get results. The effects of an oil price reduction by 50 per

    cent showed a strong linkage between the government budget and the rest of the economy.

    Consequently, a decline in oil price decreased welfare in urban areas. A decrease in the

    export price of agricultural products diminished agricultural production and as a result

    farmers real income decreased in Indonesia.

    Chadha et al. (1997) analysed the impacts of economic reform in India in a study done for

    the National Council of Applied Economic Research (NCAER) using a CGE model.

    Reform was described by a reduction in tariffs and Non Trade Barriers (NTBs) on imports,

    and these reforms plus a reduction in export subsidies. A five per cent increase in GDP was

    identified as a result of full reform in India. Trade liberalisation brought about a positive

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    12/24

    12

    shift in agriculture and efficiency, and a significant improvement was found in Indias

    manufacturing sector.

    Japans Official Development Assistance (ODA) delivers government aid to developing

    countries. One of the ODA schemes is providing loans to developing countries at lowinterest rates, dependent on whether or not the initial payment is to be paid back. Kawasaki

    (2002) assessed the effects of ODAs loan on six Asian countries: China, Indonesia,

    Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand and Vietnam. He also studied the impacts of unilateral

    trade liberalisation of Japanese imports from those countries. In order to analyse these

    impacts, a GTAP model was adopted and simulated. This model is not a forecasting CGE

    model and only shows the difference between when cooperation measures were applied

    and when they were not. The assessment shows that investment and the real GDP of the six

    Asian countries receiving loans increased because of the ODA loans. Also loans to these

    countries produced economic welfare gains, but the welfare gains to Japan from trade

    liberalisation were much greater.

    Application of CGE Model for Iran

    Several researchers have applied the CGE model to Iran since 1995. A static CGE model

    has been adopted to study the effects of trade reform and subsidy reduction on energy,

    medicine, food and agriculture in Iran. These policies could have negative and positiveeffects on the economy and each sector of economic activity if implemented. In this section

    a number of CGE assessments are reviewed and the impacts of trade liberalisation and

    subsidy reduction on the economy of Iran are explained briefly.

    A multi-sector CGE model was used by Jensen and Tarr (2002) to analyse the impacts of

    trade, foreign exchange and energy policy reforms on welfare in Iran. They highlighted two

    exchange rates in 1999: the official rate and the market exchange rate for a US dollar. The

    difference between these exchange rates provided a subsidy for imports equal to 79 percent. They also pointed out that the prices of petrol and gasoline were 10 per cent of the

    world price in Iran, and that the government paid a subsidy on petroleum products of

    between 74 and 94 per cent. There were 20 types of households, 10 urban households and

    10 rural households with different levels of income in the model. They found that

    tariffication and a reduction in the tariff rate to 15 per cent caused an increase in aggregate

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    13/24

    13

    welfare by 5.5 per cent. If this scenario is combined with the elimination of non-trade

    barriers, the incomes of the poorest rural and urban household could increase by 20 and 11

    per cent respectively. Furthermore, the combination of exchange rate unification and

    energy reform (removing all energy subsidies) would increase aggregate welfare by 39 per

    cent. The poorest rural households gained (239 per cent) and the poorest urban households

    gained (116 per cent) as a result of the energy reform. Jensen and Tarr estimated that the

    aggregate welfare gains for the Iranian economy were 50.7 per cent due to applying zero

    tariffs, unification of the exchange rate and zero petroleum subsidies. They also argued that

    there is a great opportunity for Iran to help the poor with direct income payments.

    Salami et al (1995) presented a paper using the CGE model about Irans economy at the

    2002 Annual Meeting of Canadian Economics Association held at University of Calgary .

    They simulated the CGE model of Iran in the short run. The results showed that factor-

    neutral technical change had a positive effect on the imports of non-trade and competing

    sectors, but a negative effect on exports. The growth of the neutral technical rate of change

    on factors would lead to an increase in employment and real GDP, but it could cause a

    trade deficit. Conversely, labour-saving capital-using technical change showed a negative

    effect on employment and GDP while resulting in growth of imports and exports. The

    subsidy reduction would decrease employment and real GDP in Iran.

    Esalmi (2005) studied the effects of agricultural land productivity on the economy of Iran

    using a 25-sector CGE model and Iranian inputoutput table for 1991. The model was

    simulated for the elimination of domestic and international market barriers. His results

    revealed that removing trade barriers will increase agricultural land productivity if it

    includes a suitable trade policy. Furthermore, an increase in the agricultural sector leads to

    growth in food manufacturing and employment. This policy also decreases food prices and

    causes an increase in welfare, real GDP and food security.

    Likewise, Zolnoor(2002) assessed the effects of trade liberalisation on the economy of Iran

    by applying a CGE model. Using input-output data for Iran with the base year 1991, he

    points out that trade liberalisation increases GDP. In addition, an increase in manufacturing

    tariffs leads to growth in agriculture, manufacturing and the construction sectors but a

    decline in services.

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    14/24

    14

    Methodology: The Iranian CGE Model

    The Iranian CGE model is calibrated with the input-output table based on data of 1991. The

    theoretical structure of the model will now be explained.

    Structure of production

    Each industry can produce several commodities by using a number of inputs. According to

    specific assumptions, a multi-input, multi-output production structure is applied in the

    model. The relationship between inputs and outputs can be formulated by a production

    function. Inputs are composed of primary factors, intermediate goods and other costs.Figure A-1 illustrates schematically the structure of production. Primary factors (land,

    capital and labour) are combined with the constant elasticity of substitution (CES) function

    at the bottom level of the nested structure. A CES production function was used to combine

    land, labour and capital in producing units of primary factor in the formulation of equation

    4-1.

    1,

    1,

    )(

    =

    = ijnh

    jiijj XAZ

    i =1,, h and j =1,,n (4-1)

    Where Zj the CES is production function for industry j or is the aggregate factors for

    industry j.A is a positive coefficient, ij is a distribution parameter with i from 1 to h for

    primary factors (Capital, Labour and Land) and 1 to n for industries. Xij is primary factor i

    used in industryj, is a substitution parameter that is greater than zero and the elasticity of

    substitution is equal to +11

    .

    This structure was selected for all industries because we assume that the structure of

    production is the same in different sectors in Iran. Moreover, this assumption decreases the

    number of equations and calculations required. The domestically-produced and imported

    intermediate inputs are combined in the same way, using the CES form. Among

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    15/24

    15

    intermediate inputs, there is imperfect substitution. In addition, at a higher level (Activity),

    aggregate intermediate and aggregate primary inputs are combined with other costs through

    a Leontief production function to produce outputs. Aggregate primary factors, intermediate

    inputs and other costs cannot be substituted for each other. The Leontief production

    function is equivalent to a CES production function with the substitution elasticity set to

    zero. It is a fixed proportion production function that factors are always used in fixed ratios.

    This function only operates along the ray where it shows a constant ratio of factors.

    Figure A-1 The Structure of Production

    Demand for primary factors (labour, land and capital)

    To determine the composition of demand for primary factors, total primary factor

    costs)(

    1

    =

    h

    i

    iiXP are minimised subject to the following production function:

    pp

    i

    n

    i

    ijXZ

    1

    1

    )(

    =

    = (4-2)

    The associated first-order conditions are:

    Domestic Good 1 Imported Good 1Capital

    Im orted Good GDomestic Good G

    LabourLand

    CESCES

    Good GGood 1

    CES

    Primary factorsup to

    Other Costs

    Output

    Leontief

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    16/24

    16

    )1(

    1

    )1(

    +

    =

    +

    =

    =

    h

    i

    iikk

    k

    kXX

    X

    ZP (4-3)

    Where

    is the Lagrange coefficient.

    Thus

    +=

    1)(k

    i

    i

    k

    i

    k

    X

    X

    P

    P

    (4-4)

    Then substituteXi into the production function and solve forXk to derive conditional factor

    demand for primary factors in the form:

    )1(

    1

    1

    1

    +

    +

    =

    ave

    kkk

    PPZX

    (4-5)

    The percentage change form of this equation is:

    )( avekk ppzx = where k= land, labour and capital (4-6)

    and avep is the average price.

    =

    =h

    i

    iiave PSp1

    ,

    +=

    1

    1and

    ++

    ++

    =

    11

    1

    11

    1

    ik

    iii

    P

    PS ,

    is a parameter and S is the share of costs for each primary factor.

    Equation (4-6) shows that a percentage increase in output and average price of other factors

    leads to a percentage increase in demand for this input. For instance, if the prices of land

    and capital are increased, demand for labour will grow relatively. A contrary relationship is

    portrayed between demand for labour and its price, where a one per cent increase in labour

    price decreases demand for labour in the percentage form.

    Equation (4-6) is rewritten with technical change as:

    xk-ak= z-(pk+akpave) (4-7)

    where akis technical change for each factor.

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    17/24

    17

    Technical changes are constant in the CGE model, but if they do change the improvement

    in technology (the growth of the technical change) reduces demand for inputs. For instance,

    demand for labour often declines when technology replaces labour. In equation (4-7), the

    technical change has a direct negative effect and an indirect effect on the demand for

    factors. Depending on the elasticity of substitution among factors, an increase in the

    technical change of one factor reduces demand for it.

    Household demand

    The nesting structure for household demand is illustrated in Figure A-2. At the bottom

    level, domestic and imported goods are consumed by residents according to a constant

    elasticity of substitution (CES) function. Utility per household is derived from the Klein-

    Rubin utility function:

    c

    ccc

    XQ

    U )(

    1=

    (4-30)

    where Q is the number of households; Xc is total consumption of good C; c is the

    subsistence level of consumption of good C; and c is the marginal budget share of good c.

    0 c 1 and c=1. To determine the source-specific commodity demand, the utility

    function is maximised subject to household budgets (PcXc). Equation (4-31) shows its

    percentage form:

    xH

    cs H

    cs = xH

    c-s H

    [pH

    cs + H

    cs - pH

    c-s] (4-31)

    wherexHcs is the percentage change of household demand for commodity C and source S,

    xH

    c-s is household demand for the import/domestic composite of commodity C in

    percentage form. Hcs is a households basic taste change;pH

    cs is the percentage change in

    the purchase price of commodity c from source s. pHc-s is the percentage change in the

    value of the import/domestic composite of commodity c and H is the Armington elasticity

    of substitution between import and domestic commodities for households.

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    18/24

    18

    Figure A-2 The structure of Household Demand

    Demand for the import/domestic composite of commodities has a positive effect on

    household demand for commodity Cand source S. An increase in the purchasing price of

    commodity C decreases household demand for commodity C. The price growth of

    commodities which can be replaced with good Cin consumption causes a rise in demand

    for S. A change in household taste for a commodity alters demand for it and for substitute

    commodities. If this change is negative, the demand for the commodity will be reduced. A

    negative change in household tastes for substitute commodities for commodity Cleads to

    an increase in the demand for commodity C.

    Consumption demand for imported and domestic goods is divided into two sections. There

    are demands for luxury and subsistence categories. A households budget is spent on twokinds of goods, subsistence and luxury goods, thus:

    XT(c) = Xsub(c)+Xlux(c). (4-32)

    Domestic good 1 Imported good 1 Imported good CDomestic good C

    CES CES

    Good CGood 1 Up to

    Klein Rubin

    Household Utility

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    19/24

    19

    Total household demand is separated into demand for subsistence goods (Xsub) and luxury

    goods (Xlux). If Vc was the household budget, optimal expenditure on goods would be

    equal to this budget such that:

    Vc =PcXc (4-33)

    where Xc.is the subsistence category and PcXc is expenditure on each subsistence good.

    Hence, the sum of the households luxury costs is derived as follows.

    C = V -PcXc (4-34)

    Expenditure on luxury goods is derived from the remainder of the household budget after

    spending on subsistence goods. Therefore, the household expenditure function contains the

    cost of subsistence and luxury goods (equation 4-35).

    PcXc = Pcc + c(V-PcXc) (4-35)

    Or

    PcXc = Pcc + cC (4-36)

    where c is luxury good c and c is the marginal budget share of good c (0c1 and

    c=1). Total household demand for a commodity as a percentage change is derived by

    differentiating equation (4-35) with respect to x and dividing PcXc resulting in:

    xc =c( - pc) (4-37)

    where c equals

    =

    c

    c

    cc

    c

    XXP

    C 1 , with its supernumerary proportion of total expenditure on

    Xc, and = dC/Cis the percentage change in aggregate expenditure for luxury goods.

    Equation (4-38) shows the percentage change in total household demand:

    xH= xsub + xlux (4-38)

    where demand for supernumerary goods in percentage changes is written as:

    xlux + pc = wlux + alux (4-39)

    pc is the consumer price index, wlux is total nominal supernumerary household expenditure

    and alux is the taste change for supernumerary demand.

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    20/24

    20

    Also the total demand for subsistence can be seperated by:

    Xsub = Q Asub (4-40)

    WhereAsub is the individual household subsistence level (Horridge, 2003).

    Its percentage change form is:

    xsub = q + asub (4-41)

    Here q is the number of households and asub is a taste change for subsistence demand.

    Results and conclusion

    Table a.1 Macroeconomic Results of Trade Reforms under UR

    (Percentage changes)

    Variable Description Short run Long run

    Employ_ireal wagex0gdpexpx3totdelBx0imp_cp3totp4totp5totp6totx1cap_i

    x1prim_ix2tot_ix5tot

    Aggregate employment: wage bill weightsAverage real wageReal GDP from expenditure sideReal household consumption(Nominal balance of trade)/[nominal GDP](change) Import volume index, duty-paid weightsConsumer price indexExports price index, local currencyGovernment price indexInventories price indexAggregate capital stock, rental weights

    Aggregate effective primary factor useAggregate real investment expenditureGovernment consumption

    2.450*0.710*-0.0210.99-13.52-4.14-15.07-16.920*

    1.060*0*

    0*11.993.47-2.830*17-13.95-7.62-10.66-15.488.24

    3.878.92-2.83

    *- Exogenous variables which were not changed in the simulations based on assumptions

    The macroeconomic impacts of trade reforms on GDP and overall employment are

    significant. Real GDP might expand over 0.71 per cent in the short run. (see Table above).

    Falling domestic prices of inputs encourage export producers to produce more. With zero

    change in real wages, the results in the short run show a 2.4 per cent increase in demand for

    labour. The labour-intensive and export industries can expand employment.

    Table a.1 illustrates the striking outcome of a 22.77 per cent increase in exports. Imports

    could get a boost because of falling prices in the domestic market (by 11 per cent) through

    the tariff reduction. Thus, this could produce a deficit in the trade balance. The delB

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    21/24

    21

    proportion (Nominal trade balance/[nominal GDP]) shows a deficit in the trade balance (of

    0.02 per cent) due to the reduction in tariffs.

    Similarly the CGE model is simulated by a 24 per cent decrease in the tariff on agricultural

    products and a 27 per cent tariff reduction on non-agricultural goods. The results show an11.99 per cent rise in the average real wage is due to tariff reductions under the UR.

    The implementation of the model has been explained and then the results of both the short-

    run and the long-run tariff reduction under the Uruguay Round have been analysed in this

    chapter. The results were divided into macroeconomic and sectoral results. As is shown by

    the results discussed in preceding sections, Iran would gain from tariff cuts, boosting

    production in export and export-related industries. In addition, industries which employed

    abundant factors might expand and the sectors servicing these industries could also grow in

    the long run. Trade liberalisation in the long run would have a stronger effect than in the

    short run on production, level of exports, and employment.

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    22/24

    22

    Bibliography

    Aksoy, M. A. & Beghin, J. C. (2005), Global agricultural trade and developing countries. TheInternational Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank, 17-71.

    Alexander's Gas & Oil Connections. (2002), Thursday, June 27, 2002,EIA country analysis:

    Iran. Retrieved 2/9/2006, 2006, www.gasandoil.com/goc/nesw/ntm22674.htm

    Arndt, C., Robinson, S. & Tarp, F. (2001), Parameter estimation for a computable generalequilibrium model: A maximum entropy approach (Discussion Paper No. 40). TMDIFPRI,Washington.

    Atici, C. (2002). The impacts of a complete trade liberalization on household groups in Turkisheconomy. Paper presented at the Erc/METU International Conference in Economics VI, Ankara,Turkey.

    Central Bank of Iran. (2005),Annual review. Central Bank of Iran, Tehran.

    Central Bank of Iran. (2004), Gross national product and income by economic sector. CentralBank of Iran, Tehran.

    Chadha, R., Alan, S. P., Deardorff, A. V. and Stern, R. M. (1997),Analysis of India's policyreforms (Discussion Paper No.413). School of Public Policy University of Michigan, Michigan.

    Daryanto, A. (1999), Growth and change in Indonesian economy: The role of the agriculturalsector. Unpublished PhD thesis, UNE, Armidale.

    Dupuy, A. (2005),Hicks neutral technical change revisited: CGE production function andinformation of general order(Working Paper No. 6). Faculty of Economics & BusinessAdministration, University of Maastricht, Netherlands.

    Esser, C. (2005), OPEC revenues: Country details, Iran, Retrieved June 14, 2006, fromhttp://www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/cabs/orevcoun.html

    Estelami, H. (1999), A study of Iran's responses to U.S. economic sanctions.Middle East Reviewof International Affairs Vol.3, pp.51-61.

    Harrison, W. J. & Pearson, K. R. (2002),An Introduction to GEMPACK: Document No. GPD1-GPD8. GEMPACK User documentation, Vol. 1-8., Centre of Policy Studies and Impact Project,Melbourne.

    International Monetary Fund (2004),Islamic republic of Iran: 2004 (Staff report No. 04/306).International Monetary Fund (IMF), Washington.

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    23/24

    23

    International Monetary Fund. (2004),Islamic Republic of Iran: 2004 Article IV consultation-staffreport (Staff-Report No. 04/308). International Monetary Fund, Washington.

    International Monetary Fund. (2004),Islamic Republic of Iran: 2004,IMF concludes article IVconsultation with the Islamic Republic of Iran (Staff Report No. 04/109). International MonetaryFund,Washington.

    Iranian Parliament Research Centre. (2004), Protest to the low of the fourth five-yeardevelopment plan. (The low 3), Retrieved February 22, 2004, http://www.majlis.ir/mhtml/

    Jensen, I. (2001), The Leontief open production model. Retrieved October 12, 2005,http://online.redwoods.cc.ca.us/instruct/darnold/laproj/Fall2001/Iris/lapaper.pdf

    Jensen, J. & Tarr, D. (2002), Trade, foreign exchange, and energy policies in the IslamicRepublic of Iran. (Working Paper No. 2768). The World Bank, Development Research Group,Washington.

    Kawasaki, K. (2002), The impact of Japanese economic cooperation on Asian economicdevelopment. (Discussion Paper No. 16). Economic and Social Research Institute, Tokyo.

    Khondker, B. H. & Raihan, S. (2004). Welfare and poverty impacts of policy reforms inBangladesh. Paper presented at the Northwest Unversities Development Consortium Conference(NEUDC), HEC Montreal, Canada.

    Konan, D. E. & Maskus, K. E. (1999),Joint trade liberalization and tax reform in a small openeconomy: The case of Egypt(Seminar Paper No. 97-13). Centre for International EconomicStudies, Adelaide.

    Manchin, M. (2004), The economic effects of a Russia-EU FTA (Discussion paper No. 131/2).Tinbergen Institute, Amsterdam.

    Monaco, R. M. (1997),A brief review of alternative approaches to inter-sectoral policy analysisand forecasting (Working Paper No. 97-2004). Department of Economics, University ofMaryland, USA.

    Moradi, M. A. (2002).Nonlinear modelling of inflation in Iran. Paper presented at the PolicyModelling Conference, Brussels, EcoMod Net.

    Oktaviani, R. & Drynan, R. G. (2000). The impact of APEC trade liberalisation on theIndonesian economy and agricultural sector. Paper presented at the Third Annual Conference onGlobal Economic Analysis, Melbourne, Australia.

    Overseas Development Institute. (1995),Developing countries in the WTO. Retrieved March 28,2006, www.odi.org.uk/publications/briefing/odi_developing.html

  • 8/14/2019 82.Mashallah.Salarpour

    24/24

    Pradhan, B. K. & Sahoo, A. (1998),MIMAP-India CGE model (Research Paper, 2-6, November1998). International Development Research Centre, New Delhi.

    Regmi, A., Trueblood, T. & Shapouri, S. (2000),Emerging trade issues for developing countries.Economic Research Service/USDA, Washington.

    Salami, H., Alavalapti, J. & Veeman, T. (1995).Effects of technical change and subsidies in theagricultural sector on the economy of Iran: A general equilibrium analysis. Paper presented atthe Sixth international CGE Modelling Conference, University of Waterloo, Ontario, Canada.

    Siddiqui, R. & Kemal, A. R. (2002),Remittances, trade liberalization and poverty in Pakistan:The role of excluded variables in poverty change analysis. Globalization and Poverty, Vol. 1, pp.4-16 and 31-44.

    Sidiqui, R. & Iqbal, Z. (2001), Tariff reduction and functional income distribution in Pakistan: ACGE model (Technical Paper No. 10). Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.

    Siriwardana, M. & Dollery, B. (2003),An empirical analysis of the proposed Australia-Japanfree trade agreement(Working paper No. 2003-2). University of New England, School ofEconomics, Armidale.

    Siriwardana, M. & Iddamalgoda, A. (2003),Effects of the economic crisis on Singapore and itspolicy responses. University of New England Asia Centre (6, 2003), pp.1-16.

    Statistical Centre of Iran. (2006), Publications information base. Retrieved 14/6/2006, 2006,http://amar.sci.org.ir/

    Tarr, D., Fane, G., Madani, D., Jensen, J., Mazo, K. & Sperling, A. (2001), Trade and foreign

    exchange policies in Iran (Report No. 22953-IRN). Social and Economic Development Group,Middle East and Africa Region, The World Bank.

    United Nations Industrial Development Organization. (1999),Islamic Republic of Iran: Industrialsector survey on the potential for non-oil manufactured exports (No. NC/IRA/94/01D/08/37).United Nations Industrial Development Organization.

    World Trade Organisation (WTO). (2006), The agriculture agreement: new rules andcommitment. Retrieved March 28, 2006, www.wto.org/